Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 38

A GAME-THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE ON

TRANSACTION COST AND THE DECISION TO MAKE, BUY OR MAKE-AND-BUY

December 2001

Khai Sheang LEE* & Wei Shi LIM**

RPS #2001-034 (MKTG)

Associate Professor, Department of Marketing, Faculty of Business Administration, Bldg. 1, National University of Singapore, Business Link, Singapore 117591. E-mail: fbaleeks@nus.edu.sg Associate Professor, Department of Decision Sciences, Faculty of Business Administration, Bldg. 1, National University of Singapore, Business Link, Singapore 117591. E-mail: fbalimws@nus.edu.sg

**

Copyright Faculty of Business Administration, National University of Singapore.

A Game-Theoretic Perspective on Transaction Cost and The Decision to Make, Buy, or Make-and-Buy

Abstract This paper examines a firms outsourcing decision over time. We identify specific learning and the salvageability of specific learning by suppliers as reasons for a firm to adopt a make-and-buy strategy, even when outsourcing is less costly initially. We show that when specific learning effect is high, the firm follows a makeand-buy strategy, capitalizing on the cost savings in buying, while simultaneously acquiring specific know-how for an eventual switch to a make-only strategy. When specific learning effect is moderate, the firm adopts a make-and-buy strategy, followed by a buy-only strategy. In this way, the firm minimizes the appropriation risk in outsourcing. Finally, outsourcing completely is optimal for the firm only if specific learning effect is low. Key Words: Game Theory, Industrial Marketing, Transaction Cost Economics, Small Numbers Bargaining.

1. Introduction Since Coase's (1937) seminal work on transaction cost, which was later developed by Williamson (1979, and 1981), transaction cost economics (TCE) has been extensively applied to examine the procurement problem faced by firms. According to TCE, transaction cost varies depending on the characteristics of the transaction associated with the exchange relationship, for example, asset specificity, uncertainty, and frequency (Williamson 1985). TCE argues that, buyers should

internalize (or make) their supply requirements to preempt against the hazards of opportunism in engaging external agents or suppliers when transaction specific assets are involved in exchange relationships, and outsource (or buy) their requirements otherwise. Based on the arguments of TCE, extensive empirical studies have been conducted to examine the effect of transaction specific assets on a firms decision to

make or buy. Nonetheless, questions of whether a firm should make some of its requirements and buy the rest, or how a firms governance decision changes over time, have largely been ignored. This is hardly surprising given that the paradigm problem of TCE is on the make-or-buy decision, and that in TCE, "organizational form is often modeled as a binary variable - make or buy" (Shelanski and Klein, 1995, p338). The emphasis of TCE on individual transaction as the unit of analysis ignores how different governance forms can be combined (Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). Some researchers have proposed that combined governance forms such as make-and-buy, franchised-and-owned units, and direct-and-indirect distribution channels, could be viewed conceptually as hybrid modes that lie on a continuum, with market exchange at one end and hierarchical integration at the other (Shelanski and Klein, 1995; and Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). Challenging this view, Bradach and Eccles (1989) proposed that combined governance forms were more appropriately viewed as plural forms, which they defined as "an arrangement where distinct organizational control mechanisms are operated simultaneously for the same function by the same firm" (Bradach and Eccles, 1989, p112). The authors suggested that, to understand why firms often follow plural forms, like make and buy, the focus must shift away from individual transactions to control mechanisms, and proposed three control mechanisms that govern economic transactions price, authority, and trust. However, like Dutta et al. (1995), we contend that it is not necessary to invoke these control mechanisms, and that plural forms can be examined through the lens of TCE. The objective of this paper is to formally examine how appropriation concerns (Klein et al., 1978; and Walker, 1988) arising from transaction specific assets and small numbers bargaining affect a firm's decision to make only, buy only, or make and buy, their supply requirements. We seek to provide an explanation as to why

firms both make and buy their supply requirements, and how their governance decision change over time. As the majority of prior research in TCE are empirical studies (Shelanski and Klien, 1995; and Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997) a formal analysis following a game theoretic approach could provide useful insights. A

distinctive contribution of this paper is that it clarifies the findings (or lack of) in earlier empirical studies. In this paper, we propose that (1) specific learning and (2) the salvageability of this specific learning as two reasons for a buyer to change his governance decision over time and to follow a make-and-buy strategy, even if a supplier could supply at a lower cost initially. When transaction specific assets in the form of specific human capital are involved in an exchange relationship, buyers and suppliers may be "locked-into" transactions asymmetrically (Williamson, 1979 and 1981). This allows a supplier to transfer or salvage, in part or in full, the know-how that he has acquired from the specific relationship (Anderson and Weitz, 1986; and Pisano, 1990) to supply other buyers in the market. Furthermore, this specific learning, that is acquired by a supplier, may not be salvageable nor patentable (Monteverde and Teece, 1982) by a buyer. We show that such asymmetry in the salvageability of specific learning affects the outcome in small numbers bargaining, and hence a buyers governance decision to make, buy, or make-and-buy. Furthermore, we show that a buyers optimal governance decision changes as a supplier acquires specific learning over time. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The next section contains the literature review. Section 3 and Section 4 present a game theoretic model of

industrial procurement and the analyses respectively. Section 5 examines the change in governance over time that arises from learning specificity and its salvageability,

while Section 6 discusses the results. The final section concludes and provides directions for future research. All proofs to the lemmas and propositions presented in this paper are included in the Appendix.

2. Literature Review 2.1 TCE and Governance Decision Extensive studies have been conducted to identify and to examine various governance mechanisms as safeguards against the hazards of opportunism in engaging external agents when transaction specific assets are involved in exchange relationships. For example, Williamson (1983, 1984) proposed the use of hostages to credibly commit to exchange relationships. Heidi and John (1990) examined the utility of relationships to safeguard relationship-specific investments and to facilitate adaptation to uncertainty. Stump and Heide (1996) suggested that opportunism by suppliers could be controlled through partner qualification and selection, incentive design, and monitoring. Anderson and Weitz (1992) proposed that pledges in

idiosyncratic investments could be effective in reducing opportunism in channel relationships. Klein et al. (1978) proposed that reputation served as collateral against opportunism, while Klein and Leffler (1981) suggested that brand name is a form of specific asset that served as collateral by suppliers to deliver high quality. Others proposed that a multiple sourcing strategy could safeguard against delivery failures (Leavy, 1994; and Wilson, 1994) and suppliers' opportunism post contract award (Seshadri, 1991 and 1995). For small firms, for which internalization is not feasible because of resource limitations (Lee et al. 1999; Lim et al. 2000), Heidi and John (1988) proposed that close bonds with clients safeguard against opportunistic

behaviors by principals. In all these studies, the focus is on pure governance forms, rather than plural forms.

