Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 24

Koninklijke Brill NV, Leiden, 2010 DOI: 10.

1163/002249910X12573963244485
Journal of the Economic and
Social History of the Orient 53 (2010) 266-289 brill.nl/jesh
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in
Early Modern South India
David Washbrook*
Abstract
Classically, economic theory and anthropology have been concerned with the dichotomy
between non-market and market systems of exchange, and with the transition from the
former to the latter. From this perspective, the two are necessarily conceived as juxtaposi-
tional and antithetical. However, for long periods of history, non-market and market sys-
tems of exchange subsisted side-by-side, creating a hybrid institutional environment. In
the context of South India between sixteenth and eighteenth centuries, this paper seeks to
explore a range of issues arising from such hybridity and, especially, how market and non-
market factors could work together to sustain particular economic structures and to direct
development in very particular ways. It especially focuses on the implications of institu-
tional hybridity for merchant and banking capital.
Depuis pas mal de temps les historiens conomiques et les anthropologues sont proccups
par la dichotomie qui existe entre le systme dchange qui a des formes non marchandes
de circulation du produit social et celui ayant des formes marchandes de circulation des
biens. Et dans le prolongement de cette division, par le passage du premier systme au
second. Cest dans cette perspective que ces deux mondes conomiques sont perus comme
juxtaposs et antithtiques. Durant de longues priodes historiques les deux systmes
dchange se sont maintenus cependant cte cte, et par cela ont cr un cadre institu-
tionnel hybride. Cette contribution se propose dexaminer lventail de sujets soulev
par cette division binaire dans le contexte de lInde du Sud aux seizimedix-huitime si-
cles. Elle sintresse particulirement lassociation des dterminants des deux catgories qui,
eux, ont soutenu des structures conomiques spciques et qui ont contribu au dveloppe-
ment de faon tout fait spciale. Larticle traite en particulier des consquences de lhybri-
dit institutionnelle dans le domaine des fonds de commerce et des fonds bancaires.
Keywords
non-market and market-systems, South India, early-modern economic development,
economic institutions
*
)
David Washbrook, Trinity College, Cambridge, United Kingdom, david.wash-
brook@sant.ox.ac.uk
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 267
One of the most enduring conceptual dichotomies in economic anthro-
pology is the one posited by Polanyi between market and non-market
forms of exchange.
1
Whereas the rst involves the exchange of goods in
relation to scarcity, competition, and (usually) monetary mediation, the
second involves exchanges of gift determined by status, power, and com-
munity need. Te presumption has been that, with the growth of trade
andcertainlythe emergence of capitalism, the latter would give way to
the former, which Polanyi himself clearly regretted. And not Polanyi alone:
E. P Tompsons idea of moral economy comes close to Polanyis concept
of non-market exchange, and was also seen to suer an unfortunate and
regressive fate at the hands of the (presumably immoral) principles asso-
ciated with Smithian economics.
2
Te sharpness of these conceptual dichotomies and the value judge-
ments of their authors have necessarily guided subsequent approaches to
analysis. Market and non-market, moral and immoral, phenomena are
seen as standing in juxtaposition and their history is represented in terms
of the inevitable (if brutal) displacement of the one by the other. In par-
ticular, non-market, moral economies tend only to be viewed in retreat.
Yet this may miss the extent to which, over very long periods, the princi-
ples of the two have co-existed together creating hybrid structures of
remarkable persistence. It may also miss the extent to which, even in
advanced capitalist economies today, markets continue to be distorted
by relations of gift, based on status, power, and community need, espe-
cially through the mediation of the nation state. Te institutional eco-
nomics associated with Douglass North has drawn attention to these
distortions and demonstrated their signicance in determining specic
market outcomes in the real world.
3
Nonetheless, North-ians are also
inclined to have their own implicit moral view: albeit, in reversal of the
Polanyi/Tompson position, one in which the market ought to overcome
distortions in order to achieve greater e ciency. Tis, no less, lends an
element of teleology to their perspectives on history.
In this paper, conversely, I want to explore issues related to hybridity
and, especially, how market and non-market factors may work together to
1)
K. Polanyi, Te Great Transformation: Te Political and Economic Origins of our Time
(New York: Rhinehart and Company, 1944).
2)
E. P. Tompson, Te Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth Cen-
tury. Past and Present 50 (1971): 76-136.
3)
D. C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1990).
268 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
sustain particular economic structures over a long period, but also direct
them in very particular ways. For the purposes of this paper, I also want to
consider the special implications for merchant and banking capital of
operating in such a hybrid environment.
I
My case study concerns the economy (or economies) of southern India
between the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries, which by all accounts con-
tained most of the elements associated with a market economyand one
given to expansion (albeit unstably) at various points in this period. Te
region, of course, lay at the core of an international textile trade stretching
from South-East Asia to Europe. Its systems of production strongly favored
both an advanced division of labor and an exchange of raw materials over
long distances, much cotton being brought from the interior for weaving
in coastal settlements.
4
Te relations of both waged (in various ways)
labor and raw cotton and thread exchange were mediated by monetary
values and took place in institutionalized and recognizable markets.
5

