Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 20

World Development Vol. 34, No. 11, pp.

1922–1941, 2006
Ó 2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.11.024

Decentralized Corruption or Corrupt


Decentralization? Community Monitoring
of Poverty-Alleviation Schemes in Eastern India
RENÉ VÉRON
University of Guelph, Ont., Canada

GLYN WILLIAMS
University of Sheffield, UK

*
STUART CORBRIDGE and MANOJ SRIVASTAVA
London School of Economics, UK
Summary. — Democratic decentralization and community participation often stand at the center
of an agenda of ‘‘good governance’’ that aims to reduce corruption and increase the state’s account-
ability to its citizens. However, this paper suggests based on empirical studies on the Employment
Assurance Scheme in rural West Bengal that the strength of upward accountability (especially to
political parties) is as crucial as downward accountability to communities. When these vertical
accountabilities are weak, horizontal accountability structures between local civil society and offi-
cials can mutate into networks of corruption in which ‘‘community’’ actors become accomplices or
primary agents.
Ó 2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — corruption, decentralization, participation, poverty alleviation, West Bengal, India

1. INTRODUCTION means of dealing with corruption and rent-


seeking behavior. The structural adjustment
Development theory has recently paid in- programs that were implemented by the World
creased attention to issues of accountability Bank and the IMF in the 1980s and early 1990s
and transparency. Corrupt practices and sys- thus remained relatively silent on accountabil-
tems are said to undermine growth and access ity structures in non-market institutions. They
to public services, in addition to being morally
repugnant. 1 The question of corruption, how-
ever, is dealt with very differently by competing
intellectual and policy-making traditions.
Drawing on Anne Krueger’s early work on * We would like to acknowledge the financial support of
rent-seeking, many neoliberal economists have the United Kingdom Economic and Social Research
sought to connect landscapes of corruption to Council, as well as the Department for International
the dominance of predatory states or bureau- Development (DFID), for this research. The views pre-
cratic populism. They have recommended the sented in our analysis, however, are our own and
‘‘rolling back’’ of the state—of the license and not necessarily those of DfID. Final revision accepted:
permit raj in the case of India—as the primary November 10, 2005.
1922
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1923

trusted that the expansion of free markets and ernance’’ looks beyond the state sector and
competition would remove the scope for gener- stresses the importance of public participation,
alized rent seeking. but civil society makes an appearance mainly as
After two decades of deregulation and eco- a safeguard against corrupt officials (see World
nomic liberalization, however, levels of political Bank, 2000a). Yet recent critical studies on par-
and bureaucratic corruption seem not to have ticipatory development also reveal the ‘‘funda-
dissipated in most countries, and perhaps least mental weaknesses’’ of many local community
of all in the transitional economies of the institutions that are divided along the lines of
former Soviet bloc (see Humphrey, 2002). class, gender or ethnicity (see Leach, Mearns,
Whereas many hard-liners might insist that cor- & Scoones, 1997). This paper thus takes a crit-
ruption persists only where liberalization has ical look at the practices of civil society, and
been incomplete, or where states have been left at the complex relations—as well as ‘‘blurred
with too many regulatory powers, many donor boundaries’’ (Gupta, 1995)—between the state
agencies are promoting an agenda of ‘‘good and civil society. Such a perspective takes inspi-
governance’’ that seeks to address issues of ration from the works of Harriss-White and
accountability and transparency on a broader White (1996), amongst others. Based on coun-
front. In doing so, they follow political scien- try case studies, Harriss-White and White
tists who increasingly regard corruption as a found that in many cases rent-seeking had in-
sign of ‘‘bad governance.’’ Dhareswar and col- creased under economic liberalization and had
leagues have argued that ‘‘corruption ought to changed its character: corruption was now
be seen as a symptom of the state’s fundamental more likely to be initiated and controlled by ac-
weaknesses, not some basic or single determi- tors in civil society, including businesspersons,
nant of society’s ills’’ (Dhareswar et al., 2000, than it was by state actors. Formal democrati-
p. 136; emphasis added), and that appropriate zation had created opportunities, incentives
designing of political and economic institutions and pressures for politicians and elected offi-
would therefore be capable of defeating wide- cials ‘‘to compensate for political uncertainty
spread rent-seeking (see also Rose-Ackerman, by building up a capital stake through corrup-
1999). 2 Multi-pronged strategies for strength- tion’’ (Harriss-White & White, 1996, p. 3). Cor-
ening good governance—including public- bridge and Kumar (2002) made a similar point
sector and judicial reforms, economic policy in their study of the tree trade in Jharkhand.
measures and financial controls, the strengthen- While their paper argues for a reduction of
ing of civil liberties, and of structures of partic- state controls in some parts of the timber trade,
ipation of civil society—are thus proposed as a they show how local elites and political brokers
way of dealing with bad governance. Proposals have joined with some forest officials in resist-
for decentralization have also cut into initia- ing the deregulation of trade in the jack(fruit)
tives for the promotion of ‘‘good governance’’ tree. Robbins (2000) has further shown that
and have been proposed as a conduit for insti- the rural poor in Rajasthan are driven to par-
tutional public reform that can enhance levels ticipate in the corruption of forms of common
of political accountability, participation and property management from which they might
voice (see World Bank, 2000a, 2001). Decen- be expected to benefit.
tralization now stands at the heart of a bundle This paper aims to go beyond recent
of measures that is meant to enhance state critiques of participatory development that
capabilities (see World Bank, 2000b). focus on the perils of assuming strong and
This comprehensive view of anti-corruption homogenous communities to suggest, in
strategies is an important step forward, and addition, that key members of ‘‘village com-
particularly so when compared to the more munities’’ can be accomplices to, or prime
simplistic perspectives linking reduced corrup- agents of, local networks of corruption. Collu-
tion to a ‘‘rolling back’’ of the state. But the sion can of course transcend the boundaries of
framework of ‘‘good governance’’ continues a community, as Mosse (2001) has shown in
to see state actors as the prime agents of his studies of the Western India Rainfed
corrupt practices—a view that is reflected in Farming Project. In this case it was mostly
the classic and commonly used definition of better-off and male villagers, and ‘‘outsiders’’
corruption as ‘‘the abuse of public office for from the project staff, who joined together
private [economic and political] gain’’ (Dhare- in homogenizing and representing local
swar et al., 2000, p. 137; see also Bardhan, knowledge and local needs. In other cases, a
1997). It is true that the agenda for ‘‘good gov- collision of interests can form ‘‘corruption
1924 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

