Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 27

Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514 540

Firm networks and firm development: The role of


the relational mixB
Christian Lechnera,*, Michael Dowlingb,1, Isabell Welpec,2
a

ESC Toulouse, 20, Bd. Lacrosses, 31068 Toulouse Cedex 7, France


University of Regensburg, Management of Innovation and Technology, Regensburg 93040, Germany
c
Exist-HighTEPP Program, University of Regensburg, Regensburg 93040, Germany

Abstract
This study examines the role of different networks, called the relational mix, on the development
of the entrepreneurial firm. Our regression analysis of survey data from 60 venture capital-financed
firms questions the importance of network size on firm development. Rather, our results suggest that
different types of networks are more important for firm development. In particular, we found a
significant positive relationship for reputational networks and a weak significant negative
relationship for cooperative technology networks at founding with time-to-break-even. Social
networks at founding have no direct effect on time-to-break-even and a significant negative
relationship with sales in the years after foundation. Furthermore, our findings show the important
role of marketing information and co-opetition networks (relationships with direct competitors) on
firm development in the years after foundation. These results suggest that the relational mix is a more
appropriate construct for explaining network development than network size alone.
D 2005 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Entrepreneurship; Networks; Firm growth; Performance

An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 2003 Babson Kauffman Entrepreneurship Research
Conference, June 57, at Babson College, Boston, MA.
* Corresponding author. Tel.: +33 561 29 49 23; fax: +33 561 29 49 94.
E-mail addresses: c.lechner@esc-toulouse.fr (C. Lechner)8 Michael.Dowling@wiwi.uni-regensburg.de
(M. Dowling)8 Isabell.Welpe@Exist-Hightepp.de (I. Welpe).
1
Tel.: +49 941 9433226; fax: +49 941 943 3230.
2
Tel.: +49 941 943 1704; fax: +49 941 943 3230.
0883-9026/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jbusvent.2005.02.004

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

515

1. Executive summary
The use of external relationships is considered an important development factor for the
entrepreneurial firm. Previous research on inter-firm networks has focused on the role of
the entrepreneur in network building, on the initial size of an entrepreneurial firms
network in regard to firm performance, or on structural characteristics of networks. This
study addressed a different question: During the process of firm development, what is the
value of different kinds of network relationships?
We adapted a model of the brelational mixQ (i.e., that firms use different types of
networks in different development phases). The relational mix consists of value-added
networks that go beyond exclusively economic relationships and includes:
social networks: relationships with other firms based on strong personal relationships
with individuals such as friends, relatives, long-standing colleagues that became friends
before foundation, and so forth;
reputational networks: made up of partner firms that are market leaders, or highly
regarded firms or individuals, and where one of the main objectives in entering into this
relationship is to increase the entrepreneurial firms credibility;
marketing information networks: relationships that allow for the flow of market
information through distinct relationships with other individuals / firms;
co-opetition networks: relationships with direct competitors;
co-operative technology networks: technology alliances involving joint technology
development or innovation projects.
The adapted model assumes that the relational mix changes with a firms development
and that inability to change leads to a growth barrier.
To test hypotheses based on this model, we used survey data from 60 venture capitalfinanced start-up firms of less than 10 years of age in Austria, Germany, and Switzerland.
The evidence from the regression analysis supports our model: the relational mix is a more
important factor for explaining firm development than sheer network size. Reputation
networks have a positive influence while cooperative technology networks at foundation
have a negative effect on time to break-even. Entrepreneurs should be aware of the
important signaling effects that reputational partners can have in overcoming liability of
newness. Early technology partnering might be an indicator that firms are not yet ready to
exploit business opportunities or not attractive enough to enter into more value-adding
partnerships. Moreover, it seems that firms use their initial technology base to exploit a
business opportunity and that technology partnering is a means to enhance the technology
platform later on to prepare the company for the future. We also found that marketing
information networks and co-opetition networks in the years after foundation are
positively associated with sales. Relationships with competitors play an important role
for firm development since competitors can be a source for firm development when used
as sub-contractors, or for the joint realization of larger projects that might otherwise be
unattainable for the start-up. In this sense, co-opetition networks seem to increase the
entrepreneurial firms flexibility and to ensure sales growth in times of uncertainty. We did
not find a significant positive influence of social networks at foundation on time-to-break-

516

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

even. It seems that while constituting the start-up base of the entrepreneurial firm and
being the most common type of relationship at the beginning of the firm, social networks
are not a good discriminator for the success or speed of firm development. Social networks
seem to have an indirect effect. Over-reliance on social networks over time may in fact
constitute a growth problem, since it may indicate that firms are not capable of developing
other important ties. In conclusion, our study suggests that networking should be a
proactive task of entrepreneurs and that strategic network building over time is an
important factor for the development of the entrepreneurial firm. Further research on the
development of certain network types, the role of management style on developing
networks, and the contingent value of network types is needed to enhance our
understanding of the development processes of entrepreneurial firms.

2. Introduction and literature


Survival, performance, and development of the entrepreneurial firm are at the heart of
entrepreneurship research (Gartner, 1985; Bygrave and Hofer, 1991; Venkataraman, 1997;
Virtanen, 1997; Shane and Venkataraman, 2000). Entrepreneurial firms are characterized
by a lack of internal resources and other start-up handicaps as expressed in the theoretical
constructs of liability of newness (Stinchcombe, 1965) and liability of smallness (Baum,
1996). The strategic use of external resources through inter-firm networks in many
different industries (Powell, 1987; Lorenzoni and Ornati, 1988; Jarillo, 1989) that are often
embedded in regional clusters (Boari and Lipparini, 2000; Lechner and Dowling, 2000) is
regarded as one effective means to overcome these liabilities. In this context, inter-firm
networks are considered an important model of organization development (Richardson,
1972; Powell, 1987, 1990) to enable an entrepreneurial firm to grow and survive (Jarillo,
1988; Lorenzoni and Ornati, 1988; Nohria, 1992; Johannisson, 1998; Venkataraman and
Van de Ven, 1998; Freel, 2000).
There is a long history of research on networks in the management and organization
theory literature. Networks can be defined as a specific set of linkages between a defined
set of actors with the characteristic that the linkages as a whole may be used to interpret the
social behavior of the actors involved (Mitchell, 1969; Alba, 1982; Lincoln, 1982).
Different types of relations define different types of networks even if the same units are
connected (Knoke and Kuklinsky, 1983).
Network research distinguishes three components: network content, network structure,
and network governance in order to explain the role of networks in firm performance.
According to the theory of structural embeddedness, network structure and a firms or a
persons network position are considered to be both opportunities and constraints (Aldrich
and Zimmer, 1986). Favorable positions are regarded as network resources (Granovetter,
1974, 1985; Burt, 1992; Easton, 1992; Hakansson and Snehota, 1995; Gulati, 1999;
McEvily and Zaheer, 1999); over-embeddedness, however, (btrapped-in-its-own-netQ) can
lead to inability to act (Uzzi, 1997; Gargiulo and Benassi, 2000). A rich literature suggests
that networks are a particular governance form in which the development of trust plays a
major role in influencing resource exchange and costs compared to market coordination or
integration of activities (Richardson, 1972; Thorelli, 1986; Powell, 1987, 1990; Larson,

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

517

1992; Lorenzoni and Lipparini, 1999). In this sense, inter-firm networks constitute a third
way of organizing the business, which is neither by markets nor by hierarchies (Di
Maggio, 1986; Powell, 1990; Lorenzoni, 1992; Jarillo, 1993).
Empirical research has shown an association between the development and
transformation of relationships, size, and growth of a firms inter-firm networks and firm
growth (Jarillo, 1989; Zhao and Aram, 1995; Ardichvili and Cardozo, 2000; Chell and
Baines, 2000; Huggins, 2000; Delmar et al., 2003; Hoang and Antoncic, 2003; Sawyer et
al., 2003). Besides research on personal networking and networks, network content
research has concentrated strongly on the differences between strong and weak ties (Hoang
and Antoncic, 2003), otherwise known as the structural approach (McEvily and Zaheer,
1999). Recently, it was shown that specific kinds of relations (network content) are more
important in a different economic context (Gulati and Higgins, 2003).
Research on firm networks as a mode of transaction governance, the role of strong and
weak ties, and the analysis of structural properties of networks has produced important
insights (Hoang and Antoncic, 2003). However, research on different network types and
on network evolution remains relatively underdeveloped. bThe aggregate network can be
viewed as an overlapping set of networks of different transactional content. The only
conceptually meaningful strategy of analysis is to distinguish each network by its content,
[and] analyze it separatelyQ (Fombrun, 1982, p. 280). And as Burt (1997, p. 357) observed,
bnetwork content is rarely a variable in the studiesanalysts agree that informal
coordination through interpersonal networks is important as a form of social capital, but
their eyes go shifty like a cornered ferret if you push past the network metaphor for details
about how specific kind of relations matter.Q
Networking has also been found to be important for entrepreneurial firms. Most
research in this setting has analyzed egocentric networks (i.e., the relationships of one
focal actor with other actors) (Wassermann and Faust, 1994; Johannisson, 1998). Because
of the new ventures liabilities, such firms must mobilize social relationships (Starr and
MacMillan, 1990) to access external resources. An entrepreneurs personal networks are
all relationships between an entrepreneur and other individuals (Dubini and Aldrich,
1991). An entrepreneurs social networks are strong personal ties such as family and
friends. Research has shown that the entrepreneurs personal and social networks maybe
are the most important strategic resources of entrepreneurs for the start-up firm (Dubini
and Aldrich, 1991; Ostgaard and Birley, 1994; Johannisson, 1995, 1998, 2000; Lipparini
and Sobrero, 1997; Aldrich, 1999; Ardichvili et al., 2003). Organizational networks or
inter-firm networks are relations between organizations that can have various functions,
also called sub-networks according to their relational content (Dubini and Aldrich, 1991;
Lomi, 1997; Podolny and Page, 1998; Lechner and Dowling, 2000). The merging of
personal and organizational networks seems to be a common feature of young firms (Zhao
and Aram, 1995; Johannisson, 1998, 2000). Founders and the firm are inseparable at startup (Dollinger, 1985; Begley and Boyd, 1986). As the firm grows, the founders personal
networks and firm networks merge (Zhao and Aram, 1995; Hite and Hesterly, 2001;
Cooper, 2002). These merged networks can be considered an organizational form
(Johannisson, 2000).
Initially, it seems that networking for entrepreneurial firms is based on pre-existing
relationships, which become more complex over time by having different functions and

