Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 36

Tax Increment Financing and Education Expenditures:

The Case of Iowa



Author: Phuong Nguyen-Hoang, Assistant Professor at the School of Urban and Regional
Planning, and Public Policy Center, University of Iowa
Postal address: 344 Jessup Hall, Iowa City, IA 52242
Email: phuong-nguyen@uiowa.edu
Phone: 319-335-0034
Abstract: This is the first study to directly examine the relationship between tax increment
financing (TIF) and education expenditures, using the state of Iowa as a case study. I find that
greater use of TIF is associated with reduced education expenditures. I also find little evidence to
support the commonly held proposition that school spending increases when TIF districts expire.
Finally, the negative price effect of TIF on education spending is increasingly larger for school
districts in lower wealth or income groups compared to their peers in higher wealth or income
groups. The negative, though small, effect of TIF on education spending, coupled with no gain
from the often-claimed long-run benefits of TIF, justifies policy measures to protect school
districts from TIF.

This paper is a pre-print version and it has been accepted for publication in Education
Finance and Policy, vol. 39, issue 4.


1

<A>Introduction
Tax increment financing (TIF) has become an increasingly popular economic
development tool in the United States since its first use in California in 1952.
1
As of 2013, only
Arizona has not enacted TIF legislation.
2
In recent years, TIF has been a hot-button issue in
Iowathe state of focus in this paper. In 2011, there were more than 2,200 TIF districts in Iowa.
Nearly 86 percent (or 297) of the school districts in the state contained one or more TIF districts
in at least one year during the sample period between 2001 and 2011. These 297 school districts
with TIF districts accounted for 96 percent of state total enrollment in 2011.
Two major reports (Fisher 2011; Fisher and Lipsman 2012) detail how TIF in Johnson
and Polk counties in Iowa has been abused, with consequences for overlapping jurisdictions
including school districts. For one, the merged Iowa River Landing/Coral Ridge Mall Urban
Renewal Area in Johnson County diverted $4.99 million in property taxes from the Clear Creek
Amana and Iowa City Community school districts, leading them to increase property tax rates by
$2.83 and $0.56 per $1,000 of taxable value, respectively.
To use TIF, municipal and county governments establish a TIF district and are then
allowed to divert the additional property taxes (associated with increased property values in the
district) as TIF funds to defray development-related costs. In the absence of TIF, the additional
property taxes would have been accessible to other overlapping jurisdictions, such as school
districts and counties. Indeed, one of the key issues in using TIF is how it may affect overlapping
jurisdictions, especially school districts and their spending. However, as reviewed later in this
paper, most studies on TIF focus on issues other than education finance. A few of them, such as
Lehnen and Johnson (2001) and Weber (2003), examine the impact of TIF on school district

1
TIF is also less commonly known as a Tax Allocation District (TAD) as in Georgia, Revenue Allocation
District (RAD) as in New Jersey, or Tax Increment Reinvestment Zone (TIRZ) as in Texas.
2
Californiaas noted, the first state to enact TIF legislationrepealed its TIF law in February 2012.
2

finances, particularly school district property tax revenues. No study has directly examined the
relationship between TIF and education expenditures. This paper aims to fill this gap in the
literature. Given the widespread use of TIF in Iowa and potentially sizeable fiscal impacts on
school districts, the empirical findings from this paper have implications for TIF policy in Iowa
and other states.
How might TIF affect education expenditures? In many cases, TIF freezes the property
tax base at a level below what it would be without TIF, and lower property wealth is likely to
reduce the amount of money local taxpayers are willing to pay for education. This mechanism
can be explained using a demand, or tax price, mechanism (tax price is defined as the share of a
voters house value to the districts tax base measured by total per pupil taxable property value).
TIF proponents often claim that voters in a school district with a TIF project have lower tax
prices of, and thus higher demand for, education expenditures than in the absence of TIF. Tax
prices may be lower from a larger property tax base after the TIF project comes to an end, and/or
when the TIF project is designated to a blighted area with properties that would have depreciated
in value without TIF. The voters would enjoy a larger tax base and demand more education
services when the TIF project produces positive spillover effects on neighboring properties.
Opponents, however, argue that TIF may increase voters tax prices of education spending and
thus lower their demand for it. Higher tax prices occur when cities adopt TIF for areas rich in
properties that would have trended upward in value, even without TIF, and/or when TIF
negatively affects the value of neighboring non-TIF properties within the school district.
I use panel data on Iowa school districts between 2001 and 2011 to answer four
interrelated research questions: (1) How are education expenditures generally affected by TIF
use? (2) Are there differential effects from different types of TIF properties on education
3

spending? (3) Does education spending increase when TIF districts expire? and (4) Does TIF
affect the spending of school districts in different wealth or income groups differently? To
preview, I find that heavier use of TIF is associated with decreased school district spending,
holding all other factors constant. Also, residential and industrial TIF properties (but not
commercial TIF properties) have significant negative effects on school district spending. I find
little evidence of increased education expenditures once TIF districts expire. Finally, the lower a
school districts wealth, the more TIF negatively affects education spending.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section presents background on
TIF use in Iowa, a review of TIF-related literature, and basic information on school finance in
the state. I then present a theoretical framework on how TIF might affect school expenditures,
followed by a section that elaborates on my empirical strategy. I then discuss empirical results,
and conclude with policy implications and suggestions for future research.

<A>Background
<B>How TIF Works and TIF in Iowa
TIF is a financing tool used by local governments, mostly cities and counties, to fund a
project to address blight or promote economic development. Although some TIF programs are
based on sales and income taxes (Smith 2009), property tax increment financing is used in most
states with TIF-enabling legislation, including Iowa.
3
A TIF project in Iowa begins when a
municipality designates an urban renewal area with clearly defined boundaries as a TIF district

3
The only example of a sales taxbased TIF district in the state is the Iowa Speedway Project in Newton
(approved in 2005).
4

or area.
4
The TIF district is governed by an authority empowered to enter into contractual
agreements and sell debt backed by TIF revenue.
Once established, the city freezes the assessed value of all taxable property within the
TIF district at the base yearthe year immediately prior to when the TIF district becomes
effective. During the subsequent life span of the TIF project, the increase in assessed value above
the base value is the incremental value. Tax increment thus refers to tax revenues generated on
this incremental value by all overlapping taxing jurisdictions, namely, the city, school districts,
counties, and other special-purpose districts. The TIF governing authority uses this tax increment
to finance development (via bond issuance or on a pay-as-you-go basis), while property tax
receipts from the frozen tax base continue to be channeled to the corresponding overlapping
jurisdictions. All of the incremental value that may have built up over the years becomes
accessible to these overlapping jurisdictions upon expiration of the TIF project.
TIF in Iowa is authorized by the Urban Renewal Law (Iowa Code, Chapter 403). This
law, enacted in 1957, allowed municipalities to use TIF only in slum or blighted areas.
5
(Whether
a TIF district is blighted and whether it cannot be redeveloped through regular private enterprise
but for the TIF incentive, also known as the but for test, are two common considerations for
TIF approval.) A legal amendment in the 1985 Iowa Acts (Chapter 66) puts Iowa among a few
states that do not currently require the presence of slum or blight conditions for TIF adoption.
This amendment suggests that cities in Iowa are allowed, and would probably prefer, to adopt
TIF for non-blighted areas, enabling them to capture a portion of the incremental value that
would have been available to overlapping jurisdictions.

