Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 9

What are the challenges and associated solutions for companies working

together in Collective Action to fight corruption?

By Cornelius Dube, 20 April 2009

Abstract

This paper discusses corruption as referring to the offering, giving, receiving, or


soliciting, directly or indirectly of anything of value to influence improperly the actions
of another party. It focuses on corruption by agents at company level; implying those
corrupt activities financed by the companies and intended to benefit the company rather
than individuals. Participation by companies in these activities has resulted in the
prisoner’s dilemma strategy, where the dominant strategy is to participate in corruption,
as refraining to do so would enhance competitors’ chances of getting the associated
product or service. This has resulted in the creation of another market, the ‘corruption
market’, intertwined with the product or service market.

The paper discusses the challenges that the existence of the ‘corruption market’ poses
towards a collective action by the business in fighting corruption. These include the
difficulty in getting more details on its operations; getting competitors to avoid
participating when each has an incentive to cheat; challenges in initiating the collective
action process; financing of the collective action process and the factors outside the
business sector’s influence such as the pressure exerted by the public sector.

The paper recommends the use of existing bodies and associations in the business sector
in overcoming each of these challenges. This would see the establishment of a Committee
to oversee the whole process, which would also be part of a national reference group to
get buy-in from national stakeholders. Thus, while the efforts by the business sector in
collective action would significantly reduce corruption, an initiative involving all
stakeholders initiated by the business would achieve more. The starting point however
would be the business sector, as they are the most active participant in the corruption
market.

1. Introduction

Normally, when the word corruption is mentioned, what comes into the mind is a
government/public official being involved in underhand dealings with a private entity or
person. This is just one facet of corruption, normally referred to as private-to-public
corruption in that a private player would be paying some additional unofficial payments
to the public official for some business gain. The common definition of corruption as the
abuse of public office for private gain may also be taken to imply that private entities or
players by themselves, away from the public offices can not be corrupt. However, focus

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


on corruption has since moved to all players in the market and not only on public
officials.

On its website, Transparency International defines corruption as the misuse of entrusted


power for personal or private gain. It becomes apparent that any individual who finds
himself with some position of power can be corrupt, regardless of whether the individual
is from the public or private sector. Most importantly, the private sector players may be
involved in corruption on their own without public officials, normally referred to as
private-to-private corruption. Thus arguably the private sector players are the more active
players in the ‘corruption market’ than the public officials.

While understanding the merits of the arguments presented by some authors that there
could be some positive sides to corruption, such as in speeding up processes that could be
delayed by bureaucratic tendencies or its role as a price mechanism to correct
disequilibria in resource allocation (Clarke and Xu, 2001), the negative sides of
corruption are well documented and will far outweigh any purported positives.
Corruption steeply increases business costs, as it adds up to about 10% to the total cost of
doing business globally, up to 25% to the cost of procurement contracts in developing
countries, and its costs constitute more than 5% of global GDP (International Chamber of
Commerce, Transparency International, the United Nations Global Compact and the
World Economic Forum Partnering Against Corruption Initiative, 2008). Corruption
scares away foreign investors, thereby preventing job creation and limiting sustainable
development, and acts as a real barrier to development and business growth over time at
company, industry, national and global levels (World Bank Institute, 2008).

This paper focuses on the business’s role in corruption and how such actions have further
made it more challenging for companies to work together in collective action to fight
corruption. Its focus is on corruption aimed at benefiting the company rather than the
individual, the assumption being that it would be a company sanctioned venture, as the
costs to facilitate it would be financed by the company. The context therefore includes
both private-to-private corruption and private-to-public corruption, and not ‘petty
corruption’, which takes place at lower levels of the administration (Boehm, 2007).
Corruption in this context is therefore the offering, giving, receiving, or soliciting,
directly or indirectly of anything of value to influence improperly the actions of another
party (IFI Anti-corruption Task Force, 2006).Thus corruption discussed here could be
with respect to bribery, extortion, or even state capture but the participants would be
doing so in their capacity as representatives of companies.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 describes how business has
managed to create a ‘corruption market’ and the associated challenges that this brings
towards a collective approach to fighting corruption. Section 3 proposes some
mechanisms through which companies, in consultation with other stakeholders, can use
to address such challenges. Concluding remarks then follow in section 4.