518

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

being more socially embedded: social relations are transformed into socio-economic and,
finally, into more complex relations (Larson and Starr, 1993). Green and Brown (1997)
have suggested that over time, newly developed organizational relationships become more
important than the a priori personal networks. Previous research has shown that the overall
network structure of egocentric networks changes from an unplanned to a planned and,
finally, a structured network (Lorenzoni and Ornati, 1988; Lorenzoni and Baden-Fuller,
1995). Once structured, however, it seems that both over-embeddedness (Uzzi, 1997;
Gargiulo and Benassi, 2000) and a firms limited relational capability (i.e., the capability to
establish, maintain, and develop relationships) (Dyer and Singh, 1998; Lorenzoni and
Lipparini, 1999; Pihkala et al., 1999; Lechner and Dowling, 2003) poses a potential barrier
to growth. However, this research does not explain which network types (content) are most
important to manage or how firms should overcome these growth barriers.
Research on network types and performance has focused on pre-start-up activities in
order to explain nascent entrepreneurship (i.e., personal networks have been analyzed at or
prior to the creation of the company in terms of size and networking activity) (Aldrich,
1999). Context-specific research investigated the positive or negative role of social
networks at start-up, but which types (content) of network matter most for firm
performance have not been studied extensively (Ostgaard and Birley, 1994). Some
research was conducted on the role of single network types such as reputational (e.g.,
Stuart et al., 1999) and cooperative technology networks (e.g., Deeds and Hill, 1996;
Kelley and Rice, 2002), but little is known for example about the role of co-opetition
networks. Studies analyzing multiple network types are rare (Baum et al., 2000).
Moreover, entrepreneurship research on networks usually lacks a development perspective
(Hoang and Antoncic, 2003) and an analysis of the value of different ties (Gulati and
Westphal, 1999). It has been argued that research bon the process of network development
in the entrepreneurial contextQ and the link between process and firm performance is the
most promising path (Hoang and Antoncic, 2003, p. 12).
Lechner and Dowling (2003) proposed a network development model based on varying
network types. Based on case study research in a German IT cluster, they identified that
firms use relationships for a variety of purposes and that every firm has an individual
relational mix. They argued that the relational mix (i.e., the different types of networks)
changes over time in order to enable firm growth. Finally, they proposed a four-phase
development model of entrepreneurial firms. In phase 1, firms seek to overcome liability
of newness by basing the development of the network mainly on social (understood as
strong ties such as family and friends) and reputational networks (relationships with
prominent firms that can lend the young firm reputation). While the relative importance of
social and reputational networks decreases with the firms development, co-opetition
networks (i.e., cooperation with competitors) increase over time. In phase 2, firms use
marketing information and co-opetition networks to overcome the usual period of unstable
sales growth; in phase 3, co-opetition remains a relevant issue but cooperative technology
networks are most important. Finally, in phase 4, firm growth is limited by path-dependent
relational capability that eventually reaches its limits and leads to the reconfiguration of a
more stable network by introducing hierarchic levels within the network or to the
integration of activities previously performed outside the firm. This qualitative study
seems to be one of the few where different network types were used to understand the role

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

519

of networks at and beyond foundation, but the importance of different network types at
and beyond foundation and their impact on the performance of the entrepreneurial firm
have not been tested empirically with larger samples.
For the study reported here, we adapted the model of the relational mix developed by
Lechner and Dowling (2003). We tested the influence of their proposed network types at
and beyond foundation by using their main arguments concerning the importance of
particular networks. Our first and fundamental research question is: Is the relational mix a
better predictor of firm performance, both at and after foundation, than the size of the
overall network?

3. Development of hypotheses
3.1. Relational mix versus network size
Different studies have proposed a simple relationship between network size and firm
performance (Johannisson, 2000). Case study research has suggested that network size is
related to the growth of firms (Zhao and Aram, 1995). Inter-firm networks can provide
access to complementary resources to develop, produce, and market products (Deeds and
Hill, 1996). Entering into inter-firm relationships has costs, risks, and benefits. Costs
include both financial resources and time. The marginal benefits of alliances can decline
while costs increase (Deeds and Hill, 1996). Some researchers that have specifically
studied technology partnering have demonstrated a curvelinear relationship between
network size and performance (Deeds and Hill, 1996). It has been argued that the
relational capability (i.e., the capability to enter and maintain relationships) is limited
(Pihkala et al., 1999) but path-dependent. In other words, firms learn to better manage
more relationships over time (Deeds and Hill, 1996; Lechner and Dowling, 2003). In
addition, certain types of inter-firm relationships can be managed in greater number
(Rothaermel and Deeds, 2001). It seems, however, that for young firms, there is still a
positive relationship between size and performance (Rothaermel, 2001). A start-ups initial
performance has been shown to increase with the size of the alliance network of firms at
foundation (Baum et al., 2000). Overall, previous research has led to the general
hypothesis that network size is a good indicator for explaining the performance of young
firms.
Hypothesis 1. Network size (i.e., the total number of network ties) increases firm
performance.
However, it has also been argued that the size of the network hides more important
network properties (Fombrun, 1982). These properties include the relational mix (i.e.,
different network types; social networks, co-opetition networks, marketing information
networks, reputation networks, and cooperative technology networks) that enabled growth
in different stages of firm development (Lechner and Dowling, 2003). These types of
networks are not pure exchange networks but are socially embedded complex relationships
(Larson, 1992). A more fine-grained picture of network development should therefore be a
better indicator for firm development than sheer network size (measured as total numbers

520

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

of relations). In Section 3.2, we develop a set of more detailed hypotheses linking specific
types of networks and therefore the relational mix to start-up and later performance in
entrepreneurial firms.
3.2. Social networks
We define social networks as strong and active relationships with other individuals that
existed before the creation of the firm. These include family (non-business), friends, and
former colleagues. It seems to us important to distinguish between active relationships
(i.e., those effectively used for business purposes) and existing but unused relationships,
called latent networks (Ramachandran and Ramnarayan, 1993), in order to understand the
actual role of networks for firm performance.3 Family and friends (i.e., non-business
networks) are considered to be part of the start-up resources of the firm (Johannisson,
2000). The entrepreneurs social networks are regarded as an important resource for the
start-up firm (Ostgaard and Birley, 1994; Johannisson, 1995; Lipparini and Sobrero,
1997). These strong ties have various benefits for the entrepreneur at the start of the firm
by providing access to resources. Social networks help entrepreneurs avoid opportunism
and uncertainty through trust, predictability, and voice. Because the entrepreneur can trust
the other party, it is easier to predict his/her behavior, avoid problem in the relationship,
but better deal with them when they do occur (Aldrich, 1999). Therefore, resource access
is immediate and the working relationship does not need a bwarm-up periodQ in which the
two partners get to know each other. As a consequence, such networks should allow
entrepreneurs to achieve performance targets faster, such as realizing the first sale and
reaching profitability (Uzzi, 1997; Davidsson and Honig, 2003). The more social
relationships the start-up possesses, the faster the entrepreneurs should be able to access
necessary resources. Social networks act as fast entrance ticket to an industry (Lechner and
Dowling, 2003). Large family and friends networks should therefore affect firm
performance positively (Johannisson, 2000). Founders personal networks at the start of
the firm have also been associated with growth (measured as number of employees) in the
subsequent year (Hansen, 1995) as well as social capital in the pre-start-up phase with
initial success such as the first sale (Lechner and Dowling, 2003). Therefore, their initial
size should influence growth (Zhao and Aram, 1995; Baum et al., 2000).
Hypothesis 2. The number of social network ties at foundation will reduce the time
needed to reach performance targets.
However, some researchers have argued that the quality of relationships, often
depending on the founders context, will influence firm performance (Ostgaard and Birley,
1994). Over-reliance on social networks, for example, could cause problems after the startup phase. First, while social networks give certain, low-cost, rapid access to resources, the
number of appropriate social ties that are beneficial for the requirement of the business
might be limited. There may be diminishing marginal returns for adding new relationships
(Deeds and Hill, 1996). A software entrepreneur reported in a study by Lechner and

We would like to thank Howard Aldrich for this distinction during a personal communication.