Moreover, the cotton industry did not sit on top of an economy otherwise
characterized by subsistence production. Large quantities of basic food
stus were also moved around in itKerala was fed from Tanjavur,
northern Tamil Nadu from Andhra and even Bengal. Capital goods were
also traded through widely dispersed markets, especially cattle which
would not breed in the rice-producing, deltaic lowlands but were brought
to market from the upland hills.
6
From at least the eleventh century, there
is also evidence of rights to land being bought and sold and taxes being
paid in money. Te resulting transactions gave rise to substantial merchant
and banking institutions whose activities were multiple and various.
7
In
4)
P. Parthasarathi, Te Transition to a Colonial Economy Weavers, Merchants and Kings in
South India 1720-1800 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001).
5)
F. Perlin, Proto-Industrialization and Pre-Colonial South Asia. Past and Present 98
(1983): 30-95.
6)
D. A. Washbrook, Land and Labour in Late Eighteenth Century South India: Te
Golden Age of the Pariah? In Dalit Movements and the Meanings of Labour in India, ed.
P. Robb (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1993) 68-86.
7)
On the general characteristics of the southern economy in this era see, Sanjay Subrah-
manyam, Te Political Economy of Commerce: Southern India, 1500-1650 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1990); D. Ludden, Peasant History in South India (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1985).
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 269
reviewing the recorded prices across many economic sectors during this
period, K. N. Chaudhuri was in no doubt that they reected strong ele-
ments of price rationality.
8
But, at the same time, there were many features of the economy which
suggested a dierent kind of rationality. Issues of caste had ramications in
all markets. Tis was, of course, most obvious in the labor market where
the division of labor and skills broadly followed caste prescriptions. But
it was true, no less, in capital markets where (especially with regard to
paraiyansUntouchables) caste inuenced access to land and could deter-
mine even more minutely the distribution of state and community taxa-
tion. And it was even true of certain commodity markets where the price
of a good (for example, paraiyan cloth) was often determined as much by
who had made it as by what its quality and intrinsic value might have
been.
9
Recent studies of the grain market have made clear that, in spite of
evidence of large-scale exchange, there was little integration so far as
price factors are concerned.
10
Equally, the rights to property and resources that were bought and
sold were dened by criteria that were distinctly non-economic. Claims
to superior land rights (kaniachi, later mirasi) were validated by reference
to ancestry (connections to those who had originally cleared the land), to
gifts from the gods, and to recognition by relevant kings. Teir formal
sale was also divinely mediated: land rights were gifted to a god who then
gifted them onto the new owner in return for a gift of money, which the
god then passed back to the original giftee. Property documents were
usually lodged with the gods too, held in choultry depositaries.
11
Other
important forms of property, such as maunyam or inam privileges to reve-
nue immunity were simply dened as direct gifts from kings and gods,
which in many cases would then pass into market circulation.
12
8)
K. N. Chaudhuri, Markets and Traders in India during the Seventeenth and Eight-
eenth Centuries. In Economy and Society: Essays in Indian Economic and Social History, eds
K. N. Chaudhuri and C. Dewey (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1979): 256-75.
9)
Washbrook, Golden Age.
10)
R. Studer, India and the Great Divergence: Assessing the E ciency of Grain Markets
in Eighteenth and Nineteenth Century India. Journal of Economic History 68 (2008):
393-437.
11)
Ludden, Peasant History.
12)
B. Stein, Privileged Landholding. In Land Tenure and Peasant in South Asia, ed.
R.E. Frykenberg (Delhi: Orient Longman, 1977): 67-77.
270 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
Moreover, even money itself was subject to extra-economic forms of valu-
ation. Most of the South lay outside the zone of the Mughal (classically,
the Akbar) silver rupee, made use of multiple coinages, and preferred
to make gold its ultimate standard of value.
13
However, in eect, it
operated a tri-metallic systemgold, silver, and copperon bullionist
principles, with the value of each being determined by demand and the
availability of the others in local markets. Nonetheless, certain communi-
ties developed an atavistic attachment to certain types of coinage and
would take no other, regardless of actual metal content. In the late eight-
eenth century, for example, the East India Company experienced serious
problems in procuring Salem blue cloths from its new territories in Kar-
nataka since the local weavers insisted on being paid only in pagodas
minted by the Portuguese in their Porto Nuevo settlement, which had long
lost its minting functions.
14
Equally, the Canteroi pagoda of Hyder Ali and
Tipu Sultan carried particular prestige and a premium over the East India
Companys star pagoda for several years after the defeat of Mysore. In
South India, money was never simply money.
In the 1960s, the existence in the same eld of so many aspects of
both a market and a non-market economy drew the attention of the Soviet
historian Chicherov. Deferring to the principles of classical Marxism, he
understood the situation to reect a particular moment in the transition to
capitalism. On the one hand, he supposed that a subsistence economy,
premised on the caste-based principles of the jajmani system, existed side-
by-side with, and parallel to, a market-based system (serving the interna-
tional demand for textiles) and that the two were not inter-penetrative,
except for the division of labor time. He also supposed that the market
system would progressively overtake the subsistence system, drawing the
whole economy under the logic of global capitalism.
15
However, much of
Chicherovs data came from the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries and,
if we were to return to South India at the end of the eighteenth century, it
would still not be clear how far the transition had gone. While pressure
(much of it coercive and extra-economic) from the European companies
was beginning to make its mark on economic organization, the same
13)
J. F. Richards, ed., Te Imperial Monetary System of Mughal India (Delhi: Oxford Uni-
versity Press, 2000).
14)
Washbrook, Golden Age.
15)
A. Chicherov, Economic Development in the Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries: Outline His-
tory of Crafts and Trades (Moscow: Moscow Publishing House, 1971).
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 271
curious combination of market and non-market relations remained very
much in evidence.
16
Moreover, it was hardly the case that the subsistence
and market systems ever ran parallel without touching. As noted previ-
ously, subsistence itself frequently depended on an ability to buy food,
commodities, and capital goods from outside: the subsistence and market
economies were, in fact, inter-penetrative.
Elsewhere, I have attempted to reconcile this paradox.
17
To summarize
briey, the local provision of subsistence was always very di cult. Cli-
matic and environmental factors made the delivery of water to particular
placeswhether by monsoon rain or river spateunpredictable and haz-
ardous. Yet when water arrived, it was possible to produce tropical crops
in super-abundance. In response, local societies developed relations of
exchangeinvolving labor and capital as well as commoditiesto iron out
the dierences. Te South was never characterized by the existence of self-
contained, subsistence-oriented village communities. It rather depended
on circulating resources over large areas, and the larger the better since risk
was then more widely spread. Money came to penetrate these exchange-for-
subsistence relationships and to facilitate their progressive expansion. By
the seventeenth century, London, Amsterdam, Manila, and Arabia were all
economically part of South India: sales in their markets provided cash which
could be used to buy food from Bengal and South-East Asia.
But, and importantly, the institutional conguration supporting the
market in South India did remain based in local institutions geared, in
rst instance, to subsistence provision and response to community need.
Caste organizations (guilds) dominated the labor market and the dissemi-
nation of skills. Temples played a critical role in the redistribution of
resources and in ensuring trust through the threat of divine sanctions.
Especially in the interior, lineage organizations and little kingships deter-
mined primary access to resources. Te key here was the weak (or attenu-
ated) development of big kingship or the centralized bureaucratic
state/empire. Although the Chola Empire (tenth-twelfth centuries) may
have been more centralized than, for example, Burton Stein conceived in
his model of the segmentary state, there seems little doubt that thereafter
de-centralization was the core feature of subsequent politiesVijayanagar,
16)
Parthasarathi, Transition.
17)
D. Washbrook, India in the Early Modern World Economy: Modes of Production,
Reproduction and Exchange. Journal of Global History 2 (2007): 87-111.
272 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
the Nayaksuntil the late seventeenth century.
18
Te Mughal drive south
into Golconda oered the promise of a stronger imperial state, but was
never fully realized before the British conquest. Several new regional states
arose or sought to congure state power in new waysTravancore,
Mysore, Arcot, Hyderabadand put increased pressure on local commu-
nity institutions.
19
But they became involved in half-a-century of bitter
political conict with one another and were unable to consolidate their
new claims to authority. Tis left the state in South India very dualistic
in the sense outlined by Frank Perlin for Marathawad.
20
Authority over
resources derived from two dierent sources: from the prerogatives of kings
and emperors, but also from those of community institutions. Te two
continued to exist side-by-side, betimes coalescing but also potentially
clashing. Before the British conquest, what the state was, and who repre-
sented it, were complex questions in South India.
Complex, too, was the relationship of this state to the market, and
how monetary exchanges were institutionalized. Actual markets tended to
form around all and any point of available authoritytemples, armies,
little kings, lineage and caste headships. Necessarily, there was little uni-
formity between them in rules and conventions. Few royal authorities, for
example, insisted on payments being made in their own coinages: bullion-
ism meant the acceptance of many coins, even in revenue payment. Also,
measurements were largely matters of local custom. Not only did they vary
across regions (for example, the Chingleput veli was six times larger than
the Tanjavur veli) but, in the same place, the same standard of measure-
ment could be applied dierently to dierent commodities and even peo-
ple. Te maund and the garce were deemed to be of dierent weights when
weighing grain, cotton, or salt.
21
And the East India Company discovered,
in the villages which it acquired behind Fort St David, that the tola
had fourteen dierent meanings depending on the caste to which it was
being applied.
22
18)
B. Stein, Peasant State and Society in Medieval South India (Delhi: Oxford University
Press, 1980); Sanjay Subrahmanyam, Penumbral Visions: Making Politics in Early Modern
South India (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2001).
19)
D. A. Washbrook, South India 1770-1840: Te Colonial Transition. Modern Asian
Studies 38 (2004): 649-721.
20)
F. Perlin, State Formation Reconsidered. Modern Asian Studies 19 (1985): 415-80.
21)
Chitra Sivakumar and S. S. Sivakumar, Peasants and Nabobs: Agrarian Radicalism in
Late Eighteenth Century Tamil Country (Delhi: Hindustan Publishing House, 1993).
22)
Ibidem.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 273
Equally, the resolution of commercial disputes raised tricky issues. Tey
were easiest to handle within discrete caste organizations where the threat
of out-casting provided a potent sanction. And, among merchant castes,
there is some evidence of a cross-caste mahajan supplying similar functions.
But trade was never conned to merchant castes alone and the multiplicity
of dierent authorities, together with the high degree of physical mobility,
made it possible for many to evade unfavorable judgements. Sometimes
recourse might be had to divine sanctions: the priests of the Tirupati tem-
ple, it was said, experienced few defaults on the money they lent out since
failure to repay brought a ferocious curse from Sri Venkateswara himself.
23