4
A TIF district in Iowa can encompass an entire urban renewal area. Alternatively, multiple TIF districts
can be contained in a single urban renewal area (Cory and Martin 2012). For simplicity, I interchangeably
use TIF districts or areas in this paper.
5
Under Chapter 403, blight was defined as an economic and social liability imposing onerous municipal
burdens which decrease the tax base and reduce tax revenues.
5

The Urban Renewal Law has had additional important amendments over the years. For
one, counties in Iowa were authorized to use TIF only for industrial purposes (1991 Iowa Acts,
Chapter 214).
6
TIF can also be used for development of affordable housing for low- and
moderate-income people (1996 Iowa Acts, Chapter 1204). Since 1996, public hearings have been
legally required for the initial approval of an urban renewal plan, although not for each TIF
district that is established under the plan (1996 Iowa Acts, Chapter 1047). However, overlapping
jurisdictions are still unable to opt out of the establishment of a renewal area or TIF district.

These legal amendments led to a soaring increase in the number of TIF districts in Iowa.
In 1989, there were approximately 185 TIF districts in Iowa, most of which were based on the
blight requirement in the pre-1985 law (Talanker and Davis 2003). By 1999, the number of TIF
districts statewide had increased to 2,496 (Swenson and Eathington 2002), before decreasing to
2,125 in 2011 (Robinson 2011). Iowa cities and counties use TIF at rates comparable with other
Rust Belt states such as Wisconsin and Illinois (Briffault 2010).
Iowa school districts subject to TIF vary significantly in terms of the number of TIF
districts within their jurisdictions. The Davenport School District had the greatest number, with
fifty-nine TIF districts in 2011. As shown in the first panel of Table 1, it has become more
common for school districts to contain a large number of TIF districts. For example, from 2001
to 2011, there was a six-fold increase in the number of school districts each containing at least 30
TIF districts. The second panel of Table 1 shows that school districts are now less likely to have
TIF districts in their jurisdictions expire. For example, 128 school districts had TIF districts
expire from 2001 to 2003, compared to the period 2009 to 2011 when only 29 school districts
had TIFs expire. The third panel of Table 1 shows fewer school districts experiencing new TIF

6
Among local governments in Iowa, municipalities are still the primary recipients of TIF revenues. In
fiscal year 2011, 40 out of 99 counties and 349 out of 947 incorporated cities received TIF revenues
(Robinson 2011).
6

districts over time. School districts with new TIF districts still outnumbered those with expired
TIF districts in all the years during the sample period.
<B>Related Literature
Studies on TIF appeared in academic journals as early as the late 1970s (Davidson 1978).
This now substantial body of literature has revolved around key issues. For one, scholars have
sought to identify the factors that drive municipalities to adopt TIF. Population size,
intergovernmental aid, industrial composition, fiscal pressure, and tax competitionbut not
blightare associated with the likelihood of municipal TIF adoption (Anderson 1990; Dye and
Sundberg 1998; Man and Rosentraub 1998; Man 1999; Byrne 2005). Another key issue is how
TIF adoption can affect the values of property within TIF districts and have spillover effects on
property outside TIF districts. While Byrne (2006) examines factors influencing property value
growth within TIF districts, Smith (2006) finds that properties in TIF districts exhibit higher
rates of appreciation than those outside TIF districts, and higher rates than prior to TIF
designation. Weber, Bhatta, and Merriman (2003) find that improved industrial TIF parcels
appreciate at the same rate as otherwise identical industrial non-TIF parcels.
Several studies explicitly examine TIF spillover effects on property in non-TIF areas.
Bossard (2011) finds evidence of nonlinear TIF spillover effects on the growth of non-TIF
property values in school districts. Several studies find negative spillovers from TIF use. Dye
and Merriman (2000) show that the non-TIF portions of Illinois municipalities with TIF districts
have slower real value growth than communities without TIF. Dye and Merrimans (2003)
subsequent finding that TIF adoption has no impact on the growth of citywide property values
suggests that value growth in TIF districts is offset by declines in non-TIF areas in the adopting
city. Specifically, commercial and industrial TIF districts hinder the growth of commercial non-
7

TIF property values. Weber, Bhatta, and Merriman (2007) also find that residential houses
adjacent to commercial and industrial TIF districts see decreases in appreciation rates, and they
argue that industrial TIF districts produce negative spillovers through development that is noisy,
polluting, aesthetically unappealing, and, like commercial development, conflicts with residential
land uses (p. 279). These authors also posit that negative spillover to residential neighborhoods
from commercial TIF districts might result from traffic congestion and the lack of pedestrian
access around the big-box retail stores typically found in commercial TIF districts. By contrast,
Merriman, Skidmore, and Kashian (2011) find positive, though not precisely estimated,
stimulatory effects of commercial TIF on commercial activity in non-TIF areas.
Three studies examine the effects of TIF on school revenues. Lehnen and Johnson (2001)
find that TIF is not a revenue drain for school districts in Indiana because TIF was not intensely
adopted in 1995the only year with data available. Weber (2003) finds an inverse relationship
between TIF intensity and property tax revenues across school districts in Cook County, Illinois.
However, Weber, Hendrick, and Thompson (2008) find little effect of TIF on school revenues
when they extend the sample to include all districts in Illinois.
A few studies focus on TIF in Iowa, in addition to the two Fisher reports cited earlier.
Nydle (2009) and Perri (2001) examine legal aspects of TIF in Iowa. Lawrence and Stephenson
(1995) develop a model to determine which Iowa taxpayers under which taxing authorities fund
TIF expenditures and receive subsidies from TIF programs. Pacewicz (2013) looks at the role of
TIF in the financialization of urban politics in two cities in Iowa. Swenson and Eathington (2002,
2006) examine the growth of TIF in Iowa and how it might impact economic development in
Iowa cities. This study is the first to examine directly how TIF affects education expenditures.
8

<B>School Finance in Iowa
School districts in Iowa, as in other states, are financed primarily by property taxes and
state aid. Iowa adopts a foundation aid formula. The foundation level is equal to 87.5 percent of
state cost per pupil, as determined by the previous years state cost per pupil plus the regular
allowable growth (usually 1 to 4 percent) set annually by the states General Assembly. All
districts contribute to the foundation level with property taxes at a uniform (statewide) rate of
$5.40 per $1,000 of assessed valuation available to school districts (that is, the incremental value
of TIF areas is excluded). The state provides aid for the difference between the foundation level
and this uniform levy (or, the required local contribution). Under this formula, state aid per pupil
is smaller for property-rich than for property-poor districts. Beyond this foundation level,
districts can use an additional levy to meet district costs per pupil, as derived by their previous
year district cost per pupil plus the state-determined regular allowable growth. Since the
maximum district cost per pupil can be no more than 105 percent of the state cost per pupil,
district costs per pupil vary minimally across districts.
Little variation in district costs per pupil does not necessarily mean little variation in
actual expenditures. As indicated in Table 2, after adjusting for inflation, total operating
expenditures per pupil vary substantially, with a standard deviation of nearly $3,000. The
maximum spending was nearly eight times as much as the minimum spending. This substantial
variation results from different expenditure ceilings that are determined by districts total
spending authority. Spending authority for any given year comprises the total district cost,
miscellaneous income, and unspent spending authority, which is the difference between the
districts total spending authority and actual expenditures in the previous year.
9