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


2. Business Challenges in fighting corruption

2.1 The ‘Corruption Market’

Companies generally engage in corruption as a way of beating their rivals to a service. In


other words, corruption is regarded as a way of surviving competition albeit unfairly. As
such it is business that is both the victim and the perpetrator; while one company is
successful in landing a bid or service through the use of corruption; others are counting
their losses due to this unfair competition. It is also apparent that companies are very
much aware of instances in which they have lost out because of corruption, either
because they have also participated before or because they have been informally
informed. PricewaterhouseCoopers International (2008) reported that in a survey almost
45% of respondents say they have not entered a specific market or pursued a particular
opportunity because of corruption risks. In other words, due to fear that they can not
fairly compete in the corruption prone market, the number of players is substantially
lower than its potential, giving higher probability of success for corruption to the
remaining companies. About 39% also said their company has lost a bid because of
corrupt officials, and 42% say their competitors pay bribes. If such a high percentage is
victims of corruption, it is difficult to imagine that there could only be one or two
companies that have so many victims. Rather it is apparent that there are many
companies that are involved, some preferring to compete all the way along. In such a
process, companies are now also competing for corruption in addition to the associated
service or product; hence the existence of a ‘corruption market’.

It is not difficult to understand how the competition for corruption comes about even
though the ‘corruption market’ can be difficult to delineate outside the associated
product/service market. A firm will not necessarily know the number of firms who will be
willing to participate in corruption, even though the number of firms in the market is
known. Thus a prisoner’s dilemma situation would come out, where a firm has to decide
whether to pay the corruption cost (say a bribe for example) or not. The firm will know
that if any of its competitors pay the bribe, then its chance will decrease, hence the
strategy to pay the bribe would enhance its chances. Thus it is not too off the mark to
assume that in markets that are more prone to collusion such as procurement and
constructions markets, a significant number would opt to pay bribes. This knowledge that
competitors will also pay bribes eventually creates a platform where firms will bid up the
bribe as well; hence the costs of corruption would be directly proportional to the number
of players in the corruption market. This makes the competition twofold; the product
competition and the ‘corruption’ competition.

It can be generally argued that it is difficult to separate corruption and collusion, given
that the same markets susceptible to cartels are also vulnerable to corruption. There is
much in common between cartels and corruption, as both strive to create an uneven
playing field for competitors in the market. It is during the process of bribe
competition where awareness of competitors and the nerve for cartel activities, such as
schemes for bid-rigging, price fixing or market allocation activities,

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


emerge. It would not be surprising for investigations that uncover illegal
payments to also uncover cartel activity involving multiple firms and their executives.

As the cost of corruption goes up with the number of participants in the ‘corruption
market’, there are high barriers to entry into the corruption game. This is also
compounded by the fact that there are also transaction costs of corruption, which are high
due to the need to avoid detection and the penalties once caught. This may lead to
situations where risk averse or honest firms exit the market, leaving fewer players in the
market. A combination of high entry barriers and few players in the market is a recipe for
cut-throat competition; hence there is basis to assume that the ‘corruption market’ would
be highly concentrated with those firms with financial muscles being able to ‘out-corrupt’
others and winning most of the corrupt business arrangements. This also leads to the
same scenario normally witnessed in the goods market, where fierce competition will
result in firms opting for collusive behaviour. Thus it is also not far fetched to expect to
find ‘corruption cartels’ in susceptible markets.

2.2 The challenges

Having discussed how the private sector actively participates in the corruption market, it
may not be difficult to understand the need for the players to work together in collective
action to fight corruption. Given that corruption has resulted in the creation of the
secondary market, which is deeply entangled with the genuine market and hidden;
ridding corruption becomes beyond the scope of individual corporations. Actions by one
company will not have significant impact in the corruption market unless complemented
by the others. This definitely calls for a collective approach to the situation, where both
actual and potential players in the two markets (good and corruption) have to work
together to be rid of the vice. The success of such an approach depends on the
development of a collaborative and sustained process of cooperation in fighting
corruption between all stakeholders.

This is prone to several challenges, none which is fortunately insoluble. Firstly, it is


difficult for firms to accept that they are participants in the corruption market, for they are
not immune to prosecution, even if they admit it as part of solution seeking. Thus a more
detailed disclosure on the operation of the market, which would form basis for collective
action solutions, is difficult to comprehend.

Secondly, getting firms who are used to working outside the competitive framework to
work together is always difficult, as each has an incentive to cheat fair competition
principles. Competing firms will always regard each other with suspicion if one of them
takes an active role in calling and trying to organise the framework for collective action.

Thirdly, it would be difficult for the firms to work together in the elimination of this
implicitly defined corruption market, and avoid the same for the explicitly defined
product market, give that the two markets are intertwined. Thus developing collective
strategies for the corruption market may easily result in collusive behaviour in the
product market, on which competition laws can descend heavily.

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


Fourth, it is also important to understand that the interests of the companies can rarely
converge; victims of corruption would want the practice to end while those that have
benefited most have incentives to see the trend continuing. Small companies with little
resources to finance corruption or to finance the compounded penalties once caught,
would be interested more in participating in the collective action while big firms with
deep pockets would reluctantly participate. The collective action plan therefore needs to
give incentives for all companies to take part.