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

521

Dowling (2003): bAt the beginning, we only teamed up with friends but how many friends
can you have? Sometimes friends were not the right partners for the job requirementQ (p.
11). Second, networks can give access to different resources such as financial, information,
or help in finding first customers or suppliers. Social network analysis has shown that
strong ties are often characterized by high similarity and that strong relationships between
one focal actor with two other members of a network tend to lead to at least one weak tie
between the two other actors (Granovetter, 1974; Burt, 1992). Structural hole theory (Burt,
1992, 1997) has stressed the benefits of brokerage opportunities that are created by the
lack of connection between third parties.4 Since social networks are strong ties, the
information gathered from one member of the network might be rich, but the information
gathered from all members of this network might be redundant. Third, besides quality and
redundancy issues, large social networks can have an additional negative effect on
subsequent firm performance. Structural hole theory also suggests that a lack of structural
holes in the network of a focal actor not only reduces the diversity of resources accessible
but also the actors autonomy to engage in new relations (Burt, 1992, 1997). This
phenomenon of social over-embeddedness could eventually lead to a growth barrier (Uzzi,
1997; Gargiulo and Benassi, 2000). Social networks, while important for the establishment
of the firm and for reaching first milestones (Johannisson, 2000), may not be sufficient for
subsequent firm development (Lechner and Dowling, 2003). As a consequence, other
types of networks should become more important after start-up (Dollinger, 1985; Green
and Brown, 1997). These existing networks could subsequently be transformed into richer
and more complex networks (Larson, 1991, 1992; Dubini and Aldrich, 1991) to enable
firm development. It has been, however, argued that the decreasing importance of family
and friends networks is more implicit that explicit in most research (Cooper, 2002).
Therefore, if we compare firms and their networking behavior in subsequent years, other
networks should become more important for firm performance.
Hypothesis 3. The number of social network ties will be negatively associated with firm
performance in the years after foundation.
3.3. Reputation networks
Larson (1992) has suggested that social networks and reputation were pre-conditions
for economic exchange. Therefore, relationships with other firms can have important
reputational or signaling effects (Stuart et al., 1999; Gulati and Higgins, 2003; Deeds et al.,
2004). We define reputational networks as ties with firms where entrepreneurs estimated
that the main reason for entering into the relationship was to gain reputation. Reputational
networks consist of ties with prominent firms and individuals such as well-known venture
capital firms, leading firms in a given market, or highly reputed customers. However, to
enter into reputational relationships, entrepreneurial firms must be able to offer attractive
resources (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven, 1996). But even excellent resources may not

The lack of connection between two actors B and C, who are both connected to an actor A, is called a
structural hole and is the basis of structural hole theory (Burt, 1992).

522

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

suffice to overcome the reluctance of firms to engage into exchange relationships with
very young firms since economic exchange with these firms is perceived to be risky
(Bhide, 2000). Gaining reputation is an effective means of overcoming liability of newness
and increasing firm performance (Larson, 1992; Gulati and Higgins, 2003; Roberts and
Dowling, 2002).
Industries can be understood as a community with credible and reputable firms.
Affiliation with one of these firms increases the reputation of the start-up company and
should therefore be considered a corporate goal. Reputation leads to social and economic
trust in capabilities (Larson, 1992), and reputational networks can replace experience and
the lack of a track record (Stuart et al., 1999): b. . .the impact of inter-organizational
relations is driven more by who a company is associated with than by the volume of its
relations (Stuart et al., 1999, p. 345). Increased reputation should facilitate the access to
other stakeholders such as suppliers and clients who are willing to engage with the young
firm since the perceived risk of an exchange relationship is lower. As a consequence, the
existence of reputational partners should facilitate selling products. Therefore, entrepreneurial firms that build reputational networks early on should reach performance targets
faster. In later phases, the firm will need fewer reputational networks as it develops its own
reputation. In addition, with growing size, firms tend to integrate activities and reduce the
number of inter-firm relationships (Rothaermel and Deeds, 2001). Overall, reputational
networks should accelerate the development of start-ups through the creation of options
for developing more and richer relationships in the future (Larson, 1992; Lechner and
Dowling, 2003). Reputational networks were proposed to influence firm growth (Lee et
al., 2001) and to reduce the time to reach performance targets such as time-to-IPO (Stuart
et al., 1999). The existence of reputational networks at the start of a firms life cycle should
therefore reduce the time needed to reach performance targets such as realizing the first
sale, realizing a certain sales volume, or reaching break-even. A lack of reputational
networks should slow down firm development (i.e., lengthen the time needed to reach
performance targets). In this sense, the opportunity to gain reputation partners is, first, the
outcome of firm capabilities and resources. Second, the active cooperation with
reputational partners is an important form of networking. The resulting network influences
as a consequence firm performance.
Hypothesis 4. The number of reputational network ties at foundation will reduce the time
needed to reach performance targets.
3.4. Co-opetition
Co-opetition networks involve relationships with direct competitors. The management
literature generally considers industries to be collections of firms bound together by
rivalry, therefore questioning the value of relationships with competitors (Dollinger, 1985).
Particularly technology alliances with competitors are supposed to harm firm development
(Baum et al., 2000). However, it has been argued that relationships with competitors can
help entrepreneurs towards a better understanding of their firm context and opportunities,
thus influencing firm performance (Dollinger, 1985). Co-opetition (i.e., cooperation

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

523

between competitors) seems to be a widespread phenomenon of entrepreneurial firms


(Dowling et al., 1998). Firms can use competitors as subcontractors in times where the
firm has temporarily reached full capacity. This cooperative behavior, especially with
regional competitors, will increase the likelihood of the favor being returned. Moreover,
firms can form alliances with competitors in order to handle large projects. Overall,
relationships with competitors can give access to temporarily needed resources or lead to
the temporary pooling of resources, which should positively influence firm performance
especially in the years after foundation, when sales tend to grow discontinuously (Lechner
and Dowling, 2003). While it has been argued that co-opetition networks at foundation
might be harmful because such relationships could lead to the disclosure of competitive
information (Baum et al., 2000), lack of co-opetition networks can also constrain firm
development in the years following foundation. Entrepreneurial firms that view
competitors not only as pure rivals but also as a potential resource should therefore be
more successful (Lechner and Dowling, 2003).
Hypothesis 5. The number of co-opetition networks will positively influence performance
in the years after foundation.
3.5. Marketing information networks
Marketing information networks are relationships that allow for the flow of market
information through distinct relationships with other individuals/firms. Marketing
networks are useful for informal environmental scanning while marketing research is
based on formal environmental scanning. Research on marketing planning in large firms
has, in general, shown a positive relationship between formal marketing planning and firm
performance, but its usefulness was questioned for small firms that favor personal and
informal environmental scanning (Brush, 1992). Customers have also been shown to be an
important input for the development of innovations (Von Hippel, 1978; Malecki and
Poehling, 1999). In addition, suppliers, competitors, and distribution channels are valuable
information sources (Dollinger, 1985) that can influence strategy-making in entrepreneurial firms (Ostgaard and Birley, 1994). Family and friends networks are perceived as of
little value for marketing information (Brush, 1992). It has been argued that marketing
information networks are associated with an open management style in which the
responsibility for networking is an important function for all employees (Lechner and
Dowling, 2003) since marketing networks can be considered an outcome of network
complexity (Larson and Starr, 1993; Lorenzoni and Lipparini, 1999; Hite, 2000). This
means also that relationships with other firms develop only over time into marketing
networks. First clients with whom a firm had developed a simple exchange relationship
become real partners over time. Clients or suppliers of new firms can increase their
commitment over time with the new firm since they have a stake in its survival (Bhide,
2000). Customers become dlead usersT only through learning-by-using, which implies
some path dependency (Von Hippel, 1978). In addition, it seems that start-ups have only a
few important clients at the beginning, which serve later on as referrals (Lechner and
Dowling, 2003). Marketing information networks should therefore positively influence
firm performance in the years after foundation, suggesting that external marketing

524

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

information networks are more important than an internal marketing planning function
(Brush, 1992; Malecki and Poehling, 1999).
Hypothesis 6. The number of marketing information network ties will positively influence
firm performance in the years after foundation.
3.6. Cooperative technology networks
Cooperative technology networks are relationships with other firms in order to jointly
develop technology for the creation of innovation. Initially, start-up companies often lack
the reputation and resources to enter into cooperative technology networks with other
firms (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven, 1996; Ahuja, 2000). It seems also that start-ups
initially exploit their own technology base before entering into cooperative technology
networks (Lechner and Dowling, 2003). Because they are time- and resource-intensive,
cooperative technology networks should be developed after the start-up phase but before a
firms maturity. Building technology portfolios has been shown to be a way to foster
alliance formation, which in turn influences the firms innovation rate and therefore leads
to the continuous development of the entrepreneurial firm beyond its original technology
portfolio (Kelley and Rice, 2002).
However, technology partnering is a costly and time-intensive form of inter-firm
collaboration. The nature of this type of relationships limits the extensive use of this type
of relationship. In fact, a curvelinear relationship between the size of cooperative
technology networks and new product development was demonstrated in the study by
Deeds and Hill (1996). Nevertheless, we believe the advantages of technology cooperation
will still positively affect firm performance.
Hypothesis 7. The number of cooperative technology network ties will positively
influence performance in the years after foundation.