networks’’—a term we borrow from Jean Car- and perceptions of corruption that are common
tier-Bresson, who found that in France and there. Despite having identical formal institu-
Italy ‘‘the organization of corruption by social tions of local governance and community mon-
networks [. . .] prevails and enables a real insti- itoring, leakage of EAS funds was much higher
tutionalization of procedures’’ that ‘‘turns into in Old Malda than in Debra. In Section 5 we
a political, economic and social exchange’’ take a closer look at corruption networks in
(1997, p. 466). Rent-seeking then consists of Old Malda block, networks in which local
rather more than distortions to simple market councilors, beneficiary-committee members
exchanges or bargains between individuals. and ordinary villagers were all participating.
In certain circumstances, it can lead to the The ‘‘deep’’ decentralization of government
building of social institutions that rely on programs was accompanied here by the decen-
and reinforce trust among their major partici- tralization of corruption to local councilors
pants. who were virtually unaccountable to the com-
These ideas provide useful conceptual start- munity, political parties or the development
ing points for a paper that seeks to illuminate administration. Councilors generally did not
the complex relationships between decentraliza- belong to the traditional elite. They formed a
tion, civil society, and corruption in eastern In- newly emerging class of political entrepreneurs
dia. The objective of our paper is to investigate that had captured the decentralized state for
how formal structures of decentralization and purposes of private gain and which inhibited
participation influence the prevalence, charac- the effective functioning of community-based
ter and spaces of corruption in different social monitoring schemes. In Section 6 we show that
and political settings. We focus on interactions these same formal community monitoring insti-
between the ‘‘community,’’ elected officials and tutions were much more effective in curbing
civil servants that have constrained and enabled corruption in Debra block. If community insti-
the leaking of government funds from India’s tutions were distorted here, it was mainly
Employment Assurance Scheme (EAS) in two because they were subject to the extended arm
localities in rural West Bengal. We chose to of the ruling party, the Communist Party of
analyze the EAS because of its distinctive com- India-Marxist (CPI-M). Indeed, upward
munity-based system of funds monitoring that accountability in the form of effective party-
allows us to draw conclusions on the interrela- political control over local councilors, execut-
tion between participatory decentralization and ing agents and beneficiary committees, was
corruption. However, we do not claim to pro- probably more important for limiting corrup-
vide a representative and comprehensive study tion in Debra than was community participa-
of the level and organization of corruption in tion. The CPI-M effectively controlled leakage
West Bengal or India. 3 Neither do we believe of EAS funds, but not without diverting some
that leakage from the EAS is particularly ram- development money into party coffers. Ironi-
pant. 4 cally, some of these funds from central govern-
In Section 2 we discuss contrasting hypothe- ment were used to strengthen local government.
ses regarding the effects of decentralization on In Section 7 we conclude that participatory
rent-seeking. These focus on the elite capture decentralization is no panacea for reducing cor-
of participatory programs and their distortion ruption, as some factions within communities
by higher level officials. We also explain how are ready to build a nexus with bureaucrats
we tried to deal with the challenge of studying and politicians. Under such circumstances,
corruption empirically. In Section 3 we describe the strengthening of horizontal accountability
the Employment Assurance Scheme (EAS) and structures through decentralization is ineffec-
a monitoring system that can be interpreted as tive in curbing corruption. In the absence of
a mesh of horizontal and vertical accountability effective vertical structures of political and
structures designed to break the nexus of power administrative accountability and control, as
relations that can hold between government well as perceptible judicial involvement, 5 hori-
officers, politicians and private contractors. In zontal accountability structures between local
the next three sections we turn our attention civil society and officials can mutate into net-
to Old Malda block (Malda district) and Debra works of corruption in which ‘‘community’’
block (Midnapore district). Section 4 intro- actors become either primary agents or accom-
duces the social, political and economic settings plices, particularly when communities are di-
of the field sites, and compares the levels, forms vided.
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1925

