Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 21

1

Web Appendix to Peter Starke, Alexandra Kaasch and Franca van Hooren: Political
Parties and Social Policy Responses to Global Economic Crises: Constrained
Partisanship in Mature Welfare States, J ournal of Social Policy, 43:2.

In this appendix, the characterizations of domestic responses of Australia, Belgium, the
Netherlands and Sweden to four global economic shocks are described in detail. These
characterizations are based on the available secondary literature as well as on some primary
sources. A more extensive discussion of social policy responses in these countries can be
found in our book The Welfare State as Crisis Manager (Starke et al., 2013). Social policy
responses to crisis refers to legislative changes in the fields of pensions, passive and active
labour market policy, social assistance, family policy and health care which were linked to the
economic downturn. In a few cases, changes were implemented in the aftermath of shocks
that had already been planned before the downturn or responded to developments largely
unconnected to the crisis. We focus on one dimension of social policy change, namely,
changes in social rights of citizenship (see Stephens, 2010 for an overview), in other words,
eligibility and entitlement rules for benefits (transfers and social services). This excludes
changes in funding and administration of welfare state schemes. All crisis reactions are coded
as expansion (+), retrenchment () or non-reaction (0). The codings are indicated at the end of
each country subsection.

Reactions to the first oil shock

Social policy reactions to the first oil shock were clearly expansionary, at first, in Belgium
and in the Netherlands. Both countries set up early retirement schemes (De Deken, 2002;
2

Kohli et al., 1991) and expanded some other labour market programmes, both in close
cooperation with the social partners. In Belgium, early retirement started in 1975, with the
introduction of the bridge pension (prpension conventionnelle), based on a national
collective agreement between trade unions and employers. Workers above the age of 60 years
(55 for women) who were made redundant would not only get the usual unemployment
benefits, but also a top-up designed to compensate for half the gap between the benefit and
their former earnings. Recipients would not have to be available for work. The funding
normally came from their former employers or sectoral employer funds (Gieselink et al.,
2002: 583). The law allowed for more favourable rules to be agreed upon in sectoral
agreements, which meant that in some sectors, individual workers could retire from the age of
48 (De Deken, 2002: 30). The direct fiscal impact of early retirement for the government was
relatively moderate at first, due to co-funding from employers. This changed from 1976/77,
when the early retirement option was expanded to cover not just workers recently made
redundant but also older long-term unemployed and invalidity beneficiaries above the age of
60. New benefits, such as the prpension lgale were funded out of the unemployment
insurance and from 1977, real early retirement on pension benefits was made possible
(Gieselink et al., 2002). Early exit from the labour market was an explicit crisis response
measure, more specifically, an instrument to deal with rising youth unemployment. The
various schemes became extremely popular with both workers and employers who used
them to shed less productive workers in their attempt to adapt to global competition and,
despite significant retrenchment over the years, are still in place, today. Consequently,
Belgian employment rates for older workers are among the lowest in the OECD. (+)
In the Netherlands, expansion was followed by a brief period that can be characterised
as non-response. There were a number of initial expansionary measures that should not be
seen as crisis responses, because they were planned by the centre-left Den Uyl government
3

already before the advent of the first oil shock. These include an increase in the level of public
pensions
1
so that the pension benefit for married couples became equal to the minimum wage;
expansion of social services, including home care services for families; and the introduction
of a universal social insurance for disabled adults (AAW) in 1975. More directly related to the
economic downturn were experiments with voluntary early retirement (VUT) in 1976.
2

Quickly after that, early retirement schemes were included in collective agreements in many
different sectors. In the Netherlands, these early retirement schemes were entirely financed by
employers and employees (De Vroom and Blomsma, 1991). Due to high inflation and
increasing budget deficits (van Zanden, 1998: 68) doubts emerged about the feasibility of
expansionary social policy measures after 1975 (Toirkens, 1988: 32-4). In June 1976 a plan
was introduced to keep public expenses under control. It included cuts in childcare and
disability benefits (WAO) and in healthcare provision. Yet most of these proposed cuts were
never implemented. The last years (up to 1977) of the Den Uyl government can therefore be
characterised as non-response. The subsequent centre-right Van Agt I government proposed
more cutbacks (Nobelen, 1983: 118). Again, only few of them were implemented, such as a
cut in childcare benefits in 1979.
3
Meanwhile, the centre-right government continued to
support early retirement as a way to fight unemployment
4
, but, in contrast to Belgium, early
retirement continued to be at the discretion of the social partners. Overall, we characterise the
Dutch response to the first oil shock as expansion followed by a mixture of small expansion
and retrenchment measures which together effectively constituted a non-response. (+, 0)
Non-response was initially also the dominant theme in Australia. The reformist
government of Gough Whitlam (Australian Labor Party, ALP) greatly expanded a number of
core welfare state programmes and set up a new, universal health care system in the early

