Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 15

姝 Academy of Management Review

2005, Vol. 30, No. 2, 383–396.

GOVERNMENT CORRUPTION AND THE ENTRY


STRATEGIES OF MULTINATIONALS
PETER RODRIGUEZ
University of Virginia

KLAUS UHLENBRUCK
University of Montana

LORRAINE EDEN
Texas A&M University

Multinational enterprises (MNEs) often encounter government corruption when oper-


ating in host countries; however, in the international management literature, it is
typically assumed that government officials pursue national interests rather than
their own. We introduce a two-dimensional framework to further the understanding of
public sector corruption and identify its implications for MNEs. Using an institutional
perspective, we examine how the pervasiveness and arbitrariness of corruption can
affect an MNE’s organizational legitimacy and strategic decision making. We apply
our analysis to the mode of entry decision.

Through laws, regulations, and institutions, Corruption is everywhere, to be sure, but it is


governments influence and sometimes domi- not the same everywhere. Indeed, corruption
nate transactions within an economy. Govern- varies across countries as much as labor costs
ments, to a large degree, “set the rules of the or corporate tax rates (Smarzynska & Wei, 2000).
game” that make up the fundamental reward The challenges firms face on entering foreign
structure of an economy and thereby determine countries largely reflect their efforts to under-
the nature of commercial activity within it. But stand and adapt to local corruption. Assessing
government rules and institutions rarely are corruption by level alone, however, is inade-
crafted—and never operate—solely for the ben- quate and of limited use to firms. As recent stud-
efit of the general public. Rather, all govern- ies show (Shleifer & Vishny, 1993; Wei, 1997), the
ments are beset in their pursuit of legitimate experience of operating in a corrupt environ-
objectives by the presence of corruption. Corrup- ment is substantially characterized not only by
tion—the abuse of public power for private benefit— the amount of corruption but also by the uncer-
warps the rules of the game. Often, corruption tainty associated with corrupt transactions.
rewards unproductive behavior by channeling To adapt and perform effectively within a new
unmerited contracts and rights to firms in ex- environment, firms must comprehend and appre-
change for bribes, thereby penalizing efficient ciate corruption’s essential characteristics. Espe-
and innovative firms. Indeed, corruption is at cially for multinational enterprises (MNEs), under-
least as harmful to firm growth and economic
standing the nature of corruption in a given
development as bad monetary policy or fiscal
country and differentiating it from corruption in
insolvency (Tanzi, 1998). Nevertheless, coping
other countries are central to decisions on entry
with corruption is an intrinsic activity in inter-
and expansion. Moreover, the study of corruption
national business that sometimes offers appre-
itself, apart but not isolated from other institu-
ciable advantages to individual firms (Bod-
tions, has the potential to substantially expand
dewyn, 1988; Boddewyn & Brewer, 1994; Ring,
our understanding of how governments differ
Lenway, & Govekar, 1990).
and how they matter in the decisions of firms. In
the management literature and international
We thank guest editor Peter Smith Ring, Bert Cannella,
business literature, researchers generally assume
and three anonymous reviewers for invaluable advice. Any that government—and its agents—maximize the
errors are ours alone. public interest (e.g., Dunning, 1993; Lenway &
383
384 Academy of Management Review April

Murtha, 1994; Zahra, Ireland, Gutierrez, & Hitt, tries. After this, we use this framework to gener-
2000), and, thus, they fail to consider the effects ate propositions regarding mode of entry choice
of corruption on firms. Others view corruption as as an adaptive response to corrupt govern-
an opportunity for political behavior by MNEs ments. In the final section we discuss our con-
(Boddewyn, 1988; Boddewyn & Brewer, 1994). clusions and suggest topics for future research.
Despite its potential for illuminating the var-
ious challenges and opportunities posed by cor-
A TWO-DIMENSIONAL FRAMEWORK OF
ruption, a meaningful framework characterizing
CORRUPTION: PERVASIVENESS AND
the nature of corruption has yet to be developed
ARBITRARINESS
in the management literature. Other disciplines
have begun to contribute to this effort (Bardhan, The effort to represent the complex character-
1997; Johnston, 1997; Shleifer & Vishny 1993), but istics of an environment within a simple theo-
no study has put forth a serviceable model. Our retical framework is valid only as long as the
purpose in this article is therefore twofold: (1) to simplification facilitates meaningful analysis
offer a parsimonious framework that allows for while still capturing essential features of the
effective differentiation of corrupt environments environment. Our aim in this section is to
and (2) to further the understanding of corrup- achieve such a successful reduction by develop-
tion and how it affects multinational entry. ing a simple framework that allows for effective
Entry strategy is a critical element in interna- differentiation of corrupt environments and their
tional expansion. The mode of entry substan- consequent influences on firm behavior.
tially determines a firm’s resource commitment, The wide variety of corrupt behaviors confounds
investment risk, degree of control, and share of the attempt to characterize corruption in a way
profits from international operations (Davis, De- that distinguishes one environment from the next.
sai, & Francis, 2000; Schrader, 2001). Drawing on For the most part, scholars have responded to this
institutional theory, we discuss the implications challenge either by categorizing corrupt transac-
of government corruption for the MNE’s organi- tions by the parties and stakes involved (Elliott,
zational legitimacy (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999), 1997; Maitland, 2002; Rose-Ackerman, 1999) or by
thereby developing a set of propositions ex- aggregating all categories of corrupt transactions
plaining how corruption, through its impact on into a single index (ICRG, 1999; Kaufmann, 1998;
organizational legitimacy, can alter the entry Transparency International, 2000; Treisman, 2000).
mode decisions of multinationals. Others have distinguished types of corrupt activ-
We use institutional theory because it pro- ities based on the characteristics of the partici-
vides a theoretical explanation for MNE re- pants in corrupt transactions or the objectives of
sponses to government actions (Westney, 1993). the parties involved (Hellman, Jones, Kaufmann, &
Institutional theory is particularly appropriate Schankerman, 2000; Schacter & Shah, 2001). Each
for our purposes because it emphasizes contex- of these strategies for measuring corruption is
tual factors influencing entry mode decisions valuable for some purposes, but none offers ready
(Yiu & Makino, 2001) and draws attention to non- interpretations of key differences in the experi-
market pressures (Davis et al., 2000; Haveman, ence of corruption across states.
1993; Oliver, 1991). The core insight of institu- One of the main challenges of describing cor-
tional theory is that organizations strive for ex- ruption is addressing both its transaction- and
ternal legitimacy by complying with their insti- state-specific characteristics. This problem
tutional context (Glynn & Abzug, 2002); arises because corruption refers both to a type of
organizational legitimacy is influenced by cor- transaction—that is, one that involves the abuse
ruption through its widespread effects on formal (or misuse) of public power for private gain—
and informal institutions. Moreover, institu- and to a prominent statewide relationship
tional theory addresses the importance of rela- among public officials, established institutions,
tionships between entry mode choice and MNE and private parties. It may be that corruption is
internal legitimacy of subsidiaries (Rosenzweig defined by characteristics of a particular trans-
& Singh, 1991), which may be threatened by com- action, but its nature is differentiated by sys-
pliance with corruption. temic qualities, which refer to the set of corrupt
In the following section we develop a frame- transactions in a given country. Thus, when
work for differentiating corruption across coun- scholars say that corruption in Ukraine is differ-
2005 Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, and Eden 385