Fifth, some resources are obviously required in mobilising stakeholders for such an
approach to evolve and get buy-in by all companies and stakeholders. Such resources
would need financing and the challenge is to ensure that while the resources are being
sought, no big dents are made to the firms’ pockets; otherwise they would prefer to be
free riders, knowing that the enjoyment of the ultimate benefit of a corruption free market
would be non-exclusive.

Finally, it would be difficult for business to have a strategy without taking into account
the potential reactions of the other party involved; that is the public sector. As long as the
public office abusers are totally left out of the process, they will continue to put spanners
on the strategies, to continue getting their shares. As Mitra (2003) argues, corruption in
the public office is difficult to stop as it is also a result of corruption; a cycle which is in
the interest of the players to preserve. Most of the agents participate in the corruption
market as a way of recouping the costs of corruption that they also paid in gaining their
position. This includes examples where agents borrow money to finance corruption, and
the repayment, with interest, will also have to be financed by corruption as the formal
earnings would not be enough. Thus collective action not endorsed by public agents will
be highly prone to sabotage.

A collective action plan for companies to work together should therefore be developed
with these challenges in mind.

3. Possible strategies for collective action


Lack of transparency and accountability in the public sector is normally a recipe for
corruption. So too is the existence of loopholes in the regulatory regime and enforcement
of various laws, including the anti-corruption law. It is the private sector which has first
hand information concerning the level of transparency and accountability in the public
sector, as it deals with the public sector regularly. It is also the private sector which is best
suited to judge the strength of the anti-corruption regulatory regime in the country, as
their strategies in corruption would have been modelled taking advantage of those
weaknesses. Thus efforts to improve transparency and accountability, as well as the
strength of the regulatory regime in curbing corruption have a huge probability of success
if the private sector views are taken into account. Similarly, it is the private sector that is
more suited to expose the various economic opportunities for which corruption is being
used as a tool to exploit. Thus the importance of the private sector as a player in anti-
corruption efforts can not be trivialized, and a strategy is required to gather this
knowledge for use in the anti-corruption drive.

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


The most critical requirement is for companies to speak with one voice in the fight
against corruption. The business sector needs to look at itself first and put its house in
order before shifting attention to its corrupt counterparts from the public sector. The
private sector needs to own up to its critical role in promoting and sustaining corruption
in order to understand its need to play the most critical role in nipping the vice in the bud.
Corruption can easily be eradicated if players from the private sector refrain from
participating in corrupt activities. However the prisoner’s dilemma situation brought
about by the uncertainty on fellow competitors’ action makes this difficult. Thus
companies have to collectively make the decision, through open and transparent
commitments and pledges which can be easily monitored. This apparently implies that
companies have to engage in discussions among themselves to outline the numerous
benefits that accrue to the sector as a whole as a result of the movement of resources from
corrupt officials back into the business coffers. If companies can find means of sitting
together clandestinely to conspire against the consumers through illegal cartels despite
strict competition laws, it can surely not be difficult for competitors to have an open
meeting to fight corruption! Such meetings may be analogous to a cartel in the
‘corruption market’, the only difference being that this would be an anti-corruption cartel,
with no harm to consumers but to corruption.

It would be difficult for buy-in if such a platform is initiated by individual companies, but
it will not be difficult if existing structures that business already has in place, through
various associations and body representatives including association of small scale
enterprises, are used. Thus the existing structures would be used as the avenue through
which all inclusive anti-corruption meetings and actions would be devised and this can
work through the following process.

The bodies, through their own structures across the whole country, would each call up
meetings with their constituencies and discuss the various facets through which
corruption exists and some means of closing off these facets, which would form the basis
for collective action. All companies would therefore get opportunities to sit together and
outline the requirements for collective actions that can be undertaken to fight corruption.
Selected representatives from these bodies would become members of the Anti-
Corruption Business Committee, which would meet to discuss the collective action
strategies that each representative would table. The Committee would come up with
explicit steps and action plans for the collective action approach and identify all possible
concerns that have to be addressed for this to happen, including policy and paradigm
shifts on the part of the government and other stakeholders. Thus the objective of the
Committee would be to recommend strategies, acceptable to all players, which each
business unit can adopt to instil a corruption free culture into the economic activities. The
Committee would also fare better in soliciting views and first hand information on the
operation of the various corruption syndicates, with firms free to give the information
without fear of prosecution.

There is always a limit on the extent to which anti-corruption action by the private sector
on its own can succeed without the involvement of the other corrupt arm; the public

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


sector. Thus collective action by the private sector has to lead to incorporation of the
public sector; hence establishment of a platform where views of the public sector can be
discussed and harmonized is a crucial step. The same applies to other critical stakeholders
like civil society representatives and independent regulatory authorities, who can also
influence positively the anti-corruption efforts. Collective action by the business also has
higher chances for success if it receives buy-in from all the other stakeholders.