The catchall term of miscellaneous income includes any income a school district
receives other than the uniform and additional levies and state foundation aid. Examples include
investment interest, fees for student services, income surtaxes, federal aid, state grants, and funds
raised for educational programs such as instructional support programs (ISP) and educational
improvement programs (EIP).
7
Specifically, funds for the ISP and EIP can be increased up to 10
and 5 percent of the district cost, respectively. These additional funds for ISP or EIP can come
from property taxes exclusively, or from a combination of property taxes and revenues from an
income surtax that is charged as a percent of an individuals state income tax liability.
8
Notably,
some property tax levies are not subject to TIF funds captured by cities or counties. Property tax
levies in this category are those for debt service and for physical plant and equipment (PPEL).
Therefore, my empirical work focuses only on the effects of TIF on operating expenditures.

<A>Theoretical Framework
How TIF might affect education expenditures can be examined in terms of how TIF
might affect demand for education services. Demand for publicly provided education services
depends on factors such as local residents income, demographic characteristics representing
differential preferences for education, and the price of education services. Of these factors, TIF
most plausibly affects the demand for education services through the price that voters have to
pay for additional education spending. As education is a publicly provided normal good, the
higher the price, the lower the demand for education spending, and vice versa. This section
presents a theoretical framework for potential effects of TIF on education spending by

7
The property tax levy for instructional support programs is not available for TIF use if TIF debt incurs
after April 24, 2012, which post-dates the last year of my sample period. Also, funds for both of these
programs are included in a school districts operating funds.
8
Iowa is among a few states (including Kentucky, Ohio, and Pennsylvania) that authorize school districts
to levy local income taxes for specific education programs (Ross and Nguyen-Hoang 2013).
10

comparing a voters tax liability or price (and thus his/her demand for education spending) in the
presence and absence of TIF.
The tax liability, , of a voter in a school district is determined by school district tax rate,
, and this voters taxable property value, , or
(1)
This district has a budget constraint represented by equation (2)

, (2)
where E is total operating expenditures per pupil;

is total taxable property value per pupil; is


total state aid per pupil; and is other revenues per pupil such as income surtaxes and federal
aid. As discussed above, state education aid per pupil (A) is distributed to make up the difference
between the foundation level () equal to 87.5 percent of state district cost per pupil, and local
contributions equal to the product of the uniform property tax rate (

) of 0.0054 and total


taxable property value per pupil (

). Equation (2) can be rewritten as equation (3):


(

(3)
In a typical school districts annual budget process, the district calculates per pupil
property tax revenues that need to be raised () by subtracting F and O from E. As the final step
to establish how much the district will spend (Mikesell 2014, p. 495), the property tax rate, , is
set by equation (4):


(4)
The first term of (4),

, gives an additional tax rate that the district needs to levy on


local residents in addition to the uniform rate,

.
9
Substituting (4) into (1) yields

9
Total school district property tax rates were always higher than the uniform rate during the sample
period, ranging between $8.168 and $24.426 per $1,000 assessed valuation.
11

(


(5)
I now incorporate the potential effects of TIF into equation (5). Of the factors in this
equation, TIF is mostly likely to affect

, which is negatively correlated with the voters tax


liability, . Let us take a closer look at how this might happen.
10
I can divide the school district
into two areas: the TIF and non-TIF (N) areas. While the non-TIF area has its own taxable
property values per pupil (

), the TIF area has two separate taxable property values per pupil:
frozen value (

) and incremental value (

). The frozen value,

, is set by freezing the previous


years values of the properties within the TIF district, called the base value (

). While


produces additional revenue that, rather than being channeled to the school district, is captured
by the initiating city or county to finance TIF activities, the school district is still entitled to


and

, or

.
11

Assuming that there is no spillover effect of TIF on non-TIF areas (or on

), I focus first
on how

and thus

might be smaller or larger with TIF than without TIF. One of two common

10
Potential effects of TIF on education expenditures can be explained through a budgeting mechanism.
This mechanism also examines how TIF might affect

. Unlike the demand mechanism, the effects of


TIF on education spending E are captured in the first term on the right-hand side in equation (2),

. The
budgeting mechanism is less appropriate for this study. While TIF might change

, the final link between


TIF and E depends crucially on whether school districts can set the tax rate, , at will. If they can do so,
the effects of TIF on E are then confounded and harder to untangle. The budgeting mechanism would be
more appropriate in a state with limits on property tax rates levied by school districts (as in California
with Proposition 13). This is not the case for Iowa, where school districts are not subject to state-imposed
cap limits on property tax rates.
11
While a districts assessed value that is used to compute its required contribution in Iowas state
education aid formula is based only on non-TIF areas, or

), other states may calculate the local


contributions based on the total local property tax base, regardless of whether it is available to the school
district; that is,

). Working this contribution formula through equations (2)(4), a voters


tax liability in those states equals ((

). All else being equal, a marginal increase in

, a
key measure of TIF use, raises the tax liability of a voter (via

) more in those states than in Iowa,


which suggests that the marginal effect on education expenditures of TIF, especially in cases of higher tax
price and thus lower spending demand, is highly likely to be larger in those states than in Iowa.
12

scenarios may occur, depending on the underlying trend (or growth rate) of the base value,

.
12

The first scenario illustrated by Figure 1 occurs when

has a positive (upward) underlying


trend (i.e., the property tax base of the TIF district is poised to increase even without TIF). The
frozen value,

, is lower than what

would have been in the absence of TIF. Put differently,


the voter has higher annual tax liabilities and lower annual demand for education spending
during the TIF period than he or she would have had without TIF. A portion of

captures the
difference between

and

that would otherwise have been accessible to the school district.