4. Methods
4.1. Sample and survey design
The hypotheses were tested using data from a pre-tested survey sent to CEOs and
founders of VC-financed firms in German-speaking countries in 2003. Since there was no
comprehensive database on VC-financed companies in Germany, Switzerland, Austria,
Liechtenstein, and Luxembourg, over a period of 6 months, we developed a database
identifying 1453 VC-backed companies in these countries. In a first step, data of the
German Venture Capital Association and the European Venture Capital Association were
accessed, leading to 182 VC firms, which should cover about 90% of venture capital firms
in German-speaking countries. We discovered other 47 venture capital firms via lists of
other German researchers, business plan competitions, and personal networks. In a second
step, available material on these VC firms concerning their portfolio firms was analyzed,
and the VC firms were contacted directly for information on portfolio companies. Based

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

525

on this information, we compiled a list of firms that had received venture capital in these
countries. We only considered VC-financed companies that were still actively managed
(i.e., they had to have venture capital money under management). We also excluded firms
that had received growth-stage and late-stage financing (controlled additionally by a
question in the survey) but concentrated on seed and early-stage financing. We estimate
that the firms cover about 80% of the entire population of VC-backed companies with
these characteristics5 and that the database is representative since it does not contain any
systematic omission errors.
A survey was the most appropriate means of collecting data because secondary
resources did not contain detailed information regarding network types, network size,
attitudes towards networking, etc. (Davidsson and Wiklund, 2000). Therefore, all
information, network, and performance data were self-reported, but previous research
gives support to the reliability and validity of self-reported measures (Brush and
Vanderwerf, 1992; Orpen, 1993), especially if other sources are unavailable, as in the
study of young and privately held small firms (Dess and Robinson, 1984). To ensure that a
high proportion of the answers was valid, the questionnaires were sent to the CEOs and/or
founders of the start-ups, using a key informant approach (Huber and Power, 1985; Brush
and Vanderwerf, 1992; Chandler and Hanks, 1993): CEOs and founders are considered the
single most knowledgeable and valid information sources (Hambrick, 1981; Vanderwerf
and Brush, 1989; Glick et al., 1990). We are, of course, aware of the trade-off between
objective data collected from secondary sources at several different times and data richness
derived from primary sources; given the unavailability of sufficient data, we therefore had
to opt for a survey approach of self-report data (Davidsson and Wiklund, 2000; Lyon et al.,
2000).
Following Vanderwerf and Brushs (1989) recommendations, we restricted the sample
firms in the following way. The firms were less than 10 years of age, which is consistent
with research on entrepreneurial firms (Covin et al., 1990). The average age of the firms in
our sample of 5 1/2 years comes close to the stricter recommendations of other researchers
(Robinson, 1999; Zahra et al., 2000). Founding management had to still be with the firm
(Robinson, 1999). To be able to measure performance effects, we also excluded firms that
reported zero sales for all years of data collection. The choice of VC-backed firms was
driven by different considerations. In our opinion, the restriction might dampen industry
effects that are typical in strategic management research (Dess et al., 1990), since VCs in
Europe particularly invest in attractive industries and therefore we assume minor industry
effects across industries. Moreover, the selection of these firms acts as a form of control of
founding conditions that renders the start-up base of the firms more homogeneous except
for network composition (Baum et al., 2000). Additionally, VC-backed firms are not
subject to corporate sponsorship and can therefore be considered independent entrepreneurial ventures (Robinson, 1999).
The questionnaire was sent to a random sample of 570 firms in the developed database.
A total of 142 questionnaires (i.e., about a quarter of the questionnaires returned) came

This estimate is based on the analysis of Finance magazine (Finance Magazin, February 2002) and an
approximation given by the Bundesverband Deutscher Kapitalgesellschaften (BVK).

526

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

back because the firms had gone out of business, reducing the effective sample to 428
firms. Of the 75 questionnaires received, 60 met all sample selection criteria and were
sufficiently completed. This translates to an effective response rate of 14%, which can be
considered acceptable given that the average age of the firms was only about 5 1/2 years.6
The final sample therefore consisted of 60 VC-financed start-ups, which had to be less
than 10 years old, had a sales track record, and were located in one of the countries
mentioned above. Sample firms come mainly from the IT, services, media, bio-tech, and
environmental industries.

5. Measures
5.1. Dependent variables
A difficult decision in entrepreneurship research is the choice of performance measures.
There are no commonly accepted performance measures for new ventures (McGee and
Dowling, 1994). We used both time-to-break-even and sales as performance measures.
Reaching break-even can be considered one of the firms basic goals and therefore an
adequate performance measure for start-ups (Davidsson and Honig, 2003). Respondents
were asked when they had reached break-even (months after foundation), or when they
thought they would reach break-even (in months). For those who had not yet reached
break-even, time-to-break-even was calculated by adding their estimates to the age of the
firm (recorded in months). Davidsson and Honig (2003) studied pre-venture endowments
in the form of social and human capital and their effect on business outcomes by applying
a time measure of performance (manifestation of first sale/profitability 18 months after
foundation). While they use a nominal measure (yes/no) at time intervals, we determined a
real time measure for moving into the profit zone (time-to-break-even in months).
Gatewood et al. (1995) also applied a time measure for the influence of start-up behavior
and success. Teach et al. (1989) also used the variable time-to-break-even as a
performance measurement in order to evaluate the discovery of new venture ideas on
performance. Overall, it seems that time measures are particularly appropriate for
measuring effects of pre-start-up and start-up endowments or activities and firm
performance. The use of a time measure seems to us both reasonable and important
especially when measuring the effect of initial network endowments, since other research
on inter-organizational relations has underlined the importance of speed to reach
performance targets (Stuart et al., 1999).
To measure network effects on firm performance in the years after foundation, we used
a 1-year time lag between networks and sales. We chose sales and not sales growth
because of possible distortions due to minimal or non-existent sales at the beginning of the
firms existence. Sales volume and sales growth are a common performance measure
especially for small and young firms (Begley and Boyd, 1986; Cardozo et al., 1996; Rue

McDougall et al. (1994), for example, reported a 11% response rate and Chandler and Hanks (1993) reported
a 19% response rate.

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

527

and Ibrahim, 1998; Weinzimmer et al., 1998; Robinson, 1999; Lebrasseur et al., 2003;
Delmar et al., 2003) and are arguably a sufficient single indicator for firm performance
(Venkatraman and Ramanujam, 1987; Delmar et al., 2003). Sales are relatively insensitive
to capital intensity and degree of integration, and therefore an appropriate measure for
studying networks even if they are sensitive to inflation (Weinzimmer et al., 1998; Delmar
et al., 2003). In addition, the relatively low inflation rate during the period of interest in the
countries concerned does not call for a particular control for inflation.
Since many researchers expect a causeeffect relation between networking activity,
network composition, and firm performance (Birley, 1985; Aldrich and Zimmer, 1986;
Dubini and Aldrich, 1991), we thought that some form of time lag was conceptually
important for our study: entrepreneurs develop networks not only as a response to
immediate needs but for future use (Johannisson, 2000). In line with other research, we
used an 1-year time lag between network size or relational mix and sales (i.e., we
compared the independent variables in t 0 with sales in t 1). In their study, Lebrasseur et al.
(2003) used a 1-year time lag between start-up activities and sales in the subsequent year.
Lee et al. (2001) compared sponsorship-based linkages and performance in the subsequent
2 years. Hansen (1995) and Chrisman and McMullan (2000) compared the entrepreneurs
support networks with organizational growth measured as employees and amount of
payroll in the subsequent year, therefore also applying a 1-year time lag.
In summary, we used time-to-break-even as a time measure of performance at
foundation and sales as performance measure in the years after foundation.

5.1.1. Model specifications


We tested two main models according to our hypotheses using OLS regression. In
both models, we compared the explanatory power of a control model using network
size only with a sub-model using the relational mix. We are aware that some research
(e.g., Deeds and Hill, 1996) has demonstrated a curvelinear relationship between
specific network types (technology partnering) and specific forms of intermediary
performance (new product development). The arguments against a simple linear
relationship between networks and overall firm performance are costs, benefits, risks,
and relational capability over time (Deeds and Hill, 1996; Pihkala et al., 1999;
Lechner and Dowling, 2003). Limited relational capability might eventually lead to
integration of some activities or restructuring of the existing network (Lorenzoni and
Ornati, 1988; Delmar and Davidsson, 1998; Lechner and Dowling, 2003; Rothaermel
and Deeds, 2001). We made the assumption that the firms in our sample were not
yet affected by diminishing returns of inter-firm relationships because of their young
age (Rothaermel, 2001).
In the first model, we tested the influence of networks at foundation on time-to-breakeven. The independent variables were network size and the relational mix in the first full
year of the firms existence. We had actual registration dates of the company foundation
and therefore decided to take the first full year of existence as the start-up point (i.e., the
first year in which the company existed effectively for 12 months), since the fact, that
some companies have existed only for 2 or 3 months in the first year registered, would
have strongly biased the results.