ent from corruption in Egypt, they typically are outright purchase of facilitating services and
referring to an identical class of transactions beneficial regulatory decisions (Boddewyn &
but intend to accentuate the particular charac- Brewer, 1994). Moreover, firms may select perva-
teristics of the overall experience with corrup- sively corrupt institutional environments in
tion in the two countries. their search for a venue where activities that are
We direct our analysis of corruption toward deemed illegitimate in some countries are
these aggregate characteristics that apply to the deemed appropriate or are simply overlooked in
set of all corrupt transactions with governments others (Suchman, 1995). Firms might also
in a given country. In doing so, we address a achieve legitimacy by complying with corrup-
second challenge as well: separating the effort tion where it is broadly diffused (cf. Oliver, 1991).
to describe corruption from the effort to explain Finally, we would expect pervasiveness to go
its origins and possible remedies. Corruption in hand in hand with important economy-wide ef-
any nation state owes its nature and trajectory fects of corruption. The quality of infrastructure
to a variety of economic, historical, and institu- services, public institutions, economic growth,
tional antecedents. Efforts to explain the histo- and financial stability is likely to be lower
ries of states and their characteristics are vital, where firms are heavily involved in corrupt
but beyond the scope of this paper, in which we transactions, regardless of an individual firm’s
are concerned with the experience of corruption ability to extract benefits in such an environ-
and its relationship to firm behavior. ment (Keefer, 1996; Rose-Ackerman, 1978, 1999).
Our review of the substantial literature on The pervasiveness of corruption varies widely
corruption reveals two key dimensions that to- across countries and is somewhat related to the
gether differentiate corruption across countries: popularized concept of the level of corruption
pervasiveness and arbitrariness.1 Pervasiveness (Transparency International, 2001; World Bank,
is the average firm’s likelihood of encountering 2000).2 But corruption varies by more than just
corruption in its normal interactions with state the degree to which it engages firms. Numerous
officials. Pervasiveness, which is independent empirical studies have highlighted varying de-
of the nature of corrupt transactions themselves, grees of uncertainty associated with corruption.
reflects an expectation of the proportion of inter- We label this characteristic arbitrariness and
actions with the state that will entail corrupt define it as the inherent degree of ambiguity
transactions. More than this, “pervasiveness” associated with corrupt transactions in a given
captures the degree to which a firm is obliged to nation or state. Where corruption is arbitrary,
address corrupt behavior. Our notion of perva- laws and informal policies may be subject to
siveness, as it relates to the expected level of capricious and varied interpretation (Ahlstrom
involvement of firms with corrupt officials, could & Bruton, 2001), or overlapping and tenuous ju-
result from brief or protracted corrupt transac- risdictions may lead to ineffectual bribes (Old-
tions, but in either case signals the degree to enburg, 1987). Arbitrariness may also result from
which corruption is a regular and meaningful part the ability and willingness of corrupt officials to
of commercial activity in a given country. In this vary the set of necessary approvals to extract
sense, pervasiveness correlates with the necessity maximal bribes (Banerjee, 1997; Levy, 1989) or
of actively addressing the opportunities or threats from the entry of bureaucrats into the market for
posed by corruption, which may be substantial. extortion (Shleifer & Vishny, 1993).3 Indeed,
Owing to its firm-level construction, perva- many circumstances and characteristics of
siveness is meant to be a value-neutral charac-
terization. Heavy involvement with corrupt offi- 2
However, as mentioned earlier, the “level” of corruption
cials has been associated directly and indirectly as reported by Transparency International and others is an
with numerous social and commercial maladies aggregation of all categories of corrupt acts and is not di-
but may just as readily offer some firms oppor- rected at an individual’s or a firm’s experience in corrupt
tunities to internalize environmental threats transactions.
3
through absorption (Ring et al., 1990) or by the This analysis is inspired by Shleifer and Vishny (1993),
who describe the “industrial structure” of corruption. A par-
adoxical message of their analysis is that “organized” cor-
ruption regimes may be more extractive yet less harmful to
1
For extensive reviews of research on corruption, see firm performance than disorganized and less extractive re-
Bardhan (1997), Tanzi (1998), and Treisman (2000). gimes.
386 Academy of Management Review April

states may promote arbitrariness. Rather than At the opposite extreme is hierarchical and
theorize on particular causes, we emphasize stable corruption characterized by predictable
that arbitrariness renders important features of and effective bribery. For example, under Mar-
corrupt transactions less transparent and, more cos’s heavy hand, all graft in the Philippines
important, less predictable, since they do not was controlled from the top down. Bureaucrats
emerge from a stable underlying structure or at all levels who supplied complementary ap-
process. provals were part of a somewhat unified and
“Arbitrariness,” as we use it, proceeds from controlled system (Alfiler & Concepcion, 1986).
normal statistical uncertainty, which is charac- Consequently, corrupt payments were regular,
terized by quantifiable risk over knowable out- predictable, and typically effective (Easterly,
comes, toward “Knightian” or immeasurable un- 2000; Shleifer & Vishny, 1993) The authoritarian
certainty, where the underlying probability regimes of Suharto in Indonesia (Easterly, 2000)
distribution over events is unknown (Fox & Tver- and Mexico under the PRI (Cothran, 1994; Morris,
sky, 1995; Knight, 1921). Where corruption is 1991) were also known for systemic and predict-
highly arbitrary, transactions with government able corruption.
officials are characterized by an enduring un- The two dimensions of corruption—pervasive-
certainty regarding the size, target, and number ness and arbitrariness—are independent, cap-
of corrupt payments necessary to obtain an ap- turing wholly different aspects of corruption, but
proval. Consequently, a low degree of efficacy is neither is sufficient to fully characterize the lo-
attached to engagement with corrupt officials, cal environment; they are simultaneously expe-
despite the fact that such involvement may be rienced and must be considered together. An
quite regular. In the limit, arbitrariness renders illustrative exercise is to consider moving along
the corrupt environment largely unknowable, various trajectories from any given point in a
since rules of behavior, expectations over out- hypothetical two-dimensional space, shown in
comes, and the power and purview of enforcers Figure 1. Consider first moving along arrow A
are inherently unstable. Firms are unlikely to from the midpoint of the pervasiveness axis to
achieve legitimacy by engaging government of- the right, increasing arbitrariness while holding
ficials in an arbitrarily corrupt environment (Ol- pervasiveness constant. Firms expect to con-
iver, 1991). front corrupt state officials equally often along
The best example of highly arbitrary corrup- this trajectory, all the while experiencing in-
tion is that of Russia throughout the 1990s. Fol- creased levels of ambiguity regarding the size,
lowing the demise of the formidable and intru- nature, and efficacy attached to these encoun-
sive Soviet state, Russian reformers seeking real ters. As the processes that generate corruption
change followed the mantra of “freedom first, become less learnable, firms find it more diffi-
rules later.” Into the institutional void rushed cult to make use of any benefits they may derive
formerly powerful party officials with dubious from engaging corrupt officials. The ability to
and overlapping claims to authority, newly plan for corruption fades along this path, as
elected but corrupt politicians, and organized does the value of engaging in local corruption
rackets offering protection from venal bureaucrats so as to acquire and maintain legitimacy.
(Hoffman, 2002; Peng, 2001). The result was wide- Consider next moving upward along arrow B
spread corruption, of course, but one truly char- from the midpoint of the arbitrariness axis, in-
acterized by “arbitrary power, individual whims creasing pervasiveness while holding arbitrari-
and private score settling” (Hoffman, 2002: 234). ness constant. The terms and outcomes of cor-
Arbitrary corruption also occurs in more sta- rupt transactions remain only somewhat
ble and democratic states. The process of land predictable along this course, but they arise
consolidation in the north Indian state of Uttar more and more regularly and are attached to an
Pradesh was fraught with bribery but accompa- ever-higher proportion of interactions with gov-
nied by a complex and near endless appeals ernments. Firms find it increasingly necessary
process that took force once initial decisions to address corruption. Opportunities to utilize
were made (Oldenburg, 1987). As a result, bribes corruption for any purpose grow, as do the costs
of multiple sizes dotted the long event and only associated with opting out and avoidance.
rarely were effective at inducing the desired Finally, consider any northeastward move-
treatment. ment. By construction, the principal effect of
2005 Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, and Eden 387