TIF adoptions for areas rich in appreciating property benefit cities but fiscally constrain
overlapping jurisdictions including school districts. Opponents often cite this scenario in their
criticisms of TIF. The second scenario happens when a TIF district is established for an area with
declining (or negative-trending) property values. This is usually the case for blighted areas. A
voters tax liability is lower with TIF than in the absence of TIF because

would have been


lower than the frozen value,

. This is the best scenario in which local residents, all else being
equal, benefit from lower tax liabilities, thereby probably increasing their demand for education
spending.
13

Three points are worth mentioning. First, either scenario 1 or 2 may occur when


as in Figure 1, that is, when the values of properties within TIF districts have a higher rate of
appreciation than those of similar properties outside TIF districts (as in the case of Smiths
[2006] finding). Second, scenario 1 may even occur when the values of TIF properties trend

12
The term underlying indicates that the growth trend of

that is observed prior to TIF adoption would


have continued in later years in the absence of TIF.

during a TIF period is a counterfactual as


illustrated in Figure 1.
13
The third and less likely scenario occurs when

has a zero growth rate (i.e.,

during the TIF period


would have been equal to

). Any increase in

can be attributed completely to TIF. The voters tax


liability with TIF is equal to that without TIF; TIF thus has no effect.
13

upward at the same rate as those of comparable non-TIF properties (as found in Weber, Bhatta,
and Merriman [2003] for improved industrial TIF parcels in Chicago).
I now relax the assumption of no spillover. As evidenced in the literature discussed
earlier, the adoption of TIF may generate spillover effects on property near TIF districts. In other
words,

can be a function of

. The value of

is larger or smaller with TIF than it would


have been without TIF, when

has positive or negative spillover effects, respectively. Together


with the discussions in the preceding paragraph, this observation suggests that a voters demand
for education spending is lower (higher) as a result of his higher (lower) tax liability with TIF
than without TIF when

has negative (positive) spillover effects, and/or when

has a positive
(negative) underlying growth rate.
14
It is thus difficult to accurately predict whether the
relationship between TIF and Iowa school districts education expenditures is neutral, positive,
or negative. Instead, the data can inform us about this relationship.
The earlier review of the TIF literature also suggests that the spillover effects from TIF
may vary depending on the type of TIF district (i.e., commercial, industrial, residential). Put
differently, the size of the spillover effects and thus of the demand for education spending
(holding everything else constant) may vary depending on type of TIF property. The second
research question is intended to explore these potentially differential effects of different TIF
property types.
The above discussions apply to TIF districts during their life spans. When a TIF district
expires, its incremental value (

) in the immediately preceding year (or year


t1
) becomes
accessible to the school district in the current year, making its

with TIF larger than what it



14
For cases in which

has positive (negative) spillover effects, and

has a positive (negative)


underlying growth rate, whether is higher or lower with TIF than without TIF depends on the size of the
spillover effects relative to the size of the absolute difference between

and what

would have been


without TIF.
14

would have been without TIF.
15
At the expiration of the TIF district, decreases, resulting in a
lower price of education services and thus in higher demand for education spending. This is one
of the major arguments for TIF. The third research question is motivated by this argument for the
potential effects of expired TIF districts.
TIF cities would prefer areas with appreciating properties (scenario 1) to blighted areas
with depreciating properties (scenario 2). Only with these TIF areas would they be able to
capture the portion of property tax increases that otherwise would have been available to
overlapping jurisdictions. In other words, cities tend to adopt TIF for purposes other than
addressing blight. Man (1999) finds that Indiana cities under fiscal pressures are more likely to
adopt TIF. Fiscally strained cities are likely to have lower property tax bases, be located in
lower-wealth school districts, and adopt non-blighted TIF areas. Controlling for total numbers of
TIF districts and

, lower-wealth school districts are to have more non-blighted TIF districts,


and thus have a lower demand for education spending, than their higher-wealth peers.
16
I test this
likelihood in the fourth research question.

<A>Empirical Strategy
In keeping with TIF literature, I employ a reduced-form constant-elasticity expenditure
model to estimate the effects of TIF on school district spending.
17
Under this reduced form, I

15
An example of a school districts receiving a sizeable increase in its tax base following an expired TIF
district is Lewis Central School District (LCSD) in Council Bluffs. This school district benefited from
three expired TIF districts in 2003. These three districts had a combined incremental value of over $40.3
million in 2002. This amount became available to LCSD in 2003, dramatically increasing its tax base by
13 percent to about $535.4 million. The 13 percent jump was much higher than the year-on-year increase
of between 5 and 7 percent in the previous three years when none of the TIF districts expired.
16
This likelihood assumes away differences in spillover effects across school district groups. This
assumption is innocuous because there is little reason for such differences.
17
The constant elasticity demand model is dominant in the applied literature on public and education
spending (Duncombe 1996).
15

specify operating expenditures per pupil (E) to be a function of measures related to TIF use (Y),
and a vector of control variables (X) as in equation (6):

, (6)
where i and t index school districts and years. In equation (6), represents district fixed effects
to control for time-invariant district-specific unobserved factors. As adopted in Downes and
Pogue (1994), these district fixed effects also account for time-invariant unobserved efficiency
factors, thereby addressing most of the relative efficiency differences across districts.
18
Year
dummies, , control for common factors affecting all school districts in Iowa in a given year.
Vector X includes all other control variables (unless otherwise specified, all financial
measures are in 2010 dollars and per pupil terms). The first group of control variables includes
characteristics of the student body, such as enrollment, percent of African-American students,
and shares of disadvantaged students, including those receiving free or reduced-price lunch, and
those with Limited English Proficiency (LEP). A higher concentration of disadvantaged students
is expected to induce greater expenditures. Studies reviewed in Fox (1981) and Andrews,
Duncombe, and Yinger (2002) provide empirical evidence that economies of size in education
may help larger districts incur lower costs per pupil. Following this literature, I specify the log of
per pupil expenditures as a quadratic function of the log of enrollment. The second group of
control variables represents voter income (measured by median household income following the
median voter framework of public choice to be discussed), income surtaxes, and
intergovernmental aid (namely, state and federal aid) that school districts receive.
19
Higher voter

18
Studies such as Duncombe and Yinger (2011) may specify efficiency factors that do change over time
as a function of voter income and tax price. However, I use different measures of tax price for vector Y,
and variables indicating voter income are included in vector X of equation (6). For ease of interpretation,
these efficiency effects are disregarded.
19
I do not have data on investment income or student fees. However, they are expected to play a
negligible role in counteracting the use of TIF. Both investment income and student fees traditionally
16

income and additional revenues from income surtaxes or intergovernmental aid are expected to
increase education expenditures.
The third group of variables includes variables representing district-level differences in
demographic characteristics, namely, the share of the population that graduated from four-year
college and the share of owner-occupied housing units. These populations, compared to non-
college graduates and renters, respectively, may have different preferences for school
expenditures. Specifically, college-educated people may desire greater school spending
(Bergstrom, Rubinfeld, and Shapiro 1982; Hilber and Mayer 2009). Since school quality is found
to be capitalized into property values (Nguyen-Hoang and Yinger 2011), homeowners are also
expected to prefer higher education expenditures.
20

<B>Variables of TIF Use
I have two sets of TIF-related measures (Y). I show in the theoretical framework that the
potential effects of TIF on education expenditures revolve mostly around the property tax base,

, and the ratio of

. The first measure in my empirical estimations that captures this ratio is


based on the median voter framework.
21
In this public-choice framework, a school districts level
of spending is the one desired by the majority of its local residents, that is, as chosen by the
median voter. The median voter is decisive; so is his tax price indicating his preference, or
demand, for education. Using Bergstrom and Goodmans (1973) definition, the median voter is
the citizen with a median income who is assumed to own a house of median value. The standard

account for a very small proportion of a school districts operating budget. Also, school districts have
little control over investment receipts primarily determined by market forces.
20
While I log percentage variables indicating student characteristics, I do not log demographic variables
(also in percentage terms). The decision of whether to log percentage variables is to maximize
explanatory power. The main results change little whether all of the percentage variables are logged or
not logged.
21
The median voter framework is just one of the formal public choice voting models. As reviewed in Gill
and Gainous (2002), none of the voting models perfectly describes reality.
17

measure of the price for public services is, therefore, the ratio of median house value to total per
pupil taxable property value accessible to the school district. In this standard measure of tax price
(

), the numerator, , is the median voters. Although

may capture a portion of the effect of


TIF on education spending, it is not a direct indicator of TIF use, and does not allow us to
quantify how much of this effect can be attributed to TIF.
The second set of TIF measures is related more closely to TIF use. The first and key
measure in this set is the incremental taxable property value per pupil in all TIF areas of a school
district in the current year, or

in the theoretical framework.