Nonetheless, if Arjun Appadurai is correct in his assessment that the
authority applied by kings to temple disputes was administrative rather
than executive, there was a serious problem.
24
Administrative authority
appears to have meant the recognition and validation of locally-derived
arrangements. But where the local community lacked means to discipline
peripatetic members, there was little hope of resolution.
II
Elsewhere, I have attempted to outline the logic of development implied
by the early modern South Indian economy, but mainly with regard to
production and reproduction.
25
To summarize: the system appears to
have been geared to ironing out instabilities in local production regimes
and recovering from (if less surviving) sharp famines, which could be
frequent (north Coromandel, for example, experienced signicant famines
in 1718-9, 1728-36, 1747, 1769, 1781-3, 1789, 1792, and 1798).
26
Te
system also favored the physical expansion of production, albeit with the
implication of a somewhat careless use of natural resources. Virgin land
was constantly being cleared for the plough, and labor and capital were
adept at moving onto new pastures. But this was often at the expense of
vacating land which (usually due to water problems) had lost its fertility,
sometimes permanently due to silting up or desertication.
23)
Ibidem.
24)
A. Appadurai, Worship and Conict Under Colonial Rule: A South Indian Case Book
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981).
25)
Washbrook, World Economy.
26)
R. Ahuja, Labour Relations in an Early Colonial Context: Madras c. 1750-1800.
Modern Asian Studies 36 (2002): 793-826.
274 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
Moreover, what the system did not encourage were xed, permanent
investments. Te technologies of the time were inadequate to signicant
water storage or altering the courses of rivers in spate. Some eorts were
made at tank storagebut ine ciently under a burning sunand at
well-digging, but rarely very deep. For the most part, irrigation technolo-
gies centered on the better distribution of water when it arrived, but they
could do little to make it arrive. Nonetheless, there was an expansionary
drive within the economy, perhaps reective of the increasing ability to tap
external resources through trade. In population terms, there appears to have
been a strong growth in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, checked
(probably by war and disturbance) in the rst half of the eighteenth cen-
tury, but beginning to recover by the turn of the nineteenth century.
27

However, here my major interest lies less in the history of material pro-
duction and social reproduction than the implications of the system for
the organization of exchange and merchant and nance capital. First, of
course, the system made huge demands for an infrastructure of exchange.
At least as much value was added to production by moving it to the right
place for sale, at the right time, as by growing or manufacturing it. In
the grain basket of Tanjavur, paddy could be produced so super-abun-
dantly that it had little value except in so far as it could be shipped to
Kerala and Sri Lanka; equally, cotton in the interior districts where it grew
had a limited value until transported to the textile industries and outlets
on the coast. Te nature of the economy made exchange a near-ubiquitous
activity (even landless laborers in the paddy-producing areas were said to
exchange rice, which they received as wages in shares of the crop, for dry
grains brought from inland, which they preferred to eat).
28
It also gave rise
to an enormous infrastructure supplying functions of transporting, exchang-
ing, and buying and selling practically everythingincluding money (bul-
lion) itself, i.e. shro ng. As Dharma Kumar noted from evidence from
the turn of the nineteenth century, South India had an exceptionally large
services sector for a pre-modern economy.
29