2.2

Plural Governance Forms More directly related to our study are those which examined plural forms. For

example, Heidi (1994) recommended a typology of three governance forms market governance, hierarchical governance, and bilateral governance, and argued that nonmarket governance cannot be described by a single continuum. However, the author did not identify the determinants of plural governance structures. In Dutta et al. (1995, p194), it was proposed that adding a direct sales force to augment the rep channel serves as a safeguard against lock-in problems with the reps and provides a manufacturer with insight into downstream marketing activities when performance is ambiguous. The authors reported that the degree of lock-in problems faced by a manufacturer and performance ambiguity increases the probability that a dual channel will be used. However, since governance responses were coded as reps only and reps plus house accounts in their study, the authors did not distinguish when increasing asset specificity would increase the probability of dual channels vis--vis house accounts only. This is critical, as lock-in problems that arise from specific assets would also increase the probability in following a house accounts only strategy. In Gallini and Lutz's (1992) study of franchisors store-mix decision, it was suggested that, given the information asymmetry between franchisors and potential franchisees, stores owned by new franchisors signal business prospects to potential franchisees. As a result, when this information asymmetry between franchisors and potential new franchisees diminishes, all stores will be franchised. On the other hand,

Weiss and Anderson (1992, p106) hypothesized that the more extensively the manufacturer uses house accounts in a sales district, the more likely it is to convert the district to a direct sales force. This suggests that a firm following a make-and-buy strategy would likely switch to a make-only strategy eventually, which is contrary to Gallini and Lutz's (1992) arguments. Compared to these studies, we clarify the conditions when a buyer, who follows a make-and-buy strategy initially, will eventually switch to a buy-only or a make-only strategy. In a related study, Farrel and Gallini (1988) proposed that a monopolist intentionally licenses other firms to utilize his proprietary technology to produce and compete directly with him, because second sourcing or invited competition served as a safeguard for a buyers specific investment. Although the authors' proposition, which was empirically tested by Dutta and John (1995), provides an explanation as to why firms make-and-license, it is silent as to why firms both make and buy. Another study by Carlton (1979) suggested that partial integration arises because firms integrate and use the market to satisfy the high and low probability demands respectively. Compared to Carlton (1979), we propose an alternative explanation, based on TCE arguments, for the use of plural governance forms by firms.

2.3

Learning Specificity Williamson (1979) described asset specificity as the most important dimension

affecting transactions. Although there are various forms of specific assets (e.g., Klein et al., 1978; Williamson, 1981; and Nooteboom, 1993a), we focus on learning specificity or specific human capital in the form technical know-how that arises from learning by doing (e.g., Williamson, 1981; Klein, 1988; Monteverde, 1995; Hart and Moore, 1990). This is because specific human capital has a stronger influence on

governance decisions than other forms of specific assets (Masten et al., 1989) and is the most commonly assessed form of specificity in TCE studies (Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). For example, it was postulated that specific know-how affects

transaction cost and governance decisions (Pisano, 1990), could be a barrier to change (Nooteboom, 1993b), and increases the likelihood of vertically integrated production (Monteverde and Teece, 1982). Indeed, Monteverde and Teece (1982, p206) suggested that, Even if the title to specialized equipment used by the supplier is held by the assembler, this need not provide protection against rent appropriation if transaction specific know-how has been generated". We formalize the authors' argument and extend it to examine the effect of rent appropriation on plural forms over time.

3. A Game Theoretic Model To gain a more precise insight into the hazards of small numbers bargaining (Williamson, 1979; and 1981) when transaction specific assets are involved in exchange relationships, we propose a 2-period bargaining game. We will first

describe the game before we discuss some characteristics of the model. In Period i (i = 1, 2), buyer B and supplier S bargain over price Pi ( 0). We apply the Nash bargaining solution concept to derive the bargaining outcome. Let the unit cost of production for j (j {B, S}) be Cj(q), which is endogenous on q ( 0), the cumulative quantity produced up to Period i for buyer B. Therefore, in Period 1, the suppliers production cost in producing for buyer B is CS(0). We normalize the buyers purchase requirement per period to be 1, and use to denote the portion of his requirement that he chooses to buy vis--vis to make. We define the learning-by-doing effect as an efficiency gain from cumulative production (Irwin

and Klenow, 1994). The learning effect is transaction specific in that a supplier learns, or acquires specific knowledge in production, only if it is awarded the supply contract in part or in full. Learning specificity, as we have defined, is a form of specific human capital that arises from learning-by-doing (Klein et al. 1978; Williamson 1979 and 1981; Schelanski and Klein 1995). Taking into account the effect of specific learning on cost, we therefore assume that the production cost function Cj(q) has the following characteristics (Figure 1). (a) CB() > CS() for all 0, that is, with the same amount of production experience , suppliers have a cost advantage over buyer B (Maltz, 1994). This is because a "supplier who aggregates uncorrelated demands can realize collective pooling benefits" (Williamson, 1979, p245). (b) CB(1) < CS(0), that is, because of specific learning, buyer B could acquire a cost advantage over suppliers who did not possess any specific learning, if it chooses to produce in house. Otherwise, it will never be beneficial for the buyer to produce in house. (c) Cj() is continuous and twice differentiable, such that Cj() < 0 and Cj() > 0, that is, Cj() is strictly decreasing and convex with respect to . This implies that, by Period 2, if supplier S was awarded a contract to supply ( > 0), then supplier S would acquire specific learning in producing for buyer B and hence, gain a cost advantage over other suppliers in the market who did not possess such expertise (Monteverde and Teece, 1982). (d) d/d Cj() d/d Cj() (j = B, S) for all between 0 and 1, that is, the rate of decrease of Cj() with respect to is no more than that of Cj(). This implies that, if supplier S is to supply other buyers in the market, his rate of specific

learning in supplying these buyers will be no more than his rate of specific learning in producing for buyer B if he is to continue producing for buyer B. This is not unreasonable given that the specific learning that we are interested in is a form of specific asset and hence, is unique to the B-S dyadic relationship (Williamson, 1979), although it is salvageable (to an extent that is specified) in our model. (e) d2/d2 Cj() > 0 (j = B, S). This property is similar to the requirement in (c) whereby we have Cj() > 0.

(Insert Figure 1 here)

We consider the case when the market is competitive in that supplies are readily available from competing symmetric suppliers. Hence, in the initial period, the suppliers optimal choice of price P1 is the competitive market price CS(0). However, in the presence of learning specificity, the situation is transformed from one of competitive market into one of small numbers bargaining. For each period i (i = 1, 2), depending on the bargaining outcome Pi, supplier S decides on whether or not to supply buyer B, while the latter chooses to outsource a portion i ( [0,1]) of his requirements to the supplier, while producing a portion (1-

i) of the required supplies himself. That is, B decides on whether to make (i = 0),
buy (i = 1), or make-and-buy (i (0,1)). Hence, (1, P1, 2, P2) defines the supply contract between buyer B and supplier S for the two-period game. For simplicity, our model consists of two periods instead of an arbitrary n periods. However, it is worthwhile to note that the results obtained are not compromised.

Let ( [0,1]) denote the degree of salvageability of learning by supplier S outside of the specific buyer-supplier (B and S) exchange relationship. This means that the specific knowledge acquired by S is transferable in that he can use this knowledge, in part or in full to the extent as defined by , to produce at a cost CS(), such that CS(0) CS() CS() (Figure 1), to supply other buyers B' in the market at a price PS [CS(), P*], where P* = CS(0). Obviously, PS cannot be less than the production cost CS() but neither can it be higher than the competitive market rate CS(0). In other words, the supplier S could benefit from the salvageability of the specific knowledge that he has acquired, by supplying other buyers B' in the market. In doing so, the supplier S earns a premium () = (CS(0) - CS()) ( 0) , by charging PS = (() + CS()) = (1-)CS() + CS(0), where [0, 1] represents the bargaining power of the supplier S vis--vis other buyers B' in the market. The premium () = (CS(0) - CS()) is maximized when = 1. Note that () is non-decreasing in and if = 0 and strictly increasing if > 0 (Figure 1). Obviously, if = 0, then (0) = 0. Given that supplier S earns a minimum premium

() by supplying other buyers B', he can therefore demand a minimum price (CS()
+ ()) from buyer B (Figure 1). The buyer B chooses a portion (= {1, 2}) of his supply requirement to buy vis--vis to make, to minimize his total cost of purchase over the two periods. We assume that, whenever B is indifferent between producing internally and outsourcing, he chooses to produce internally. The payoff (cost) of buyer B over the two-period game is thus given by

B(1,P1,2,P2) = [1P1 + (1 - 1)CB(0)] + [2P2 + (1 - 2)CB(1-1)],


where B chooses to minimize B(1,P1,2,P2).