22
(I naturally log-transform

and
replace undefined logged values (when

) with 0.)

reflects the potential effects of TIF on

. Higher

captures greater absolute differences between

and what

would have been


without TIF (as in the earlier two

-related scenarios), and/or greater spillover effects on

. As
previously discussed, the coefficient of

can be neutral, positive, or negative. A negative


coefficient of

suggests undesirable consequences of TIF on education spending: TIF captures


a portion of the property tax base of the TIF areas that would have increased and been available
to school districts without TIF, and/or makes the property tax base of the non-TIF area smaller
(as a result of negative TIF spillovers) than with no TIF.
Following Merriman, Skidmore, and Kashians (2011) finding that the number of
existing TIF districts within a municipality affects property values, I use a subordinate TIF-
related measure, namely, the number of new TIF districts within a school district (

) in the
current year. This measure might also capture the same potential effects of TIF on

as

. The
coefficients of

and

are thus expected to have the same sign. When both

and

are both

22
For school districts with multiple TIF areas, the estimated coefficient indicates the average effect of all
TIF areas.
18

estimated, the coefficient of

indicates whether an increased concentration of TIF districts has


any effect on educational spending, in addition to the effect from

.
In equation (6),

represents the total incremental value from property of all types. As


discussed earlier, the spillover effects from TIF may vary depending on the type of TIF district,
namely, commercial, industrial, or residential. To investigate potential differential effects from
different types of TIF property on education spending (the second research question), I
disaggregate

into three major types of TIF propertyresidential, commercial, and


industrial
23
and estimate them together with other variables described in equation (6).
A major argument for TIF use is that overlapping jurisdictions, including school districts,
may benefit financially when TIF districts expire, releasing

that has potentially built up over


the years to the overlapping jurisdictions, and thus lowering local voters tax price. To capture
this potential price effect of expired TIF districts (the third research question), I employ the ratio
of the incremental taxable property value to the total taxable property value, both in year
t1

(

),
24
and the number of expired TIF districts within a school district (

).
25
These two
variables are expected to be positively correlated with education expenditures.
To investigate the fourth question as to whether TIF affects the education expenditures
of lower-wealth school districts more than those of higher-wealth districts, I include in equation
(6) an interaction between the main measure of TIF (

), and a variable indicating a school



23
Other property types include agricultural land and buildings, railroads, and utilities with or without gas
and electric property. These properties represented only 2.7 to 4.3 percent of the total incremental value in
TIF districts during the sample period. Also, the data do not have an indicator of TIF type for individual
TIF districts; I am thus unable to disaggregate

or

.
24
This ratio captures the intensity of the TIF use in year
t1
. I use this measure instead of the incremental
taxable property value per pupil in the preceding year because I do not have enrollment data for the
academic year 19992000. The estimation results reported in Table 5 are still insignificant when I divide
the incremental property value in year
t1
by the enrollment in the current year, or when I log this ratio.
25
New TIF districts are in the current year but not in the immediately preceding year, while expired TIF
districts exist in the immediately preceding year but not in the current year.
19

districts relative level of wealth or income (W).
26
This variable, W, is coded 0, 1, and 2 for
districts in which the median housing value in Census 2010 was below the 33rd percentile,
between the 33rd and 67th percentiles, and above the 67th percentile, respectively. If the
coefficient of

is significantly negative, a positive significant coefficient of the interaction term


then means that TIF has milder price effects on higher-wealth school districts. To test the
robustness of the results, I interact

with a variant of W, which is based on school districts


median household income in Census 2010.
27

<B>Potential Endogeneity
One might be concerned over potential endogeneity as a result of reverse causality
between education expenditures and TIF use. In a school district that expects education spending
to grow rapidly, its officials might be more resistant to TIF establishment than in school districts
with more stable spending. Put differently, school districts with low education spending are
prone to TIF adoption. If such a link between spending and TIF existed, estimated results would
be biased downward.
This concern for potential bias is not warranted for several reasons. First, although
previous studies recognize TIF to be potentially endogenous, none of them provides significant
evidence of endogeneity. Dye and Merriman (2000) reject endogenous TIF adoption; Man and
Rosentraub (1998) and Anderson (1990) find insignificant relationships between school district
related variables and TIF adoption; and Weber (2003) does not find evidence of endogenous TIF
in the estimations of school district revenues, state aid, and effective tax rates. Second, unlike

26
As shown and discussed in the results section,

does not show significant impacts on education


spending. Its interaction with W is not significant either and thus is not reported. The interaction between
W and T
P
is also insignificant and not reported.
27
W cannot be estimated separately. It is dropped in fixed effects models because it is constant for each
district.
20

their peers in other states, school districts in Iowa cannot choose to opt out of the TIF process.
28

Third, as argued in Weber, Hendrick, and Thompson (2008), the endogeneity is generally not an
issue for estimating the effects of TIF at the school district level because local governments
(mostly municipalities) that make TIF adoption decisions in Iowa are distinct from school
districts. The boundaries of school districts do not coincide with those of municipalities and
counties (the two jurisdictions with the authority to establish TIF districts). The designation of
TIF districts is, thus, unlikely to be correlated with school districts fiscal conditions. All in all,
potential downward bias is not a major cause for concern; one can, however, treat my estimates
as conservative.
Table 2 provides summary statistics of all the variables used to estimate different variants
of equation (6), and their sources. The data included 347 school districts in Iowa between 2001
and 2011.
29
Of these, fifty districts did not have any TIF district during the sample period. Nearly
84 percent of the total observations had positive TIF values. Incremental taxable property values
per pupil within TIF districts represented by

showed marked growth and variation with the


standard deviation of $17,266.
30
Of the three major property types subject to TIF, commercial
properties provided school districts with the most incremental per pupil value, followed by
residential and industrial properties.


