Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 22

Decision Analysis

Chapter 12

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-1

Chapter Topics

Components of Decision Making


Decision Making without Probabilities
Decision Making with Probabilities
Decision Analysis with Additional Information
Utility

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-2

Decision Analysis
Overview
Previous chapters used an assumption of certainty with regards to
problem parameters.
This chapter relaxes the certainty assumption
Two categories of decision situations:
Probabilities can be assigned to future occurrences
Probabilities cannot be assigned to future occurrences

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-3

Decision Analysis
Components of Decision Making
A state of nature is an actual event that may occur in the future.
A payoff table is a means of organizing a decision situation,
presenting the payoffs from different decisions given the various
states of nature.

Table 12.1 Payoff table


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-4

Decision Analysis
Decision Making Without Probabilities

Figure 12.1 Decision


situation with real
estate investment
alternatives
12-5

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Decision Analysis
Decision Making without Probabilities

Table 12.2 Payoff table for the real estate


investments
Decision-Making Criteria
maximax

maximin

minimax regret
Hurwicz
likelihood
Copyright
2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

minimax
equal
12-6

Decision Making without Probabilities


Maximax Criterion
In the maximax criterion the decision maker selects the
decision that will result in the maximum of maximum payoffs;
an optimistic criterion.

Table 12.3

Payoff table illustrating a maximax decision

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-7

Decision Making without Probabilities


Maximin Criterion
In the maximin criterion the decision maker selects the
decision that will reflect the maximum of the minimum
payoffs; a pessimistic criterion.

Table 12.4 Payoff table illustrating a maximin decision


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-8

Decision Making without Probabilities


Minimax Regret Criterion
Regret is the difference between the payoff from the best
decision and all other decision payoffs.
Example: under the Good Economic Conditions state of
nature, the best payoff is $100,000. The managers regret for
choosing the Warehouse alternative is $100,000$30,000=$70,000

Table 12.5

Regret table

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-9

Decision Making without Probabilities


Minimax Regret Criterion
The manager calculates regrets for all alternatives under each
state of nature. Then the manager identifies the maximum
regret for each alternative.
Finally, the manager attempts to avoid regret by selecting the
decision alternative that minimizes the maximum regret.

Table 12.6 Regret table illustrating the minimax regret


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall
decision

12-10

Decision Making without Probabilities


Hurwicz Criterion
The Hurwicz criterion is a compromise between the maximax
and maximin criteria.
A coefficient of optimism, , is a measure of the decision
makers optimism.
The Hurwicz criterion multiplies the best payoff by and the
worst payoff by 1- , for each decision, and the best result is
selected. Here, = 0.4.
Decision
Apartment building

Values
$50,000(.4) + 30,000(.6) = 38,000

Office building

$100,000(.4) - 40,000(.6) = 16,000

Warehouse

$30,000(.4) + 10,000(.6) = 18,000

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-11

Decision Making without Probabilities


Equal Likelihood Criterion
The equal likelihood ( or Laplace) criterion multiplies the
decision payoff for each state of nature by an equal weight,
thus assuming that the states of nature are equally likely to
occur.
Decision
Apartment building

Values
$50,000(.5) + 30,000(.5) = 40,000

Office building

$100,000(.5) - 40,000(.5) = 30,000

Warehouse

$30,000(.5) + 10,000(.5) = 20,000

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-12

Decision Making without Probabilities


Summary of Criteria Results
A dominant decision is one that has a better payoff than
another decision under each state of nature.
The appropriate criterion is dependent on the risk personality
and philosophy of the decision maker.
Criterion

Decision (Purchase)

Maximax

Office building

Maximin

Apartment building

Minimax regret

Apartment building

Hurwicz

Apartment building

Equal likelihood

Apartment building
12-13

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Decision Making without Probabilities


Solution with QM for Windows (1 of 3)

Exhibit 12.1
12-14

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Decision Making without Probabilities


Solution with QM for Windows (2 of 3)
Equal likelihood weight

Exhibit 12.2
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-15

Decision Making without Probabilities


Solution with QM for Windows (3 of 3)

Exhibit 12.3
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-16

Decision Making without Probabilities


Solution with Excel

=MIN(C7,D7)
=MAX(E7,E9)

=MAX(F7:F9)

=MAX(C18,D18)
=MAX(C7:C9)-C9
=C7*C25+D7*C26

=C7*0.5+D7*0.5
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Exhibit 12.4

12-17

Decision Making with Probabilities


Expected Value
Expected value is computed by multiplying each decision
outcome under each state of nature by the probability of its
occurrence.