528

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

In the second model, we tested the influence of networks on firm performance after
foundation. We calculated networking years for this purpose in order to gain a better
understanding of the role of networks in the years after foundation. This method gave a
richer and more consistent data set (Baum et al., 2000) instead of taking firms of different
ages and their last years networks, which would actually mean using networking years
without being able to control for some form of evolution. We had asked the firms to
indicate different network types at the start of the firms existence and for the 5 years
following. For this model, we did not use firms as observations but the networking years
24, leading to 159 cases. We added the age of the firmmeasured in monthsas a control
variable.
5.2. Independent variables
The important independent variables of interest were the cumulative number of different
types of inter-firm relationships. We defined partners, in general, as those active relationships
with other firms that go beyond the simple exchange function. We measured number of
network ties for the variables below by counting the number of direct relationships.
5.2.1. Overall network size
The respondents were asked specifically to indicate the total number of relationships
that they regarded as important for their business, independent of the value of economic
exchange. Network size was therefore the cumulative number of all active inter-firm
relationships that were instrumental for the business.
5.2.2. Social networks
We defined social networks as strong personal relationships with members of other
firms or stakeholder before the founding of the firm based on social relationships with
individuals, such as friends, relatives, long-standing colleagues who have become friends,
and so forth. Respondents were asked to indicate how many of these active and strong
relationships they have had before starting the company.
5.2.3. Reputation networks
Reputation partners are firms that are market leaders or highly regarded firms that can
give reputation or legitimacy to the young firm. Respondents were asked to give the
cumulative number of relationships where the main objectives was to enter into such
relationships to increase the entrepreneurial firms credibility.
5.2.4. Co-opetition networks
Co-opetition networks were defined as relationships with direct competitors. Different
types of relationships were possible: competitors used as sub-contractors, being a subcontractor of the competitor, competitor as partner to respond to call for tenders, or
competitor as an important source of information. The variable measured the cumulative
number of all these types of relationships with competitors.7
7

We did not use the different co-opetition relationships in this study but aggregated the data.

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

529

5.2.5. Marketing information networks


Marketing information networks are those relationships with other firms that lead to
information about market opportunities. They fall into the following categories: (1) the
other firm is an important source of information concerning products, markets, or clients;
(2) the other firm serves as referral in order to establish contact with a new client; and (3)
the other firm helps to better tailor a product or service to market needs. Market
information networks is a count variable.
5.2.6. Cooperative technology networks
Cooperative technology networks were defined as the number of technology alliances
such as joint research and/or development projects, licensing, and cross-licensing
agreements.
5.2.7. Measurement of the relational mix
The relational mix is made up of social, reputation, co-opetition, marketing
information, and cooperative technology networks. The measurement of the relational
mix poses a methodological and practical problem, since there may be double counting or
overlap of different network types in one relationship. A firm might serve as a member of
both a firms reputational network and its co-opetition network, and even be part of the
firms cooperative technology network later. Marketing information might come from a
social network member for a week, a technology collaborator the next week, and
reputational network company the week after. We acknowledge this problem, but prior
case study research suggests that entrepreneurs can distinguish between value-adding
relationships and all other relationships with other firms (Dubini and Aldrich, 1991).
Second, entrepreneurs can identify the relationships they consider to be most important
(Larson, 1992). Third, in a given time period, entrepreneurs tend to label their economic
exchange partners and classify them according to the main benefit that the partner provides
(Lechner and Dowling, 2003). Despite possible overlaps, networks can be analysed with a
rational-choice framework (Johannisson, 2000). In the pre-test of the questionnaire, we
received various comments in this sense (e.g., bFirm A, one of our suppliers, adds value to
our business by giving us timely information about market trends; we regard A mainly as a
market informant; Firm B, one of suppliers, co-develops product solutions with us, they
are a real innovation partner,Q etc.). Obviously, the importance or the main benefit of one
actor can change over time. While we cannot control in our study whether entrepreneurs
added new ties to develop different kinds of relationships or if they were able to transform
relationships according to new priorities, we can provide a snapshot about the types of
relationships used at a point in time. The lack of auto-correlation of the independent
variables seems to support our assumption. Additionally, one would expect the number of
total relationships reported by the firms to be smaller than the sum of the different network
types if double counting were an important methodological problem. The results, however,
showed that the total number of important relationships reported was slightly higher than
the sum of the relationships of the different network types. This can indicate that the
respondents were able to classify most of their relationships according to a specific
function and therefore as specific network type while only a small fraction of relationships
was difficult to classify.

530

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

5.3. Descriptive statistics


Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics of the sample in general, for networks in the first
full year of existence, and for the subsequent years. The 60 firms have, on average, a timeto-break-even of 53 months. As expected, social networks are the most numerous
networks. The number of social networks and the overall size of networks are consistent
with other research (Aldrich, 1999; Dodd and Patra, 2002). Sales ranges and their
development show that this is a sample of growth firms.

6. Results
6.1. The importance of the relational mix at foundation
As discussed above, with partial model 1b (Table 2), we tested the influence of the
relational mix at foundation on time-to-break-even. The model was significant, with
moderate explanatory power. DurbinWatson statistics and collinearity statistics were also
acceptable. In this model, social and reputation networks had negative coefficients as
expected (i.e., they reduce the time-to-break-even but only reputation networks had a
significant influence on time-to-break-even; p = 0.03). Hypothesis (2) is therefore not
supported but Hypothesis (4) is supported. Surprisingly, technology networks showed a
positive coefficient and the relationship was weakly significant ( p = 0.09), indicating that
early technology partnering delays reaching firm performance targets.
6.2. The importance of the relational mix on firm performance in the years after
foundation
Table 3 presents the OLS regression for the partial model 2b. As already discussed, this
model is significant ( p b 0.001) with a relatively high explanatory power (adjusted
Table 1
Descriptive statistics
Average time-to-break-even (months)
Number of firms

53.18
60
Networks in year 1 (mean)

Networks in years 24 (mean)

Social networks
Reputation networks
Co-operation networks
Marketing information networks
Technology networks

6.57
2.80
0.84
2.64
1.34

8.51
4.47
2.40
5.25
2.19

Sales data in year 1

Sales data in years 25

1,582,642
1,000,000
015,000,000

4,608,141
1,600,000
30,00080,000,000

Average sales (in o)


Median (in o)
Range (in o)

531

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540


Table 2
OLS regressionnetworks at founding
Model 1
Dependent variable: time-to-break-even (in months)

Model 1a: network size

Model 1b: relational mix

Standardized regression coefficients (significance)


Intercept

(0.000)

(0.000)

Research variables
Network size
Social networks
Reputational networks
Co-opetition networks
Marketing networks
Technology networks
Adjusted R 2
F
df
DurbinWatson
n

!0.223 (0.087)

0.003 ( p b 0.087)
3.0346
1/58
2.06
60

!0.218 (0.139)
!0.298 (0.029)*
0.011 (.936)
!0.069 (0.627)
0.214 (0.093)
0.123 ( p b 0.032)
2.658
5/54
1.87
60

OLS regressionnetwork size at founding (first full year of existence) and time-to-break-even versus relational
mix at founding (first full year of existence) and time-to-break-even.

R 2 = 0.39); the DurbinWatson coefficient of 1.61 was especially positive considering that
we tested network years against sales and not individual firms. Collinearity statistics were
quite strong. In this model, the control variable age did not have a significant influence on
Table 3
OLS regressionnetworks after founding
Model 2
Dependent variable: sales (in o) lagged by 1 year
Standardized regression coefficients (Significance)
Intercept
Controls
Age
Research variables
Network size
Social networks
Reputational networks
Co-opetition networks
Marketing networks
Technology networks
Adjusted R 2
F
df
DurbinWatson
n

Model 2a: network size

Model 2b: relational mix

(0.095)

(0.368)

0.167 (0.035)

0.073 (0.217)

0.213 (0.007)

0.074 ( p b 0.001)
7.149
2/153
1.67
159

!0.147
0.168
0.508
0.208
0.058
0.389
17.459
6/149
1.61
159

(0.043)*
(0.020)*
(0.000)*
(0.006)*
(0.370)
( p b 0.001)

OLS regressionnetwork size in the years after founding (years 24) and sales in the following year versus
relational mix and sales in the following year.