28
Overlapping jurisdictions may legally opt out of participation in the TIF process in eleven states
(Weber 2003).
29
There were 359 school districts as of the 20102011 academic year. However, given that district
consolidations have substantial expenditure implications (Duncombe and Yinger 2007), districts that were
reorganized or consolidated during the sample period were deleted from the dataset.
30
The summary statistics without the fifty non-TIF school districts are quite similar.
21

<A>Results
Table 3 presents the regression results on the general effects of TIF on education
expenditures (the first research question) with the specification of both

and

. (The results
are almost identical when they are estimated separately.) The coefficient of

is negative but
insignificant, showing ambiguous evidence of this variable on education spending. The other two
TIF measures, namely, tax price (

) and total incremental taxable property value per pupil (

),
show negative price effects on school expenditures, indicating lower demand for spending in
response to higher prices. A 1 percent increase in

and

is associated with a reduction of 0.12


and 0.0018 percent, respectively, in school district operating expenditures. I am unable to
directly quantify the impact of TIF with the coefficient of

. The price effect of TIF measured


by

on education expenditures is relatively small. Suppose that an average-spending district


that has the average

of $10,750 and enrollment of 1,344 increases its

by approximately one
standard deviation to slightly over $28,000. This 160 percent increase in

would induce a
reduction of only 0.29 percent (160 0.0018 percent) in this districts operating spending per
pupil ($31), thus, a reduction of $41,664 in total spending.
Many of the other variables are highly significant with expected signs. I find a quadratic
relationship between enrollment and education spending. While more students decrease
education expenditures per pupil, diseconomies of size start to set in at an enrollment of about
24,300. (In Iowa, only the enrollment of the Des Moines School District exceeds this threshold.)
A 1 percent increase in the share of low-income students is associated with an increase of nearly
0.02 percent in operating expenditures. Voters higher income also increases their demand for
education expenditures. The demand also becomes higher with increased income surtaxes and
state and federal aid. The effect of state aid is more than nine times larger than that of federal aid.
22

As with Nguyen-Hoang (2013), an increase in the shares of college graduates and homeowners
within a district is associated with higher school spending.
Table 4 reports the estimation results for the second research question regarding the
potential differential effects of different TIF types on education expenditures. This table shows
that incremental property values of residential and industrial properties in TIF districts are
negatively related with school district spending. An increase in the incremental values of
residential and industrial properties is associated with a reduction of 0.0012 percent,
respectively, in educational spending. This price effect of residential TIF on demand for
education spending can be explained by, as reviewed in Nguyen (2005), the negative, though
small, spillover effects of affordable housing on the values of nearby properties. (The primary
purpose of residential TIF in Iowa is to create affordable housing.) In keeping with the
theoretical framework, the negative price effect of industrial TIF on education expenditures may
be explained by negative spillover effects on nearby properties (Dye and Merriman 2003; Weber,
Bhatta, and Merriman 2007) and/or a positive growth trend of industrial TIF properties (Weber,
Bhatta, and Merriman 2003). The coefficient of commercial TIF is insignificant probably
because of mixed spillover effects of all commercial TIF districts within a school district on
nearby properties: some commercial TIF districts have positive spillovers (Merriman, Skidmore,
and Kashian 2011), others negative (Weber, Bhatta, and Merriman 2007).
Table 5 reports the results for the third and fourth research questions. In columns 1 and 2,
I find little empirical evidence for effects of expired TIF districts measured by either the ratio of
incremental taxable property value to total taxable value in year
t1
(

), or the number of expired


TIF districts within a school district (

). Although the signs of these two variables are positive


as expected (i.e., higher demand for education spending in response to lower prices), their
23

coefficients are not precisely estimated. This seemingly puzzling finding provides little support
for the argument that overlapping jurisdictions would benefit when TIF projects expire. This
finding can be plausibly explained by insufficient statistical power,
31
or by an unfavorable
attitude toward growth government spending among the large majority of voters. This attitude
may come from the voters fear of a ratchet effect in school district spending (i.e., once
increased, the spending will not be lowered).
Columns 3 and 4 of Table 5 provide evidence on the differential effects of TIF on the
education expenditures of school districts with different levels of wealth or income. A 1 percent
increase in

for the lowest wealth or income school districts (W = 0) is associated with a


reduction of 0.0034 or 0.0038 percent in education spending, respectively. This price effect for
the lowest income district group is approximately twice as large as the average effect reported in
Table 3. The positive significant interaction terms of logged

W in columns 3 and 4 suggest


that the negative price effect of TIF on educational expenditures becomes smaller for higher-
income school districts. While the spending of school districts in the middle group (between the
33rd and 67th wealth or income percentiles) is expected to decline by only 0.0015 or 0.0017
percent in response to a one-percent increase in

, changes in

have no significant effect on the


educational expenditures of school districts in the highest wealth or income group.
32
These
findings suggest that, all else being equal, cities in the lowest wealth or income group were more
likely to designate non-blighted areas as TIF districts even though property values would have
increased without TIF.


31
Compared to nearly 84 percent of the observations with positive TIF values, only 270 (or 7 percent of)
observations have at least one expired TIF district during the sample period.
32
Using column 3, the statistical test of a linear combination of (0.0034 + 2 0.0019) (with the lincom
Stata command) provides an insignificant result.
24

<A>Conclusion
Tax increment financing (TIF) has been a popular tool for economic (re)development in
many states. Of these, Iowa is a top user of TIF with more than 2,200 TIF districts. TIF has been
a hot-button policy issue in the state following recent reports on the (ab)use of TIF in Polk and
Johnson counties. Integral to the controversy is how TIF may affect overlapping taxing
jurisdictions, particularly school districts. On the one hand, proponents of TIF hold that voters in
a school district may demand greater education expenditures from lower tax prices associated
with a larger property tax base when one of these scenarios occur: cities in the district adopt TIF
for blighted areas that would have otherwise depreciated, TIF exerts positive spillover effects on
neighboring property, or TIF districts expire. On the other hand, opponents of TIF argue that
voters in a school district may face higher tax prices of education spending and thus demand less
of it when TIF district property values frozen during the TIF period would have increased
without TIF (and been available to the school district), or when TIF induces negative spillover
effects on property near TIF districts.
This is the first study to directly examine the relationship between TIF and education
expenditures. I find that greater use of TIF is associated with reduced education expenditures. I
also find little evidence to support the commonly held proposition that school spending increases
from TIF when TIF districts expire. This finding might reflect voters fear of the ratchet effect
(i.e., school spending, once increased, keeps going up). Finally, the negative price effect of TIF
on education spending is increasingly larger for school districts in lower wealth or income
groups compared to their peers in higher wealth or income groups. The effect of TIF on the
spending of school districts in the lowest income group is approximately twice as large as the
25

average effect. These school districts might have more non-blighted TIF districts that would not
have passed the but for test.
These findings have policy implications for Iowa and elsewhere. The negative, though
small, effect of TIF on education spending, coupled with no gain from the often-claimed long-
run benefits of TIF, justifies policy measures to protect school districts from TIF. For one, school
districts, as in Ohio, Georgia, Texas, and Pennsylvania, should be allowed to opt in, or out of,
TIF plans initiated by cities. In addition, the but-for test should be reinstated as a major
condition for TIF approval. Reinstating the test would particularly help the lowest-income school
districts most affected by TIF.
Finally, state education aid formulas could buffer the effects of TIF on education
expenditures. In Iowa, the aid is designed to make up the difference between the foundation level
and a school districts required contribution based only on its non-TIF tax base. Practically, the
state partially offsets the districts potential tax base losses from TIF. As noted earlier, the
negative price effect of TIF on education expenditures, which I find to be relatively small for
Iowa, is likely to be higher for states that employ a school districts total tax base (i.e., including
the TIF incremental value) to compute required local contributions in their state aid formulas.
Identifying and studying U.S. states that include TIF incremental value in the calculation of local
contributions would help reveal the full extent of TIF effects on education expenditures.