2. STUDYING CORRUPTION regression analyses based on public perceptions


(e.g., Azfar et al., 2001).
Strong advocacy of administrative and As an example of theoretical modeling, Bard-
democratic decentralization as part of a ‘‘good han and Mookherjee’s analysis of decentralized
governance’’ agenda is based on a number of versus centralized delivery systems in the con-
assumptions. Ostrom, Schroeder, and Wynne text of infrastructure services provides a useful
(1993) suggest that decentralization can pro- point of entry. They conclude that decentraliza-
mote cost-effectiveness, improved accountabil- tion provides welfare gains and lower levels of
ity and reduced corruption. Decentralization corruption only if services are financed with
is said to bring the state closer to its citizens user fees. Where decentralization is financed
(see also Azfar, Kähkönen, & Meagher, with local taxes or central grants, the effect on
2001). Local politicians and elected councilors rent seeking is indeterminate (Bardhan &
are assumed to be more effective and interested Mookherjee, 2001). This obviously applies to
in monitoring the activities of local government anti-poverty programs, including India’s
officers than distant civil servants and auditors Employment Assurance Scheme, where local
because they are open to de-selection (see Bard- governments have authority over implementa-
han & Mookherjee, 2001). In other words, local tion using central grants, but where other forms
elected officials would become accountable of financial devolution, including the collection
‘‘downwards’’ to the local community. Decen- of ‘‘user fees’’ from the beneficiaries, would
tralization can also provide spaces for make little sense in view of stated equity goals.
enhanced rates of participation in civil society. Elsewhere, the same authors analyzed anti-pov-
Participatory decentralization is assumed to in- erty programs more specifically. They deduced
crease local vigilance, particularly when accom- that better cost-effectiveness and reduced
panied by fiscal devolution or the collection of bureaucratic corruption would occur under a
user fees (see Azfar et al., 2001). Proponents of decentralized system of administration despite
decentralization believe that ‘‘horizontal’’ increased coordination problems, lack of econ-
accountability structures between local officials omies of scale and lower capacity at the local
and civil society will reduce the scope for rent government level (Bardhan & Mookherjee,
seeking. From this viewpoint, any failure of 2000). Making use of a principal-agent frame-
decentralization to curb corruption is the result work, they argued that decentralization can
of incomplete or distorted decentralization—or mitigate the problem of high information costs
referring to the title of this paper ‘‘corrupt that exist in bureaucratic top-down systems,
decentralization’’—where too much authority where bottlenecks in communication and diffi-
is retained at the central level. culties in obtaining information constrain the
Empirical studies from India and elsewhere effective monitoring of local officers (agents)
concur that resistance within the bureaucracy by the central authority (principal). 6 However,
can hinder and distort effective democratic the benefits from reduced information costs can
decentralization (see Jha, 1999; Mukarji, easily be outweighed if the capture of local gov-
1999). But effective decentralization also de- ernment and anti-poverty schemes by local
pends on the strength of the communities elites is greater than the extent of elite capture
affected and on underlying informal social, of national government. Elite capture of the
economic and political structures (see Alsop, state at different spatial scales depends on ‘‘tra-
Krishna, & Sjoblom, 2001; Nambiar, 2001). ditions of political participation, voter aware-
Furthermore, political support ‘‘from above’’, ness and literacy, allocation of social and
and in the form of a strong pro-poor govern- economic power within communities, lobbying
ment in power at the center, is crucial in reduc- and campaign contributions by wealthier
ing the risk of elite capture of decentralized groups, fairness and regularity of elections,
state institutions (see Crook & Sverrisson, transparency in local decision-making pro-
2001; Kohli, 1987). Although research on cesses and government accounts, media atten-
decentralization has been expanding rapidly, tion and so on’’ (Bardhan & Mookherjee,
only a few studies have empirically tested 2001, p. 3; see also Bardhan & Mookherjee,
the proposition that decentralization leads to 2000). These authors thus predict less effective
a reduction in the levels of corruption. The and less well targeted implementation of decen-
majority of decentralization-corruption studies tralized programs in regions of high poverty
have been either logical-deductive models or incidence. 7
1926 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

To sum up, decentralization does not neces- ery’’, and that local governments aim ‘‘to max-
sarily reduce corruption, but it can sometimes imize a weighted sum of welfares of two classes
open the door to the abuse of public funds of local users: elites and non-elites’’ (Bardhan &
and the decentralization of corruption (see also Mookherjee, 2001, p. 4). Whether these
Crook & Manor, 1998; Schleifer & Vishny, assumptions are empirically correct or not,
1993). taking individual behavior in a ‘‘market for
Bardhan and Mookherjee’s theoretical mod- corruption’’ as the sole starting point runs the
els usefully point to the crucial importance of danger of not recognizing corruption networks
elite capture, underlying political institutions, embedded in structures of social exchange
and informal social structures including power (Cartier-Bresson, 1997). Individuals may find
relations, awareness and literacy. They are per- it difficult either to stay out of these corruption
haps less successful in grasping the dynamic networks, or to enter into them. In the case of
nature and mutual influence of political institu- the routinized implementation of poverty-alle-
tions, social structures and corruption. The viation schemes in rural India, for example,
state and major political and social structures local-level corruption is well organized and
are presented as given and unchanging, provid- fairly institutionalized, such that even honest
ing a fixed stage on which bureaucrats and pol- officers come under social pressures or even
iticians perform like narrowly rational, threats from their peers to become part of the
economic, or political actors. Such theoretical system of corruption. 8
models rely on sometimes crude assumptions Yet individual agency is responsible for the
about individual behavior and objectives: for dynamic nature of corruption networks, includ-
example, that bureaucrats ‘‘maximize their net ing the tensions and fissures that make them
incomes, that is, bribes less the cost of deliv- more visible (and researchable) to outsiders.

Figure 1. Location of the districts surveyed.


DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1927

We studied corruption in rural West Bengal as Yet this information had to be evaluated in
one part of a collaborative research project that the broader political and social context in order
investigated the state’s activities and roles in to exclude, as far as possible, false or exagger-
relation to rural poverty and empowerment in ated allegations of corruption that were made
five localities in eastern India (see Figure 1). with the objective of damaging a person’s or a
The spheres of activities of the state were di- political party’s reputation. Although obtain-
vided into developmental, empowering, protec- ing access to official files and records was dif-
tive, and disciplinary functions, which were ficult, if not impossible, the triangulation of
studied with reference to the EAS, primary edu- information obtained from different intervie-
cation, tenure- and labor-law enforcement, and wees and observations allowed us to ‘‘crack’’
policing, respectively. In order to capture both the corruption networks, and to draw a fairly
horizontal and vertical accountability struc- clear qualitative picture of corruption and its
tures, and corruption networks that transcend organization in Old Malda and Debra. We
different spatial scales, we moved constantly be- are aware that generalizations about levels
tween the village, block, and district levels. The and organization of corruption from these
team worked intensively in one fairly typical two case studies must be treated with caution.
village community in each of the selected dis- But we trust that the qualitative empirical re-
tricts. Local field assistants and the authors search points to the general problems of decen-
lived with the communities for most of 1999 tralization and corruption. 11
and spring 2000. In addition to using a wide
range of ethnographic methods, we conducted
an extensive questionnaire survey with a strati- 3. MONITORING THE EMPLOYMENT
fied random sample of 100 households, includ- ASSURANCE SCHEME
ing 80 that were identified as ‘‘poor’’ on the
basis of data on assets, employment, household The Government of India was aware that
composition and food security from an earlier corruption networks emerged around the
village census (see also Corbridge, Williams, implementation of poverty-alleviation schemes
Srivastava, & Véron, 2005). The questionnaire when it introduced the Employment Assurance
included a few questions on perceptions of cor- Scheme (EAS) in 1993. Within the EAS and
ruption of officials, and on the fairness of the other recent poverty-alleviation schemes, the
courts and the police. Information was also government particularly attempted to break
gained from informal conversations with indi- the nexus between bureaucrats, politicians and
vidual or groups of villagers. This research gave private builders (contractors) by including local
us insights into local perceptions and under- communities in scheme implementation and
standings of corruption, 9 and pointed to inci- monitoring. 12 At the time of our fieldwork,
dents that could be studied further. However, the EAS was the largest employment provision
these data are limited because many villagers program in India. The central government
did not have a clear picture of the corruption (with 20% matching funds from state govern-
networks at work. In some cases, informants ments) aimed to respond to local employment
also feared retribution and avoided the topic shortages during agricultural slack seasons,
or underplayed its significance. and provide up to 100 days of local employ-
More informative data came from more than ment to a maximum of two adults per house-
40 interviews with local government officers, hold. Like other wage-employment or ‘‘food
elected councilors, contractors, and so on in for work’’ programs, the EAS directly ad-
each locality. It was helpful that our research dressed one of the most pressing needs of the
topic was a broad one, since before raising rural poor, that is, seasonal unemployment.
the issue of corruption with the interviewees The government encouraged the uptake of
we were in many cases able to build trust from labor-intensive projects from which the poor
repeated household and office visits. We also would benefit the most. In each block the labor
must admit that we sometimes needed luck component of expenditure had to average at
to be in the right place at the right time. 10 least 60% (and the material component maxi-
Although there was certainly concealment as mum 40%), with schemes that were focused
well as exaggeration, some interviewees—par- on water and soil conservation measures
ticularly those who stood at, or were pushed (40%), minor irrigation works (20%), roads
to, the margins of the corruption networks— (20%) and school buildings (20%). The pro-
opened up and gave us valuable information. gram was unlikely to be of much interest to
1928 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the better-off villagers, as the principal benefit job worker and the involved government offi-
was short-term unskilled manual labor that cer. The beneficiary committee was to be
was to be paid at the government minimum elected in a special village meeting prior to the
wage. It could therefore be expected that self- start of the works, where villagers were also in-
targeting would be effective, and that uptake formed about the assets to be created and days
by non-poor beneficiaries would be much lower of employment provided with the particular
than in, say, subsidized credit schemes such as project. As the name suggests, the members of
the Integrated Rural Development Program the committee would consist of beneficiaries
(since 1999 known as SGSY, Swaranjayanti of the project and thus be involved in the man-
Gram Swarozgar Yojana). ual work. Community control of the EAS in
But the central and state governments also West Bengal was further strengthened with a
introduced direct measures to curb leakage of ‘‘social audit,’’ namely, the public presentation
EAS funds. They designed a monitoring system of project expenditures in the statutory bian-
that combines a set of accountabilities, includ- nual gram sansad or village meeting for all
ing downward accountability to the commu- (ca. 500–1,000) voters of the electoral ward. 13
nity, horizontal accountability between actors Democratic accountability was ensured by
at the same spatial scale, and upward account- making the panchayats (elected local councils),
ability to higher levels of the bureaucracy. First specifically the panchayat samiti (block council,
of all, the Government of India banned con- intermediate tier between village council [gram
tractors (private professional builders) from panchayat] and district council [zilla parishad])
the execution of EAS projects, which were sup- the implementing agency of the EAS. This
posed to be fairly small. Policymakers believed was possible in West Bengal unlike in most
that these small schemes would not require the other states because the panchayats had been
organizational and technical expertise of pri- well established at the time when the EAS
vate professionals. The exclusion of contractors was introduced in 1993–94. On the recommen-
was expected to reduce leakage, as it would sti- dation of West Bengal’s Department of Panch-
fle the rent-seeking opportunities for govern- ayats and Rural Development, district and
ment officers created by the tender system. block councils could devolve the implementa-
Instead of private contractors, government offi- tion of EAS projects to the gram panchay-
cers such as the Sub-Assistant Engineers at the ats—again strengthening local accountability.
block level and the Job Assistants at the gram The bureaucracy facilitated the implementation
panchayat level were to organize and supervise with their organizational and technical exper-
the works. Furthermore, the guidelines pro- tise and procedures. The Block Development
vided for the appointment of a ‘‘job worker’’ Officer (BDO), the senior-most officer at the
from the community to act as an executing block level, acted as the official executive agent
agent on behalf of the government officers. and was supported by the Block Cashier, Sub-
The job worker was to be elected by the villag- Assistant Engineers, etc. and the gram panch-
ers or to be appointed by the local councils. ayat-level Secretary and Job Assistant.
This local person was believed to be more Table 1 summarizes the responsibilities of
accountable to the community than outside various actors in the local monitoring of the
contractors or government officers and, as a EAS, reflecting the high degree of community
joint beneficiary of newly created village assets, involvement. The executing agent, or job
would have a personal interest in keeping leak- worker, comes from the community itself, and
age low. Therefore, it was expected that job the beneficiary committee and elected local
workers would abstain from common corrupt councilors check the job worker’s activities.
practices, such as over-reporting labor in the While the Sub-Assistant Engineer, and for
muster rolls, underpaying local workers, inflat- smaller works the Job Assistant, take the mea-
ing the figures in the measurement sheets and surements of completed works, their technical
using inferior-quality materials. documentation has to be accompanied by a
The Government of West Bengal attempted completion letter from the beneficiary commit-
to further increase local accountability of the tee. Only then can the BDO and block council
EAS and other anti-poverty programs. The prepare and submit the utilization certificate
state government ordered that for each project, necessary to draw further EAS funds from the
a ‘‘beneficiary committee’’ would have to be central government.
formed with the responsibilities of monitoring This complex multi-actor monitoring system
project implementation and supervising the includes a triangle of local horizontal account-
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1929

Table 1. Local monitoring of the EAS: main actors and responsibilities


Employment records Material supply Measurement Completion Utilization
(Muster Rolls) forms of completed work letter certificate
Job worker (‘‘foreman’’) P P
Beneficiary committee S S P+S
Elected councilors S S
Block council chairperson S
Job assistant/sub-assistant P P+S
engineer
Block Development P+S
Officer
P = Prepare; S = Sign.