Exchange even began within the village, where the jajmani system (albeit
archetypically) reected the distribution of resources between the dierent
27)
Sumit Guha, Te Population History of South Asia from the Seventeenth to the Twen-
tieth Centuries: An Exploration. In Asian Population History, eds Tsui Jung Lui et al.
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001): Ch. 4.
28)
Washbrook, Golden Age.
29)
Dharma Kumar, Te Forgotten Sector. In Colonialism, Private Property and the State,
ed. Dharma Kumar (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1998): 55-92.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 275
castes. It extended to larger villages which acted as casbahs to surrounding
territories. It acquired regional dimensions through the activities of the
banjaras, whose vast herds of pack bullocks brought cotton, iron, and dry
grains from the interior and took back salt, ne rice, and ne cloth. And,
also, through the activities of maritime communities where a coastal sea
trade followed the winds, bringing rice from the north and taking back salt
from the south. And it reached sub-continental and international dimen-
sions through the activities of specialist merchant communities, freighting
southern manufactures (especially textiles) to foreign ports from Europe to
the Levant to South-East Asia.
Each of these dierent levels of trade involved somewhat dierent
people and gave rise to somewhat dierent kinds of organization. At, as it
were, the bottom of the system, much primary exchange of goods and
commodities was in the hands of people linked to production. Large farm-
ers, who also lent money to small producers, appear to have dominated the
bases of the grain trade; and head weavers and small merchants drawn
from the weaving castes were in charge of the cloth trade.
30
For a long
time, shro ng was largely carried out by gold and silver smiths. But
inter-regional trade necessitated a dierent kind of connection. Banjaras
not only carried goods across the interior on their pack bullocks but bought
and sold them in their own right. Tey were very far from the pedlars and
gypsies depicted in colonial times. Teir caravans could stretch to thou-
sands of bullocks and they articulated the interior economy with that of
the coast. If sometimes treated with suspicion (for their legendary criminal
activities), they also enjoyed considerable prestige and no little power.
Teir annual arrival in parts of Tanjavur, for example, was greeted with
festivals and the conveying of temple honors to their nayaks; and their
non-arrival was greatly feared since it portended economic marginaliza-
tion.
31
Teir bullocks were also vital to military operations: the East India
Company kept close surveillance on the relations of its nemesis, Tipu Sul-
tan, with the banjaras and, in 1792, gained its rst conrmation that he
planned war when reports from Seringapatnam indicated that he had
negotiated the supply of 25,000 carriage cattle.
32
Indeed, it was not least
30)
Parthasarathi, Transition.
31)
Washbrook, World Economy.
32)
M. Wilks, Historical Sketches of South Indian History from the Origin of the Hindoo
Government of that State to the Extinction of the Mohammedan Dynasty in 1799, ed.
M. Hammick (Mysore: Government Branch Press, 1930).
276 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
the success of the Company in disrupting Tipus access to cattle, and thus
means of mobility, that led to his eventual demise.
33
Parallel to, and frequently working with, the banjara caravans were
specialist merchant castes, who used their own internal organizations to
develop trade over long distances. Most prominent, down the south-east
coast, were Telugu Komatis who specialized in chilli, turmeric, and tobacco,
grown in Andhra, but were also involved in the cloth and rice trades. Tey
spread across many of the casbahs in the Tamil and Kannada countries, but
kept their identity and cohesion through maintenance of their language
and, also, worship at their own sectarian temples.
34
Across smaller regions,
and in relation to dierent trades, similar caste organizations played simi-
lar functions among a variety of Chetty groups, and also in the extreme
south among Tamil Muslim Labbai merchants. At the apex of the system
were two dierent kinds of foci. On the one hand, there was the very long
distance or international sea-borne trade. Some discrete Chetty and Labbai
families carried this on in their own right. But frequently it depended on
knowledge of overseas markets and foreign contacts. Foreign traders
Armenians, Persians/Mughals, Jews, Arabslong played an important role
in southern commerce. From the sixteenth century, they were progressively
joined by a variety of Europeans. From the rst, the Europeans behaved dif-
ferently, especially at sea: seeking to link the control of trade to the exercise
of armed power.
35
However, on land, their impact was very limited until the
eighteenth century and, like other foreigners, they were largely dependent
on their ability to connect to internal commercial networks.
But there were also other foci of inter-regional trade. Courts and armies,
in their own right, were major consumption centers, drawing supplies
from wide areas and passing them upward to imperial authorities as vari-
ous kinds of tribute. Temples were also important centers for economic
investment and re-distributionto support masses of annual pilgrims but
also to create fairs for the trans-regional exchange of specialist goods, and
these were not always of a religious nature.
36
Te small temples around
33)
Washbrook, South India.
34)
D. A. Washbrook, Te Development of Caste Organisation in South India. In South
India: Political Institutions and Political Change, eds C. J. Baker and D. Washbrook (Delhi:
Macmillan, 1975): 150-203.
35)
Sanjay Subrahmanyam, Te Portuguese Empire in Asia 1500-1700: A Political and
Economic History (London: Longman, 1993).
36)
B. Stein, Te Economic Function of a Medieval South Indian Temple. Journal of
Asian Studies 19 (1960): 163-76.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 277
Arni, in the north Arcot district, for example, long served as the fair ground
for peninsular Indias largest sale of war horsesmany shipped from Ara-
bia to the west coast and then trekked across the Ghats.
37

It was principally in relation to foreign, courtly, and temple centers of
trade that caste as the organizing principle of commercial relations was
inclined to break downor, at least, to be supplemented by others.
38

Access to the privileges of authority allowed many people from non-
commercial ormanufacturingcastes into the market place: high-status
Brahmins, Muslim warriors and grandees, even the occasional Untouch-
able (e.g. Nadars).
39
Power could transcend caste here, albeit that overtime
it might give rise to caste-like developments (for example, Smartha Brah-
mins from Kallidaikurichi who became a specialist money-lending caste).
40

As the Souths trans-regional and international trading connections
expanded, so did the social pluralism of those involved in trade, especially
via banking where cash could often be the solvent of tradition. Certainly
by the early eighteenth century, the commercial communities of most
major trading centersboth coastal and interiorreected the most
diverse of origins.
In other contexts, most notably China, attempts have been made to
map a hierarchy of connections between dierent levels of the marketing
system, which also served to diuse political power and state authority.
41

But, in South India, any such map would look more like anarchy than
hierarchy. In the rst place, there were multiple rival centers at the top:
dierent courts, dierent ports, even dierent temples competing for the
same mobile resources. Trades in dierent products followed dierent
routes: even basic foods were not necessarily locally supplied. Ten, ban-
jara caravan routes followed a haphazard set of courses, depending on the
availability of water and grazing. Tere was very little symmetry but, rather,
37)
J. Gommans, Mughal Warfare: Indian Frontiers and Highroads to Empire 1500-1700
(London: Taylor and Francis, 2002).
38)
On this breakdown in the environs of Madras city, see T. Mizushima, Nattar and Socio-
Economic Change in South India in the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries (Tokyo: Tokyo
University press, 1986).
39)
R. L. Hardgrave, Te Nadars of Tamil Nadu: Te Political Culture of a Community in
Change (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1969).
40)
H. L. Pate, Gazetteer of the Tinnevelly District, vol. 1 (Madras: Government of Madras,
1917).
41)
G. W. Skinner, Marketing and Social Structure in Rural China, part 1-3. Journal of
Asian Studies 24 (1964-5): 3-44; 195-228; 363-99.
278 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
a constant uidity and circulation. Indeed, far from providing a stable
socio-economic map onto which political authority could graft itself, the
nature of the exchange economy in South India tended to undermine
the possibilities of such authority. Faced with an oppressive power, labor
and capital were inclined to move, banjara caravans to take new routes,
merchants to seek other markets, bankers to look for other clients.
42
Te
high levels of movement in the southern economy, which helped it to sub-
sist and survive, also tended to neutralize attempts to create xed geo-
graphical points from which to exercise political power and authority:
particular kingdoms were, for the most part, short-lived aairs.
43