532

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

sales. Co-opetition and marketing information networks had a significant and the strongest
influence on sales in the years after foundation. Hypotheses (5) and (6) are therefore
strongly supported. As expected, social networks had a negative impact on sales.
Hypothesis (3) is therefore supported. Reputation networks had a moderate effect on
sales. Cooperative technology networks had no relevant and significant influence on
sales. Hypothesis (7) is therefore not supported.
6.3. Relational mix versus network size
One of the goals of this study was also to compare performance effects of the network
size (i.e., the total number of relationships with other firms) versus a more fine-grained
measurement (i.e., different network types and their mix). Therefore, two main OLS
regression models were tested, with total network size and the relational mix as
explanatory variables for firm performance measured in model 1 by time-to-break-even
and in model 2 by sales. In model 1 (Table 2), we used the individual firms as cases
(n = 60) and tested the size of networks in the first full year of existence against time-tobreak-even. Descriptive statistics showed that overall time until break-even was rather
long (mean = 53 months, or almost 4 1/2 years). Model 1a with network size alone had
weak explanatory power and was only significant at the 0.10 level. Therefore, we conclude
that network size at founding, at best, weakly influences time-to-break-even. The model
using the relational mix (model 1b), on the other hand, was significant, with moderate
explanatory power (adjusted R 2 = 0.12, p = 0.032). Therefore, we can conclude from the
results of models 1a and 1b that the relational mix is more effective in explaining
performance at foundation than network size only.
In model 2 (Table 3), we tested the role of network size and relational mix in the years
after foundation (years 24) on the following years sales with firm age as the control
variable. Model 2a was significant but with relatively low explanatory power (adjusted
R 2 = 0.074, p b 0.001). Age as a control variable and network size had a positive and
significant influence on sales. The model therefore showed a firms network size to have a
very moderate influence on a firms development (measured in sales). However, the
second partial model, model 2b, which tested the influence of the relational mix on sales,
was a better explanatory model. The overall model was significant and demonstrated a
much higher explanatory power than network size model (adjusted R 2 = 0.39).
Overall, we conclude that network size is moderately linked to firm performance, and
the relational mix is a better explanatory concept than network size for firm performance at
and beyond foundation.

7. Discussion
The objective of this study was to empirically test the importance of the relational mix
on entrepreneurial firm development. The tested models demonstrated that the relational
mix has a higher explanatory power than network size alone. There was a positive and
significant relationship between reputation networks at start and a shorter time-to-breakeven. On the other hand, there was a negative relationship between early technology

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

533

networks and time-to-break-even, meaning that technology networks may actually delay
achieving break-even. These findings are consistent with the model of Lechner and
Dowling (2003). Gaining reputation can be considered an important means of gaining
legitimacy with positive signaling effects to the markets of resource providers (Stuart et
al., 1999; Roberts and Dowling, 2002; Deeds et al., 2004). Our analysis suggests that
reputation networks also play a moderate role after the start-up phase, meaning that
reputational networks remain positively associated with firm development. Concerning
technology networks, it seems that firms use their initial technology base to exploit a
business opportunity and that technology partnering is a means to enhance the technology
platform later on to prepare the company for the future (Kelley and Rice, 2002). Early
technology partnering might therefore be an indicator that firms are not yet ready to
exploit business opportunities or not attractive enough to enter into more value-adding
partnerships (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven, 1996). Somewhat surprising was the nonsignificant relationship between social networks and time-to-break-even. Social networks
are considered an important start-up resource of the entrepreneurial firm (Johannisson,
1995; Zhao and Aram, 1995; Baum et al., 2000). Our study did show that social networks
are the firms largest networks at the start of its existence (mean = 6.57 in the first full year
of existence, whereas every other network type contained no more than three relationships). It may be that since social networks are the start-up base for almost all firms, that
they are not a good discriminator of successful firm development. It is also possible that
social networks are more important at the critical stage of pre-foundation when
entrepreneurs assemble their very first resources and have some initial level of financial
backing and a small number of customers and suppliers, but not when firms are already
focusing on sales growth and time-to-break-even. The literature on nascent entrepreneurship seems to support this position (Aldrich, 1999; Davidsson and Honig, 2003). Social
networks seem to have an indirect effect. The quality of social networks can be very
different and the use of social networks might also make a difference. The negative and
significant influence of social networks on sales after foundation, however, was expected
and confirmed, supporting the view that social networks move into the background as
other types of networks emerge to support the growth of the firm. A high dependence on
social networks over time could be considered an indicator that firms are not capable of
developing other important ties. It might also indicate a tendency towards overembeddedness (Gargiulo and Benassi, 2000). Our analysis demonstrated the significant
and positive influence of co-opetition and marketing information networks on sales after
the start-up phase. Our findings therefore support other research that underlines the
importance of external and informal marketing information scanning instead of a more
formal marketing approach for young firms (Brush, 1992). Little is known, however, about
how firms develop marketing networks. It has been suggested that marketing networks are
a function of management style and open firm culture, and therefore a task of all
employees (Lechner and Dowling, 2003). In contrast, it has been argued that networks are
developed mainly by the entrepreneurial team at the beginning of the firms life cycle
(Ostgaard and Birley, 1994; Johannisson, 1995; Lipparini and Sobrero, 1997). Concerning
the importance of co-opetition networks, the analysis of the survey data suggests that of
those firms that had relationships with other competitors, about one third was using
competitors as subcontractors and receiving subcontractor jobs from competitors as well as

534

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

carrying out large projects together with competitors. Co-opetition networks seem to
increase the entrepreneurial firms flexibility and to promote sales growth after the start-up
phase. Our analysis was not able to demonstrate a relationship between technology
networks and sales development after foundation. As expected, technology networks are
rather small in number (mean = 1.87 over all networking years), which might explain the
low relevance in the overall model. Other research also suggests that the building of
technology networks has more of an indirect effect on firm performance (Kelley and Rice,
2002) and results might only be revealed in the long run. The time frame of our study
might not have been sufficiently broad to test the influence of technology networks on firm
development.
In general, our study emphasizes the importance of the relational mix and the change of
the relational mix on firm development. This result supports the perspective in
entrepreneurship research that many factors interacting in a complex way in a dynamic
context determine firm development (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000). The study
questions further the use of overall network size as a simple measure.
We acknowledge several limitations to our research. We have already addressed the
question of self-reported data. We cross-checked the financial data randomly for
consistency through press releases issued on the websites of 12 companies. This research
was limited to venture capital-financed firms and therefore to high-tech firmsnonventure capital-financed firms may experience different constraints (especially of a
financial nature). We see this limitation more as a strength since networking has been
associated with lack of resources and we were able to demonstrate the link between
networking and firm development of less constrained firms. The selection of these firms
acts as a form of control on foundation conditions that renders the start-up base of the
firms more homogeneous except for network composition (Baum et al., 2000). This
approach finally led to an initial homogenous group of firms, reducing the bias of crossindustry analysis. However, given the selection process of VC firms, our sample might
naturally have a growth bias. Moreover, we did not include regional effects in our model.
It is suggested that the development of egocentric networks depends on larger sociocentric or regional networks and vice versa, as can be found in regional clusters
(Johannisson, 1998; Lechner and Dowling, 2000). Therefore, we did not control for sparse
regions or industries (i.e., regions or industries where networking was difficult because of
the lack of partner firms) (Dubini, 1989; Davidsson, 1995). However, other research
suggests that entrepreneurs in sparse regions try to establish relationships with other firms
outside their original location (Birley and Westhead, 1990). In addition, our sample did not
have any systematic regional bias due to the construction of the overall population.
Another argument concerns possible signalling effects due to the fact that the firms are
VC-backed. Venture capital firms may also facilitate access to other reputational partners.
However, this does not explain intra-sample differences. Concerning reputation networks,
we mentioned above that reputation networks can be the outcome of excellent resources
and that these excellent resources explain firm performance. While we cannot control for
this reverse causality in the model, we argue based on case study research (Lechner and
Dowling, 2003) that excellent resources without reputation networks are not sufficient to
overcome liability of newness. In this study, we did not measure network structure (i.e.,
neither indirect ties nor non-redundant ties). The influence of measures such as direct

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

535

network size is particularly heavily constrained by the efficiency of the overall network.
Replication with an ever larger sample would, of course, be desirable.

8. Conclusions
Networking is very important for entrepreneurial firms. This study supports the view
that entrepreneurial networking is as much about adding new and different relationships as
about transforming existing relationships, therefore empirically supporting case-based
research in the field (Larson, 1992; Dubini and Aldrich, 1991; Lechner and Dowling,
2003). This study has both theoretical and practical implications. Complex development
models are still rare in entrepreneurship research (Hoang and Antoncic, 2003). This study
addresses the area with a specific aspect of networking (i.e., the role of the relational mix
on firm development). We think that our findings advance research because they
demonstrate that the complex measure of the relational mix provides more explanatory
power than previously used measures such as network size. Second, it underlines the
importance of different networks in different situations (Gulati and Higgins, 2003). We
believe that more development-oriented and detailed network studies are needed to
enhance our understanding of the complex development processes of entrepreneurial
firms. Both quantitative and qualitative studies investigating network structure efficiency
through network mapping over time would lead to new insights and propositions to further
research on networks in entrepreneurial firms. Additionally, we lack knowledge about how
to develop certain network types and think that studies linking management style and
networking could produce promising insights.
From a practical perspective, understanding network dynamics helps answer the
question of which ties matter when. Young firms that are constrained by liability of
newness should use their social networks to develop early reputation networks to foster
firm development. Our study also showed that marketing information networks play an
important role in firm development. External and informal marketing information scanning
seems not only to be a necessity for young firms because of resource constraints but also
an effective means of detecting and exploiting market opportunities instead of a more
formal approach to marketing. Furthermore, the study revealed the importance of
relationships with competitors for firm development. While it is not an easy decision for an
entrepreneur, our research suggests that there are true benefits to entering into a
relationship with a competitor. Finally, technology partnering seems to be a means of
enhancing the technology platform of the firm and to be more important at a later stage of
the firms development. Overall, our study suggests that networking should be a proactive
task of entrepreneurs and that strategic network building over time is an important factor
for the development of the entrepreneurial firm.