ability structures formed by the beneficiary structures. Local government officers are mon-
committee, local councilors and local govern- itored by their seniors, and EAS documents are
ment officers (see Figure 2). Having these three checked at higher levels of the bureaucracy. But
actors check on each other is likely to reduce the local monitoring of the EAS complements
the risk of collusion between any one of them the conventional bureaucratic checks with
and the executing agent, who may well become community accountability and with political
the ‘‘site’’ of leakage (without necessarily being accountability, which are also given promi-
the main instigator) due to the hands-on nence in the decentralization literature.
responsibilities of preparing employment re- Community accountability is expected to be en-
cords (muster rolls), paying laborers and sured through the beneficiary committee that is
arranging the supply of materials. Figure 2 also directly accountable downward to the commu-
indicates that the actors involved in the local nity, as its members are elected or feel moral
monitoring of the EAS are embedded in verti- pressure ‘‘from below.’’ Political accountability
cal (downward and upward) accountability of the councilors to the voters is assumed to be

Political/Democratic
Accountability

Elected
Councilors

Executing
Agent

Beneficiary Local Gov’t


Committee Officers
“Community” Bureaucratic
Accountability Accountability

Figure 2. Monitoring of the Employment Assurance Scheme in West Bengal.


1930 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

effective due to the panchayat elections held Debra’s population is more stable. Substan-
regularly every five years. tial adivasi immigration into a predominantly
general-caste Hindu population occurred about
50 years ago. Social tensions between the main
4. SCOPE AND LEVELS OF CORRUPTION community groups rarely came to the surface in
IN OLD MALDA AND DEBRA the study village. 15 The population is better
educated and politically more conscious than
It can not, of course, be expected that the the one in Old Malda. 68% of the people in
apparently well-designed EAS monitoring sys- the study village are literate, and further efforts
tem would be capable of totally eliminating in child and adult education have been fairly
leakage on the ground, or that the formal mon- successful. Irrigated agriculture provides al-
itoring system would work equally in different most year-round employment, and the land
social, economic and political contexts. There- reforms in the late 1970s have reduced the vul-
fore, it is necessary to illuminate the regional nerability of sharecroppers. But the poverty
context of the case studies and to locate EAS rate is still 45% with 11% of the households fac-
leakage in the wider context of corruption in ing seasonal food insecurity. The CPI-M has
the studied areas. been a dominant presence in the study village,
Old Malda has a diverse population, includ- also forming the block council and the gram
ing general caste Hindus, ‘‘Scheduled Castes’’ panchayat. The party has a strong local organi-
(formerly untouchable castes), ‘‘Scheduled zation with offices in every gram panchayat and
Tribes’ (various adivasi groups), Muslims and committees in every village. Tribal peasants, in
recent clandestine immigrants from nearby particular, formed a strong support base for the
Bangladesh. Serious tensions arise regularly be- CPI-M. By the late 1990s, however, the party
tween these community groups—in our study faced increasing political competition from the
village tensions were mainly between the bet- Trinamool Congress (TC), which enjoyed
ter-off, general-caste Hindu immigrants from growing support among sections of the rural
Bangladesh on the one hand, and the generally middle class.
poor Santals (Scheduled Tribe) and Mal- A glance at the figures in Table 2 on the
pahariya (who are variably regarded as Sched- incidence of corruption as perceived by the
uled Tribe or Caste). But elsewhere in the villagers appears to support Bardhan and
block Hindu–Muslim conflicts are also consid- Mookherjee’s hypothesis that levels of corrup-
erable. Only 48% of the adult population is lit- tion are higher in areas of high poverty and
erate; only 39% of women and less than a illiteracy. Table 2 suggests that the levels of
quarter of the adivasi population have at least corruption were higher in Old Malda than in
basic writing and reading skills. The education Debra: 36% and 10%, respectively, of the villag-
system is malfunctioning, and levels of general ers reported that officials would be corrupt, and
awareness and political consciousness are very most of these allegations were backed up with
low. According to our own household classifi- concrete incidents (these figures probably
cation based on assets, employment and house- under-report perceived corruption to some de-
hold composition, 69% of the households are gree due to respondents’ fear of retribution).
poor, out of which 32% face seasonal food in- Confirming our assumption that rent seeking
security. 14 Rain-fed agriculture provides only behavior of government officers is not the sole
limited and seasonal employment, and many
poor households rely on non-agricultural day
labor in Malda town. Seasonal out-migration Table 2. Villagers’ perception of corruption
is high from September to November when Old Malda (%) Debra (%)
large tracts of land are inundated. The Com-
Yes, they do 36 10
munist Party of India-Marxist (CPI-M) formed
No, they do not 47 86
the block council but shared power with the
Refused to comment 6 0
Indian National Congress (INC) in the gram Do not know 11 4
panchayat. Politics is based around personal-
ized networks of patronage and violence, and Total 100 100
not on strong party organizations. The political Answers to the question whether government officers,
leadership lacked deep roots in the locality (see local councilor or politician would sometimes misuse
Véron, Corbridge, Williams, & Srivastava, their position for personal gain.
2003). Source: Village surveys.
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1931