FIGURE 1
Two Dimensions of Corruption: Pervasiveness and Arbitrarinessa

a
Countries and their locations in Figure 1 are included for illustrative purposes only.

such a path is a straightforward combination of (Mauro, 1995) and openness to international


the two previous effects. Advancing along both trade (Ades & DiTella, 1999). Together, these ef-
dimensions, however, raises the challenge to fects suggest that corruption also deters entry
firms more acutely than moving along a single via exporting, although no study has yet directly
dimension. Moving to an environment where examined the effect of corruption on entry via
corruption is both more pervasive and more ar- arm’s-length strategies. Clearly, corruption re-
bitrary raises the demands of adapting to the duces aggregate entry, but many firms choose to
local environment and simultaneously makes enter a locale despite the challenges corruption
those demands more difficult to address. Taken presents.4
together, pervasiveness and arbitrariness cap- While both firm- and investment-specific
ture fundamental features of the experience of characteristics matter greatly in determining
corruption in a given state. In the following sec- whether entry into a given country by any mode
tion we discuss the relationship of this frame- will be profitable, our focus is on the marginal
work of corruption to the entry mode decisions of influence of corruption on the entry decision. Put
MNEs. another way, we focus on how the nature of
corruption influences the choice of entry mode
as an adaptive behavior of firms. Using the
ENTRY INTO CORRUPT COUNTRIES
framework discussed above, we propose how
Corruption significantly reduces direct invest-
ment flows into an economy, as a growing body 4
Moreover, MNEs cannot reasonably avoid public sector
of research shows (Lambsdorff, 1999; Mauro, corruption altogether, since it is present to some degree in
1995, 1998; Wei, 1997). Also, corruption is nega- all countries (Transparency International, 2001) and is sub-
tively associated with economy-wide growth stantial in many of the largest world markets.
388 Academy of Management Review April

MNEs might choose a mode of entry so as to over, there remains a lack of consensus concern-
mitigate the consequences of corruption for the ing the antecedents of entry mode choice (Lu,
firm, to insulate itself from government interven- 2002). Extant research, strongly influenced by
tion (Jacobson, Lenway, & Ring, 1993), or to avail transaction cost economics, has focused on min-
itself of opportunities created by corruption imizing the costs of entry and operations. How-
through political behavior (Boddewyn, 1988). ever, this literature overlooks political behavior
The mode of entry decision is critical to MNE by MNEs, which can be both a defense against
performance and survival and has been care- threats from the state and a means to create
fully studied in the international business liter- economic opportunities for the firm (Boddewyn,
ature (for recent reviews, see Buckley & Casson, 1988; Ring et al., 1990). The entry literature is
1998; Chang & Rosenzweig, 2001; Davis et al., also silent on nonmarket transactions, which
2000; Root, 1994). The two main categories of may be critical to survival and performance
entry are (1) nonequity modes, such as exporting (Blumentritt & Nigh, 2002; Boddewyn & Brewer,
or licensing, where a local agent distributes 1994). Yet nowhere can the actions of govern-
and/or produces the firm’s goods and services in ment and political actors be considered truly
a host country, and (2) foreign direct investment exogenous to MNE strategies; political and non-
(FDI)—that is, equity modes. When an equity market transactions are often essential, espe-
mode is chosen, an entering firm may invest via cially where corruption is significant. We apply
a wholly owned subsidiary or via a joint venture institutional theory to the analysis of entry mode
with another firm, typically a local partner, choices of MNEs in corrupt environments to ex-
whose knowledge and/or network ties can help amine these less appreciated aspects of entry.
overcome less formal barriers to entry. Traditionally, institutional theorists have
Host country conditions, such as investment studied the effects of government agencies, in-
risk, industry structure, and culture, are among terest groups, regulatory structures, laws, social
the most salient determinants of entry mode norms, and values on the structures and pro-
choice (Anderson & Gatignon, 1986; Kogut & cesses of domestic firms (DiMaggio & Powell,
Singh, 1988). Similarly, conditions of the enter- 1983; Scott, 1995; Zucker, 1983). These theorists
ing MNE—its home country environment, re- have predicted that firms will conform to their
sources, international experience, strategic dis- institutional context so as to achieve (external)
position, and competitive advantage—affect the legitimacy, which, in turn, renders their exis-
choice of entry mode (Buckley & Casson, 1976, tence and actions desirable and appropriate in
1998; Hill, Hwang, Kim, 1990). According to the the view of customers, suppliers, and the gov-
entry literature, firms choose FDI over arm’s- ernment (Dacin, 1997; Suchman, 1995). Without
length entry modes when they are willing to legitimacy, firms may not have access to valu-
accept the financial risk associated with the able resources that are vital to survival and
control necessary to minimize the costs of trans- profitability. Thus, firms’ economic choices are
ferring firm-specific advantages via the in- constrained by socially constructed norms of ac-
trafirm hierarchy. Evaluating control needs and ceptable or appropriate behavior (Oliver, 1997).
financial risk also affects the decision to partner Nevertheless, institutional theorists recognize a
or not when entering via FDI. In exchange for significant role for firm choice in the adaptation
partial control and a stake in the profits, a part- to the institutional context (Kostova & Roth, 2002;
ner reduces the level of resources committed Oliver, 1991) and the dependence of competitive
and, especially when the partner is local, can be advantage on a firm’s ability to manage the
helpful in reducing the burden of adjusting to a institutional context (Oliver, 1997).
new environment. The challenges of attaining legitimacy and
Within the substantial literature on entry adapting to multiple institutional contexts are
mode choice, researchers have focused little on especially high for MNEs. A host government’s
the influence of host country corruption.5 More- ignorance about foreign MNEs may lead to the