1
Tweede Kamer, Zitting 1973-1974, 12 600 XV, Nr. 2.
2
Tweede Kamer, Zitting 1975-1976, 13 686, Nr. 1.
3
Tweede Kamer, Zitting 1979-1980, 15 800 XV, Nr. 2.
4
See e.g. Bestek 81, Tweede Kamer, Zitting 1977-1978, 15 081, Nr. 2; Zitting 1978-1979, 15 726, Nr. 1; Zitting
1979-1980, 15 800 XV, Nr. 2.
4

1970s (Manning, 1981; Scotton, 2000), but this had been largely announced and partly
implemented prior to the crisis and occurred despite rather than because of the first oil shock
(Whitwell, 1986: 64). A genuine crisis response, particularly in social policy, was lacking
(Saunders and Deeming, 2011: 379). On the peak of a constitutional crisis, in 1975, Whitlam
was dismissed by the Governor-General. After elections and a change in government in 1975,
a number of incremental cutbacks were introduced, including in unemployment benefits and
the minimum pension (Manning, 1985). Universal health care suffered a death by a thousand
cuts between 1976 and 1981. This was in line with a clear change in rhetoric, away from the
Keynesianism of the Whitlam years. Famously, the new governments slogan was Fight
Inflation First. (0, )
Sweden decided to wait and see at first and relied on classical Keynesian stabilisation
as a response to the first oil shock, which meant that Swedish governments followed a
Keynesian strategy of bridging the crisis by introducing expansive policies
(verbryggningspolitiken) (Lundberg, 1984), in the expectation that growth would soon
return. In addition, the government and central labour market organisations tried to prevent
stagflation by negotiating the Haga Agreements (1974-75), a form of incomes policy (Erixon,
2008: 380; Immergut and Jochem, 2006: 119). However, the centre-right coalition
government, in office from 1979 until 1982 faced a mounting crisis. Apart from devaluation
in 1977, the centre-right government used tax policies, labour market policies, and the
expansion of child benefits, amongst other things, in an attempt to meet the growing
problems. In order to protect families with children, the child benefit was increased (Prop.
1977/78: 61)
5
and pensioners received automatic compensation through the indexation of
pensions. A stabilisation programme in October 1977 (Prop. 1977/78: 45) focused on
supporting national demand, protecting employment and reducing inflation. Related labour

5
All government propositions can be accessed via the Swedish governments website
http://www.sweden.gov.se/sb/d/574.
5

market policies were enacted by means of two separate employment packages (January 1977
and November 1977), which included an expansion of educational programmes for young
people and women, and specific support for the steel industry. Overall, these reactions to the
crisis were considered intentionally expansive (Mjoset, 1987: 430). (0, +)

Reactions to the second oil shock

Reactions to the second oil shock were more diverse and, in some countries, restrictive for the
first time. Australia, by contrast, increased welfare state benefits as part of a quasi-corporatist
bargain. Elections took place at the height of the crisis, in 1983, which brought the ALP back
to power. The central pillar of the new governments macroeconomic and social policy
response to the economic difficulties was the Prices and Incomes Accord (known as the
Accord), a series of eight quasi-corporatist agreements that ran until 1996 (Ahlquist, 2011;
Archer, 1988; Stilwell, 1986). At the heart of this agreement between the ALP leadership and
trade unions but without the participation of employers was an exchange of wage
moderation for improvements in the social wage, including the reintroduction of universal
health care and a general lift in social benefits (Edwards and Whiteford, 1988: 68). The only
exception to these expansionary policies was the tightening of the pensions means test. (+)
Belgium and the Netherlands chose selective and incremental retrenchment to counter
rising deficits and high inflation. In Belgium, retrenchment entered the agenda when the
second oil shock arrived, but no significant measures were taken until the Christian
democratic-Liberal government of Wilfried Martens (Martens V) took office in late 1981. The
government introduced a devaluation of the Belgian franc and intervened heavily in wage
setting in the early 1980s, by suspending automatic wage indexation (an important element of
6