(1)

10

A suppliers unit profit is given by (Pi - CS(i)), and he bargains over prices P = {P1, P2} to maximize his payoff, which is given by S() = {1[P1 - CS(1)] + 2[P2 CS(2)]}. Williamson (1979, p242) suggested that in a bilateral monopoly, Although both (buyer and seller) have a long term interest in effecting adaptations of a joint profit maximizing kind, each also has an interest in appropriating as much of the gains as he can on each occasion to adapt. Our model is consistent with the author's argument in that buyer B and supplier S bargain over prices in each period to maximize their individual payoffs. Supplier S in our model is opportunistic in that he maximizes rent appropriation by exploiting the fact that his possession of idiosyncratic know-how makes him difficult to be replaced. The quasi-rent (Klein et al., 1978) appropriable by the supplier, or the appropriation risk faced by the buyer, can be defined as = (P2 - CS(1)), which is also consistent with Monteverde and Teeces (1982) measure of opportunism as price hikes in follow-on periods. In the next section, we will present the formal analysis of the game, first stating the best responses of B and S in the respective subgames, and eventually the subgame perfect equilibrium of the game.

4.

Analysis: Make, Buy, or Make-and-Buy

We first state the following lemma, which will be useful in our analysis. Essentially, the lemma states that, given a fixed degree of salvageability , the minimum price that supplier S can demand from buyer B is strictly decreasing in , the proportion of the buyer's supply requirement that is outsourced.

11

Lemma 1: Given , the curve (CS() + ()) is strictly decreasing in ( (0, 1)), that is, / [CS() + ()] < 0.

Using backward induction, we begin our analysis of the game from the final period. Suppose buyer B buys 1 and makes (1 - 1) of his requirement in Period 1. In Period 2, the unit cost of production of supplier S becomes CS(1), due to learning from the earlier period. In contrast, suppliers who were not awarded any prior supply contract would not benefit from learning specificity, and hence their unit cost of production would remain at CS(0). The incumbent supplier S therefore has a cost advantage over other competing suppliers in Period 2, as a result of learning specificity, since CS(1) < CS(0), 1 > 0. Given the prior production experience of buyer B, his unit cost of production in Period 2 becomes CB(1-1). For supplier S to secure the supply contact in Period 2, he must therefore offer a price that at least matches the buyers unit cost CB(1-1) or the competitive market price CS(0), whichever is lower, that is, P2 Min[CB(1-1), CS(0)]. On the other hand, since learning is partially salvageable by S outside of the specific buyer-seller relationship, supplier S is assured of a minimum premium

(1). Hence, he can demand a price P2 (CS(1) + (1)) from buyer B. We


observe that (CS() + ()) CS(0), where equality holds when = 0. The bargaining outcome in Period 2, P2*, is therefore bounded below by the minimum price level (CS(1) + (1)), if (CS(1) + (1)) CB(1-1), and bounded above by the maximum price level Min[CB(1-1), CS(0)]. That is, (CS(1) + (1)) P2* Min[CB(1-1), CS(0)], in which case buyer B also chooses to outsource all his requirements in Period 2, that is, 2 = 1.

12

On the other hand, if buyer B could produce at a cost that is lower than the minimum price demanded by supplier S, that is, (CS(1) + (1)) > CB(1-1), then obviously buyer B will choose to produce all his requirements in Period 2. Lemma 2 states this result and the bargaining outcome, where denotes the bargaining power of supplier S vis--vis buyer B in Period 2. As Lemma 2 shows, the buyer's choice of

1 in Period 1 affects both the buyer's and the supplier's unit production cost in Period
2, and the appropriation risk = (P2*(1,P1)) - CS(1)).

Lemma 2: Given (1, P1) as the decision choices in Period 1, the Nash equilibrium of the subgame beginning at Period 2 is given by, (2 (1,P1), P2 (1,P1)) =
* *

(0, CB(1-1)), if CB(1-1) CS(1) + (1), (1, (1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + Min[CB(1-1), CS(0)]), otherwise.

Next, we shall examine the cases when the effect of specific learning for the buyer is (i) high, such that CB(1-1) CS(1) + (1), (ii) moderate, such that CS(1) + (1) < CB(1-1) CS(0), and (iii) low, such that CS(1) + (1) CS(0) < CB(1-

1). Before we proceed with the analysis of the cases stated, we first define a few
notations that will be used later. With reference to Figure 1, let (0,1) be such that CB(1-1) CS(1) + (1) for all 1 . Note that always exist, since CS(0) +

(0) = CS(0) + 0 > CB(1) but CS(1) + () = CS(1) + [CS(0) - CS()] < CS(0) + (1 )CS(1) < CB(0). Hence, by the Intermediate Value Theorem, there exists an in the
interval (0,1) such that CB(1-) = CS() + (). Similarly, since CB(1 - ) < CS(0) and CB(0) > CS(0), again by the Intermediate Value Theorem, the existence of ( [ ,1]) such that CB(1 - ) = CS(0) is assured. Given that CS() + () is

13

decreasing in (Lemma 1) and that CB(1-) is increasing in , we deduce that CS(1) + (1) < CB(1-1) CS(0) for all 1 [ ,] and CS(1) + (1) CS(0) < CB(1-1) for 1 (, 1). Finally, let a,b denote the subgame where 1 is between a and b.

3.1

High Specific Learning Effect: CB(1-1) CS(1) + (1) With reference to Figure 1, for values of 1 between 0 and , since CB(1-1)

CS(1) + (1), Lemma 2 implies that the buyers 2-period payoff is given by

B(1,CS(0),0,CB(1-1)) = [1CS(0) + (1 - 1)CB(0)] + CB(1-1). Let a denote the


solution to the first order condition CS(0) - CB(0) - CB(1-1) = 0. It is easy to check that the second-order condition is CB(1-1) (> 0). Hence, the buyers cost is

minimized when 1 equals a, if it exists. Otherwise, the buyers cost is minimized at one of the boundary points, 0 or . Proposition 1 thus follows.

Proposition 1: In the subgame 0,, the optimal decisions for buyer B are: 0, if CS(0) - CB(0) > CB(1-1), 1 [0, ],

1 * =

, if CS(0) - CB(0) < CB(1-1), 1 [0, ], a, if a (0, ) such that CS(0) - CB(0) - CB(1-a) = 0.

P1* = CS(0), 2 = 0, and P2* = CB(1-1*). Furthermore, 1*, 2*and P1*, P2* are independent of , , and . The appropriation risk faced by the buyer is = (CB(1-

1*) - CS(1*)).