subsidiaries in Eastern European and formerly Soviet econ-


5
A noteworthy exception is the study by Smarzynska and omies. This study does not distinguish characteristics of
Wei (2000), in which the authors found that corruption in- corruption (e.g., level versus uncertainty) and addresses
creases the likelihood of joint ventures over wholly owned only FDI forms of entry.
2005 Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, and Eden 389

use of stereotypes, the application of prejudicial ance with local corruption (Oliver, 1991). In such
standards, and the promotion of aggression an environment, an entering MNE will need to
from local interest groups, thereby increasing find alternative sources of external legitimacy.
the liability of foreignness (Hymer, 1976). MNEs Furthermore, arbitrary corruption increases
may avert these costs through isomorphism with the benefits of external legitimacy. Government
the host country environment, which should en- officials face less risk when abusing nonlegiti-
hance external legitimacy, resource availabil- mate firms and, thus, are more likely to support
ity, and survival capabilities (Zaheer & Mosa- and/or engage in corrupt behavior toward them.
kowski, 1997).6 External legitimacy is also more A firm with a high degree of legitimacy can
likely to be enhanced when the MNE develops evoke the support of other institutions to protect
partnerships with local organizations and per- itself from corruption in general (cf. Powell, 1988;
sonal relationships with host government agen- Suchman, 1995) or to create a defense against
cies and their officials (Boddewyn & Brewer, corrupt officials (Ahlstrom & Bruton, 2001). This
1994). protection is most valuable when corruption is
highly arbitrary, because firms will be uncertain
as to whether and how their freedom to operate
AN INSTITUTIONAL PERSPECTIVE ON
will be reduced by corrupt activities. The higher
CORRUPTION AND MNE ENTRY STRATEGY
the external legitimacy of a firm, the lower the
To study the effects of arbitrariness and per- probability that corruption will limit its activi-
vasiveness of corruption on equity entry, we as- ties.
sess the partnering choice in light of the nature Arbitrary corruption likely encourages the de-
of host government corruption, assuming that an velopment of social networks, which can be im-
MNE has decided to enter the host country. We portant sources of external legitimacy. When
also address how internal institutional pres- dealing with uncertain and nontransparent
sures resulting from corruption may lead the rules, firms develop “coping mechanisms” (Ra-
firm to prefer arm’s-length entry to FDI. Because daev, 2000). In states where the government can-
firms will simultaneously encounter degrees of not enforce property rights and contracts, firms
both dimensions of corruption, we end this sec- must build their own relational trust in order to
tion with a discussion of entry choice as it re- engage in transactions with other firms (Rose-
lates to combinations of arbitrariness and per- Ackerman, 2001). When people do not believe
vasiveness. that the state will protect their property rights,
Arbitrariness of corruption increases the in- interpersonal trust will be “very important but
centives for an MNE entering via direct invest- very scarce” (Rose-Ackerman, 2001: 49). Rela-
ment to partner with local firms. The core insight tional trust can be developed through repeated
of institutional theory is that organizations trades, reputation, and social networks. Once
strive for external legitimacy by complying with trust is developed in existing partners, firms are
the institutional context (Glynn & Abzug, 2002). reluctant to shift (Rose-Ackerman, 2001), creat-
Yet this process is obstructed by the complexity ing barriers to entry by new firms. A small group
of the institutional environment (Kostova & Za- of firms in a network, in effect, can act like a
heer, 1999). Where corruption is highly arbitrary, cartel. Firms cope by resorting to negotiations
firms cannot easily determine their critical con- with partners and to private persuasion. The
stituents. Moreover, a firm may face a multiplic- result is the development of business circles or
ity of corrupt agents, creating numerous and networks that exclude newcomer firms.
possibly conflicting pressures (Pfeffer & Salan- In order to enter these social networks and
cik, 1978; Scott, 1987). The resulting complexity of promote its legitimacy, an MNE will likely
the institutional environment reduces the firm’s choose a local partner when entering a country
ability to conform and thereby gain legitimacy with highly arbitrary corruption. When faced
and other economic advantages through compli- with uncertainty, newcomers rely on estab-
lished firms as sources of information and legit-
imacy (Tolbert & Zucker, 1983). Research indi-
6
Parallel arguments for isomorphism are motivated from
cates that a joint venture provides significant
a financial development framework and discussed at length sources for legitimacy gains, as well as knowl-
in Rajan and Zingales (2003). edge of dealing with the local government and
390 Academy of Management Review April

other institutions (Makino & Delios, 1996; Shan & (Ring et al., 1990). The diversity of national en-
Hamilton, 1991). Foreign firms may be induced to vironments offers firms the opportunity to select
trade ownership for legitimacy in the local en- among corrupt environments for those that
vironment (Yiu & Makino, 2002). A further advan- match particular motives or the requirements of
tage of a local joint venture partner is the reduc- a given investment (Suchman, 1995). Some MNEs
tion in interaction with government agencies may enter a pervasively corrupt country to avoid
and the associated chance for meeting corrupt another environment where legitimacy must be
officials, because foreign firms are more often acquired through acts of adherence to more
subjected to regulatory constraints than local costly practices. Corruption can allow firms to
firms (Yiu & Makino, 2002). buy their way out of costly requirements in strin-
gent environments. Oliver (1991) points to chem-
Proposition 1: The higher the arbitrari-
ical plant migration to third world countries,
ness of corruption in a host country,
where, presumably, the demands of legitimacy
the higher the likelihood that an MNE
are less costly. When government decisions can
will choose to enter with a local part-
be readily influenced through bribery, officials
ner rather than via a wholly owned
may create market imperfections that benefit
subsidiary.
entering MNEs by changing regulatory stan-
Unlike arbitrariness, pervasiveness reduces dards or raising the institutional complexity for
the likelihood that a firm entering via FDI will competitors.
choose a local partner rather than a wholly Compliance with corruption, especially where
owned subsidiary, because the benefits to part- it is pervasive, assists in overcoming the liabil-
nering are reduced and compliance with pres- ity of foreignness, increases external legiti-
sures to engage in corruption is expected. Oliver macy, and thereby decreases the benefits of a
summarizes the motivation for compliance in local partner. Moreover, the costs of partnering,
the face of pervasive corruption: “When institu- such as sharing profits, are not reduced by per-
tional rules or norms are broadly diffused and vasiveness but are likely to rise if MNEs in-
supported, organizations will be predicted to ac- crease profits because of effective exploitation
quiesce to the pressures because their social of government corruption.
validity is largely unquestioned” (1991:169). Part-
Proposition 2: The higher the perva-
nering does not meaningfully reduce the likeli-
siveness of corruption in a host coun-
hood or costs of confronting corruption where
try, the higher the likelihood that an
firms regularly comply with corrupt agents.
MNE will enter via a wholly owned
Rather, because corruption is socially valid
subsidiary rather than with a local
where it is pervasive, compliance with the prac-
partner.
tices of a corrupt environment is likely to yield
external legitimacy. Firms may acquire legiti- Conformity to the external institutional con-
macy by acquiring government consent with text is not the only institutional concern in se-
their actions. The state can provide the firm with lecting the appropriate mode of entry. Adapta-
resources and procurement contracts that make tion of the subsidiary to host country conditions
it appear accepted and legitimate, which may may lead to the adoption of local norms and
improve the firm’s visibility in the eyes of local customs that are at odds with those of other MNE
customers and reduce the need for integration subunits, thereby threatening internal legiti-
into local networks. macy. Researchers recently have emphasized
Pervasiveness also tends to reduce institu- the importance of intrafirm institutional pres-
tional complexity as perceived by firms. If firms sures, which confer internal legitimacy on sub-
can acquire the goodwill of government agents, units when they conform to the norms and struc-
they may overcome typical challenges of entry tures of the rest of the organization. Conformity
and postentry operational and strategic prob- by subunits to the parent organization’s norms
lems (Boddewyn & Brewer, 1994), such as obtain- eases replication and integration and allows for
ing local licenses or necessary infrastructure. better control (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999; Rosen-
Likewise, the MNE can reduce the risk of gov- zweig & Singh, 1991).
ernment intervention if it can co-opt officials We propose that the impact of corruption on
through engagement in corrupt transactions the decision to enter via arm’s-length modes
2005 Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, and Eden 391