26

<A>References
Anderson, John E. 1990. Tax increment financing: Municipal adoption and growth. National Tax
Journal 43(2): 155163.
Andrews, Matthew, William D. Duncombe, and John Yinger. 2002. Revisiting economies of size
in American education: Are we any closer to a consensus? Economics of Education Review
21(3): 245262.
Bergstrom, Theodore C., and Robert P. Goodman. 1973. Private demands for public goods.
American Economic Review 63(3): 280296.
Bergstrom, Theodore C., Daniel L. Rubinfeld, and Perry Shapiro. 1982. Micro-based estimates
of demand functions for local school expenditures. Econometrica 50(5): 11831205.
Bossard, Jennifer A. 2011. The effect of tax increment financing on spillovers and school district
revenue. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Nebraska at Lincoln, Lincoln, NE.
Briffault, Richard. 2010. The most popular tool: Tax increment financing and the political
economy of local government. University of Chicago Law Review 77(1): 6595.
Byrne, Paul F. 2005. Strategic interaction and the adoption of tax increment financing. Regional
Science and Urban Economics 35(3): 279303.
Byrne, Paul F. 2006. Determinants of property value growth for tax increment financing districts.
Economic Development Quarterly 20(4): 317329.
Cory, Mark, and Patricia J. Martin. 2012. ABCs of Iowa urban renewal: A practical guide for
cities and counties. Des Moines, IA: Ahlers and Cooney, P.C.
Davidson, Jonathan M. 1978. Tax increment financing as a tool for community redevelopment.
University of Detroit Journal of Urban Law 56: 405444.
27

Downes, Thomas A., and Thomas Pogue. 1994. Adjusting school aid formulas for the higher
cost of educating disadvantaged students. National Tax Journal 47(1): 89110.
Duncombe, William D. 1996. Public expenditure research: What have we learned? Public
Budgeting and Finance 16(2): 2658.
Duncombe, William D., and John Yinger. 2007. Does school district consolidation cut costs?
Education Finance and Policy 2(4): 341375.
Duncombe, William D., and John Yinger. 2011. Making do: State constraints and local responses
in Californias education finance system. International Tax and Public Finance 18(3): 337368.
Dye, Richard F., and David F. Merriman. 2000. The effects of tax increment financing on
economic development. Journal of Urban Economics 47(2): 306328.
Dye, Richard F., and David F. Merriman. 2003. The effect of tax increment financing on land
use. In The property tax, land use, and land use regulation, edited by Dick Netzer, pp. 3761.
Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Dye, Richard F., and Jeffrey O. Sundberg. 1998. A model of tax increment financing adoption
incentives. Growth and Change 29(1): 90110.
Evans, William N., and Ioannis N. Kessides. 1993. Localized market power in the US airline
industry. Review of Economics and Statistics 75(1): 6675.
Fisher, Peter. 2011. Tax increment financing: A case study of Johnson County. Iowa City, IA:
Iowa Fiscal Partnership. Available www.iowafiscal.org/2011docs/111121-TIF-JC.pdf.
Fisher, Peter, and Michael Lipsman. 2012. Tax increment financing in Polk County. Iowa City,
IA: Iowa Fiscal Partnership. Available www.iowafiscal.org/2012docs/120315-TIF-polk.pdf.
Fox, William F. 1981. Reviewing economies of size in education. Journal of Education Finance
6(3): 273296.
28

Gill, Jeff, and Jason Gainous. 2002. Why does voting get so complicated? A review of theories
for analyzing democratic participation. Statistical Science 17(4): 383404.
Globerman, Steve, and Daniel Shapiro. 2008. The international mobility of highly educated
workers among OECD countries. Transnational Corporations 17(1): 235.
Hilber, Christian A. L., and Christopher J. Mayer. 2009. Why do households without children
support local public schools? Linking house price capitalization to school spending. Journal of
Urban Economics 65(1): 7490.
Lawrence, David B., and Susan C. Stephenson. 1995. The economics and politics of tax
increment financing. Growth and Change 26(1): 105137.
Lehnen, Robert G., and Carlyn E. Johnson. 2001. The impact of tax increment financing on
school districts: An Indiana case study. In Tax increment financing and economic development:
Uses, structures and impact, edited by Craig Johnson and Joyce Man, pp. 137154. Albany, NY:
State University of New York Press.
Man, Joyce Y. 1999. Fiscal pressure, tax competition and the adoption of tax increment
financing. Urban Studies 36(7): 11511167.
Man, Joyce Y., and Mark S. Rosentraub. 1998. Tax increment financing: Municipal adoption and
effects on property value growth. Public Finance Review 26(6): 523547.
Merriman, David F., Mark L. Skidmore, and Russ D. Kashian. 2011. Do tax increment finance
districts stimulate growth in real estate values? Real Estate Economics 39(2): 221250.
Mikesell, John. 2014. Fiscal Administration. 9th edition. Boston, MA: Wadsworth Publishing.
Nguyen, Mai Thi. 2005. Does affordable housing detrimentally affect property values? A review
of the literature. Journal of Planning Literature 20(1): 1526.
29

Nguyen-Hoang, Phuong. 2012. Cost function and its use for intergovernmental educational
transfers in Vietnam. Education Economics 20(1): 6991.
Nguyen-Hoang, Phuong. 2013. Tax limit repeal and school spending. National Tax Journal
66(1): 117148.
Nguyen-Hoang, Phuong, and John Yinger. 2011. The capitalization of school quality into house
values: A review. Journal of Housing Economics 20(1): 3048.
Nydle, Christopher M. 2009. Iowas agribusiness in a TIF. Drake Journal of Agricultural Law
14(3): 485450.
Pacewicz, Josh. 2013. Tax increment financing, economic development professionals and the
financialization of urban politics. Socio-Economic Review 11(3): 413440.
Perri, Brad. 2001. Financing the future: Interpreting the economic development area provision
of the Iowa TIF statute. Drake Law Review 50(1): 159179.
Robinson, Jeff. 2011. Tax increment financing. Presentation given to Iowa Senate Ways and
Means Committee, Des Moines.
Ross, Justin, and Phuong Nguyen-Hoang. 2013. School district income taxes: New revenue or a
property tax substitute? Public Budgeting and Finance 32(2): 1940.
Smith, Brent C. 2006. The impact of tax increment finance districts on localized real estate:
Evidence from Chicagos multifamily markets. Journal of Housing Economics 15(1): 2137.
Smith, Lauren Ashley. 2009. Alternatives to property tax increment finance programs: Sales,
income, and nonproperty tax increment financing. Urban Lawyer 41(4): 705724.
Swenson, David, and Liesl Eathington. 2002. Do tax increment finance districts in Iowa spur
growth or squander public resources? Unpublished paper, Iowa State University.
30