Thus the other task of the Committee therefore would be to play a critical role in
lobbying for the establishment of a National Anti-Corruption Reference Group (NARG),
which would include members from the Committee and representatives from the public
sector and civil society. This would also include members from the anti-corruption
authorities and competition authorities in addition to the policy makers to ensure intense
debate on corruption matters within the confines of other laws. The purpose of NARG
would be simply to ensure that the collective action approach taken by the business
receives a complementary response from other stakeholders whose action have an impact
in the corruption market. Thus NARG would discuss the merits for the various concerns
and recommendations made by the Committee and recommend complementary roles that
the players from the public sector and civil society can play in eliminating corruption.
The reference group would also make policy recommendations for the strengthening of
the regulatory regime governing corruption.

It is also important for a strategy to be developed to mobilise resources towards financing


of the various initiatives and meetings to enable the Committee to perform its task. This
might call for business to contribute to a fund in the event that donor support can not be
mobilised, whose proceeds would be used strictly to facilitate the collective action
programme. However, the contribution requirement has to be conscious of the different
sizes of companies. Thus it is important for companies themselves to agree on the mode,
preferably a fixed percentage linked to assets, turnover or profits, which can be paid as
contributions towards the fund. It would also be left to business to decide whether all
companies, including SMEs should contribute or there would be a size cut-off on eligible
companies. Government funding can also be sourced at the NARG stage.

Even though the Committee may fail to lobby for the formation of NARG, the collective
efforts by the business sector alone would have a chance of success if strategies are
developed to counter the pressure the public sector would continue to exert in seeking to
continue with the corruption drive. As NARG is outside the control of business, more can
still be done at the Committee stage as long as incentives can be developed to try and
discourage firms from cheating the agreed collective action norms. Thus in the event that
NARG fails to materialise, that should not be an excuse to ditch the collective action
approach.

4. Conclusion
Corruption is both demand driven and supply driven. While the public sector’s role in
facilitating corruption through demands for extra payments and facilitations outside the
normal payment schedules is well appreciated, the role of the private sector in offering to

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


indulge in corrupt activities as a way of beating competition can not be ignored. In
addition, while corruption among players from the public sector among themselves is
negligible, the same can not be said about corruption among private sector players on
their own. Thus, the most active participants in the corruption market are players from the
business sector.

Being the dominant players in the corruption market, no successful efforts towards the
elimination of corruption can be embarked on without involving the business sector.
Moreover, as they are the most corrupt player; action by the private sector that is not
imposed upon them but embarked upon at their initiation, will work best in eliminating
corruption. The call for collective action by the business in the fight against corruption is
therefore not misplaced.

Collective action towards a common objective of corruption elimination by the business


sector therefore has high chances of success. But for the call for collective action to be
imbibed, conviction is needed that it is in the interest of all stakeholders to pursue it.
Businesses have to be made aware of the numerous benefits of a corruption free society
to the business sector as a whole, and how it is in their interest to help in attaining it.
Such a collective action is also not without some short run costs to some companies; the
opportunity cost in terms of the potential to lose out contracts as a result of competition,
which corruption was being used to shield, may be real. However these are far
outweighed by the benefits to accrue to companies and the economy in general through
the elimination of corruption. Costs incurred in the collective action process, through
opportunity costs or directly, should therefore not be used as an excuse to shy away from
the process.

References
• Boehm, F (2007), ‘Regulatory Capture Revisited –Lessons from Economics of
Corruption’, Working paper, JEL: K42, L97, B52, D73.
• Clarke, G. R.G and Xu L C (2001), ‘Ownership, Competition, and Corruption:
Bribe Takers Versus Bribe Payers’, Journal of Economic Literature.
• IFI Anti-corruption Task Force (2006), ‘Uniform Framework for Preventing And
Combating Fraud and Corruption’, African Development Bank, Asian Development
Bank, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development European Investment Bank,
International Monetary Fund, Inter-American Development Bank and World Bank.
• International Chamber of Commerce, Transparency International, the United Nations
Global Compact and the World Economic Forum Partnering Against Corruption
Initiative (2008), ‘The Business Case against Corruption’, (a joint publication).
• Mitra, S (2003) “Corruption as cascades”, Social Change, Volume 33, No. 4
• PricewaterhouseCoopers International (2008), ‘Confronting corruption: The business
case for an effective anti-corruption programme’, PricewaterhouseCoopers.
• World Bank Institute (2008), ‘Business Case for Collective Action Against
Corruption’, World Bank.

Cornelius Dube, April 2009


Cornelius Dube, April 2009

Вам также может понравиться