versus FDI is determined largely by the institu- The relationship between arbitrariness and
tional distance (i.e., differences among the reg- the decision to enter via arm’s-length modes is
ulatory, normative, and cognitive institutions) more complex and its ultimate impact less clear.
between the MNE’s home and host countries. It To begin with, arbitrariness of corruption has an
is easier for an MNE to deal with institutional indeterminate impact on the institutional dis-
pressures and to introduce subunits in host tance between a subsidiary and the parent MNE.
countries similar to its home nation. The greater Uncertainty encourages compliance with pres-
the institutional distance, the greater the threat sures from the institutional environment (Di-
to internal legitimacy of a new subsidiary as it Maggio & Powell, 1983; Thompson, 1967). Because
faces two sets of isomorphic pressures—the arbitrary corruption increases environmental
MNE’s and the host country’s (Davis et al., 2000; uncertainty, it provides incentives for a subsid-
Kostova & Roth, 2002). iary to conform to the local conditions. However,
Corruption affects institutional distance the arbitrariness also reduces the perceived eco-
most where it is highly pervasive. Under perva- nomic and legitimacy gains from engaging in
sive (i.e., broadly diffused) corruption, MNE sub- corruption, encouraging the firm to resist local
units can largely be expected to comply with corruption (Oliver, 1991). We argue that arbi-
corrupt government agents. Becoming isomor- trariness results in offsetting pressures to con-
phic with a pervasively corrupt environment form to the corrupt environment. Thus, arbitrari-
means complying with pressures to pay bribes, ness has no clear impact on the institutional
engage in corrupt activities, and so on, which distance between a subsidiary and its MNE. Fol-
may support the subsidiary’s external legiti- lowing institutional theory, we do not expect
macy, because it conforms to local business that the arbitrariness of corruption indepen-
norms and creates acceptance by government dently affects the decision to select an arm’s-
agencies. length entry mode versus FDI.7
However, in complying with their institutional We do expect the relationship between cor-
environment at home or in other countries, many ruption and entry to be moderated by the previ-
MNEs may have adopted norms and practices ous experiences of the MNE. Firms vary in their
that ban corrupt behaviors by their subunits. For ability to negotiate a given institutional context
instance, MNEs headquartered in the United and manage important external contingencies
States are subject to the Foreign Corrupt Prac- (Boddewyn, 1988; Oliver, 1997). Kostova and Za-
tices Act, which forbids firms listed on U.S. ex- heer (1999) suggest that MNEs with extensive
changes from engaging in corruption anywhere. organizational experience should be better able
Strong regulatory or normative institutional to cope with legitimacy issues than de novo
forces may exist that condemn engaging in cor- MNEs. Large MNEs with mature international
ruption within some MNEs. Yet the more the operations should have developed better organ-
subunit of such an MNE becomes embedded in
the norms, rules, and practices of corruption in a
host country, the greater the institutional dis- 7
Our argument is based solely on institutional theory.
tance it creates between itself and the rest of the From an economic perspective, however, arbitrariness of
corruption may lead to arm’s-length entry modes. Uncer-
MNE network (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999). In this
tainty may make FDI more delayable or less reversible
way, achieving external legitimacy in the host (Rivoli & Salorio, 1996). A delayable investment means that
country strains internal legitimacy within the the foregone profits from delay are not large. An irreversible
MNE network (Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1990). To avoid investment means that there are high barriers to exit. The
this internal tension and still access a perva- resulting uncertainty implies that the “wait and see” option
may be quite valuable. Where prospects for political and
sively corrupt foreign market, MNEs may decide
economic reform are unresolved, there are large downside
to enter via nonequity modes. risks and FDI will be less likely. At the same time, firms can
seek insurance for reasonably predictable but still irregular
Proposition 3: The higher the perva- events. In such cases, uncertainty is reduced to risk and the
siveness of corruption in a host coun- costs of corruption are akin to taxes on the MNE. It is the
irresolvable, unpredictable aspect of corruption that is most
try, the higher the likelihood that an
devastating for MNEs; it cannot be solved by waiting and
MNE from a home country with anti- cannot be covered by insurance. In such cases, we argue
corruption laws, norms, or values will that the arbitrariness of corruption makes arm’s-length
choose an arm’s-length mode of entry. modes of entry more likely.
392 Academy of Management Review April