Table 12.7 Payoff table with probabilities for states of


nature
EV(Apartment) = $50,000(.6) + 30,000(.4) = $42,000
EV(Office) = $100,000(.6) - 40,000(.4) = $44,000
EV(Warehouse) = $30,000(.6) + 10,000(.4) = $22,000
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-18

Decision Making with Probabilities


Expected Opportunity Loss
The expected opportunity loss is the expected value of the
regret for each decision.
The expected value and expected opportunity loss criterion
result in the same decision.
EOL(Apartment) = $50,000(.6) + 0(.4) = 30,000
EOL(Office) = $0(.6) + 70,000(.4) = 28,000
EOL(Warehouse) = $70,000(.6) + 20,000(.4) = 50,000

Table 12.8 Regret table with probabilities for states of nature


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-19

Expected Value Problems


Solution with QM for Windows

Expected values

Exhibit 12.5
12-20

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Expected Value Problems


Solution with Excel and Excel QM (1 of 2)

Expected value for


apartment building

Exhibit 12.6
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-21

Expected Value Problems


Solution with Excel and Excel QM (2 of 2)
Click on Add-Ins to access
the Excel QM menu

Exhibit 12.7
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-22

Decision Making with Probabilities


Expected Value of Perfect Information
The expected value of perfect information (EVPI) is the
maximum amount a decision maker would pay for additional
information.
EVPI equals the expected value given perfect information
minus the expected value without perfect information.
EVPI equals the expected opportunity loss (EOL) for the best
decision.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-23

Decision Making with Probabilities


EVPI Example (1 of 2)

Table 12.9

Payoff table with decisions, given perfect information

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-24

Decision Making with Probabilities


EVPI Example (2 of 2)
Decision with perfect information:
$100,000(.60) + 30,000(.40) = $72,000
Decision without perfect information:
EV(office) = $100,000(.60) - 40,000(.40) = $44,000
EVPI = $72,000 - 44,000 = $28,000
EOL(office) = $0(.60) + 70,000(.4) = $28,000

12-25

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Decision Making with Probabilities


EVPI with QM for Windows
The expected value, given
perfect information, in Cell F12

=MAX(E7:E9)
=F12-F11

Exhibit 12.8
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-26

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees (1 of 4)
A decision tree is a diagram consisting of decision nodes
(represented as squares), probability nodes (circles), and
decision alternatives (branches).

Table 12.10 Payoff table for real estate investment example


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-27

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees (2 of 4)

Figure 12.2 Decision tree for real estate investment example


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-28

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees (3 of 4)
The expected value is computed at each probability node:
EV(node 2) = .60($50,000) + .40(30,000) = $42,000
EV(node 3) = .60($100,000) + .40(-40,000) = $44,000
EV(node 4) = .60($30,000) + .40(10,000) = $22,000
Branches with the greatest expected value are selected.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-29

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees (4 of 4)

Figure 12.3 Decision tree with expected value at probability


nodes
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-30

10

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees with QM for Windows
Select node to add from

Number of branches
from node 1

Add branches from node


1 to 2, 3, and 4

Exhibit 12.9
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-31

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees with Excel and TreePlan (1 of 4)
Exhibit 12.10

12-32

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees with Excel and TreePlan (2 of 4)
To create another branch, click
B5, then the Decision Tree
menu, and select Add Branch

Invoke TreePlan from


the Add Ins menu

Exhibit 12.11
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-33

11

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees with Excel and TreePlan (3 of 4)

Click on cell F3,


then Decision Tree

Select Change to
Event Node and add
two new branches

Exhibit 12.12
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-34

Decision Making with Probabilities


Decision Trees with Excel and TreePlan (4 of 4)
Add numerical dollar and probability
values in these cells in column H