Yet if socio-economic, or institutional, conditions were so anarchic,
and transaction costs necessarily so high, how were often distant markets
kept supplied, and why should merchant capital remain interested in the
South? To some extent, it should be noted, that the Souths problems did
undermine its erstwhile position in world trade. From the late seventeenth
century, trade with Persia seems to have declined, and the Europeans began
to move their operations to the easier elds of trade to be found in Ben-
gal.
44
Nonetheless, the southern textile trade never entirely declined and
the grain and salt trades certainly continued. Te answer to the Souths
problem may have lain in internal systems which discounted particular
di culties against other advantages.
Te inability to deliver products on time was a major weakness of the
system (as the records of the European Companies with their ships waiting
in the roads to catch tide and wind make clear). Banjara caravans fol-
lowed variable routes and producers were more responsive to the weather
(which determined the allocation of their time between, say, spinning and
farming) than to money. Also quality was a constant issue.
45
Te struc-
ture of power in, for example, the weaving industry strongly favored
corporately organized producers against competing merchant capitalists.
Before the nineteenth century, merchants never advanced thread (i.e. put
out) or controlled product design, which was in the hands of the produc-
ers themselves. By convention, producers could cancel contracts at any
time prior to delivery simply by returning any money advances which they
42)
Washbrook, South India.
43)
Subrahmanyam, Political Economy.
44)
Om Prakash, Te Dutch East India Company and the Economy of Bengal 1630-1720
(Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1985).
45)
Parthasarathi, Transition.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 279
might have received from merchants. Labor, here, was the master of capi-
talor, at least, a remarkably equal partner.
46
It were, especially, the prob-
lems connected to time and quality that drew the European Companies,
and particularly the English, into seeking forms of political power inland.
But these disadvantages were o-set against other advantages, especially
of potential cheapness. Banjara caravans may not have been very predict-
able, but their transport costs were very low. Teir bullock herds ate o the
land and bred on the hoof. Equally, the coastal craft plying the salt and
grain trades followed the tides and winds without costs of power. Te high
oscillations in the markets for everythingincluding bullionalso cre-
ated opportunities. Weavers, for example, were often paid in copper, whose
value against gold and silver depended on local conditions of supply and
demand. Where copper was plentiful, their cloth could have a very low
value in the gold or silver terms in which most merchants (including Euro-
peans) made their nal evaluations. In that case textiles might be acquired
very cheaply indeed. Te Dutch established their strong position in south-
ern markets in the seventeenth century especially through their ability to
import Japanese copper.
47
Equally, when local agricultural conditions were
poor, much labor time would be spent spinning thread in compensation.
Tis, however, glutted local thread markets, driving down prices and mak-
ing textiles especially cheap. By playing the various intersecting markets
in bullion, cotton, thread, and grainit was possible to speculate very
high levels of prot from southern trade.
But it was also possibleand very easyto lose out. Great fortunes
might be made in the commerce of this period as, for example, by Kasi
Viranna who was the English Companys rst dubash in Madras and, by
legend, the author of their own success.
48
But, as Ashin Dasgupta has
pointed out, such fortunes rarely lasted very long and, usually, fell foul of
a vagarious fortune represented by famine, war, ship-wreck, or changes in
political power.
49
In eect, wealth was di cult to accumulate, protect, and
convert into institutionalized forms of capital. But the way in which mer-
46)
Perlin, Proto-Industrialization.
47)
T. Raychaudhuri, Jan Companie in Coromandel: A study in the Interrelations of European
Commerce and Traditional Economies (Den Haag: Nijho, 1962).
48)
K. N. Chaudhuri, Te Trading World of Asia and the English East India Company 1660-
1760 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978).
49)
A. Dasgupta, Foreign Trade: Indian Merchants and the Trade in the Indian Ocean,
1500-1750. In Cambridge Economic History of India, vol. I: c. 1200-1750, eds I. Habib and
T. Raychaudhuri (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982): Ch. 13-2.
280 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
chants attempted to do so had important implications for the nature of
trade and the development of the economy.
Necessarily, they were highly risk-averse and looked to share and o-
load risks at every opportunity. One strategy, as K. N. Chaudhuri has
noted, was to divide their activities as widely as possibleinvesting in
multiple trades so that failure in one could be o-set against success in
others.
50
Tis made capital widely available for short-term adventures and
encouraged commercial entrepreneurialism. But it also restricted invest-
ments in long-term, xed arrangements. Partnerships for single voyages
were not uncommon in sea trade, and various insurance mechanisms seem
to have been developed. But permanent (e.g. joint-stock) commercial insti-
tutions were rare, even within the bounds of caste (where, for example, the
banking consortia organized by the Nattukkottai Chetties in the nine-
teenth century do not appear to have had an early modern precedent).
51

A second strategy, noted by Sanjay Subrahmanyam, was to seek security
(such as it was) by approaching various authorities to gain the protection
of rights supported by their inuence.
52
While tax-farming may have
been a late, and post-Mughal development in North India, it was a feature
of the South from, at least, Vijayanagar times.
53
Merchant communities
were also major donors to the principal temples, often gaining trading
privileges in return. A dominant mercantile strategy in the early modern
period was portfolio capitalism, the building up of rights and shares in
various aspects of the scal system, which could be used to gain liens on
crops or goods or to hold position in competitive markets. In the eight-
eenth century, as regional states of the period began to take on aspects of
the Mughal sovereignty brought south against Golconda and the Mar-
athas, the claims of the state on resources expandedand, with them, the
importance of such connections. Monopolies and demands for taxation
pressed heavily on an increasing number of markets.
54
But the fragileand
intensely competitivenature of this state power meant that it rarely pro-
vided security for very long. Moreover, the tightening nexus with the state
also implied a shift in the character of commerce, from which many mer-
chant groups could lose out. States intensied their relationship with the
50)
Chaudhuri, Markets and Traders.
51)
D. Rudner, Caste and Capitalism in Colonial India: Te Nattukottai Chettiars (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1994).
52)
Subrahmanyam, Political Economy.
53)
B. Stein, Vijayanagara (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).
54)
Washbrook, South India.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 281
market in order to raise greater quantities of cash to support their military
machines. Tis began to give primacy to functions of banking over mere
tradingbringing, for example, northern (especially Gujarati) banking
houses into the South, from which they had been remote before.
55