As Proposition 1 shows, when the effect of specific learning on the buyers cost is high, such that CB(1 - 1) CS(1) + (1) CS(0), the optimum choice of

14

is independent of , , and , and is driven solely by the effect of specific learning. This is consistent with Williamson's (1979) suggestion that asset specificity is the single most important factor that drives transaction cost and governance decision. Note also that, when the effect of specific learning is high, appropriation risk , and hence governance decision, is driven by the relative difference in production costs of the buyer vis--vis the supplier, that is, = (CB(1-1*) - CS(1*)). This perhaps provides an explanation for Walker and Webers (1984) observation that comparative production cost is the strongest predictor of governance decision, in their empirical study. When there exists a ( (0, )) such that the gradient of the buyers cost function at (1 - a) equals CB(0) - CS(0), the buyer adopts the make-and-buy policy in Period 1. This is because, if the buyer chooses a make-only strategy in Period 1, then he is not capitalizing on the cost savings from outsourcing, given that his initial unit cost is higher than that of the supplier's. On the other hand, if the buyer chooses a buy-only strategy in Period 1, then he could not credibly internalize the production of his requirement in the next period. The buyer therefore optimizes by following a make-and-buy strategy initially, but switches to the make-only strategy when he has acquired a cost advantage over the supplier. Obviously, the greater the effect of specific learning on cost reduction, the earlier the buyer switches to the make-only strategy, to the extent that he would follow a make-only strategy right from the beginning if the effect of specific learning is sufficiently high. This happens when the gradient of the buyer's cost function CB(1 - ) is greater than CB(0) - CS(0) (Proposition 1). Proposition 1 therefore implies that, even though the effect of specific learning is high, which suggests that the buyer internalizes his production, he could do better

15

by following the make-and-buy strategy initially. An external supplier is engaged initially for part of the buyers requirements, until the latter has acquired sufficient specific learning to produce more efficiently. Corollary 1 therefore follows.

Corollary 1: When the effect of specific learning is high, a make-only strategy right from the beginning is not optimal. The buyer is better off following a make-and-buy strategy initially, then switching to a make-only strategy when he has acquired a cost advantage over his supplier. The buyer's decision is independent of the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier.

3.2

Moderate Specific Learning Effect: CS(1) + (1) < CB(1-1) CS(0) For the subgame a,b = ,, where the specific learning effect is moderate,

the minimum price demanded by supplier S (= CS(1) + (1)) in Period 2 is less than buyer Bs production cost, that is, CS(1) + (1) < CB(1-1) CS(0) for values of 1 [,]. Hence, Lemma 2 implies that buyer B will outsource his entire demand in Period 2, that is, 2 = 1. Given that 2 = 1, the buyers total cost is therefore given by, B(1,CS(0),1,(1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CB(1-1)) = [1CS(0) + (1 - 1)CB(0) + (1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CB(1-1)]. The buyers optimal choice of

1, which minimizes the buyers cost, is therefore the interior solution, b (,),
such that it satisfies the first order condition

CS(0) - CB(0) + [(1 - ){CS() - CS()} - CB(1-)] = 0

(2)

However, if b does not exist, then 1* is one of the boundary points or. When or is sufficiently large, the left-hand-side of (2) is positive for all 16

(,) and we have 1* = . We therefore deduce that 1* is non-increasing in and

. By a similar argument, as increases, the left-hand-side of (2) increases since [{CS(1*) + CS(1*)} - CB(1-1*)] > 0 (Lemma 1), which implies that 1* = . We therefore deduce that 1* is non-increasing in . These results are summarized in Proposition 2 below.

Proposition 2: In the subgame ,, the optimal decisions for buyer B are:

, if [(1 - ){CS(1) - CS(1)} - CB(1-1) - CB(0) + CS(0)] > 0, 1 [,]. 1 =


, if [(1 - ){CS(1) - CS(1)} - CB(1-1) - CB(0) + CS(0)] < 0, 1 [,].

b, if b (,) such that [(1 - ){CS(b) - CS(b)} - CB(1- b)


- CB(0) + CS(0)] = 0. P1* = CS(0), 2 = 1, and P2* = (1 - )(CS(1*) + (1*)) + CB(1-1*). Furthermore,

1* is non-increasing in , , and , while P2* is increasing in , , and . The


appropriation risk is given by (CB(1-1*) - CS(1*)) + (1 - )(1).

When the effect of specific learning is moderate, such that CS(1) + (1) < CB(1-1) CS(0), Proposition 2 shows that both the salvageability of specific learning and the bargaining power of supplier S ( and ) affect the buyers decision in the optimal amount to outsource 1*. At equilibrium, since the suppliers unit cost is lower than the buyers unit cost, the buyer chooses the buy-only strategy in Period 2. However, in Period 1, the buyer chooses the make-and-buy strategy. This is rather counter intuitive, as the buyers unit cost is always higher than that of the suppliers in both Periods 1 and 2, that is, CS(1) + (1) < CB(1-1) CS(0) and CS(0) < CB(0), which suggest that the buyer should outsource his entire requirement in both periods.

17

However, if the buyer outsources his entire requirement in Period 1, then in Period 2, the premium (1) that supplier S can command outside of the specific buyer-supplier exchange relationship increases, thereby increasing the appropriation risk that the buyer faces. The appropriation risk = (CB(1-1*) - CS(1*)) + (1 -

)(1), whose gradient with respect to can be rewritten as (-CB(1-1*)


CS(1*)) + (1 - )(- CS()), is positive. The term is increasing in 1*, which implies that appropriable quasi rent is increasing in the specific assets that the supplier acquires, just as Monteverde and Teece (1982) hypothesized. In addition, the

appropriation risk is also increasing in salvageabiltiy , as the premium (1) is increasing in 1 (Figure 1). Hence, while the lower cost in buying suggests that buyer B should follow a buy-only strategy in Period 1, the resulting higher bargaining outcome P2* and appropriation risk faced by buyer B in Period 2 suggest that buyer B should follow a make-only strategy in Period 1 instead. Taking these opposing forces into consideration, the buyer therefore optimally chooses to make-and-buy in Period 1. The buyers production experience in Period 1 reduces the suppliers ability to engage in opportunistic bargaining (Walker and Weber, 1984), thereby reducing the bargaining outcome in price when the buyer switches to a buy-only strategy, in Period 2. As expected, the appropriation risk , is increasing in , the bargaining power of supplier S vis--vis buyer B, since CB(1-1*) - CS(1*) > (1). As Proposition 2 also shows, the optimal proportion to buy 1* is nonincreasing in . This is because increasing salvageability of specific learning by supplier S increases the premium (1) that he could command from other buyers B', thus improving his bargaining position with buyer B. A reduction in the amount outsourced, 1*, therefore reduces the appropriable quasi rent by supplier S. Similarly, when the bargaining power of supplier S, vis--vis buyer B (as denoted by 18

) and other buyers B' (as denoted by ) increases, the amount that buyer B
outsources in Period 1 reduces. Proposition 2 therefore implies that, under moderate specific learning effect, even though the buyers unit cost is always higher than that of the suppliers, which suggests that the buyer should outsource his entire requirements in both Periods 1 and 2, he could do better by following the make-and-buy strategy initially. An external supplier is engaged to produce a portion of the buyers requirements initially, which reduces as the salvageability of specific learning increases. Corollary 2 thus follows.

Corollary 2: When the effect of specific learning is moderate, even though the buyers unit cost is always higher than that of the suppliers, a buy-only strategy right from the beginning is not optimal. The buyer is better off following a make-and-buy strategy initially, reducing the quantity outsourced as the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier increases, and switches to a buy-only strategy eventually.