Belgian wage policy). Since social welfare benefits are linked to wages, this was effectively a
benefit cutback. Some cutbacks were also introduced in early retirement schemes and for
higher-income recipients of unemployment benefits (Gieselink et al., 2002; Marx, 2007: 129).
The government used special powers to issue emergency decrees to push through these
changes unilaterally (Smits, 1983), while the trade unions were weakened by internal
conflicts, as the Christian wing of the trade union movement refrained from active opposition
against its Christian-democratic allies in government (Anderson et al., 2007: 321). ()
In the Netherlands, in 1980 the centre-right Van Agt I government froze wage
increases and thereby in a manner similar to what happened in Belgium it automatically
also froze benefit levels which were linked to private sector wages (Kuipers, 2006: 140;
Nobelen, 1983: 124). It also tightened eligibility criteria for disability benefits. In the
elections held in 1982, the economic situation had become a main issue and all parties agreed
that cuts in government expenditure were necessary (Irwin, 1983: 71). After the elections, the
new centre-right Lubbers I government saw it as one of its main objectives to decrease the
costs of social security. From 1983 until 1989 social benefits unemployment and disability
benefits as well as social assistance, old age, and child benefits were again not indexed for
inflation and wage increases.
6
These benefits included. In 1984 these benefits were cut by an
additional 3 per cent.
7
In 1985 replacement rates for disability and unemployment benefits
were cut from 80 to 70 per cent; followed by a similar cut in sickness benefits one year later.
8

Retrenchment was also enacted in social care services (Maessen, 1989). In 1986, full
disability benefits were abolished for persons that were only partially disabled.
9
In sum, we
can characterise the Dutch response to the second oil shock as retrenchment. ()

6
Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 2009-2010, 24 515, Nr. 175, Brief van de Minister van Sociale Zaken en
Werkgelegenheid.
7
Tweede Kamer, Zitting 1983-1984, 18 100 XV, Nr. 2.
8
Tweede Kamer, Zitting 1985-1986, 19 200 XV, Nr. 2.
9
Tweede Kamer, Zitting 1986-1987, 19 700 XV, Nr. 2.
7

Sweden introduced some minor cutbacks, but these were overshadowed by investment
in labour market measures. More concretely, in 1981 the centre-right governments focus
shifted towards fiscal restraint and at a time when welfare policies were becoming more
contentious (Olson, 1986: 86), this had an impact on social policies, including cutbacks in
pensions and student grants. In addition, changes to the system of job protection were
introduced, including a new probationary category (provanstllning) (Prop. 1981/82: 30).
The Health Care Act of 1982 led to a more decentralised system, a trend that was further
reinforced by the Dagmar Reform of 1985 (Bergmark, 2008). An austerity package
introduced in December 1981 did not target social policies, and still included expansionary
employment support policies. Although the government did announce cuts to sickness
benefits and introduced two waiting days (Olson, 1986), it refrained from imposing
significant cuts on most other social policy schemes (see also Immergut and Jochem, 2006:
119). Soon thereafter, the concept of a third way (den tredje vgen), introduced by the
Social Democrats in September 1982 (detailed in Prop. 1982/83:150), entered political
debates. It proposed an alternative macroeconomic policy strategy somewhere between the
Thatcher-Reagan neoliberal doctrines and the traditional Keynesian approach. Economic
balance, it maintained, should be restored without giving up the commitment to full
employment and comprehensive public social services (Ryner, 1994). Even though (apart
from the Krona devaluation) this was approached with restrictive fiscal and monetary policy,
the welfare state was not fundamentally affected. (+)

8

Crisis reactions in the early 1990s

Crisis reactions to the 1990s recession which hit some of the countries hard,
especially Sweden and Australia range from significant retrenchment in Sweden to
expansion in Australia. Sweden for the first time introduced cutbacks in virtually all transfer
programmes under the impression of deep recession, a fiscal crisis, a banking and currency
crisis and high price inflation. Already in February 1990, the Social Democratic government
under Ingvar Carlsson initially responded by proposing an austerity package, including a
freeze on all wages, prices and dividends for two years, combined with restrictions on the
right to strike (Jonung et al., 2009), which proved however difficult to enact. Concrete social
policy reforms were already part of crisis management measures introduced in early 1990.
The Carlsson Social Democratic government reduced public spending in numerous ways.
Retrenchment occurred in the fields of education, care for the elderly, child care and the
health system. Sick pay, for example, was lowered (for the first three days from 90 to 65 per
cent, and to 80 per cent for the following days). Pensions and labour market policies were also
addressed, but were not yet considered to be in urgent need of reform. The initial measures
were taken further in several steps. Particularly from September 1992 onwards,
comprehensive and explicit crisis responses importantly included social benefit cutbacks. This
strategy was declared the only way (den enda vgen) to manage the crisis. More
concretely, the years of the Bildt government saw a reduction of income replacement rates for
unemployment benefits, and a five-day waiting period for unemployment benefits. With
regard to pensions, there were also benefit cuts, as the basis for calculating benefits was
reduced by two per cent from January 1993 onwards (Feltenius, 2008). These short-term cuts
affected retirees, but did not mark such a fundamental change to the overall system. Until
1994 further retrenchment measures were carried out in various benefit schemes. Apart from
9