Exhibit 12.13

These cells contain decision tree


formulas; do not type in these
cells in columns E and I
12-35

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Sequential Decision Tree Analysis


Solution with QM for Windows

Cell A16 contains


the expected value
of $44,000
Exhibit 12.14
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-36

12

Decision Making with Probabilities


Sequential Decision Trees (1 of 4)
A sequential decision tree is used to illustrate a situation
requiring a series of decisions.
Used where a payoff table, limited to a single decision, cannot
be used.
The next slide shows the real estate investment example
modified to encompass a ten-year period in which several
decisions must be made.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-37

Decision Making with Probabilities


Sequential Decision Trees (2 of 4)

Figure 12.4 Sequential decision tree


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-38

Decision Making with Probabilities


Sequential Decision Trees (3 of 4)
Expected value of apartment building is:
$1,290,000-800,000 = $490,000
Expected value if land is purchased is:
$1,360,000-200,000 = $1,160,000
The decision is to purchase land; it has the highest net
expected value of $1,160,000.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-39

13

Decision Making with Probabilities


Sequential Decision Trees (4 of 4)

Figure 12.5 Sequential decision tree with nodal expected


values

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-40

Sequential Decision Tree Analysis


Solution with Excel QM

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Exhibit 12.15

12-41

Sequential Decision Tree Analysis


Solution with TreePlan

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Exhibit 12.16

12-42

14

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Bayesian Analysis (1 of 3)
Bayesian analysis uses additional information to alter the
marginal probability of the occurrence of an event.
In the real estate investment example, using the expected
value criterion, the best decision was to purchase the office
building with an expected value of $444,000, and EVPI of
$28,000.

Table 12.11 Payoff table for real estate investment


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-43

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Bayesian Analysis (2 of 3)
A conditional probability is the probability that an event will
occur given that another event has already occurred.
An economic analyst provides additional information for the
real estate investment decision, forming conditional
probabilities:
g = good economic conditions
p = poor economic conditions
P = positive economic report
N = negative economic report
P(Pg) = .80

P(NG) = .20

P(Pp) = .10

P(Np) = .90
12-44

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Bayesian Analysis (3 of 3)
A posterior probability is the altered marginal probability of an
event based on additional information.
Prior probabilities for good or poor economic conditions in
the real estate decision:
P(g) = .60; P(p) = .40
Posterior probabilities by Bayes rule:
(gP) = P(PG)P(g)/[P(Pg)P(g) + P(Pp)P(p)]
= (.80)(.60)/[(.80)(.60) + (.10)(.40)] = .923
Posterior (revised) probabilities for decision:
P(gN) = .250

P(pP) = .077

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

P(pN) = .750
12-45

15

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Decision Trees with Posterior Probabilities (1 of
4)
Decision trees with posterior probabilities differ from earlier
versions in that:
Two new branches at the beginning of the tree represent
report outcomes.
Probabilities of each state of nature are posterior
probabilities from Bayes rule.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-46

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Decision Trees with Posterior Probabilities (2 of
4)

Figure 12.6 Decision tree with posterior


probabilities

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-47

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Decision Trees with Posterior Probabilities (3 of
4)
EV (apartment building) = $50,000(.923) + 30,000(.077)
= $48,460
EV (strategy) = $89,220(.52) + 35,000(.48) = $63,194

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-48

16

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Decision Trees with Posterior Probabilities (4 of
4)

Figure 12.7 Decision tree analysis for real estate investment


Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-49

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Computing Posterior Probabilities with Tables

Table 12.12 Computation of posterior


probabilities

12-50

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Computing Posterior Probabilities with Excel

Exhibit 12.17
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-51

17

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Expected Value of Sample Information
The expected value of sample information (EVSI) is the
difference between the expected value with and without
information:
For example problem, EVSI = $63,194 - 44,000 = $19,194
The efficiency of sample information is the ratio of the
expected value of sample information to the expected value of
perfect information:
efficiency = EVSI /EVPI = $19,194/ 28,000 = .68

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-52

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Utility (1 of 2)