3.3

Low Specific Learning Effect: CS(1) + (1) CS(0) < CB(1-1). When 1 [, 1] (Figure 1) and a,b = , 1, Lemma 2 implies that buyer B

will choose 2 = 1 and P2* = (1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CS(0), since CS(1) + (1) CS(0) < CB(1-1). Hence, in Period 1, the buyer's total cost is given by,

B(1,CS(0),1,(1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CS(0)) = [1CS(0) + (1 - 1)CB(0) + (1 )(CS(1) + (1)) + CS(0)]. The first order condition with respect to 1 is
therefore [CS(0) - CB(0) + (1 - )(CS(1) - CS(1))], which is always negative because CS(0) < CB(0) and CS(1) - CS(1) < 0 (Lemma 1). The optimal choice of 1 is thus the boundary solution 1* = 1. Proposition 3 states this result.

19

Proposition 3: In the subgame , 1, the optimal decisions for buyer B are 1 = 1, P1* = CS(0), 2 = 1, and P2* = (1 - )(CS(1) + ()) + CS(0). The optimal proportion

1* is independent of , and , while P2* is increasing in , , and . The


appropriation risk faced by the buyer is given by = (CS(0) - CS(1)) + (1 - )().

Obviously, when the effect of specific learning on the buyers cost function is low, such that it is not possible for the buyer to produce at a cost lower than the competitive market price (that is, CS(1) + (1) CS(0) < CB(1 - 1)), the buyer optimal choice is to buy-only in both periods, regardless of the salvageability of specific learning and bargaining power and . The appropriation risk that the buyer faces is limited by the low effect of specific learning. Proposition 3 therefore is consistent with the central argument of TCE that transaction specific assets gives rise to hazards of opportunism (Klein et al. 1978; and Williamson, 1979 and 1981), and hence, firms should outsource only under conditions of low asset specificity. However, although 1* is independent of , , and , the bargaining outcome in price P2*, and hence the appropriation risk , are both increasing in , , and . This means that, as the supplier acquires increasing specific learning, and as the salvageability of specific learning increases, he can credibly demand an increasingly higher price in future negotiations. Corollary 3 thus follows from Proposition 3.

Corollary 3: When the effect of specific learning is low, a buyer follows a buy-only strategy right from the beginning, and pays an increasingly higher price as his supplier acquires increasing specific learning and as the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier increases.

20

Corollaries 1 and 3 are in general agreement with the central thesis of TCE in that, in the long run, firms should internalize and outsource under conditions of high and low specific assets respectively, which has been extensively tested and found to possess high predictive validity (Shelanski and Klein, 1995; and Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). However, prior empirical research in TCE has overlooked the

implications of moderate specific asset condition, under which, the salvageability of specific assets affects governance decision in terms of the optimal quantity to make vis--vis to buy (Corollary 2). We next examine how a buyers decision to make, buy, or make-and-buy, changes over time as a result of learning specificity and its salvageability by the supplier.

5.

Change in Governance over Time

From Propositions 1, 2, and 3, we obtain Theorem 1, which states that specific learning and its salvageability by a supplier interact to affect a buyer's decision in following a make-only, a buy-only, or a make-and-buy strategy. Observe that the buyers payoff in (3) and (5) in Theorem 1 are the same by the definition of .

Theorem 1: Depending on the parameters of the game: the degree of salvageability of specific learning by a supplier, and the bargaining power of the supplier vis--vis other buyers B and buyer B respectively, and the effect of specific learning on the cost functions CS() and CB(), one of the following is a subgame perfect equilibrium.

21

1
(1) (2) (3) (4)

P1 *

2
0 0 0 1 CB(1-1*) CB(1-1*) CB(1-1*)

P2 *

B aCS(0) + (1-a)CB(0) + CB(1-a)


CB(0) + CB(1)

a
0

CS(0) CS(0) CS(0) CS(0)

CS(0) + (1-)CB(0) + CB(1-) bCS(0) + (1-b)CB(0) + (1)(CS(b) + (b)) + CB(1-b) CS(0) + (1-)CB(0) + (1-)(CS() + ()) + CB(1-)
CS(0) + (1-)CB(0) + (1)(CS() + ()) + CB(1-) CS(0) + (1-)(CS(1) + ()) + CB(0)

(1 - )(CS(1*) + (1*)) + CB(1-1*) (1 - )(CS(1*) + (1*)) + CB(1-1*) (1 - )(CS(1*) + (1*)) + CB(1-1*) (1 - )(CS(1) + ()) + CS(0)

(5)

CS(0)

(6)

CS(0)

(7)

CS(0)

From Theorem 1, it is evident that, when a buyer follows a make-and-buy strategy, he does so only for the initial period, but eventually adopts a buy-only and a make-only strategy under conditions of moderate and high specific learning effects respectively. Hence, from Theorem 1, Corollary 4 follows.

Corollary 4: When a buyer follows a make-and-buy strategy, he does so only for an initial period. Eventually, he switches to a buy-only and a make-only strategy under conditions of moderate and high specific learning effects respectively.

Conversely, as Theorem 1 implies, a buyer following a pure form of governance (that is, make-only or buy-only) would not change to a plural form nor another pure form, based on asset specificity considerations alone.

22

Corollary 5: When a buyer follows a make-only (buy-only) strategy, he would not switch to a buy-only (make-only) strategy or a make-and-buy strategy, based on specific learning considerations alone.

Corollaries 4 and 5 thus describe and clarify how governance decision, in terms of make-only, buy-only, or make-and-buy, changes over time under different asset specificity conditions, which is an important issue that has generally been neglected by prior TCE research. Compared to earlier studies on plural governance forms (Dutta et al., 1995; Gallini and Lutz, 1992; and Weiss and Anderson, 1992), Corollary 4 shows that, a firm that follows a make-and-buy strategy will eventually switch to a buy-only and a make-only strategy when specific learning effects are moderate and high respectively.

(Insert Table 1 here)

Table 1 summarizes our results and illustrates the interaction effect of specific learning and its salvageability on governance decision over time. Under conditions of high and low specific learning, a buyer's decision to make-only, buy-only, or makeand-buy, is driven solely by the effect of specific learning, while the salvageability of specific learning by a supplier has no effect on the decision. However, under

moderate effect of specific learning, salvageability of specific learning by a supplier reduces the amount a buyer outsources when he follows a make-and-buy strategy.

23

6.

Discussion

The marketability of the know-how acquired by a supplier outside of a specific buyer-supplier exchange relationship improves the suppliers bargaining position. The supplier could therefore demand a higher price in future negotiations, thereby increasing the appropriation risk that the buyer faces. A make-and-buy strategy enables a buyer to acquire production experience, which improves his bargaining position vis--vis his suppliers in future renegotiations. Hence, when specific

learning effect is moderate, such that it is not possible for a buyer to acquire a cost advantage over his supplier through specific learning, although the buyers optimal strategy in the long run is to outsource completely, his optimal strategy is to makeand-buy initially. This is despite the fact that it is less costly initially to outsource completely. In addition, when following the make-and-buy strategy initially, the buyer should also reduce the quantity outsourced as the salvageability of specific learning by his supplier increases. Doing so reduces the price premium that arises from the suppliers market option, thereby reducing the appropriation risk that the buyer faces in future renegotiations. On the other hand, when the effect of specific learning on cost reduction is high, such that it is possible for a buyer to acquire a cost advantage over his supplier, a make-and-buy strategy allows the buyer to capitalize on the cost savings in buying initially. At the same time, the buyer could acquire specific know-how in production for the eventual switch to the make-only strategy, when he has acquired a cost advantage over his supplier. As the buyer could (and would) credibly internalize eventually, salvageability of specific learning by the supplier therefore does not affect the buyers outsourcing decision in this case.