References
Ahuja, G., 2000. The duality of collaboration: inducements and opportunities in the formation of interfirm
linkages. Strategic Management Journal 21/3, 317 344.

536

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

Alba, R.D., 1982. Taking stock of network analysis: a decade of results. In: Bachran, S.B. (Ed.), Research in the
Sociology of Organizations, vol. 1. JAI, Greenwich, CT.
Aldrich, H., 1999. Organizations Evolving. Sage, London.
Aldrich, H., Zimmer, C., 1986. Entrepreneurship trough social networks. In: Sexton, D., Smilor, R. (Eds.), The
Art and Science of Entrepreneurship. Balliner, New York, pp. 3 23.
Ardichvili, A., Cardozo, R., 2000. A model of the opportunity recognition process. Journal of Enterprising
Culture 8 (2), 103 119.
Ardichvili, A., Cardozo, R., Ray, S., 2003. A theory of entrepreneurial opportunity identification and
development. Journal of Business Venturing 18 (1), 105 123.
Baum, J., 1996. Organizational ecology. In: Clegg, S., Hardy, C., Nord, S. (Eds.), Handbook of Organization
Studies. Sage, London.
Baum, J., Calabrese, T., Silverman, B., 2000. Dont go it alone: alliance network composition and startups
performance in Canadian biotechnology. Strategic Management Journal 21 (3), 267 294.
Begley, T., Boyd, D., 1986. Executive and corporate correlates of financial performance in smaller firms. Journal
of Small Business Management, 8 15 (April).
Bhide, A., 2000. The Origin and Evolution of New Businesses. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Birley, S., 1985. The role of networks in the entrepreneurial process. Journal of Business Venturing 1,
107 117.
Birley, S., Westhead, P., 1990. dNorthsouthT contrasts in the characteristics and performance of small firms.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 2, 27 48.
Boari, C., Lipparini, A., 2000. Networks within industrial districts: organising knowledge creation and transfer by
means of moderate hierarchies. Journal of Management and Governance 99 (3), 339 360.
Brush, C., 1992. Marketplace information scanning activities of new manufacturing ventures. Journal of Small
Business Management 30 (4), 41 51.
Brush, C., Vanderwerf, P., 1992. A comparison of methods and sources for obtaining estimates of new venture
performance. Journal of Business Venturing 7 (2), 157 170.
Burt, R., 1992. Structural Holes. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Burt, R., 1997. A note on social capital and network content. Social Networks 19, 355 373.
Bygrave, W., Hofer, C., 1991. Theorizing about entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 16 (2),
13 22.
Cardozo, R., Elder, T., Harmon, B., 1996. When does growth pay? In: Reynolds, P., Birley, S., Butler, J., Bygrave,
W., Davidsson, P., Gartner, W., McDougall, P. (Eds.), Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. Babson
College, Wellesley, MA, pp. 480 490.
Chandler, G., Hanks, S., 1993. Measuring the performance of emerging businesses: a validation study. Journal of
Business Venturing 8, 391 408.
Chell, E., Baines, S., 2000. Networking, entrepreneurship and microbusiness behaviour. Entrepreneurship and
Regional Development 12, 195 215.
Chrisman, J., McMullan, E., 2000. A preliminary assessment of outside assistance as a knowledge resource: the
longer-term impact of new venture counseling. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37 53 (Spring).
Cooper, A., 2002. Networks, alliances and entrepreneurship. In: Hitt, M., Ireland, D., Camp, M., Sexton, D.
(Eds.), Strategic Entrepreneurship. Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 203 222.
Covin, J., Slevin, D., Covin, T., 1990. Content and performance of growth-seeking strategies: a comparison of
small firms in high- and low-technology industries. Journal of Business Venturing 5, 391 412.
Davidsson, P., 1995. Culture, structure and regional level of entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship and Regional
Development 7, 41 62.
Davidsson, P., Honig, B., 2003. The role of social and human capital among nascent entrepreneurs. Journal of
Business Venturing 18, 301 330.
Davidsson, P., Wiklund, J., 2000. Conceptual and empirical challenges in the study of firm growth. In: Sexton, D.,
Landstrom, H. (Eds.), Handbook of Entrepreneurship. Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 26 44.
Deeds, D., Hill, C., 1996. Strategic alliances and the rate of new product development: an empirical study of
entrepreneurial biotechnology firms. Journal of Business Venturing 11, 41 55.
Deeds, D., Mang, P., Frandsen, M., 2004. The influence of firms and industries legitimacy on the flow of capital
into high-tech ventures. Strategic Organization 2/1, 9 34.

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

537

Delmar, F., Davidsson, 1998. A taxonomy of high-growth firms. In: Reynolds, P.D., Bygrave, W.D., Carter,
N.M., Manigart, S., Mason, C.L.M., Meyer, G., Shaver, K.G. (Eds.), Frontiers of Entrepreneurship
Research 1998. Arthur M. Blank Center for Entrepreneurship, Babson College, MA, pp. 399 413.
Delmar, F., Davidsson, P., Gartner, W., 2003. Arriving at the high-growth firm. Journal of Business Venturing 18,
189 216.
Dess, G., Robinson, R., 1984. Measuring organizational performance in the absence of objective measures.
Strategic Management Journal 5 (3), 265 273.
Dess, G., Ireland, D., Hitt, M., 1990. Industry effects and strategic management research. Journal of Management
16 (1), 7 27.
Di Maggio, P., 1986. Structural analysis of organizational fields. Research in Organizational Behavior, vol. 8, pp.
335 370.
Dodd, S., Patra, E., 2002. National differences in entrepreneurial networking. Entrepreneurship and Regional
Development 14, 117 134.
Dollinger, M., 1985. Environmental contacts and financial performance of the small firm. Journal of Small
Business Management 23 (1), 24 30.
Dowling, M., Lechner, C., Bau, F., 1998. Kooperative Wettbewerbsbeziehungen-eine empirische Untersuchung.
In: Franke, N., von Braun, C.F. (Eds.), Innovationsforschung und Technologiemanagement. Springer,
Berlin.
Dubini, P., 1989. The influence of motivations and environment on business start-ups: some hints for public
policies. Journal of Business Venturing 4, 11 26.
Dubini, P., Aldrich, H., 1991. Personal and extended networks are central to the entrepreneurial process. Journal
of Business Venturing 6, 305 313.
Dyer, J., Singh, H., 1998. The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive
advantage. Academy of Management Review 23 (4), 660 679.
Easton, G., 1992. Industrial networks: a review. In: Axelsson, B., Easton, G. (Eds.), Industrial Networks: A New
View of Reality. Routledge, London.
Eisenhardt, K., Schoonhoven, C., 1996. Resource-based view of strategic alliance formation: strategic and social
effects in entrepreneurial firms. Organization Science 7 (2), 136 150.
Fombrun, C., 1982. Strategies for network research in organizations. Academy of Management Review 7,
280 291.
Freel, M., 2000. External linkages and product innovation in small manufacturing firms. Entrepreneurship and
Regional Development 12, 245 266.
Gargiulo, M., Benassi, M., 2000. Trapped in your own net? Network cohesion, structural holes, and the
adaptation of social capital. Organization Science 11 (2), 183 196.
Gartner, W., 1985. A conceptual framework for describing the phenomenon of new venture creation. Academy of
Management Review 10, 696 706.
Gatewood, E., Shaver, K., Gartner, W., 1995. A longitudinal study of cognitive factors influencing start-up
behaviors and success at venture creation. Journal of Business Venturing 10, 371 391.
Glick, W., Huber, G., Miller, C., Doty, D., Sutclif, K., 1990. Studying changes in organizational design
and effectiveness: retrospective event histories and periodic assessments. Organization Science 1,
293 312.
Granovetter, M., 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Harvard University Press, Boston, MA.
Granovetter, M., 1985. Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of
Sociology 91 (3), 481 510.
Green, P., Brown, T., 1997. Resource needs and the dynamic capitalism typology. Journal of Business Venturing
12, 161 173.
Gulati, R., 1999. Network location and learning: the influence of network resources and firm capabilities on
alliance formation. Strategic Management Journal 20 (5), 397 419.
Gulati, R., Higgins, M., 2003. Which ties matter when? The contingent effects of interorganizational partnerships
on IPO success. Strategic Management Journal 24 (2), 127 144.
Gulati, R., Westphal, J., 1999. Cooperative or controlling? The effects of CEOboard relations and the content of
interlocks on the formation of joint ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly 44, 82 111.
Hakansson, H., Snehota, I., 1995. Developing Relationships in Business Networks. Routledge, London.