Table 12.13 Payoff table for auto insurance example

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-53

Decision Analysis with Additional Information


Utility (2 of 2)
Expected Cost (insurance) = .992($500) + .008(500) = $500
Expected Cost (no insurance) = .992($0) + .008(10,000) = $80
The decision should be do not purchase insurance, but people
almost always do purchase insurance.
Utility is a measure of personal satisfaction derived from
money.
Utiles are units of subjective measures of utility.
Risk averters forgo a high expected value to avoid a lowprobability disaster.
Risk takers take a chance for a bonanza on a very lowprobability event in lieu of a sure thing.
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-54

18

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (1 of 9)
A corporate raider contemplates the future of a recent acquisition.
Three alternatives are being considered in two states of nature. The
payoff table is below.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-55

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (2 of 9)
a. Determine the best decision without probabilities using the
5 criteria of the chapter.
b. Determine best decision with probabilities assuming .70
probability of good conditions, .30 of poor conditions. Use
expected value and expected opportunity loss criteria.
c. Compute expected value of perfect information.
d. Develop a decision tree with expected value at the nodes.
e. Given the following, P(Pg) = .70, P(Ng) = .30, P(Pp) =
20, P(Np) = .80, determine posterior probabilities using
Bayes rule.
f. Perform a decision tree analysis using the posterior
probability obtained in part e.
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-56

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (3 of 9)
Step 1 (part a): Determine decisions without probabilities.
Maximax Decision: Maintain status quo
Decisions

Maximum Payoffs

Expand
Status quo
Sell

$800,000
1,300,000 (maximum)
320,000

Maximin Decision: Expand


Decisions

Minimum Payoffs

Expand
Status quo
Sell

$500,000 (maximum)
-150,000
320,000

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-57

19

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (4 of 9)
Minimax Regret Decision: Expand
Decisions

Maximum Regrets

Expand

$500,000 (minimum)

Status quo
Sell

650,000
980,000

Hurwicz ( = .3) Decision: Expand


Expand
Status quo
$285,000
Sell

$800,000(.3) + 500,000(.7) = $590,000


$1,300,000(.3) - 150,000(.7) =
$320,000(.3) + 320,000(.7) = $320,000

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-58

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (5 of 9)
Equal Likelihood Decision: Expand
Expand
Status quo
Sell

$800,000(.5) + 500,000(.5) = $650,000


$1,300,000(.5) - 150,000(.5) = $575,000
$320,000(.5) + 320,000(.5) = $320,000

Step 2 (part b): Determine Decisions with EV and EOL.


Expected value decision: Maintain status quo
Expand
Status quo
Sell

$800,000(.7) + 500,000(.3) = $710,000


$1,300,000(.7) - 150,000(.3) = $865,000
$320,000(.7) + 320,000(.3) = $320,000

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-59

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (6 of 9)
Expected opportunity loss decision: Maintain status quo
Expand
Status quo
Sell

$500,000(.7) + 0(.3) = $350,000


0(.7) + 650,000(.3) = $195,000
$980,000(.7) + 180,000(.3) = $740,000

Step 3 (part c): Compute EVPI.


EV given perfect information =
1,300,000(.7) + 500,000(.3) = $1,060,000
EV without perfect information =
$1,300,000(.7) - 150,000(.3) = $865,000
EVPI = $1,060,000 - 865,000 = $195,000
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-60

20

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (7 of 9)
Step 4 (part d): Develop a decision tree.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-61

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (8 of 9)
Step 5 (part e): Determine posterior probabilities.
P(gP) = P(Pg)P(g)/[P(Pg)P(g) + P(Pp)P(p)]
= (.70)(.70)/[(.70)(.70) + (.20)(.30)] = .891
P(pP) = .109
P(gN) = P(Ng)P(g)/[P(Ng)P(g) + P(Np)P(p)]
= (.30)(.70)/[(.30)(.70) + (.80)(.30)] = .467
P(pN) = .533
Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-62

Decision Analysis
Example Problem Solution (9 of 9)
Step 6 (part f): Decision tree analysis.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-63

21

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval
system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying,
recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of the publisher.
Printed in the United States of America.

Copyright 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

12-64

22

Вам также может понравиться