24

Obviously, when the effect of specific learning on cost reduction is low, such that it is not possible for a buyer to produce at a cost lower than the competitive market price, a buy-only strategy right from the beginning is optimal. It is also obvious that, in this case, the salvageability of specific learning by a supplier would not affect the buyers outsourcing decision. Our analysis and results contributes to the understanding of TCE and its application to governance decision-making in several research areas, which we shall next discuss.

6.1 Transaction Cost Economics and Long Term Contracts Uncertainty has been identified as a factor that affects transaction costs, and hence governance decision (Williamson; 1985), and has received much research attention (e.g. Walker and Weber, 1984 and 1987; Balakrishnan and Wernerfelt, 1986; Weiss and Anderson, 1992; and Stump and Heidi, 1996). We did not include uncertainty in our analysis. This is because we wish to show that the presence of specific learning and its salvageability by a supplier are sufficient to give rise to appropriation risk, and hence to affect governance decisions, even in the absence of uncertainty. Like Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1994), we examine the implications of the hold-up problem, when a firm cannot costlessly replace an agent if the latter possesses specific human capital. However, unlike Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1994), who focused on the make-or-buy decision and the optimal debt repayment path, respectively, our concern is on plural forms in terms of make-only, buy-only, or make-and-buy.

25

In our model, the appropriation risk is endogenous on specific learning and its salvageability. This ex-post cost differs from the agency cost that arises from the private information that agents have of their own productivity (Olsen, 1996). Several researchers applied the principal-agent approach in examining long term contracts (e.g., Aghion et al., 1994; Dewatripont and Maskin 1995; and Holden 1999), which were proposed as a substitute for vertical integration (e.g., Kleindorfer and Knieps 1982; and Joskow 1987). The underlying theme of the majority of the studies on long-term contracting (Aghion et al., 1994; Chung, 1991 and 1995; Dewatripont, 1988; Dewatripont and Maskin, 1995; Grout, 1984; Hart and Moore, 1988; Holden, 1999; Huberman and Kahn, 1988; and MacLeod and Malcomson, 1993) is one of ensuring an efficient level of investment when re-negotiation is possible. Compared to these studies, which followed the risk-sharing principal-agent approach, we follow the risk neutral transaction cost approach, in examining governance issues. It is worthwhile to note that Allen and Leuck (1995) reported that the transaction cost approach has a greater predictive validity than the former approach. We did not explicitly examine long term contracts between the supplier and the buyer. However, from our analysis, it can be shown that, any long-term contract that is re-negotiation and performance proof must take the form of subgame-perfect equilibrium (7) (Theorem 1) in our model, where the buyer adopts a buy-only strategy. The argument is as follows. Klein and Leffler (1981, p615) showed that a necessary and sufficient condition for (contractual) performance is the existence of price sufficiently above salvageable production costs. Applied to our model, this means that any performance assured long-term contract must satisfy the conditions that P1 CS(0) and P2 CS(1). These conditions are satisfied by P1* and P2* in our results, as evident from Theorem 1. It is also clear that any long-term contract that

26

appropriates all rents from the supplier, that is, P1 = CS(0) and P2 = CS(1), cannot be re-negotiation proof. This is because the supplier possesses a market option, which earns him a premium () from other buyers in the market, and which arises from the transferable specific assets that he has acquired. Hence, if P1 = CS(0) and P2 = CS(1), unless the contract is re-negotiated, the supplier would stop or disrupt supplies in Period 2. Any long term contract that is re-negotiation proof and performanceassured must therefore necessarily satisfy the condition that (P1 + P2) > (CS(0) + CS(1)), and in particular, take the form of subgame perfect equilibrium (7) as described in Theorem 1.

6.2 Empirical Studies on TCE and Procurement In a study that examines how small numbers bargaining and appropriation concerns affect firms procurement decisions, Pisano (1990) reported that a firms historical propensity to procure R&D internally does not affect its R&D procurement decision. In the author's study, historical propensity is measured as a ratio of the number of own, to total, R&D products in development. This suggested that the firms sampled in the author's study were following a make-and-buy strategy, which the author regarded as a hybrid mode when measuring governance responses. Our

analysis suggests that combined governance forms were more appropriately viewed as plural forms, instead of hybrid modes, and that asset specificity conditions be accurately categorized into three low, moderate, and high, instead of the usual two high and low, as in Pisanos (1990) study. These are important considerations

because, given that the firms sampled were following a make-and-buy strategy, Corollary 4 implies that they will eventually follow a buy-only and a make-only strategy under moderate and high asset specificity conditions respectively (Table 1).

27

Our results, which are derived theoretically, are in agreement with previous empirical findings by Masten et al. (1989) and Pisano (1990). The former reported that specific human capital has a positive and significant influence on the percentage of the component produced in-house while the latter found that small-numbers bargaining problems and the accumulation of specific technical capabilities influenced firms to internalize their R&D. These findings of theirs are in agreement with Propositions 1, 2, and 3 here, which imply that learning specificity has a positive effect on the proportion of a buyers supply requirements that he chooses to make vis-vis to buy (Table 1). However, Masten et al. (1989) and Pisano (1990) did not examine how governance decision might change over time, or how it could be affected by the salvageability of specific human capital by the supplier.

6.3 Empirical Studies on TCE and Channels of Distribution Anderson (1985) examined how specific assets affect a firms decision to internalize its sales function. It was reported that, when salespeople had high specific assets in their interactions with their clients, firms were more likely not to internalize their sales function. This observation, the author suggested, is contrary to basic TCE prediction. However, our analysis suggests that Andersons observation could be explained by the asymmetry in the salvageability of specific assets by salespeople vis-vis the firms. Client related specific assets are likely to be more salvageable by the salespeople, than by the firm. Given that this is the case, Corollary 3 implies that firms are likely to outsource their entire sales function eventually, if they had started with a plural form initially. However, under sufficiently high specific asset condition, firms will internalize their entire sales function eventually (Corollary 1).

28

Integrating channel distribution theory and ecology theory of organizational change, Weiss and Anderson (1992) examined a firms intention to change from one pure form of governance to another. The authors reported that there was considerable inertia shown by firms in changing from a rep to a direct sales force, which they attributed to managerial perceptions of high switching costs. Weiss and Anderson (1992, p110) concluded that, we provide one explanation for why specific distribution channel arrangements do not change as readily as prior theory may suggest. On the contrary, our analysis shows that the arguments based on TCE alone are sufficient to explain why firms do not change readily from one pure form to another, as given by Corollary 5.

7.