removing some special support to, for example, schools and child care, child allowances were
affected, as earnings-related benefits were cut from 90 to 75 per cent. Overall, the spending
reductions imposed by the Bildt government between 1991 and 1994 were almost exclusively
on social security, and amounted to SEK 9.4 billion. From this, 2.2 billion were cut in
pensions, 0.6 billion in sickness insurance, and 0.9 billion in family policy (Palme et al.,
2000). When the Social Democrats came back to government in 1994, they continued the path
of restrictive reform, following a TINA logic (Steinmo, 2002: 841). In the first budget
proposal of the Social Democratic government (Prop. 1994/95:100), a substantial programme
was announced to further reduce public expenditure, and to fight unemployment. The
consolidation programme, designed for the period of 1995 to 1998, comprised tax increases
and cuts in expenditure. For pensions, for example, this meant that the adjustment of pensions
was linked to the size of the budget deficit (Anderson, 2001). Regarding unemployment
benefits, it was no longer possible to re-qualify by just taking part in training programmes and
relief work. ()
Australia was also struck by a deep economic downturn but, in stark contrast to
Sweden, chose an expansionary course. The strategy centred on three core initiatives: a new
occupational pension scheme (Superannuation), a massive fiscal stimulus programme (One
Nation) and a comprehensive active labour market programme (Working Nation). The
pension initiative was tightly linked with a new Accord with the trade unions, negotiated in
1991. As in the early 1980s, the Accord included wage moderation in exchange for social
benefits. This time round, the social policy component was Superannuation, a de facto
mandatory, fully funded occupational pension financed by employers. Superannuation,
phased-in from 1992, was a key element of the governments response to the recession
(Saunders and Deeming, 2011: 381) as it allowed to expand benefits for average workers
without adding to current wages or public expenditure. It has become an important pillar of
10

the Australian pension system and one of the largest second-pillar schemes worldwide
(Bateman and Piggott, 1998; OECD, 2009b). The second element, One Nation, came shortly
afterwards, in 1992, and was announced by Prime Minister Keating as a strategy of spending
on substantial and necessary public investments now while private investment is weak and
bringing the Federal Budget back into surplus when private investment is strong (Keating,
1992: 5). Almost half of the volume consisted of social and labour market measures,
including lump-sum family payments and training schemes. As the situation on the labour
market did not markedly improve, even when economic growth picked up, the government set
up a massive active labour market scheme called Working Nation in 1994. The government
set out to bring down unemployment to 5 per cent by the year 2000 (from around 10 per cent)
through massive investment in activation schemes, founded on the principle that every
Australian has a right to a job (Keating, 1994: 30). In contrast to the workfare approach
followed by other English-speaking countries at the time, Working Nation included a so-
called Job Compact, a guarantee of a job offer or placement in a training programme or public
employment scheme for the long-term unemployed. The government introduced a mix of
individual case management, direct job creation and wage subsidies, without lowering benefit
rates (Finn, 1997). (+)
Both Belgium and the Netherlands range somewhere in between these two poles. The
Netherlands saw some important cutbacks, yet since the economic downturn of the 1990s was
very mild in the Netherlands, they can hardly be linked to economic crisis. Instead, these
cutbacks should be understood in the context of a crisis of disability, due to the very high
number of people reliant on disability benefits (De Jong, 1999: 262). A reform of disability
benefits was already announced by the centre-left Lubbers III government in 1991. It was met
by strong objections from the trade unions and in October 1991, 250,000 people demonstrated
against the plan (Lucardie et al., 1991: 18). Nonetheless, the government stuck to its
11