Swenson, David, and Liesl Eathington. 2006. Tax increment financing growth in Iowa.
Unpublished paper, Iowa State University.
Talanker, Alyssa, and Kate Davis. 2003. Straying from good intentions: How states are
weakening enterprise zone and tax increment financing programs. Washington, DC: Good Jobs
First.
Weber, Rachel. 2003. Equity and entrepreneurialism: The impact of tax increment financing on
school finance. Urban Affairs Review 38(5): 619644.
Weber, Rachel, Saurav Dev Bhatta, and David Merriman. 2003. Does tax increment financing
raise urban industrial property values? Urban Studies 40(10): 20012021.
Weber, Rachel, Saurav Dev Bhatta, and David Merriman. 2007. Spillovers from tax increment
financing districts: Implications for housing price appreciation. Regional Science and Urban
Economics 37(2): 259281.
Weber, Rachel, Rebecca Hendrick, and Jeremy Thompson. 2008. The effect of tax increment
financing on school district revenues: Regional variation and interjurisdictional competition.
State and Local Government Review 40(1): 2741.
31


Table 1 Numbers of School Districts Comprising TIF Districts
Year
2001
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
(1)
48 59 66 71 73 76 87 94 99 103 111
(2)
10 14 21 20 22 25 27 31 33 34 38
(3)
3 4 5 5 9 9 10 12 14 17 19
(4)
0 1 1 1 3 5 4 6 5 5 7


(5)
52 46 30 18 33 19 25 18 13 8 8
(6)
6 11 5 1 0 2 1 0 1 0 1
(7)
4 1 2 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0


(8)
87 97 86 88 70 62 74 77 79 60 76
(9)
20 28 26 22 15 17 21 23 20 11 22
(10)
11 12 14 7 7 5 6 5 5 4 6
(1), (2), (3), and (4) are the numbers of school districts that had 10, 20, 30, and 40 TIF districts,
respectively.
(5), (6), and (7) are the numbers of school districts that had 1, 3, and 5 expired TIF districts, respectively.
(8), (9), and (10) are the numbers of school districts that had 1, 3, and 5 new TIF districts, respectively.
Source: Authors calculations are based on data from the Iowa Department of Management.


32

Table 2 Summary Statistics for the Full Sample (20012011)
Variable Mean
Standard
Deviation
Min. Max. Source
Total operating expenditures per pupil 10,283 2,962 7,042 54,447 (1)
Tax price (T
P
) 0.42 0.21 0.03 1.30
(1), (2),
(4)
Total incremental property value per pupil (

) 10,750 17,266 0 218,647 (2)


Incremental per pupil value of residential property 3,674 7,766 0 149,040 (2)
Incremental per pupil value of commercial property 4,792 10,604 0 155,713 (2)
Incremental per pupil value of industrial property 1,908 4,567 0 49,636 (2)
Ratio of incremental taxable property value to total
taxable value in year
t1

0.0005 0.0044 0 0.0932 (2)
Enrollment 1,344 2,520 21 31,369 (1)
Percent of free and reduced-price lunch students 31.03 12.39 3.26 90.91 (1)
Percent of LEP students 1.72 4.83 0 58.66 (1)
Percent of African American students 1.44 2.68 0 30.22 (1)
Total state aid per pupil 4,341 1,023 93 16,548 (1)
Total federal aid per pupil 722 603 119 9,783 (3)
Median household income 52,523 10,162 30,314 103,353 (4)
Percent of college graduates 19.43 8.33 5.43 63.33 (4)
Percent of owner-occupied housing units 84.63 5.79 50.51 97.05 (4)
Notes: There are 3,817 observations (347 districts for eleven years from 2001 to 2011). Monetary measures are
adjusted for inflation (using government price indexes published by the Bureau of Economic Analysis) and in
2010 dollars. Sources are (1) Iowa Department of Education; (2) Iowa Department of Management; (3) Public
Elementary-Secondary Education Finance Data (www.census.gov/govs/school/); and (4) U.S. Census in 2000
and 2010 (the annual values for inter-census years and 2011 were interpolated and extrapolated by using the
linear growth rate between 2000 and 2010).



33


Table 3 General Effects of TIF on Education Expenditures
(dependent variable: logged total operating expenditures per pupil)
Variables Coefficients
Log of tax price (

) 0.12
(5.67)***
Log of incremental taxable property value
per pupil (

)
0.0018
(2.86)***
Number of new TIF districts within
school districts (

)
0.00033
(0.54)
Log of enrollment 1.01
(10.49)***
Squared log of enrollment 0.050
(7.40)***
Logged percent of free and reduced-price
lunch students
0.018
(2.12)**
Logged percent of LEP students

0.00036
(0.23)
Logged percent of African American
students
0.0017
(0.91)
Log of median household income

0.061
(1.74)*
Log of state aid per pupil 0.14
(4.28)***
Log of federal aid per pupil 0.015
(3.14)***
Log of income surtaxes per pupil 0.0028
(2.78)***
Percent of college graduates 0.0016
(1.74)*
Percent of owner-housing units 0.00077
(1.66)*
R
2
0.621
Notes: There are 3,817 observations between 2001 and 2011.
Regressions are estimated with district fixed effects and year
dummies. Hypothesis testing is done with the robust
heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation (HAC) Newey-West standard
errors. Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
34



Table 4 Effects of Different Property TIF Types
Key Variables Coefficients
Log of tax price (T
P
) 0.12
(5.66)***
Log of incremental per pupil taxable property value of residential property 0.0012
(1.85)*
Log of incremental per pupil taxable property value of commercial property 0.00036
(0.60)
Log of incremental per pupil taxable property value of industrial property 0.0012
(2.07)**
Number of new TIF districts within school districts (

) 0.00034
(0.55)
Notes: All of the unreported variables and the other notes are the same as in Table 3.
* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
35


Table 5 TIF Effects of Expired TIF Districts and for Low-Income School Districts
Key Variables
Key Distinguishing Specification
Expired TIF
ratio (

and # of
expired TIF
districts (

)
School district
types based on
median housing
value
School district
types based on
median household
income
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Log of tax price (

) 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12


(5.67)*** (6.20)*** (5.68)*** (5.73)***
Log of total incremental taxable
property value per pupil (

)
0.0018 0.0018 0.0034 0.0038
(2.86)*** (3.21)*** (3.46)*** (3.79)***
Number of new TIF districts
within a school district (

)
0.00034 0.00034 0.00035 0.00041
(0.54) (0.54) (0.55) (0.64)
Ratio of incremental taxable
property value to total taxable
value in year
t1
(

)
0.020 0.019 0.023 0.022
(0.11) (0.09) (0.11) (0.10)
Number of expired TIF districts
within a school district (

)
0.000022 0.000038 0.000058
(0.01) (0.02) (0.03)
Logged

W 0.0019 0.0021
(2.49)** (2.81)***
Notes: All of the unreported variables and the other notes are the same as in Table 3. W in column 3 is
coded 0, 1, and 2 for school districts whose median housing values in Census 2010 were below the 33rd
percentile, between the 33rd and 67th percentiles, and above the 67th percentile, respectively. W follows
the same coding procedure, except that the Census 2010 median household income is used.
* p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Вам также может понравиться