mover of corruption, villagers in Old Malda Indira Awas housing scheme); that funds from
mentioned as the bribe-taker elected panchayat wage-employment programs (e.g., the EAS)
members twice as often as civil servants. In were diverted; and that nepotism and political
many cases, panchayat members and officers favoritism were endemic. Ordinary villagers
were both mentioned, indicating some aware- rarely found these forms of corruption cultur-
ness of the political-bureaucratic nexus. Re- ally acceptable (see also endnote 8).
ported incidents of corruption in Debra were In the case of the EAS, on which our research
primarily related to political party workers. focused, the findings suggest that skimming-off
Interestingly, 20% of those who mentioned government funds was much more prevalent
any corruption case in either locality did not than the rural poor perhaps realized. Table 4
see themselves as simple victims of corrupt shows that less than one-third of the (relatively
practices. They were content because the pay- few) EAS beneficiaries in Old Malda—but all in
ment of a bribe (ghush) allowed them to access Debra—were paid the minimum wage, which
a government service or benefit to which they the Government of West Bengal had set at
were formally not entitled. Others were upset Rs. 48 (US$ 1.10) per day. Laborers in Old
when the payment of a bribe did not result in Malda, most of whom were not aware of the
prompt delivery of the demanded service. At statutory minimum wage, were underpaid by
a more general level, however, villagers re- 20–65%, with female workers found at the
garded (the system of) corruption as despicable lower end of the wage scale. Through this prac-
(see also endnote 7). The practice of bribery tice alone, circa 15% of the EAS funds were
(even the collection of small bakshish or the siphoned off.
payment of ‘‘speed money’’ [upori ai]) was seen Yet underpaying the intended beneficiaries is
as morally wrong. Arguments (on which we not the only, and rarely the most important,
prompted) that low salaries or honorariums method of diverting money from the EAS. In-
of civil servants and panchayat members, or deed, a number of candid and well-informed
the perquisite of holding public office, would officials and contractors estimated that in Old
justify bribery fell on deaf ears among the very Malda depending on the project anywhere be-
poor in rural West Bengal. tween 40% and 80% of the EAS monies from
In both studied localities, the payment of the central government would be ‘‘absorbed’’
bribes, including ‘‘speed money,’’ between Rs. somewhere between the district headquarters
50 and 500 (US$ 1.10 and 11) for the (faster) and the village. The higher number was sadly
provision of government services (e.g., delivery confirmed when we were able to compare direct
of birth certificates, ration cards and land observations of works being carried out with
deeds) seemed fairly common (see Table 3). official records that had entered the wage paid
However, it was only in Old Malda that a to each laborer under two distinct projects. In
significant number of villagers experienced or another instance, we could confirm that a small
observed that kick-backs amounting to a few road scheme listed in the official records had
thousand rupees had to be paid to receive sub- not been built at all. Local informants in Debra
sidized loans (through schemes such as the Inte- estimated EAS fund leakage to be much lower;
grated Rural Development Programme or the that is around 10%. The regional difference in
leakage also produced a visible impact in the
case of roads built with EAS monies: the
Table 3. Reported incidents and types of corruption
reported by the villagers
Table 4. Payment of statutory minimum wage under the
Old Malda Debra
EAS
Bribe for service 9 7
Old Malda (%) Debra (%)
Kick-back for receiving 5 0
government loan/benefit Minimum wage paid 26 75
Diversion of government 4 1 Below minimum wage 63 0
funds Paid by piece rate 5 0
Nepotism 12 0 Cannot remember 5 25
Unspecified/other 5 2 Total 99% 100%
Total 35 10 (N = 19) (N = 59)
Source: Village surveys. Source: Village surveys.
1932 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

semi-permanent roads in Debra lasted through involved in the direct monitoring of EAS
the monsoon while people in Old Malda were works. Furthermore, rather than appointing a
even in the dry season forced to trample their job worker from among the EAS beneficiaries,
own paths beside unusable roads. 16 elected members of the panchayat themselves
The decentralized EAS monitoring system acted as the executing agent in their respective
clearly allowed for very different levels of fund constituency. They generally had a high level
leakage within West Bengal, and decentrali- of control over small EAS projects. Govern-
zation probably has further accentuated the ment development funds that reached the gram
differences between Debra and Old Malda. panchayat were equally divided between the
Democratic decentralization seems to have re- individual councilors for schemes in their
duced corruption in Debra. Professional build- respective constituency. The local councilors
ers informed us that their ‘‘profits’’ 17 declined enjoyed almost full autonomy when spending
after the introduction of decentralized and par- their allotment for projects, and decentraliza-
ticipatory implementation and monitoring of tion in Old Malda went ‘‘deeper’’ than planned
poverty-alleviation schemes from 50% to 10% for by the government. As de facto executive
on average, and that profits made from schemes and executing agents, the local councilors very
implemented by line departments (e.g., irriga- often brought in contractors and their groups
tion) as opposed to the panchayats were still of young healthy male workers from outside
around 30–40%. Both government officers and the locality, who were able to complete projects
contractors in Debra told us that it was partic- faster and cheaper than the intended local EAS
ularly ‘‘tough’’ to carry out EAS projects be- beneficiaries. This practice benefited councilors
cause of the many political and community from different political parties and, in the
controls. absence of developmental politics, 19 was quite
By contrast, decentralization seems to have successful in paying off the political opposition.
been ineffective, if not counterproductive, to As a result the decentralized monitoring was
curb corruption in Old Malda. Clearly, the ‘‘corrupted’’ at a fairly ‘‘local’’ level (rather
decentralized EAS and community-based mon- than by a distant bureaucracy), and community
itoring met more favorable, social, economic accountability was not given much of a chance
and political preconditions in Debra than in to become effective.
Old Malda. But it would not suffice to regard However, the example of a small pond-dig-
these preconditions as the only factors that ging project also shows that individuals from
determine the impact of decentralization on the community can become part of corruption
corruption. Rather, local agency reworks for- networks. The fairly well-off and respected
mal monitoring institutions, creates corruption NCM who worked for the Congress Party
networks and thus also produces and repro- during elections became a member of the ben-
duces social and political structures. eficiary committee on the suggestion of AB,
the local councilor (from the CPI-M). NCM
explained candidly: ‘‘I have good connections
5. ‘‘DEEP’’ DECENTRALIZATION IN OLD with, and control over, the villagers here. If I
MALDA opposed a project, I would be able to stop it
with the help of my local followers. Fearing
In Old Malda local councilors played an ac- this, [AB] wanted to include me in some
tive role in reworking the formal EAS monitor- way.’’ 20 And things got better when AB
ing system and felt little resistance from decided to use ‘‘his’’ allotment from govern-
ordinary villagers who were kept unaware of ment wage-employment schemes to repair
the EAS and its participatory ideals (see also and deepen a village pond bordering NCM’s
Véron et al., 2003). Local councilors conducted house, where the latter also held a lease with
elections to beneficiary committees in the gram fishing privileges. For this EAS project,
sansads after the panchayat elections in 1998. NCM played an active role as a beneficiary-
But the biannual gram sansads in Old Malda committee member for the first time. As the
were in practice not publicized and thus were main beneficiary of the asset to be created,
unrepresentative forums. 18 For our research he had a strong self-interest in the quick and
village, four better-off people from different technically proper completion of the scheme,
hamlets were mentioned in the gram panchayat and he supervised the works vigilantly as one
records as the members of the beneficiary com- would expect. He was clearly less concerned
mittee, but we found that they were rarely about his poor and underemployed neighbors.
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1933