intentions and in July 1993 disability benefits were limited in duration and made dependent
on age (Van der Veen and Trommel, 1999: 301). The criteria for receiving benefits were
tightened from being unable to do similar work to being unable to do any type of work
(Kuipers, 2006: 154). In December 1993, employers were made responsible for continued
wage payment in the first six weeks of sickness, while the entitlement was reduced from 100
to 70 per cent of previously earned wages. After elections in 1994, the new Labour/Liberal
Kok I government tightened eligibility criteria for unemployment insurance
10
and, in 1996,
employers became responsible for continuous wage payment for sick employees for a full
year instead of the previous six weeks. In conclusion, although it is questionable whether
these policy changes were related to economic crisis, social policy developments in the 1990s
were characterised by retrenchment. ()
Belgium, while significantly affected by the downturn and the ensuing exchange rate
troubles in Europe (the EMS [European Monetary System] crisis of 1992/93), introduced
only few changes in the social policy sector, some of which were restrictive and others
expansionary. Especially compared to the other countries, the Belgian reaction in the early
1990s qualifies as a non-reaction. The Dehaene government tried to forge a new social pact
for the welfare state in 1993 (building on the historic social pact of 1944), but the talks
failed when the socialist trade unions walked out. Some measures were still implemented,
including cutbacks by way of less generous benefit indexation (Hemerijck et al., 2000: 242)
as well as, again, cutbacks for some categories of unemployed people. At the same time, early
retirement remained popular and a new early exit route, the partial early retirement pension,
was introduced. Another important labour market measure of the early 1990s was the
significant expansion of the complex system of targeted wage subsidies via reduced employer
social security contributions (Lhoest, 2010). This is why the overall crisis response in
Belgium must be characterized as highly ambivalent, hence the coding as a non-response. (0)

10
Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 1994-1995, 23 985, Nr. 3.
12


Reactions to the financial crisis of 2008

The Australian reaction in 2008 was swift and consisted of a huge fiscal stimulus programme
of which a large part was devoted to social policy schemes (especially pensions and family
benefits) (Saunders and Deeming, 2011). Even though, with hindsight, Australia had a
relatively good crisis, it was seen as a real danger by the government at the time and
described in an early statement as the economic equivalent of a rolling national security
crisis (Rudd and Swan, 2008). The fiscal stimulus was introduced in two legislative
packages, the first announced as early as in October 2008 and implemented in December, the
second from early 2009 onwards. The total volume of the fiscal stimulus in Australia has been
estimated as 7 per cent of GDP, making it the third largest in the OECD, behind only the
United States and Korea. Moreover, The Australian stimulus also consisted of an
exceptionally high share of extra spending (as opposed to tax cuts) (OECD, 2009a: 109). The
2008 package worth A$ 10.4 billion centred on social policy measures, including lump
sum payments to pensioners and low-income families, while the second emphasized
infrastructure spending. The first payments came in December, just in time for the Christmas
shopping. This was a lesson learnt from the 1992 One Nation package mentioned above,
which was criticized by economists of having come too late, at a time when the economy was
already picking up speed again (Gruen, 2009; Gruen and Stevens, 2000). Further
expansionary policy changes came in the years following the 2008 shock, but their causal
relationship to the crisis is much weaker, if not entirely absent. For example, in 2009, the
benefit levels of the Age Pension, the minimum pension, were increased, especially for single
pensioners and the long-term eligibility age was raised to 67. Yet, this reform was based on a
review of the pension system (Department of Families, 2009) and had been discussed for
13

some time. In a similar vein, a new paid parental leave scheme was introduced from 2011,
which had been an election promise predating the crisis (Brennan, 2009). The genuine crisis
responses in Australia were all introduced on a temporary basis and mostly in the form of
lump sum payments. (+)
Sweden also saw an expansionary response but it was much smaller than in Australia,
and focused, again, on central welfare state schemes, including activation and training. The
welfare state was used as a central instrument of crisis management; however this was
performed in a rather different way compared to the 1990s. The centre-right coalition
government relied on the Swedish system of automatic stabilisers. The social policy
adjustments that did take place were expansionary. These concerned ALMPs, the protection
of pension levels, investments in education, and various tax cuts. The expansions were
incremental, while the measures also clearly reflected the aims expressed by the centre-right
government from their electoral campaigns even before the elections in 2006. In the long-
term, the series of changes to the Swedish unemployment system (activation measures) may
lead to a change in policy direction, but it is questionable whether this is due to the crisis or
due to the general reform plans of the centre-right parties (with the crisis possibly even
preventing more far-reaching plans). The measures comprised, apart from various tax cuts,
support to regional and local levels with additional financial means to run social protection
schemes, and through expanding and adjusting ALMPs. (+)
The Netherlands and Belgium followed a particular dynamic from initial expansion to
retrenchment later on. In the Netherlands, the first crisis response was concerned only with
the financial sector: the state nationalised ABN AMRO bank and part of Fortis, while other
banks received massive capital support. Subsequently, in terms of social policy, in late 2008
crisis response consisted of temporary and targeted expansionary measures, including the
creation of mobility centres for redundant employees the introduction of a short-time work
14