izational capabilities for dealing with a diverse corruption in a host country and entry
set of host country environments. The more sim- via a wholly owned subsidiary is
ilar the institutional profiles of host countries, strengthened by an MNE’s previous
the easier it is for the MNE to understand and experience with pervasive corruption.
respond to their institutional pressures (Johan-
son & Vahlne, 1977). Essentially, learning how to Arbitrariness and pervasiveness jointly de-
achieve legitimacy in one environment can be scribe the nature of corruption in a given state;
internalized and utilized in another. In particu- MNEs encounter degrees of both dimensions
lar, firms may learn how to exploit corrupt gov- wherever they locate. In countries where the
ernments to raise legitimacy and reduce institu- experience of corruption is largely captured by
tional complexity. its pervasiveness, we expect that firms will tend
However, as we argued above, a simple per- to select wholly owned subsidiaries as the pre-
ception of the level of corruption is insufficient ferred mode of equity entry. Where arbitrariness
when comparisons are made across countries. is the dominant characteristic, joint ventures
Meaningful comparisons between countries re- will be the preferred choice. What then should
quire an MNE to accurately assess the nature of we expect regarding entry into countries where
local corruption. The type of corruption— public corruption is both highly pervasive and
whether it is pervasive or sporadic, confined to highly arbitrary? To address this question, we
bureaucrats or to politicians—will be important. must consider the interaction of these two di-
An MNE’s diversity of experiences in corrupt en- mensions of corruption.10
vironments is therefore likely to moderate the We suggest that as both dimensions of corrup-
relationship between the pervasiveness of cor- tion increase, arbitrariness will come to domi-
ruption and mode of entry. nate regarding entry mode choice. Although we
With regard to arbitrariness, however, we ar- expect that MNEs can fully internalize the ben-
gue that learning in one host environment is efits of pervasive corruption, higher degrees of
less transferable to others, especially when cor- arbitrariness reduce the likelihood that the MNE
ruption is highly arbitrary. The basis for this can achieve effective access to those benefits.
presumption is the observed behavioral differ- Highly pervasive corruption raises the likeli-
ence between actions taken under estimable hood that any government official the MNE en-
probabilities, which take on the character of de-
counters will be corrupt, but the outcome of en-
finable risks, and those taken under vague prob-
gaging that official in corruption grows more
abilities, in which decision makers are ignorant
and more uncertain as arbitrariness simulta-
of underlying statistical frequencies (Epstein &
neously increases. In other words, arbitrariness
Wang, 1994).8 Vague probabilities correspond to
reduces the MNE’s ability to exploit the benefits
situations where the underlying causes are of-
of pervasive corruption. As arbitrariness ob-
ten unique and where a priori calculations over
structs the comprehension of the local institu-
them are infeasible. In this way, experiences in
tional context, entering firms will likely come
highly arbitrary environments are almost al-
more and more to rely on local firms to provide
ways new and of such a variegated nature that
some measure of the legitimacy and knowledge
learning in them is difficult to exploit else-
needed to deal with host country institutions
where.9 This suggests that the experiences of
the MNE in other host countries will not moder- (Shan & Hamilton, 1991; Tolbert & Zucker, 1983).
ate the relationship between arbitrariness and
mode of entry, as it does between pervasiveness Proposition 5: The positive relation-
and mode of entry. ship between the pervasiveness of cor-
ruption and equity entry via a wholly
Proposition 4: The positive relation- owned subsidiary is weakened as the
ship between the pervasiveness of arbitrariness of corruption increases.

8
See Camerer and Weber (1992) for a survey of empirical
evidence on these behavioral differences. 10
When both little arbitrariness and pervasiveness of cor-
9
See Ellsberg (1961) for a classic discussion of risk versus ruption exist, the effect on entry mode is, in all probability,
uncertainty. negligible.
2005 Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, and Eden 393

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS MNEs have increasingly targeted for entry.


These countries’ developmental needs and com-
In the preceding pages we have emphasized
mercial possibilities cannot be fully realized
that government corruption warps “the rules of
without the capabilities and resources of MNEs,
the game” and that the prevailing one-dimen-
whose entry is contingent on the expectation of
sional view is incapable of sufficiently guiding
profitable operations. Our two-dimensional
theory or characterizing the experiences of firms
framework deepens the understanding of cor-
with corruption. We suggest that the nature of
ruption and suggests how entry mode choices
corruption should be conceived of as a combi-
can alleviate the challenges to legitimacy that
nation of two defining characteristics: perva-
result from entry where corruption is substan-
siveness and arbitrariness. Using this two- tial.
dimensional framework to describe local Empirical investigations of corruption and
corruption enables MNEs to meaningfully com- firm behavior support our theory. For example,
prehend the challenges of corruption in a par- Smarzynska and Wei (2000) found that the like-
ticular state and how they differ from those in lihood of entry with a local partner increases
other states so as to avert or exploit them. In with the level of corruption in the transition
particular, we suggest how firms might adapt economies of Eastern Europe and Central Asia.
their entry modes in response to the pervasive- However, because corruption tends to be highly
ness and arbitrariness of corruption. arbitrary in these same countries, it is not clear
We use institutional theory, which is particu- that these results can be generalized to other
larly suited to this analysis, because corruption countries where pervasiveness is similarly high
is an element of the norms and rules of states but arbitrariness low. Our analysis suggests
and, thus, affects both the external and internal that such results are not generalizable and
legitimacy of MNE subsidiaries. The examina- warns against any suggestion that corruption is
tion of government-firm interactions and of the the same everywhere.
broader institutional environment has much to We also hope we have expanded the conver-
add to the literature on entry modes, which typ- sation on MNE political behavior by emphasiz-
ically centers on firm-specific issues. By devel- ing the uncertainty associated with govern-
oping a framework for understanding corrup- ment-firm relationships. In prior management
tion, we contribute to the entry literature and research, scholars have considered the opportu-
highlight government corruption as an impor- nity corruption creates for political behavior by
tant and complex external issue affecting entry MNEs (Boddewyn, 1988; Boddewyn & Brewer,
decisions. Moreover, our analysis distills often- 1994; Ring et al., 1990). Owing to their size and
conflicting pressures exerted by corruption. An the diversity of their experiences, it has been
MNE subsidiary is more likely to engage in cor- suggested that MNEs can acquire a competitive
ruption where pervasiveness is high, although advantage through involvement with local cor-
doing so may threaten internal legitimacy if the ruption. Our analysis adds to this work and sug-
firm has established strong ethical or anticor- gests that when corruption is highly arbitrary,
ruption norms. These same internal norms, neither firm size nor previous experience with
which confer legitimacy on subsidiaries, signif- corruption is advantageous. Where corruption is
icantly influence the decision to enter via equity highly pervasive but not arbitrary, however,
versus arm’s-length modes. Of course, the na- some firms may successfully enter via FDI and
ture of local corruption matters greatly in and of engage in corrupt transactions. Through the de-
itself. Highly arbitrary corruption increases the velopment of these relationships, we character-
likelihood that MNEs entering via FDI will ize corruption as a meaningful institution and
choose a local partner, because local partners demonstrate the importance of legitimacy con-
increase external legitimacy. Pervasiveness cre- cerns to entry mode decisions.
ates opposite incentives for partnering that in- The continuing diversification and growth of
crease the likelihood of entry via a wholly MNEs necessitate effective strategies for coping
owned subsidiary. with corruption. We have furthered the under-
Corruption occurs everywhere, but it is partic- standing of the nature of public sector corrup-
ularly widespread in transition and less devel- tion and suggested means of advantageous ad-
oped economies (Hellman et al., 2000), which aptation. In future research scholars might
394 Academy of Management Review April