Banking capital was even better able to secure itself, notably against the
powers over production enjoyed by local community institutions. But its
ties to the state also put it at very great risk in the event that it banked
for the wrong side.
III
But if the structural features of the southern economy suggest multiple
risks, to o-set the prospects of great prot, how did they evolve over time,
in what direction(s) was the economy moving in this era? In terms of pro-
duction, there appears to have been considerable dynamism, at least in the
sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Te new crops from the Americas
(chilli, potato, maize, tobacco, tomato, banana) were rapidly absorbed and
adoptedalthough in interesting ways. What might be thought of as
subsistence crops, capable of enlarging the Souths local food base, were
perhaps the least successful. Rather, it was chilli, tobacco, and tomato,
which expanded the most rapidly (especially, in Andhra), where they met
needs more for pleasure and leisure than immediate survival.
56
Moreover,
they were produced largely for the marketexpanding yet further the
Souths exchange economy. Equally, southern artisans showed remarkable
skills of innovation, proliferating textile designs to suit multiple foreign
markets (often in response to direct demands from them)
57
and in develop-
ing other handcraft skills, from furniture-making (especially, in Andhra) to
iron-working (in Tamil Nadu) to ship-building (especially down the west
coast where even Europeans sought opportunities to outsource produc-
tion).
58
More tradable goods and services meant more resources to exchange
for subsistence. By these means, the population appears to have grown
quite rapidly in this period.
55)
Gujarati bankers appear to have followed the Mughals south.
56)
Subrahmanyam, Political Economy.
57)
R. Crill, Textiles from India: Te Global Trade (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2006).
58)
S. Sangwan, Ship-Building in India during the Company Rule. In History of Traditional
Navigation, eds Y. Subharayalu et al. (Tanjavur: Tamil University Press, 1989): Ch. 5.
282 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
However, at least before the end of the seventeenth century, there also
seem to have been few signs of any signicant changes in the organization
of production or of the institutions securing and re-distributing surplus.
Production remained dominated by artisan and farmer corporations with
both the state and mercantile capital kept rmly in their place. Yet it is
possible to see problems beginning to emerge. On the one side, relations
of exchange were becoming increasingly elongated over space, making
them vulnerable to disruption. From the 1680s, for example, problems in
Persian markets began to cost Andhra important markets; and, for a time,
the Mughal invasion of Golconda cut the coastal districts o from the
interior.
59
But small southern polities and risk-averse southern mercantile
organizations were incapable of providing trade routes with much protec-
tion. Also, even by the early eighteenth century, European merchant com-
panies were showing restlessness with their weak positions on land,
especially in relation to their inability to control time and quality factors in
production, and were looking to exert the political pressure which they
already possessed at sea.
60

Further, a range of internal anomalies was starting to grow. Greater
quantities of specie now permeated production, but linked to a bullionist
economy without secure coinage, transaction costs (especially from shro-
ing) were consequently inclined to inate. Also, the growing market in
property rights raised questions about the meaning and legitimacy of
those rights themselves. As noted, in the river valleys, the predominant
form of property was kaniachi (later mirasi) right linked to ancient priv-
ileges derived from connection to the community which had originally cleared
the land. But as such rights were eectively bought by outsiders
merchant Chetties, entrepreneurial members of lower castescorporate
cohesion could come under threat. Noticeably, for example, by the 1770s
when the East India Company took control of the Chingleput Jaghir
behind Madras city, only half of its villages still practised periodic re-distri-
bution of land among their shareholders.
61
Also, many other rights were
starting to be bought and sold in peculiar ways. Palaiyakarrar rights
involved the payment of fees in return for protection. But, by the mid-
eighteenth century, these were being acquired by peoplesuch as the
59)
J. F. Richards, Mughal Administration in Golconda (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1975).
60)
Parthasarathi, Transition; S. Arasaratnam, Merchants, Companies and Commerce on the
Coromandel Coast 1650-1740 (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986).
61)
Sivakumar, Peasants.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 283
French Companys dubash, Ananda Ranga Pillaiwho were from non-
martial castes (Pillai was an Idayan, shepherd) and had no means of pro-
viding protection.
62
In eect, and in ways similar to France at the end of
the ancient regime, market forces were penetrating and eating away at the
rationale of an erstwhile feudal law.
However, in South India, any revolution proved to be still-born, and
the crisis ultimately may have ushered in a colonial rule which, if anything,
reversed its direction. Te rst moment of change can be associated with
the fall-out from the Mughal conquest of Golconda, which, by the rst
quarter of the eighteenth century, had unleashed a struggle for succession
across the South, which was not nally settled until the centurys end. It
featured attempts by a series of regional states to intensify their extraction
of resources, most notably to support their expanding and increasingly
expensive military apparatuses. Monopolies on tradable goods were tight-
ened up, tax immunities (for example, enjoyed by temples) were clipped,
and new experiments (for example, Tipu Sultans visionary ryotwari sys-
tem) were tried with regard to direct taxation.
63
All this put pressure on the
corporate side of the dualistic state, threatening to break its erstwhile
power over production and exchange in order to establish a new system of
claims to, and thus rights in, property and resources.
But the eort to centralize state power failed, largely because of inter-
necine strife in a context where resources (including human resources)
remained highly mobile. Te nascent regional states of the epoch
Mysore, Travancore, Tanjavur, the Marathas, Hyderabad, Arcot (through
which the English Company increasingly expressed its inuence)fought
one another to a standstill. Tey all indulged in the practices which Chris
Bayly has termed Asian mercantilism, attempting to attract one anothers
labor forces and capital resources and to destroy one anothers trade and
productive bases.
64
But their attempts came close to a zero sum game. Sub-
stantial sections of the population moved and/or ed with serious conse-
quences for the economy in many places. Tanjavur, once the grain basket
of southern India, experienced a continuous decline in production across
the eighteenth century, made worse in the middle decades when Mysore
62)
Ananda Ranga Pillai, Private Diary 1747-1763, trans. J. F. Price and K. Rangachari
(Delhi: Asia Educational Services, 2006).
63)
Washbrook, South India.
64)
C. A. Bayly, Rulers, Townsmen and Bazaars: North Indian Society in the Age of British
Expansion, 1770-1870 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).
284 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
attempted to force its population toward the upper Kaveri.
65
In Malabar,
there was considerable displacement of the upper castes and of capital as a
result of Mysores invasion there.
66
Weaving communities appear to have
moved hither and yon to nd protection and to try to continue trade
thread, which could always nd a market, being a particularly popular
form of loot for pillaging armies. Moreover, in a curious way, the politi-
cal maelstrom at the top of the dualistic state order gave some means for
the local corporations at the bottom to defend themselves. In the weaving
industry, as Prasannan Parthasarathi has noted, artisans were by no means
passive in the face of pressures to weaken their control of production and
to cheapen the price of their labor.
67
Equally, farmer communities resisted
inated revenue demands by refusing to plant crops, concealing produc-
tion, or moving on.
68
In the end, less a new, clearly dened structure of
rights emerged than, simply, new claims to rights were lodged over old
ones, with the two struggling to nd accommodation. Shrotriems (tax
immunities given to their clients by many of the new states) sat alongside
maunyams granted by local corporations themselves, and sometimes
merged into the broad category known by the subsequent East Indian
Company state as inam. Temples conceded some of their resources to
aggressive new rulers, such as Hyder Ali and Tipu Sultan in Mysore. But
then, as the latter found themselves struggling to make allies and secure
their legitimacy, they were often re-endowed again.
69
Te old structure of
rights did not just disappear: rather, it became increasingly complicated.
For merchant capital (including that of the Europeans), the times were
particularly testing. On the one hand, the attempt to strengthen rulers
power oered means of o-loading some of the very high risks which had
to be borne. Producers could be coerced into yielding control over time
and quality; monopolies could secure market positions against competi-
tion. But, on the other hand, new forms of risk emerged. Te new rulers
commercialized
70
their royal powers in return for more secure cash
owsand, if they did not receive them, could prove coercive themselves.
65)
Subrahmanyam, Penumbral.
66)
M. Frenz, From Contact to Conquest: Transition to British Rule in Malabar 1790-1805
(Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2003).
67)
Parthasarathi, Transition.
68)
Washbrook, South India.
69)
K. Brittlebank, Tipu Sultans Search for Legitimacy: Islam and Kinship in a Hindu Domain
(Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1997).
70)
Bayly, Rulers.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 285
Many a tax farmer ended up in jail or worse. Tere was a tension between
the claims of capital and those of the state, which, given capitals lack
of armed force, could easily lead to the short-term liquidation of its
agenciesalbeit, then, with longer-term consequences for the ability of
the state to sustain credit.
Also, engagement with the state necessarily began to aect the nature of
the operations of mercantile capital. Tere was a need for money to sup-
port the states military operations. Tis put a premium on the kinds of
organization which could command it, raising ever higher the functions of
banking over those of mere commodity trading. Te eighteenth century
was the age of banking in South India no less than John Richards and
Karen Leonard have documented for the North.
71
And also, no less, its
logic led to the doors of the English East India Company which, by then,
dominated the long distance sea-trades bringing scarce specie metals to
India. Increasingly, the success or failure of particular banking and mer-
chandising households depended on their relationship to the Company.
Hyder Ali and Tipu Sultan, perhaps alone among South Indian rulers,
spotted this implication and, from the 1760s, tried to set up their own
navywith Mangalore as their own alternative entrepot, guaranteeing
independent specie ows.
72
But, by then, Indias loss of sea-power to the
Europeans was too advancedand with it, in an economy reproduced
through exchange and armed by mercenary force, Indias ultimate loss
of sovereignty.
Where the Companys conquest of the South left the relations of mer-
cantile commerce, and the structure of claims and rights supporting it,
remain questions for another paper. But, in the early days, those Indian
mercantile houses which had supported its functions, especially in relation
to banking, enjoyed a range of immediate benets. Te Company in
Madras was perennially short of cash and those who could supply it gained
considerable privileges, not least consolidated into zemindari rights to land
revenue, especially in Andhra.
73
But, over time, the benets began to peter
out. Te Company attempted to take the states nancial system under
direct management, progressively reducing its own reliance on tax farm-
71)
See the exchanges between Karen Leonard and John Richards on banking in the Mughal
Empire in J. F. Richards, Mughal State Finance and the Pre-Modern World Economy and
K. Leonard, Indigenous Banking Firms in Mughal India: A Reply Comparative Studies in
Society and History 23 (1981): 285-313.
72)
Washbrook, South India.
73)
Ibidem.
286 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
ing, and thus on Indian bankers. Also, by the mid-nineteenth century, it
was able to look for its credit needs increasingly to London and to British
interests in the locale. Indian capital lost its place at the heights of an
economy more and more under the states eective direction. What did
remain were important mercantile functions in the interior economy, in
which the Company and European business had little interest, and also
abroad where South India became a staging post for the opening out of
South-East Asia,
74
but Indian opportunities in the colonial age were of a
dierent kind and dimension.
Te Company also took a long time to sort out the tangle over rights
and claims to property and resources, which it had inherited. It was torn
between the imperatives of consolidating itself as a traditional state (as it
saw it)recreating a Hindu Golden Age represented by the restoration
of Indian corporate privilege and powerand servicing the new demands
of colonial capitalism by pressing ahead with the centralization of state
power at the expense of local corporations. In the end, of course, it deferred
to the latter but, for a long time, it was beset by internal contradictions:
not least between its legal system, which defended ancient rights, and its
revenue system which claimed an omni-competent rulers prerogative.
75