scheme (Werktijdverkorting).
11
In early 2009, a crisis response package included both short-
term expansionary social policy measures and long-term cutbacks. The short-term
expansionary measures were again targeted and temporary, including investments in
education and training to prevent youth unemployment (Actieplan Jeugdwerkloosheid)
12
and
the replacement of the existing short time work scheme by a more encompassing part-time
unemployment benefit (Deeltijd WW). The cutbacks announced in spring 2009 included cuts
in pensions, health care and childcare. Most of these cuts were eventually only implemented
by the subsequent Liberal-Christian Rutte I government, which took office in 2010. Upon
taking office, this new government committed to even more extensive cutbacks. A decrease of
childcare subsidies was implemented repeatedly in 2011, 2012 and 2013, and the universal
child benefit (kinderbijslag) was frozen in 2010 and 2011.
13
After a long period of debate
with the social partners, an increase in the retirement age was finally enacted in 2012.
Cutbacks were also enacted in the area of ALMP, affecting in particular resources for the
reintegration of recipients of unemployment benefits back to work.
14
Eligibility criteria for
social assistance were tightened for people under 27 years of age.
15
Finally, health and long-
term care saw some incremental cutbacks. For example, the out-of-pocket contribution for
mental health care was increased
16
and a (minor) wealth test was introduced for out-of-pocket
contributions for long-term care services.
17
In April 2012, the Rutte I government fell.
Subsequently, the Liberals and Christian Democrats struck a deal on the 2013 budget with
former opposition parties, the Liberal Democrats, GreenLeft and Christian Union.
18
In this
budget deal, some of the more controversial cutbacks of the previous government were

11
Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 20082009, 31 371, Nr. 56.
12
See also: Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 2009-2010, 32 123 XV, Nr. 2.
13
Staatsblad van het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden, Jaargang 2011, Nr. 424.
14
Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 2011-2012, 33 065, Nr. 3.
15
Eerste Kamer, progress report of bill 32815,
http://www.eerstekamer.nl/wetsvoorstel/32815_wijziging_van_de_wet_werk_en [accessed on 15 June 2012].
16
Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 2011-2012, 33 000 XVI, Nr. 2.
17
Eerste Kamer, progress report of bill 33024,
http://www.eerstekamer.nl/wetsvoorstel/33024_wijziging_wet_op_de [accessed on 15 June 2012].
18
Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 2011-2012, 21501-07, Nr. 910.
15

reversed, such as the higher out-of-pocket payments for mental healthcare, but the general line
of cutting back social policy was continued. The same applies for the new Liberal/Labour
Rutte II government that took office in November 2012. Overall, therefore, the Dutch crisis
response can be summarised as a short period of expansion followed by extensive cutbacks.
(+, )
While cutbacks were planned and announced from the beginning in the Netherlands,
Belgium only reluctantly turned to (incremental) retrenchment, and only after a government
could be formed at the end of a record 541-day post-electoral hiatus. However, the first crisis
responses were implemented by a coalition of Christian democrats, Liberals and (French-
speaking) Socialists, headed by Prime Minister Herman Van Rompuy and, from November
2009, by Yves Leterme. The most important expansionary measures were enacted in June
2009 on a temporary basis and renewed several times. They included working-time reductions
via various short-time work schemes, a Crisis Bonus payment of 1666 for unemployed
made redundant during the crisis, and active labour market measures. Short-time work
participation became particularly important but had already been important prior to the
crisis, as comparative analyses show (Hijzen and Venn, 2011; Vandaele, 2009). Active labour
market policy took place mostly at the regional level and was targeted at particular, for
example, young people (OECD, 2011: 72). The second phase of Belgiums crisis response
began in late 2011. No coalition had been formed since the June 2010 elections and financial
markets as well as the European Commission had become increasingly nervous. Belgium
was downgraded by several ratings agencies in November 2011. In December, Elio Di Rupo,
a Socialist, managed to form a six-party government between Socialists, Christian democrats
and Liberal parties (each from both linguistic camps). The government came in with the
announcement of a pension reform and cutbacks to unemployment benefits. In pensions, the
eligibility rules for early retirement were, again, made stricter and special pensions for
16

certain occupations and the public sector further aligned with the general scheme. In labour
market policies, a benefit used mostly by graduates was linked with work experience (through
mandatory internships) and access to sabbatical schemes which had become very popular, was
restricted. While there was a clear change in direction between the early and the later
response, the cutbacks were far from radical and followed a pattern of incremental
adjustments that had effectively started in the early 1980s. (+, )