consider further strategies that firms can use to Boddewyn, J. J., & Brewer, T. 1994. International-business
address corruption. For instance, the adoption of political behavior: New theoretical directions. Academy
of Management Review, 19: 119 –144.
an MNE-wide code of conduct may help to insu-
late MNE subunits from the pressures of local Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. 1976. The future of the multina-
tional enterprise. London: Macmillan.
corruption. Kostova and Zaheer (1999) argue that
MNEs with a geocentric managerial philosophy Buckley, P., & Casson, M. 1998. Analyzing foreign market
entry strategies: Extending the internalization ap-
will be better able to cope with the tensions proach. Journal of International Business Studies, 29(1):
between internal and external legitimacy by 539 –561.
adopting globally acceptable structures, poli- Camerer, C., & Weber, M. 1992. Recent developments in
cies, and practices. modeling preferences: Uncertainty and ambiguity. Jour-
Finally, we agree with recent work in the eco- nal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5: 325–370.
nomics literature that emphasizes the advan- Chang, S.-J., & Rosenzwieg, P. M. 2001. The choice of entry
tages to the general public, domestic firms, and mode in sequential foreign direct investment. Strategic
multinationals of reducing corruption. Govern- Management Journal, 22: 747–776.
ment corruption is a serious impediment to eco- Cothran, D. A. 1994. Political stability and democracy in
nomic development and stability in developing Mexico: “Perfect dictatorship”? Westport, CT: Praeger.
countries (Kaufmann, 1997). The U.S. Foreign Dacin, M. T. 1997. Isomorphism in context: The power and
Corrupt Practices Act and similar efforts by the prescription of institutional norms. Academy of Manage-
Organization for Economic Cooperation and De- ment Journal, 40: 46 – 81.
velopment (OECD) and other international insti- Davis, P. S., Desai, A. B., & Francis, J. D. 2000. Mode of
tutions signal a collective push to reduce cor- international entry: An isomorphism perspective. Jour-
nal of International Business Studies, 31(2): 239 –258.
ruption and should realize some measure of
success. We expect these efforts to be of great DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. 1983. The iron cage revisited:
Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in
service to MNEs in the long run, since a reduc-
organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48:
tion in corruption is strongly linked with in- 147–160.
creased rates of economic growth. While some
Dunning, J. H. 1993. Multinational enterprises and the global
consider corruption the “grease” that makes economy. Harlow, UK: Addison-Wesley.
commerce possible and profitable, we conclude
Easterly, W. 2000. The elusive quest for growth: Economists’
that such advantages mask deeper develop- adventures and misadventures in the tropics. Cam-
mental challenges that are far more costly. bridge, MA: MIT Press.
Elliott, K. A. (Ed.). 1997. Corruption and the global economy,
vol. 14. Washington, DC: Institute for International Eco-
REFERENCES nomics.
Ades, A., & DiTella, R. 1999. Rents, competition, and corrup- Ellsberg, D. 1961. Risk ambiguity, and the Savage axioms.
tion. American Economic Review, 80: 982–993. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75: 643– 669.
Ahlstrom, D., & Bruton, G. D. 2001. Learning from successful Epstein, L., & Wang, T. 1994. Intertemporal asset pricing
local private firms in China: Establishing legitimacy. under Knightian uncertainty. Econometrica, 64: 283–322.
Academy of Management Executive, 15(4): 72– 83.
Fox, C. R., & Tversky, A. 1995. Ambiguity aversion and com-
Alfiler, M. C. P., & Concepcion, D. 1986. The process of bu- parative ignorance. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110:
reaucratic corruption in Asia. In L. A. Carino (Ed.), Bu- 585– 603.
reacratic corruption in Asia: Causes, consequences, and
controls: 15– 68. Quezon City, Phillipines: JMC Press. Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett, C. 1990. The multinational corpora-
tion as an interorganizational network. Academy of
Anderson, E., & Gatignon, H. 1986. Modes of foreign entry: A Management Review, 15: 603– 625.
transaction cost analysis and propositions. Journal of
International Business Studies, 17(3): 1–26. Glynn, M. A., & Abzug, R. 2002. Institutional identity: Sym-
bolic isomorphism and organizational names. Academy
Banerjee, A. 1997. A theory of misgovernance. Quarterly Jour- of Management Journal, 45: 267–280.
nal of Economics, 112: 1289 –1332.
Haveman, H. A. 1993. Follow the leader: Mimetic isomor-
Bardhan, P. 1997. Corruption and development: A review of phism and entry into new markets. Administrative Sci-
issues. Journal of Economic Literature, 35: 1320 –1346. ence Quarterly, 38: 593– 627.
Blumentritt, T. P., & Nigh, D. 2002. The integration of subsid- Hellman, J. S., Jones, G., Kaufmann, D., & Schankerman, M.
iary political activities in multinational corporations. 2000. Measuring governance, corruption, and state cap-
Journal of International Business Studies, 33(1): 57–77. ture: How firms and bureaucrats shape the business en-
Boddewyn, J. J. 1988. Political aspects of MNE theory. Journal vironment in transition economies. Public policy re-
of International Business Studies, 19(3): 341–363. search paper No. 2312, World Bank, Washington, DC.
2005 Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, and Eden 395

Hill, C. W. L., Hwang, P., & Kim, W. C. 1990. An eclectic theory mode choice. Journal of International Business Studies,
of the choice of international entry mode. Strategic Man- 33(1): 19 –37.
agement Journal, 11: 117–128. Maitland, E. 2002. Modeling economic corruption: Implica-
Hoffman, D. E. 2002. The oligarchs: Wealth and power in the tions for multinational enterprises. Paper presented at
new Russia. New York: Public Affairs. the annual meeting of the International Studies Associ-
ation, New Orleans.
Hymer, S. 1976. The international operations of national
firms: A study of direct foreign investment. Cambridge, Makino, S., & Delios, A. 1996. Local knowledge transfer and
MA: MIT Press. performance: Implications for alliance formation in
Asia. Journal of International Business Studies, 27: 905–
ICRG (International Country Risk Guide). 1999. Brief guide to
927.
the rating system. Syracuse, NY: ICRG.
Mauro, P. 1995. Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of
Jacobson, C. K., Lenway, S. A., & Ring, P. S. 1993. The political
Economics, 110: 681–712.
embeddedness of private economic transactions. Jour-
nal of Management Studies, 30: 453– 478. Mauro, P. 1998. Corruption and the composition of govern-
ment expenditure. Journal of Public Economics, 69: 263–
Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J.-E. 1977. The internationalization
279.
process of the firm—a model of knowledge development
and increasing foreign market commitments. Journal of Morris, S. 1991. Corruption and politics in contemporary Mex-
International Business Studies, 8(1): 23–32. ico. Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press.