Conclusion

While this paper has provided some insights and a more precise understanding of the effect of specific asset and its salvageability on governance decisions over time, there are several limitations that are worth noting. We have not considered reputation effects, which may deter players from opportunistic behaviors (Klein and Leffler 1981). The issue of collusion among suppliers has been also omitted. However, given that collusion is illegal in many countries, this is a reasonable omission. Of the many types of specific assets identified (e.g., Klein et al. 1978; Williamson 1981; and Nooteboom 1993a), we have focused only on one type of specific assets, that is, specific human capital. Future studies could investigate the impact of the various types of specific assets on governance decisions. Although Williamson (1979, p245) stressed that the object is to economize on the sum of production and transaction costs, few studies have examined the combined effects of both these costs on governance decisions (Rindfleisch and Heidi, 1997). An analysis of the impact of

29

both production and transaction costs on plural forms is another direction for future research. Rindfleisch and Heidi (1997, p50) noted that "though a large body of empirical evidence has been generated on the use of various governance mechanisms, a discriminating theory of governance choice is still at an early stage of development." Towards this end, our paper is a modest attempt. However, we have only examined plural forms in terms of make, buy, and make-and-buy, and showed that the standard arguments of TCE are sufficient to explain such forms. The ability of TCE to explain other plural forms like franchising, joint ventures and licensing appears promising as another direction for future research. Finally, another logical extension would be to conduct an empirical verification of the theoretical propositions derived in this study.

References Allen, D.W., and D. Leuck, (1995), "Risk Preference and the Economics of Contracts," Proceedings of the 107th Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, (January), 447-451. Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M., and Rey, P., (1994), Renegotiation Design With Unverifiable Information, Econometrica, 62, 257-282. Anderson, Erin, (1985), "The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee: A Transaction Cost Analysis," Marketing Science, 4(3), 234-54. Anderson, Erin, and Barton A. Weitz, (1986), Make-or-Buy Decisions: Vertical Integration and Marketing Productivity, Sloan Management Review, 27 (3), Spring, 3-19. Anderson, Erin, and Barton A. Weitz, (1992), The Use of Pledges to Build and Sustain Commitment in Distribution Channels, Journal of Marketing Research, 29 (February), 18-34. Bradach, Jeffrey L., and Robert G. Eccles, (1989), "Price, Authority, and Trust: From Ideal Types to Plural Forms," Annual Review of Sociology, 15, 97-118. Balakrishnan, Srinivasan, and Birger Wernerfelt, (1986), Technical Change, Competition and Vertical Integration, Strategic Management Journal, 7 (July/August), 347-359. Carlton, D.W. (1979), "Vertical Integration in Competitive Markets Under Uncertainty," Journal of Industrial Economics, 27(3), p189-209. Chung, T-Y, (1991), Incomplete Contracts, Specific Investments, and Risk Sharing, Review of Economic Studies, 58, 1031-1042.

30

Chung, T-Y, (1995), On Strategic Commitment: Contracting versus Investment, The American Economic Review, 85(2), Papers and Proceedings of the Hundredth and Seventh Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association Washington, DC, January 6-8, 1995. (May, 1995), pp. 437-441. Coase, R. H., (1937), The Nature of The Firm, Economica, 4. Dewatripont, M.,(1988), Commitment Through Renegotiation-Proof Contracts With Third Parties, Review of Economic Studies, 55, 377-390. Dewatripont, M. and Maskin, E., (1995), Contractual Contingencies and Renegotiation, Rand Journalof Economics, 26(4), 704-719. Dutta, Shantanu, Mark Bergen, Jan B. Heidi, and George John, (1995), Understanding Dual Distribution: The Case of Reps and House Accounts, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, VII (1), 189-204. Dutta, Shantanu, and George John, (1995), Combining Lab Experiments and Industry Data in Transaction Cost Analysis: The Case of Competition as a Safeguard, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11(1), 87-111. Farrel, Joseph, and Nancy T. Gallini, (1988), Second-sourcing as a commitment: Monopoly incentives to attract competition, Quarterly Journal of Economics, (November), 673-694). Gallini, Nancy T., and Nacy A. Lutz, (1992), "Dual Distribution and Royalty Fees in Franchsing," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 8(3), 471-501. Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart, (1986), The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, Journal of Political Economy, 94 (4), 691-719. Grout, P., (1984), Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach, Econometrica, 52, 449-460. Hart, Oliver D., and John Moore, (1988), Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation, Econometrica, 56, 755-785. Hart, Oliver D., and John Moore, (1990), Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, Journal of Political Economy, 98 (6), 1119-1159. Hart, Oliver D., and John Moore, (1994), "A Theory of Debt based on the Inalienability of Human Capital", Quarterly Review of Economics, 109 (4), 841-879. Heidi, Jan B., (1994), "Interorganizational Governance in Marketing Channels," Journal of Marketing, 58 (January), 71-85. Heide, Jan B., and George John, (1988), The Role of Dependence Balancing in Safeguarding Transaction-Specific Assets in Conventional Channels, Journal of Marketing, 52 (1), 20-35. Heide, Jan B., and George John, (1990), Alliances in Industrial Purchasing: The Determinants of Joint Action in Buyer-Supplier Relationships, Journal of Marketing Research, 27 (February), 24-36. Holden, S., (1999), Renegotiation and The Efficiency of Investments, Rand Journal of Economics, 30(1), 106-119. Huberman, G. and Kahn, C.M., (1988), Limited Contract Enforcement and Strategic Renegotiation, American Economic Review, 78, 471-484. Irwin, Douglas A., and Peter J. Klenow, (1994), Learning-by-Doing Spillovers in the Semiconductor Industry, Journal of Political Economy, 102, 1200-1227. Joskow, Paul L., (1987), Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets, American Economic Review, 77 (1), 168-185.

31

Kliendorfer, Paul, and Gunter Knieps, (1982), Vertical Integration and TransactionSpecific Sunk Costs, European Economic Review, 19, 71-87. Klein, Benjamin, (1988), Vertical Integration as Organized Ownership: The Fisher Body General Motors Relationship Revisited, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4, 199-213. Klein, Benjamin, Robert G. Crawford, and Armen A. Alchian, (1978), Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents and the Competitive Contracting Process, Journal of Law and Economics, 21 (October), 297-326. Klein, Benjamin, and Keith B. Leffler, (1981), The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, Journal of Political Economy, 89 (August), 615-41. Leavy, Brian, (1994), 2 Strategic Perspectives on the Buyer-Supplier Relationship, Production and Inventory Management Journal, 35 (2), 47-51. Lee, Khai S., Guan H. Lim, and Soo J. Tan, (1999), Dealing with Resource Disadvantage: Generic Strategies for SMEs, Small Business Economics, 12, 299-311. Lim, Guan H., Khai S. Lee, and Soo J. Tan, (2000), Gray Marketing as an Alternative Market Penetration Strategy for Entrepreneurs: Conceptual Model and Case Evidence, Journal of Business Venturing, (forthcoming). MacLeod, W.B. and Malcomson, J.M.,(1993), Investment Holdup and the Form of Market Contracts, American Economic Review, 83, 811-837. Maltz, Arnold, (1994), "Outsourcing the Warehousing Function: Economic and Strategic Considerations," Logistics and Transport Review, 30(3), 245-265. Masten, Scott E., James W. Meehan Jr., and Edward A. Snyder, (1989), Vertical Integration in the U.S. Auto Industry: A Note on the Influence of Transaction Specific Assets, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 12, 265273. Monteverde, Kirk, (1995), Technical Dialog as an Incentive for Vertical Integration in the Semiconductor Industry, Management Science, 41 (10), 1624-1638. Monteverde, Kirk, and David J. Teece, (1982), Supplier Switching Costs and Vertical Integration in the Automobile Industry, Bell Journal of Economics, 13 (Spring), 206-213. Nooteboom, Bart, (1993a), Research Note: An Analysis of Specificity in Transaction Cost, Organization Studies, 14, 443-51. Nooteboom, Bart, (1993b), Firm Size Effects on Transaction Costs, Small Business Economics, 5 (4), 283-295. Olsen, Trond, (1996), Agency costs and the limits of integration, RAND Journal of Economics, 27 (3), Autumn, 479-501. Pisano, Gary P., (1990), Using Equity Participation to Support Exchane: Evidence from the Biotechnology Industry, Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 109-26. Rindfleisch, Aric, and Jan B. Heide, (1997), Transaction Cost Analysis: Past, Present, and Future Applications, Journal of Marketing, 61 (October), 30-54. Seshadri, Sudhindra, (1995), Bidding for Contests, Management Science, 41 (4), 561-576. Seshadri, Sudhindra, Kalyan Chatterjee, and Gary L. Lilien, (1991), Multiple Source Procurement Competitions, Marketing Science, 10 (3), 246-263. Shelanski, Howard A., and Peter G. Klein, (1995), Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11 (2), 335-361.