References

Ahlquist, J. S. (2011) Navigating Institutional Change: The Accord, Rogernomics, and the
Politics of Adjustment in Australia and New Zealand, Comparative Political Studies
44 (2): 127-155.
Anderson, K. M. (2001) The Politics of Retrenchment in a Social Democratic Welfare State:
Reform of Swedish Pensions and Unemployment Insurance, Comparative Political
Studies 34 (9): 1063-1091.
Anderson, K. M., Kuipers, S., Schulze, I. and Van den Nouland, W. (2007) Belgium:
Linguistic Veto Players and Pension Reform, in E. M. Immergut, K. M. Anderson
and I. Schulze (eds): The Handbook of West European Pension Politics. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Archer, R. (1988) The Australian Accord, International Review of Applied Economics 2 (2):
213-232.
Bateman, H. and Piggott, J. (1998) Mandatory Retirement Saving in Australia, Annals of
Public and Cooperative Economics 69 (4): 547-569.
17

Bergmark, . (2008) Market Reforms in Swedish Health Care: Normative Reorientation and
Welfare Sustainability, Journal of Medicine and Philosophy 33 (3): 241-261.
Brennan, D. (2009) Australia: The Difficult Birth of Paid Maternity Leave, in S. B.
Kamerman and P. Moss (eds): The Politics of Parental Leave Policies: Children,
Parenting, Gender and the Labour Market. Bristol: Policy Press.
De Deken, J. (2002) Christian Democracy, Social Democracy and the Paradoxes of Earnings-
Related Social Security, International Journal of Social Welfare 11 (1): 22-39.
De Jong, P. R. (1999) Reforming Social Policy: Learning from the Dutch Experience, Siwss
Journal of Economics and Statistics 135 (3): 253-271.
De Vroom, B. and Blomsma, M. (1991) The Netherlands: An extreme case, in M. Kohli, M.
Rein, A.-M. Guillemard and H. Van Gunsteren (eds): Time for retirement.
Comparative studies of early exit from the labor force. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Department of Families, H., Community Services and Indigenous Affairs, (2009) Pension
Review Report. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia.
Edwards, M. and Whiteford, P. (1988) The Development of Government Policies on Poverty
and Income Distribution, Australian Economic Review 21 (3): 54-73.
Erixon, L. (2008) The Swedish third way: an assessment of the performance and validity of
the Rehn-Meidner model, Cambridge Journal of Economicy 32 367-393.
Feltenius, D. (2008) From Outsiders to Influential Insiders: Pensioners' Organizations in the
Policy Process in Sweden, Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and
Practice 10 (1): 29-46.
Finn, D. (1997) Working Nation: Welfare Reform and the Australian Job Compact for the
Long-Term Unemployed. London: Unemployment Unit.
Gieselink, G., Stevens, Y. and Van Buggenhout, B. (2002) Dpart anticip des travailleurs
ags en Belgique, Revue Belge de Scurit Sociale 44 (4): 579-617.
18

Gruen, D. (2009) The Return of Fiscal Policy. Sydney:
Gruen, D. and Stevens, G. (2000) Australian Macroeconomic Performance and Policies in
the 1990s, in D. Gruen and S. Shrestha (eds): The Australian Economy in the 1990s.
Canberra, ACT: Reserve Bank of Australia.
Hemerijck, A., Unger, B. and Visser, J. (2000) How Small Countries Negotiate Change:
Twenty-Five Years of Policy Adjustment in Austria, the Netherlands, and Belgium,
in F. W. Scharpf and V. A. Schmidt (eds): Welfare and Work in the Open Economy.
Volume II. Diverse Responses to Common Challenges. Oxford: Oxford Univesity
Press.
Hijzen, A. and Venn, D. (2011) The Role of Short-Time Work Schemes During the 2008-09
Recession. Paris: OECD.
Immergut, E. M. and Jochem, S. (2006) The Political Frame for Negotiated Capitalism:
Electoral Reform and the Politics of Crisis in Japan and Sweden, Governance 19 (1):
99-133.
Irwin, G. (1983) Notes on Recent Elections. The Dutch Parliamentary Election of 1982,
Electoral Studies 2 (1): 69-83.
Jonung, L., Kiander, J. and Vartia, P. (2009) The great financial crisis in Finland and
Sweden: the dynamics of boom, bust and recovery 1985-2000, in L. Jonung, J.
Kiander and P. Vartia (eds): The Great Financial Crisis in Finland and Sweden. The
Nordic Experience of Financial Liberalization. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Keating, P. (1992) One Nation: Statement by the Prime Minister. Canberra, ACT: Australian
Government Publishing Service.
Keating, P. (1994) Working Nation: The White Paper on Employment and Growth -- Policies
and Programs. Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service.
19