Its task in establishing the greater dominance of the state and capital
over labor and production was helped by two factorsboth of which
related to an increasing sedentarization of society, which was crucial to
the process.
76
In the early nineteenth century, the Companys progressive
elimination of rival state powers reduced the forces of competition within
the system. Labor and local capital had fewer places to which they could
move and thus became more susceptible to coercive pressures to yield their
control over time and quality. Nonetheless, there were some places (for
example, in the princely states which continued to be highly inuential
across the South) where a limited retreat remained possible.
77
Also, politi-
cal resistancein the form of revenue strikes, use of law courts, and
74)
Rudner, Caste and Capitalism.
75)
D. A. Washbrook, Sovereignty, Property, Land and Labour in Colonial South India.
In Constituting Modernity: Private Property in the East and West, ed. H. Islamoglu (I.B.
Taurus: London, 2004): 69-99.
76)
C. A. Bayly, Indian Society and the Making of the British Empire (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1990).
77)
B. N. Ramusack, Te Indian Princes and their States (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2004).
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 287
occasional violent revoltslimited the eectiveness of state authority.
78

Ultimately, perhaps, it was the population expansion of the nineteenth
century, which proved to be the decisive factor. Across the century, the
South Indian population at least doubled, and possibly trebled, lling up
the land and reducing the system of circulation which had previously
governed both the use of resources and the predominant strategy of sur-
vival.
79
Te southern economy became increasingly sedentarized, sup-
ported by xed water resources (in the expanded Krishna-Godavari and
Kaveri deltas) and new technologies of well-digging. It also became dier-
ently structured with a greater emphasis on agricultural production and
less on manufacturing. Although whether it beneted from these changes
still remains questionable: the savage famines which beset parts of the
South in the 1870s and 1890s suggest that basic food security problems
were not to be resolved until the twentieth century, if they entirely
have been.
80