Johnston, M. 1997. Public officials, private interests, and sus- Oldenburg, P. 1987. Middlemen in third-world corruption.
tainable democracy. When politics and corruption meet. World Politics, 39: 508 –535.
In K. A. Elliot (Ed.), Corruption and the global economy: Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institutional pro-
61– 82. Washington, DC: Institute for international Eco- cesses. Academy of Management Review, 16: 145–179.
nomics.
Oliver, C. 1997. Sustainable competitive advantage: Com-
Kaufmann, D. 1997. The missing pillar of a growth strategy bining institutional and resource-based views. Strategic
for Ukraine. In P. Cornelius & P. Lemain (Eds.), Ukraine: Management Journal, 18: 697–713.
Accelerating the transition to market: 238 –291. Washing-
Peng, M. W. 2001. How entrepreneurs create wealth in tran-
ton, DC: International Monetary Fund.
sition economies. Academy of Management Executive,
Kaufmann, D. 1998. Research on corruption: Critical empiri- 15(1): 95–108.
cal issues. In A. K. Jain (Ed.), Economics of corruption:
Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. 1978. The external control of
129 –176. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer. organizations: A resource dependence perspective. New
Keefer, P. 1996. Protection against a capricious state: French York: Harper & Row.
investment and Spanish railroads, 1845–1875. Journal of Powell, W. W. 1988. Institutional effects on organizational
Economic History, 56: 170 –192. structure and performance. In L. G. Zucker (Ed.), Institu-
Knight, F. 1921. Risk, uncertainty, and profit. Boston: Hough- tional patterns and organizations: Culture and environ-
ton Mifflin. ment: 115–136. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
Kogut, B., & Singh, H. 1988. The effect of national culture on Radaev, V. 2000. Informalization of rules in the Russian econ-
the choice of entry mode. Journal of International Busi- omy. Paper presented at the annual conference of the
ness Studies, 19(3): 411– 432. International Society for the New Institutional Econom-
ics, Tubingen, Germany.
Kostova, T., & Roth, K. 2002. Adoption of an organizational
practice by subsidiaries of multinational corporations: Rajan, R., & Zingales, L. 2003. Saving capitalism from the
Institutional and relational effects. Academy of Man- capitalists: Unleashing the power of financial markets to
agement Journal, 45: 215–233. create wealth and spread opportunity. New York: Crown.

Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational legitimacy Ring, P. S., Lenway, S. A., & Govekar, M. 1990. Management
under conditions of complexity: The case of the multi- of the political imperative in international business.
national enterprise. Academy of Management Review, Strategic Management Journal, 11: 141–151.
24: 64 – 81. Rivoli, P., & Salorio, E. 1996. Foreign direct investment and
Lambsdorff, J. 1999. Corruption in empirical research: A re- investment under uncertainty. Journal of International
view. Transparency International working paper, Berlin, Business Studies, 27: 335–357.
Germany. Root, F. A. 1994. Entry strategies for international markets.
Lenway, S. A., & Murtha, T. P. 1994. The state as strategist in New York: Macmillan.
international business research. Journal of International Rose-Ackerman, S. 1978. Corruption: A study in political
Business Studies, 25: 513–535. economy. New York: Academic Press.
Levy, P. B. 1989. The Waterfront Commission of the Port of Rose-Ackerman, S. 1999. Corruption and government:
New York: A history and appraisal. Industrial and Labor Causes, consequences, and reform. London: Cambridge
Relations Review, 42: 508 –523. University Press.
Lu, J. W. 2002. Intra- and inter-organizational imitative be- Rose-Ackerman, S. 2001. Trust, honesty, and corruption: The-
havior: Institutional influences on Japanese firms’ entry ories and survey evidence from post-socialist societies.
396 Academy of Management Review April

Paper presented at the Workshop on Honesty and Trust Tolbert, P. S., & Zucker, L. G. 1983. Institutional sources of
in Post-Socialist Societies at the Collegium, Budapest. change in the formal structure of organizations: The
Rosenzweig, P., & Singh, J. 1991. Organizational environ- diffusion of civil service reforms. Administrative Science
ments and the multinational enterprise. Academy of Quarterly, 23: 22–39.
Management Review, 16: 340 –361. Transparency International. 2001. Corruption perceptions in-
Schacter, M., & Shah, A. 2001. Look before you leap. Notes for dex 2001. Berlin: Transparency International.
corruption fighters. IOG policy brief No. 11. Ottawa, ON: Treisman, D. 2000. The causes of corruption: A cross national
Institute on Governance. study. Journal of Public Economics, 67: 399 – 457.
Scott, W. R. 1987. The adolescence of institutional theory. Wei, S.-J. 1997. Why is corruption so much more taxing than
Administrative Science Quarterly, 32: 493–511.
tax? Arbitrariness kills. Working paper No. 6255, Na-
Scott, W. R. 1995. Institutions and organizations. Thousand tional Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Oaks, CA: Sage.
Westney, D. E. 1993. Institutionalization theory and the mul-
Shan, W., & Hamilton, W. 1991. Country-specific advantage tinational corporation. In S. Ghoshal & D. E. Westney
and international cooperation. Strategic Management (Eds.), Organization theory and the multinational corpo-
Journal, 12: 419 – 432. ration: 53–75. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Schrader, R. C. 2001. Collaboration and performance in foreign World Bank. 2000. World development report: Attacking pov-
markets: The case of young high-technology manufactur- erty. New York: Oxford University Press.
ing firms. Academy of Management Journal, 44: 45– 60.
Yiu, D., & Makino, S. 2002. The choice between joint venture
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. 1993. Corruption. Quarterly Journal
and wholly owned subsidiary: An institutional perspec-
of Economics, 108: 599 – 617.
tive. Organization Science, 13: 667– 683.
Smarzynska, B., & Wei, S.-J. 2000. Corruption and the compo-
Zaheer, S., & Mosakowski, E. 1997. The dynamics of the lia-
sition of foreign direct investment: Firm-level evidence.
Working paper No. 7969, National Bureau of Economic bility of foreignness: A global study of survival in finan-
Research, Cambridge, MA. cial services. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 439 –
464.
Suchman, M. C. 1995. Managing legitimacy: Strategic and
institutional approaches. Academy of Management Re- Zahra, S. A., Ireland, R. D., Gutierrez, I., & Hitt, M. A. 2000.
view, 20: 571– 610. Privatization and entrepreneurial transformation:
Emerging issues and a future research agenda. Acad-
Tanzi, V. 1998. Corruption around the world: Causes, conse-
emy of Management Review, 25: 509 –524.
quences, scope, and cures. Working paper No. 98/63, In-
ternational Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Zucker, L. G. 1983. Organizations as institutions. In S. B.
Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in action: Social science Bacharach (Ed.), Research in the sociology of organiza-
bases of administrative theory. New York: McGraw-Hill. tions, vol. 2: 1– 47. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Peter Rodriguez is an associate professor of business administration at the Darden


Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Virginia, where he teaches
courses on international business and economics. He received a Ph.D. in economics
from Princeton University. His research interests include international business, eco-
nomic development, and corruption.

Klaus Uhlenbruck is an associate professor and director of the Small Business Insti-
tute at the University of Montana. He received his Ph.D. from the University of
Colorado. His research interests include international diversification, mergers and
acquisitions, privatization in emerging economies, and entrepreneurial processes. A
recent focus is on institutional aspects of corruption.

Lorraine Eden is professor of management at Texas A&M University, where she


teaches courses on multinational enterprises and the economics of international
business. She received her Ph.D. in economics from Dalhousie University. Her re-
search area is the political economy of multinationals, specializing in transfer pricing,
international taxation, and regional integration.

Вам также может понравиться