538

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

Hambrick, D., 1981. Environment, strategy and power within top management teams. Administrative Science
Quarterly 26, 253 276.
Hansen, E., 1995. Entrepreneurial networks and new organization growth. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice
19 (4), 7 19.
Hite, J., 2000. Patterns of multidimensionality in embedded network ties of emerging entrepreneurial firms. Paper
Presented at the Annual meeting of the Academy of Management, Toronto, Canada.
Hite, J., Hesterly, W., 2001. The evolution of firm networks: from emergence to early growth. Strategic
Management Journal 22, 271 286.
Hoang, H., Antoncic, B., 2003. Network-based research in entrepreneurship: a critical review. Journal of Business
Venturing 18, 165 187.
Huber, G.P., Power, D.J., 1985. Retrospective reports of strategic managers: guidelines for increasing their
accuracy. Strategic Management Journal 6, 171 180.
Huggins, R., 2000. The success and failure of policy-implanted inter-firm network initiatives: Motivations,
processes and structure. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 12, 111 135.
Jarillo, C., 1988. On strategic networks. Strategic Management Journal 9, 31 41.
Jarillo, C., 1989. Entrepreneurship and growth: the strategic use of external sources. Journal of Business
Venturing 4, 133 147.
Jarillo, C., 1993. Strategic Networks. Butterworth, Heinemann.
Johannisson, B., 1995. Paradigms and entrepreneurial networks: some methodological challenges. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 7, 215 232.
Johannisson, B., 1998. Personal networks in emerging knowledge-based firms: spatial and functional patterns.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 10, 297 312.
Johannisson, B., 2000. Networking and entrepreneurial growth. In: Sexton, D., Landstrom, H. (Eds.), Handbook
of Entrepreneurship. Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 368 386.
Kelley, D., Rice, M., 2002. Advantage beyond founding: the strategic use of technologies. Journal of Business
Venturing 17, 41 57.
Knoke, D., Kuklinsky, I., 1983. Network Analysis. Sage, Beverly Hills, CA.
Larson, A., 1991. Partner networks: leveraging external ties to improve entrepreneurial performance. Journal of
Business Venturing 6, 173 188.
Larson, A., 1992. Network dyads in entrepreneurial settings: a study of the governance of exchange relationships.
Administrative Science Quarterly 37, 76 104.
Larson, A., Starr, J., 1993. A network model of organization formation. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 17
(2), 5 15.
Lebrasseur, R., Zanibbi, L., Zinger, T., 2003. Growth momentum in early stages of small business start-ups.
International Small Business Journal 21 (3), 315 330.
Lechner, C., Dowling, M., 2000. The evolution of industrial districts and regional networks: the case
of the biotechnology region Munich/Martinsried. Journal of Management and Governance 99 (3),
309 338.
Lechner, C., Dowling, M., 2003. Firm networks: external relationships as sources for the growth and
competitiveness of entrepreneurial firms. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 15, 1 26.
Lee, C., Lee, K., Pennings, J., 2001. Internal capabilities, external networks and performance: a study on
technology-based ventures. Strategic Management Journal 22, 615 640.
Lincoln, J.R., 1982. Intra- (and inter-) organizational networks. In: Bachararan, S. (Ed.), Research in the
Sociology of Organizations, vol. 1. JAI, Greenwich, CN, pp. 1 38.
Lipparini, A., Sobrero, M., 1997. Co-ordinating multi-firm innovative process: entrepreneur and catalyst in small
firm network. In: Ebers, M. (Ed.), The Formation of Inter-Organisational Networks. Oxford University Press,
New York.
Lomi, A., 1997. The Relational Analysis of Organizations. Il Mulino, Bologna.
Lorenzoni, G., 1992. Accordi, reti e vantaggio competitivo. Etas libri, Milano.
Lorenzoni, G., Baden-Fuller, C., 1995. Creating a strategic centre to manage a web of partners. California
Management Review 37 (3), 146 163.
Lorenzoni, G., Lipparini, A., 1999. The leveraging of interfirm relationships as a distinctive organizational
capability: a longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal 20 (4), 317 337.

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

539

Lorenzoni, G., Ornati, O., 1988. Constellations of firms and new ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 3,
41 57.
Lyon, D., Lumpkin, G., Dess, G., 2000. Enhancing entrepreneurial orientation research: operationalizing and
measuring a key strategic decision making process. Journal of Management 26 (5), 1055 1085.
Malecki, E., Poehling, R., 1999. Extroverts and introverts: small manufacturers and their information sources.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 11, 247 268.
McDougall, P., Phillips, P., Covin, J., Robinson, R., Herron, L., 1994. The effects of industry growth and strategic
breadth on new venture performance and strategy content. Strategic Management Journal 15 (7), 537 554.
McEvily, B., Zaheer, A., 1999. Bridging ties: a source of firm heterogeneity in competitive capabilities. Strategic
Management Journal 20 (12), 1133 1156.
McGee, J., Dowling, M., 1994. Using R&D cooperative arrangements to leverage managerial experience: a study
of technology-intensive ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 9, 33 48.
Mitchell, J.C., 1969. The concept and the use of social network. In: Mitchell, J.C. (Ed.), Social Networks in
Urban Situations. Manchester University Press, Manchester, pp. 1 32.
Nohria, N., 1992. Is a network perspective a useful way of studying organisation? In: Eccles, R. (Ed.), Networks
and Organisations. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Orpen, C., 1993. Strategic planning, scanning activities and the financial performance of small firms. Journal of
Small Business and Entrepreneurship 11 (1), 62 72.
Ostgaard, T., Birley, S., 1994. Personal networks and firm competitive strategya strategic or coincidental
match? Journal of Business Venturing 9, 281 305.
Pihkala, T., Varamaki, E., Vesalainen, J., 1999. Virtual organization and the SMEs: a review and model
development. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 11, 335 349.
Podolny, J., Page, K., 1998. Network forms of organization. Annual Review of Sociology 24, 57 76.
Powell, W., 1987. Hybrid organizational arrangements: new form or transitional development? California
Management Review, 67 87 (Fall).
Powell, W., 1990. Neither market nor hierarchy: network forms of organization. Research in Organizational
Behavior 12, 295 336.
Ramachandran, K., Ramnarayan, 1993. Entrepreneurial orientation and networking, some Indian evidence.
Journal of Business Venturing 8 (6), 513 524.
Richardson, G., 1972. The organisation of industry. Economy Journal, 883 896.
Roberts, P., Dowling, G., 2002. Corporate reputation and sustained superior financial performance. Strategic
Management Journal 23 (12), 1077 1092.
Robinson, K., 1999. An examination of the influence of industry structure on eight alternative measures of
new venture performance for high potential independent new ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 14,
165 187.
Rothaermel, F., 2001. Complementary assets, strategic alliances, and the incumbents advantage: an
empirical study of industry and firm effects in the biopharmaceutical industry. Research Policy 30,
1235 1251.
Rothaermel, F., Deeds, D., 2001. More good things are not necessarily better: an empirical study of strategic
alliances, experience effects, and innovative output in high-technology start-ups. Academy of Management
Proceedings. TIM.
Rue, L., Ibrahim, N., 1998. The relationship between planning sophistication and performance in small
businesses. Journal of Small Business Management 36 (4), 24 32.
Sawyer, O., McGee, J., Peterson, M., 2003. Perceived uncertainty and firm performance in SMEsthe role of
personal networking. International Small Business Journal 21 (3), 269 290.
Shane, S., Venkataraman, S., 2000. The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of
Management Review 25, 217 226.
Starr, J., MacMillan, I., 1990. Resource cooptation via social contracting: resource acquisition strategies for new
ventures. Strategic Management Journal 11, 79 92 (Special issue).
Stinchcombe, A., 1965. Social structure and organizations. In: March, J. (Ed.), Handbook of Organization. Rand
McNally, Chicago, IL.
Stuart, T., Hoang, H., Hybels, R., 1999. Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of entrepreneurial
ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly 44 (2), 315 349.

540

C. Lechner et al. / Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2006) 514540

Teach, R., Schwartz, R., Tarpley, F., 1989. The recognition and exploitation of opportunity in the software
industry: a study of surviving firms. In: Brockhaus, R. (Ed.), Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. Babson
College, Wellesley, MA, pp. 383 397.
Thorelli, H., 1986. Networks: between markets and hierarchies. Strategic Management Journal 7 (1), 37 51.
Uzzi, B., 1997. Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: the paradox of embeddedness.
Administrative Science Quarterly 42, 35 67.
Vanderwerf, P., Brush, C., 1989. Achieving empirical progress in an undefined field. Entrepreneurship Theory
and Practice, 45 58 (Winter).
Venkataraman, S., 1997. The distinctive domain of entrepreneurship research: an editors perspective. In: Katz,
J., Brockhaus, J. (Eds.), Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence, and Growth. JAI Press,
Greenwich, CT.
Venkatraman, N., Ramanujam, V., 1987. Measurement of business economic performance: an examination of
method convergence. Journal of Management 13 (1), 109 122.
Venkataraman, S., Van de Ven, A., 1998. Hostile environmental jolts, transaction set, and new business. Journal of
Business Venturing 13, 231 255.
Virtanen, M., 1997. The role of different theories in explaining entrepreneurship. Journal of Best Papers, ICSB
42nd World Conference.
Von Hippel, E., 1978. A customer-active paradigm for industrial product ideas. Research Policy 7, 240 266.
Wassermann, S., Faust, K., 1994. Social Network Analysis. Cambridge University Press, New York.
Weinzimmer, L., Nystrom, P., Freeman, S., 1998. Measuring organizational growth: issues, consequences and
guidelines. Journal of Management 24 (2), 235 262.
Zahra, S., Ireland, R., Hitt, M., 2000. International expansion by new venture firms: international diversity, mode
of market entry, technological learning and performance. Academy of Management Journal 43, 925 950.
Zhao, L., Aram, J., 1995. Networking and growth of young technology-intensive ventures in China. Journal of
Business Venturing 10, 349 370.

Вам также может понравиться