Bibliography
Ahuja, Ravi. 2002. Labour Relations in an Early Colonial Context: Madras c. 1750-1800.
Modern Asian Studies 36: 793-826.
Ananda Ranga Pillai. 2006. Private Diary 1747-1763. Trans. J. F. Price and K. Rangachari.
Delhi: Asia Educational Services.
Appadurai, Arjun. 1981. Worship and Conict under Colonial rule: A South Indian Case
Book. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Arasaratnam, Sinnapah. 1986. Merchants, Companies and Commerce on the Coromandel
Coast 1650-1740. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Bayly, Christopher A. 1983. Rulers, Townsmen and Bazaars: North Indian Society in the Age
of British Expansion, 1770-1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
. 1990. Indian Society and the Making of the British Empire. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Brittlebank, Kate. 1997. Tipu Sultans Search for Legitimacy: Islam and Kingship in a Hindu
Domain. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Chaudhuri, K. N. 1979. Markets and Traders in India during the Seventeenth and
Eighteenth Centuries. In Economy and Society: Essays in Indian Economic and Social His-
tory, eds K. N. Chaudhuri and C. Dewey. Delhi: Oxford University Press: 256-75.
78)
Washbrook, South India.
79)
Dharma Kumar, Land and Caste in South India: Agricultural Labour in Madras Presi-
dency in the Nineteenth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1965).
80)
Te interior districts of southern India lost 20-35% of their populations during these
famines.
288 D. Washbrook / JESHO 53 (2010) 266-289
. 1978. Te Trading World of Asia and the English East India Company 1660-1760.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Chicherov, A. I. 1971. Economic Development in the Sixteenth-Eighteenth Centuries: Outline
History of Crafts and Trades. Moscow: Moscow Publishing House.
Crill, Rosemary. 2006. Textiles from India: Te Global Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press.
Dasgupta, Ashin. 1982. Foreign Trade: Indian Merchants and the Trade in the Indian
Ocean, 1500-1750. In Cambridge Economic History of India, vol 1: c. 1200-1750, eds I.
Habib and T. Raychaudhuri. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: Ch. 13-2.
Frenz, Margret. 2003. From Contact to Conquest: Transition to British Rule in Malabar,
1790-1805. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Gommans, Jos. J. L. 2002. Mughal Warfare: Indian Frontiers and Highroads to Empire,
1500-1700. London: Taylor and Francis.
Guha, Sumit. 2001. Te Population History of South Asia from the Seventeenth to the
Twentieth Centuries: An Exploration. In Asian Population History, eds Tsui Jung Lui
et al. Oxford: Oxford University Press: Ch. 4.
Hardgrave, Robert L. 1969. Te Nadars of Tamil Nadu: Te Political Culture of a Commu-
nity in Change. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Kumar, Dharma. 1965. Land and Caste in South India: Agricultural Labour in Madras Pres-
idency in the Nineteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 55-92.
. 1998. Te Forgotten Sector. In Colonialism, Private Property and the State, ed.
Dharma Kumar. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Leonard, Karen. 1981. Indigenous Banking Firms in Mughal India: A Reply. Comparative
Studies in Society and History 23: 309-13.
Ludden, David. 1985. Peasant History in South India. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Mizushima, Tsukasa. 1986. Nattar and Socio-Economic Change in South India in the
Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries. Tokyo: Tokyo University Press.
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Parthasarathi, Prasannan. 2001. Te Transition to a Colonial Economy: Weavers, Merchants
and Kings in South India 1720-1800. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pate, H. L. 1917. Gazetteer of the Tinnevelly District, vol. 1. Madras: Government of Madras.
Perlin, Frank. 1983. Proto-Industrialization and Pre-Colonial South Asia. Past and Present
98: 30-95.
. 1985. State Formation Reconsidered. Modern Asian Studies 19: 415-80.
Polanyi, Karl. 1944. Te Great Transformation: Te Political and Economic Origins of Our
Times. New York: Rinehart and Company.
Prakash, Om. 1985. Te Dutch East India Company and the Economy of Bengal 1630-1720.
Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Ramusack, Barbara N. 2004. Te Indian Princes and their States. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Raychaudhuri, Tapan. 1962. Jan Companie in Coromandel: A Study in the Interrelations of
European Commerce and Traditional Economies. Den Haag: Nijho.
Richards, John F. 1975. Mughal Administration in Golconda. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
. 1981. Mughal State Finance and the Pre-Modern World Economy. Comparative
Studies in Society and History 23: 285-307.
Merchants, Markets, and Commerce in Early Modern South India 289
. 2000. Te Imperial Monetary System of Mughal India. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Rudner, David West. 1994. Caste and Capitalism in Colonial India: Te Nattukottai Chet-
tiars. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Sangwan, S. 1989. Ship-building in India during the Company Rule. In History of Tradi-
tional Navigation, eds Y. Subharayalu et al. Tanjavur: Tamil University Press: Ch. 5.
Sivakumar, Chitra and S.S. Sivakumar. 1993. Peasants and Nabobs: Agrarian Radicalism in
Late Eighteenth Century Tamil Country. Delhi: Hindustan Publishing House.
Skinner, G. W. 1964-65. Marketing and Social Structure in Rural China, parts 1-3. Journal
of Asian Studies 24: 3-44; 195-228; 363-99.
Stein, Burton. 1960. Te Economic Function of a Medieval South Indian Temple. Journal
of Asian Studies 19: 163-76.
. 1977. Privileged Landholding. In Land Tenure and Peasant in South Asia, ed.
R. E. Frykenberg. Delhi: Orient Longman: 67-77.
. 1980. Peasant State and Society in Medieval South India. Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
. 1989. Vijayanagara. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Studer, Roman. 2008. India and the Great Divergence: Assessing the E ciency of Grain
Markets in Eighteenth and Nineteenth century India. Journal of Economic History 68:
393-437.
Subrahmanyam, Sanjay. 1990. Te Political Economy of Commerce: Southern India, 1500-
1650. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
. 1993. Te Portuguese Empire in Asia, 1500-1700: A Political and Economic History.
London: Longman.
. 2001. Penumbral Visions: Making Polities in Early Modern South India. Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Tompson, Edward P. 1971. Te Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth
Century. Past and Present 50: 76-136.
Washbrook, David A. 1975. Te Development of Caste Organisation in South India. In
South India: Political Institutions and Political Change 1880-1940, eds C.J. Baker and
D. Washbrook. Delhi: Macmillan:150-203.
. 1993. Land and Labour in Late Eighteenth Century South India: Te Golden Age
of the Pariah? In Dalit Movements and the Meanings of Labour in India, ed. P. Robb.
Delhi: Oxford University Press: 68-86.
. 2004a. South India 1770-1840: Te Colonial Transition. Modern Asian Studies 38:
649-721.
. 2004b. Sovereignty, Property, Land and Labour in Colonial South India. In Consti-
tuting Modernity: Private Property in the East and West, ed. H. Islamoglu. London:
I.B. Taurus: 69-99.
. 2007. India in the Early Modern World Economy: Modes of Production, Reproduc-
tion and Exchange. Journal of Global History 2: 87-111.
Wilks, Mark. 1930. Historical Sketches of South Indian History from the Origin of the Hindoo
Government of that State to the Extinction of the Mohammedan Dynasty in 1799: Founded
Chiey on Indian Authorities Collected by the Author While O ciating for Several Years as
Political Resident at the Court of Mysoor, ed. M. Hammick. Mysore: Government Branch
Press.

Вам также может понравиться