32

Stump, Rodney L., and Jan B. Heide, (1996), Controlling Supplier Opportunism in Industrial Relationships, Journal of Marketing Research, 33 (4), 431-442. Walker, Gordon, (1988), Strategic Sourcing, Vertical Integration, and Transaction Costs, Interfaces, 18(3), 62-73. Walker, Gordon, and David Weber, (1984), A Transaction Cost Approach to Makeor-Buy Decisions, Administrative Science Quarterly, 29 (3), 373-392. Walker, Gordon, and David Weber, (1987), Supplier Competition, Uncertainty, and Make or Buy Decisions, Academy of Management Journal, 30 (September), 589-96. Weiss, Allan M., and Erin Anderson, (1992), Converting From Independent to Employee Salesforces: The Role of Perceived Switching Costs, Journal of Marketing Research, 29 (February), 101-15. Williamson, Oliver E., (1979), Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations, Journal of Law and Economics, 22 (October), 3-61. Williamson, Oliver E., (1981), The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach, American Journal of Sociology, 87 (November), 548-77. Williamson, Oliver E., (1983), Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange, American Economic Review, 73 (September), 519-540. Williamson, Oliver E., (1984), Credible Commitments: Further Remarks, American Economic Review, 74 (3), (June), 488-490. Williamson, Oliver E., (1985), The Economic Institution of Capitalism, The Free Press, New York. Wilson, Elizabeth J., (1994), The Relative Importance of Supplier Selection Criteria: A Review and Update, International Journal of Purchasing and Materials Management, 30 (3), 35-43.

33

Figure 1: Impact of Specific Learning on Unit Cost

CS()

CB(1-)

CB(0)

CS(0) CB(1-) (CS() + ()) Curve

CS() CB(1) CS()

()
CS()

CS(1)

(0)
0

34

Table 1: Impact of Specific Learning and its Salvageability on Decision to Make, Buy, or Make-and-Buy

Specific Learning Effect Low:


Case(iii) CS(1) + (1) CS(0) < CB(1-1)

Moderate: Case(ii) CS(1) + (1) CB(1-1) CS(0) Make-and-Buy Followed by Buy-Only

High: Case(i) CB(1-1) CS(1) + (1) CS(0)

High Salvageability

1 {, b,} such that < b <


Buy-Only

2 = 1
Make-and-Buy Followed by Buy-Only

Low Salvageability

1 = 1 2 = 1

Make-and-Buy Followed by Or Make-Only Followed by Make-Only

1 {, b,} such that < b < 2 = 1 1 < 1

1 {0, , a} such that 0 < a < 2 = 0

35

Appendix Proof of Lemma 1 d/d (CS() + ()) = d/d (CS() + CS(0) - CS()) = CS() - CS() < CS() - CS() (as given by (d) on Page 8) = (1 - ) CS() < 0. Hence, CS() + () as defined by CS() - CS() + CS(0) has a negative derivative with respect to , and is therefore decreasing in .

Proof of Lemma 2 In Period 2, B chooses (2(1,P1), P2(1,P1)) to maximize his current period payoff, which is given by [2P2 + (1 - 2)CB(1-1)]. If CB(1-1) CS(1) + (1), then B will never buy from S in Period 2. If however, CB(1-1) > CS(1) + (1), the buyer will outsource his entire requirement to the supplier S. The existence of an outside option (1) implies that P2 is bounded below by CS(1) + (1), and bounded above by Min{CB(1-1), CS(0)}. The Nash bargaining solution is therefore as given in the statement of the lemma.

Proof of Proposition 1 Since CB(1 - 1) CS(1) + (1) CS(0), 1 [0, ], Lemma 2 implies that 2 = 0. The buyers payoff can then be simplified as B(1,CS(0),0,CB(1-1)) = [1CS(0) + (1 - 1)CB(0)] + CB(1-1). It is then easy to show that B(1,CS(0),0,CB(11)) is minimized at a, if it exists, such that CB(1-1) = CS(0) - CB(0), or at one of the boundary points, 0 or . Substituting the solutions P2* = CB(1-1*) and 1* into = (P2 - CS(1)), it follows that = (CB(1-1*) - CS(1*)).

Proof of Proposition 2 Since CS(1) + (1) < CB(1-1) CS(0), 1: < 1 , it is straightforward to deduce from Lemma 2 that the buyer will choose 2 = 1. Hence, in Period 1, the optimal proportion to outsource to the same supplier 1 is selected to minimize the total cost, given by, B(1,CS(0),1,(1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CB(1-1)) = [1CS(0) + (1 - 1)CB(0) + (1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CB(1-1)]. The optimal choice for 1 is thus the interior turning point b, if it exists, or one of the boundary points or. When or is sufficiently large, the first-order-condition of B(1,CS(0),1,(1 )(CS(1) + (1)) + CB(1-1)) is positive for all (,) and we have 1* = . We therefore deduce that 1* is non-increasing in and . By a similar argument, as increases, the first-order-condition increases since [{-CS(1*) + CS(1*)} CB(1-1*)] > 0 (Lemma 1), which implies that 1* = . Hence, we deduce that 1* is non-increasing in .

36

Proof of Proposition 3 Since CS(1) + (1) CS(0) < CB(1-1), 1: < 1 1, it is straightforward to deduce from Lemma 2 that the buyer will choose 2 = 1 and P2* = (1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CS(0). Hence, the buyers objective function becomes, B(1,CS(0),1,(1 - )(CS(1) + (1)) + CS(0)) = [1CS(0) + (1 - 1)CB(0) + (1 )(CS(1) + (1)) + CS(0)], for which the first order condition is given by [CS(0) CB(0) + (1 - )(CS(1) - CS(1))], which is always negative (Lemma 1). Hence, the minimum point is the right end-point, that is, 1* = 1.

Proof of Theorem 1 Let a,b denote the subgame perfect equilibrium of the subgame a,b, that is, a,b is of the form (1, P1, 2(1,P1), P2(1,P1)). We know from Propositions 1, 2, and 3 that the subgame perfect equilibrium of the game is given by,

* = arg min B ().


= 0 , , , , ,1

The subgame perfect equilibria (1), (2) and (3) follows from Proposition 1, while the subgame perfect equilibria (4), (5) and (6) are results of Proposition 2. Finally, subgame perfect equilibrium (7) is a direct result of Proposition 3.

37

Вам также может понравиться