Kohli, M., Rein, M., Guillemard, A.-M. and van Gunsteren, H. (1991) Time for Retirement:
Comparative Studies of Early Exit from the Labor Force. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Kuipers, S. (2006) The Crisis Imperative. Crisis Rhetoric and Welfare State Reform in
Belgium and the Netherlands in the Early 1990s. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University
Press.
Lhoest, J. (2010) Les rductions de cotisations sociales dans le rgime des travailleurs
salaris. Leur rle dans le contexte historique, social et conomique, Revue Belge de
Scurit Sociale 52 (3): 495-582.
Lucardie, P., Nieboer, M. and Noomen, I. (1991) Overzicht van de partijpolitieke
gebeurtenissen van het jaar 1991. Groningen: Jaarboek van het Documentatiecentrum
Nederlandse Politieke Partijen.
Lundberg, E. (1984) The Rise and Fall of the Swedish Model, Journal of Economic
Literature 22 (4): 1-36.
Maessen, P. J. J. (1989) Bezuinigingen op de gezinsverzorging. Besluitvorming in de
verzorginsstaat. Amersfoort: Acco.
Manning, I. (1981) The 1970s: A Decade of Social Security Policy, Australian Economic
Review 14 (1): 13-19.
Manning, I. (1985) Continuity and Change in Australian Economic Policy: The Social
Welfare Services, Australian Economic Review 18 (3): 116-129.
Marx, I. (2007) A New Social Question? On Minimum Income Protection in the
Postindustrial Era. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.
Mjoset, L. (1987) Nordic Economic Policies in the 1970s and 1980s, International
Organization 41 (3): 403-456.
20

Nobelen, P. (1983) Nederland: Kwijnend corporatisme en stagnerende verzorgingsstaat, in
T. Akkermans and P. Nobelen (eds): Corporatisme en de verzorgingsstaat. Leiden:
Stenfert Kroese.
OECD (2009a) OECD Economic Outlook, Interim Report March 2009. Paris: OECD.
OECD (2009b) Pensions at a Glance. Retirement Income Systems in OECD Countries. Paris:
OECD.
OECD (2011) OECD Economic Surveys: Belgium. Paris: OECD.
Palme, J., Bergmark, ., Fritzell, J., Lundberg, O., Hrnqvist, M., Nsman, E., Sommestad,
L., Szebehely, M. and strm, A. (2000) To the Minister and Head of Ministry of
Health and Social Affairs. Stockholm:
Rudd, K. and Swan, W. (2008) Joint Press Conference Prime Minister & Treasurer, 14
October 2008 (Transcript). Australian Treasury
[http://www.treasurer.gov.au/DisplayDocs.aspx?doc=transcripts/2008/143.htm&pageI
D=004&min=wms&Year=&DocType=,
Ryner, M. (1994) Assessing the SAP's Economic Policy in the 1980s: The 'Third Way', the
Swedish Model and the Transition from Fordism to Post-Fordism, Economic and
Industrial Democracy 15 (3): 385-428.
Saunders, P. and Deeming, C. (2011) The Impact of the Crisis on Australian Social Security
Policy in Historical Perspective, Social Policy & Administration 45 (4): 371-388.
Scotton, R. B. (2000) Medibank: From Conception to Delivery and Beyond, Medical
Journal of Australia 173 (1): 9-11.
Smits, J. (1983) Belgian Politics in 1982: Less Democracy for a Better Economy, Res
Publica 25 (2-3): 181-217.
Starke, P., Kaasch, A. and van Hooren, F. (2013) The Welfare State as Crisis Manager:
Explaining the Diversity of Policy Responses to Economic Crisis. Basingstoke:
Palgrave Macmillan.
21

Steinmo, S. (2002) Globalization and Taxation: Challenges to the Swedish Welfare State,
Comparative Political Studies 35 (7): 839-862.
Stephens, J. D. (2010) The Social Rights of Citizenship, in F. G. Castles, S. Leibfried, J.
Lewis, H. Obinger and C. Pierson (eds): The Oxford Handbook of the Welfare State.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Stilwell, F. (1986) The Accord...And Beyond. Sydney: Pluto Press.
Toirkens, J. (1988) Schijn en werkelijkheid van het bezuinigingsbeleid 1975-1986. Deventer:
Kluwer.
Van der Veen, R. and Trommel, W. (1999) Managed liberalization of the Dutch welfare
state: A review and analysis of reform of the Dutch Social Security System, 1985-
1998 , Governance: An International Journal of Policy and Administration 12 (3):
289-310.
van Zanden, J. L. (1998) The Economic History of the Netherlands 1914-1995. A small open
economy in the 'long' twenthieth century. London and New York: Routledge.
Vandaele, K. (2009) The Ghent System, Temporary Unemployment and the Belgian Trade
Unions Since the Economic Downturn, Transfer 15 (3-4): 589-596.
Whitwell, G. (1986) The Treasury Line. Sydney: Allen & Unwin.

Вам также может понравиться