Rather, NCM and AB brought in contracted tor (50%). The system of fixed ‘‘cuts’’ indicates
workers from elsewhere and paid them at a that these corruption networks, including the
piece rate to do the job quickly and cheaply. involvement of the beneficiary committee, were
AB and NCM then forged the muster roll with fairly institutionalized and stable.
bogus names and thumbprints, and pocketed However, fissures in corruption networks
the difference between the contractor’s bill would at times become visible either due to
and the reported wages. In this way, no local internal conflict or because an external agency
employment has been created but corruption tries to intervene in local practices. The net-
has become decentralized down to the village works can be disturbed, or need to be read-
level. justed, when a new BDO is appointed to the
The decentralization of corruption some- block office to head the lower level government
times goes even further, and involves seemingly officers who have been working there. BDOs
petty amounts at the lowest spatial scales. are from the West Bengal Civil Service—the
While NCM is not poor and could liberally second tier of India’s bureaucracy after the
be regarded as belonging to the local elite, BS prestigious Indian Administrative Service—
comes from a very poor Santal (adivasi) house- and rotate posts every 2–4 years. In some block
hold in which people would go hungry part of offices in Malda district, young and honest
the year. BS knew that the employment of out- BDOs have made attempts to disturb corrup-
side labor for the above-mentioned scheme was tion networks. For example, when AM took
illegal, and he personally approached AB. The up her new post in Old Malda, a Sub-Assistant
youngster, rather than sharing this knowledge Engineer continued the practice adopted under
with his fellow villagers (including those from the previous BDO of sitting together with his
the Santal community), was satisfied when he four contractor-friends and single-handedly
was paid off with Rs. 112 (US$ 2.50)—suppos- giving out contracts for all types of poverty-
edly for two days of supervising the works—to alleviation schemes. AM, who first mistook
keep silent, and so made it easy for the coun- the contractors for her staff, faced a violent
cilor to avoid a public uproar. The generally gherao (blockading of the block office) when
ill-informed and divided community in Old she tried to implement the government schemes
Malda certainly weakened downward accoun- by the book. Even though she was able to have
tabilities, but the few better-informed villagers the said engineer transferred and a more trans-
did little to rectify this and hold councilors or parent public tender system introduced, she
beneficiary-committee members accountable. knows that corruption continues in her office.
Apathetic or dishonest beneficiary-committee Visibly frustrated after one year as BDO of
members were voted out of office only in excep- Old Malda, AM remarked: ‘‘I don’t [can’t] do
tional cases and only when their ousting was anything for the poor here.’’ 21
backed or initiated by political agents. It is true that West Bengal’s effective land re-
These forms of collusion between local polit- form and the reservation of seats in the panch-
ical society and parts of local civil society seem ayats for women, Scheduled Castes and
to be a common feature of poverty-alleviation Scheduled Tribes made it easier for people not
schemes in Old Malda. The fact that those belonging to traditional local elites to play an
few people who knew of the formal existence active part in local councils and local politics
of beneficiary committees (for which the Eng- more generally (see Lieten, 1996). Yet it is also
lish term rather than the Bengali term was common knowledge that a new class of oppor-
used) nicknamed these bodies ‘‘benefit commit- tunistic, ideologically less committed CPI-M
tee’’ or ‘‘benefit company’’ is further proof that councilors and party workers have emerged in
civil society was at least an accomplice of cor- the years after the Left Front Government
ruption. A contractor with ample experience came to power in the state. Individual benefit,
of executing works for poverty-alleviation particularly chances of getting better access to
schemes in the block gave details on the locally salaried government employment, has become
practiced system of ‘‘cuts’’: the ‘‘profit’’ from a an important motive for working for the CPI-
project would be distributed to the beneficiary M and other parties. If anyone, it is this new
committee (5%); the ‘‘party fund’’ (i.e., the local political elite that is capturing the local state
party committee of the CPI-M in Old Malda) in West Bengal. 22 Yet the opportunistic behav-
(5%); the Sub-Assistant Engineer (from where ior of the new political entrepreneurs took a
it is probably further divided up within the peculiar shape in Malda district, where the
bureaucracy) (40%); and the involved contrac- CPI-M and its allies (or any other political
1934 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

