Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 26

Economics 121

Zvika Neeman
Spring 2015
Yale University

Monday, March 23: Competitive Markets

How does this lecture fit?


This lecture begins the third part of our semester, the study of competitive markets. Studying competitive markets is important both because
some markets in our economy are reasonably modeled as competitive, and
because this is a useful point of comparison for other markets.
This lectures explores a partial equilibrium view of competitive markets,
meaning that we examine the supply (or firm) side of the market while
holding fixed the demand (or consumer) side. Our next topic, a general
equilibrium view of these markets, will integrate the two.

Outline
I. INDIVIDUAL CHOICE
I.1 The Basic Model of Consumer Choice
I.1.1 Modeling Choice: Preferences and Constraints
I.1.2 The Mathematics of Optimization
I.1.3 Demand Functions
I.1.4 Elasticity
I.1.5 Maximizing Utility
I.2 Applications
I.2.1 Labor Supply
I.2.2 Time
I.2.3 Consumer Surplus
I.2.4 Uncertainty

I.2.5 Uncertainty: Risk Pooling and Insurance


I.2.6 Uncertainty and Valuing Life
I.3 Utility: Does It Make Sense?
II. FIRMS
II.1 Profit Maximization
III. COMPETITIVE MARKETS
III.1 A Partial Equilibrium Model of Competitive Markets
IV MARKET FAILURE

(Competitive) Markets
The market is not an invention of capitalism. It has existed for centuries.
It is an invention of civilization. (Mikhail Gorbachev, June 8, 1990)
The moment that government appears at market, the principles of the
market will be subverted. (Edmund Burke, 17291797)
We Are The 99% that will no longer tolerate the greed and corruption of
the 1%. (occupywallst.org)

Intuitively, a competitive market has:


1. Many firms
2. Homogeneous outputs,
3. Perfect information
4. No transactions costs.
Formally, in a competitive market, R(q ) = pq .

A Partial Equilibrium Model of Competitive Markets


First, the demand side. To look at markets, we need to aggregate individual
behavior. Suppose there are m consumers in the market, indexed by k =
1, . . . , m. Then the market demand is the sum of the k individual demands.
In particular, Market demand for good xi equals

Pm
k=1 xi (p1 , p2 , . . . , pn , I (k ), k ).

We will typically be interested in the case of two goods, so that the market
Pm
demand for good x1 equals k=1 x1(p1, p2, I (k), k).
We will typically write this market demand as x1(p1, p2). Notice that there
is no income variable here, which is the sign that this is a market demand
and not an individual demand.

We would like to have a criterion for measuring the performance of a


market.
The consumer surplus is given by:

Z p00
p0

x1(p1, p2)dp1

This differs from our pervious measure of consumer surplus by using market
rather than individual demand. It is the sum of the individual consumer
surpluses.

What determines the outcome in a competitive market? This depends on


the time horizon.
In the market period or very short run the quantity supplied is fixed.
In the short run, some inputs are fixed and some variable. Firms are unable
to either enter or exit the market.
In the long run, all inputs are variable. Firms can enter and exit.
Notice that these are measured in terms of economic time, not calendar
time.

In the short run, the firms supply curve is given by the appropriate part
of its marginal cost curve. Market supply is the sum of the firms supply
curves. The firms profit maximization problem is

max pq C (q ),
q

with first-order condition

dC (q )
p
= 0.
dq

C( )
C(q)

C( )
C(q)

q(p)

Second order condition:

d2C (q )
>0
2
dq

Interiority condition:

pq (p) C (q (p)) C (0).

In the long run, all inputs are variable. In particular, firms can enter and
exit the market.
The relevant cost curves are now long-run cost curves.
The short-run and long-run cost curves emerge from similar-looking maximization problems, with the difference being the variables over which the
maximization is performed.

Short run:

C (q ) = min p1x1 + p2x2


x1
s.t. f (x1, x2) = q.

Long run:

C (q ) = min p1x1 + p2x2


x1 ,x2
s.t. f (x1, x2) = q.

Once we have the cost function, the long-run profit maximization problem
looks familiar:

max pq C (q )
q

dC (q )
= 0.
dq

The difference is in the shape of the cost function:

C( )
C(q)

C( )
C(q)

]
p

q(p)

Second order condition:

d2C (q )
>0
2
dq

The interiority condition is now:

pq (p) C (q (p)) 0.

The short-run and long-run also differ in terms of entry and exit decisions.
In the short-run, there is no entry and exit, and profits may be positive or
negative.
In long-run equilibrium, firms in a competitive market earn zero profits.
This initially sounds absurd. Why would firms earn negative profits, and
who would enter a market, only to earn zero profits?
The answer requires distinguishing normal from excess (or economic) profit.
Firms in a competitive industry earn zero excess profit.

What is the equilibrium long-run firm size, price, and number of firms?
This depends on the shape of the cost functions and whether there are
indivisibilities in inputs.
Do firms enter and leave markets? Some data:

We must now distinguish constant (or increasing, or decreasing) costs for


a firm and for an industry.
Costs that are decreasing everywhere are inconsistent with perfect competition. The result is often a natural monopoly.

R(q)
C(q)

(Eventually) increasing costs are consistent with perfect competition.


Constant costs are a knife-edge case.

Competitive markets are often viewed as leading to desirable outcomes.


Producer surplus:

Z p00
p0

C 0(q (p))dp.

Competitive markets maximize the sum of consumer and producer surplus.

Things to read:
Nicholson and Snyder cover this topic in chapter 12. Pages 409-431 develop the theory, and the remainder of the chapter explores some applications. See Chapter 8 in Perloff and Chapters 22-23 in Varian.
The organization of markets is a topic with important political as well as
economic implications. A nicely accessible and often entertaining discussion of how markets work is given by John McMillan in Reinventing the
Bazaar (Norton, 2002).

Вам также может понравиться