party or coalition) were unable to dominate the 6. CONTROLLED CORRUPTION


political landscape continually. In this situation IN DEBRA
of political oscillation, local councilors and
local political brokers could not hope that their Leakage of EAS funds was significantly
party would be able to secure them any longer lower in Debra than in Old Malda. Officers in
term benefit, and so maximizing their short- the district headquarter of Midnapore spoke
term profits by siphoning off government funds enthusiastically about the community mon-
provided a welcome alternative. Their actions itoring of decentralized poverty-alleviation
were barely constrained by political parties that schemes that were seen to be working particu-
were weakly instituted and embedded in the vil- larly effectively in this district because of high
lages: parties cannot keep local councilors on a levels of consciousness, awareness and under-
short leash because they depend on these local standing among the local people of develop-
strongmen to mobilize votes (see Véron et al., ment in general, and poverty-alleviation
2003). Local councilors in Old Malda seemed programs in particular. Adult literacy pro-
less interested in political power; very few of grams were fairly successful in Midnapore,
them ever sought reelection. 23 Rather, political and the population in our study village was
entrepreneurs weighed monetary costs against fairly well educated. Ethnic and class divisions
medium-term returns when they took a deci- were not politicized and rarely led to social ten-
sion to run for public office. The words of a sions. However, such an explanation that cen-
gram panchayat member talking to a BDO ters on attributes of local communities or civil
may be illustrative of this attitude: ‘‘Sir, now society is incomplete despite the apparent posi-
I must make money from these projects to tive correlation between literacy, awareness and
pay for my election expenditures of Rs. communal harmony on the one hand, and re-
50,000–60,000 [US$ 1,150–1,350]. Later, I’ll duced corruption in decentralized schemes on
see that I can make some profit too.’’ the other hand. Before giving full credit to the
Political entrepreneurs in Old Malda gener- apparently ‘‘strong’’ and harmonious commu-
ally are not drawn from the poorest house- nity in Debra, it is necessary to study the actual
holds. Investments in election campaigns (in role this community played (or was allowed to
the form of hand-outs, such as chicken and play) in the monitoring of the EAS.
liquor, to the rural poor, but possibly also in It may come as a surprise that the commu-
the form of kickbacks for party officials and nity-based monitoring system was in some as-
payments to thugs) can be substantial, though pects more profoundly distorted in Debra
are perhaps not always as high as in the than in Old Malda. In particular, the job
above-quoted case. Yet the political entrepre- worker and the beneficiary committee were
neurs do not belong to traditional elites either. not selected democratically—not even in a for-
Local councilor AB, for example, came from malistic sense. In our study village, the CPI-M
a SC household with nine members and an appointed NS, their most influential local party
economically modest background with no supporter, as the job worker for all small gov-
landholdings. Recent ‘‘profits’’ stemming from ernment projects with the exception of a few
public office now allowed him to extend his road schemes. The party also handpicked the
family house. Similarly, DD was in a position beneficiary committee. For nearly all projects,
to acquire a scooter only after his wife became the beneficiary committee consisted of the same
pradhan (village council president). Neighbors four or five people known to be loyal to, and
resent this new private wealth of their official working for, the party. Job worker and benefi-
democratic representatives, but they are inca- ciary-committee members therefore were not
pable of hindering its dishonest creation recog- directly accountable downward to the commu-
nizing that ‘‘the villagers are not united and nity. Their position was not debated or chal-
organized’’ and feeling that they cannot turn lenged in public village meetings, in part
to anyone because ‘‘all from the lower levels because of their fairly good track record and
work together.’’ 24 Clientelism also made it dif- in part because of the apparent futility of
ficult for ordinary villagers to take open action openly opposing the CPI-M’s command, given
against their patrons, including political bro- the party’s strong hold over the village and the
kers and councilors, who are needed to provide existing political majorities. But once appointed
access to crucial public goods such as disaster both job worker and beneficiary committee
relief and police protection (see Véron et al., were involved in scheme monitoring as pre-
2003). scribed by the guidelines.
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1935

The CPI-M’s strong hand in selecting loyal such as using bits of public road-building mate-
supporters for the formalized community insti- rial on their private house path. The lack of for-
tutions of implementing and monitoring pov- mal direct accountability ‘‘downwards’’ to the
erty-alleviation schemes in Debra should be community was compensated—and perhaps
seen in the wider context of the party’s strategy more than compensated—with the job worker’s
of controlling corruption and its decentraliza- and beneficiary committee’s political account-
tion—in the sense of both managing or orga- ability ‘‘upwards’’ to the CPI-M. This does
nizing corruption and constraining or limiting not mean, however, that downward accounta-
it. Even after more than 20 years in power at bilities were irrelevant. The job worker was
the state and local levels, the local CPI-M constantly monitored informally by laborers
seemed fearful that the formal community- on the scheme and people passing by. Because
based institutions would be captured by tradi- public information meetings were held before
tional elites, who have largely maintained their the start of each scheme, people knew about
economic power as employers and moneylend- project goals in terms of employment and asset
ers but lost their political significance (see Wil- creation. Furthermore, the local council facili-
liams, Véron, Corbridge, & Srivastava, 2003). tated a social audit by distributing leaflets on
The vanguard party showed little trust in local expenditure for each completed project.
civil society and uncontrolled democratic pro- Finally, the CPI-M was accountable to the vot-
cesses, and tried to keep control over the new ers, and corruption was made a major election
local elites, including councilors and party issue by the main opposition, the Trinamool
workers, through their strong and hierarchical Congress (TC).
party organization. 25 At the same time, the Yet the ruling party faced a dilemma. On the
CPI-M measured its success in terms of ‘‘devel- one hand, curbing corruption is important for
opment’’ and felt pressure from voters to electoral success. On the other hand, political
deliver services efficiently due to increasing corruption is an effective way of enhancing
political competition. Therefore, individual party loyalties and motivation to work for the
local councilors were not allowed to pick and party when people are rewarded with better
execute their own private schemes as their access to government benefits or jobs. Also,
counterparts in Old Malda did, but the CPI- voluntary contributions would not suffice to fi-
M-dominated village and block councils nance the party machinery given the CPI-M’s
short-listed and integrated project proposals electoral base among the rural poor. In order
emerging from the gram sansad. Also, the party to balance these conflicting political impera-
did not tolerate personal corruption of their tives, the party needed to manage corruption
‘‘lowers,’’ and in the past had not hesitated to by narrowing the spaces of private and bureau-
remove corrupt councilors from public office. cratic bribery while diverting some government
The story of a former chairperson of the block funds into the party coffers. The common use
council (sabhapati), who was dismissed from of the term ‘‘party donation’’ (besides ‘‘profit’’)
public office by the CPI-M in 1993 and subse- as the short-hand for corruption indicates that
quently lost all his political connections and the CPI-M was partly successful in implement-
capital, was still in everybody’s mind, and sent ing this strategy. 26
a warning signal to active party supporters and The mid-level cadres of the CPI-M thus dis-
councilors. They often invest considerable time torted the community-based EAS monitoring
and effort in party work and, although their not only because of the fear of elite capture
motives may not always be opportunistic, could but in part also in order to facilitate the diver-
lose much when shunned by the party. On the sion of central and state government funds into
other hand, the CPI-M sometimes rewards the party coffers. 27 One of the reasons for the
honest and effective councilors. For example, party to appoint loyal party supporters as job
the party was able to arrange salaried govern- workers and beneficiary-committee members
ment employment for the hardworking pradhan seemed to be to cover up corrupt practices that
in our study village. could financially benefit the party. It was not
The party’s control of decentralization was always necessary that all beneficiary-committee
effective in curbing corruption at lower levels members were involved in this practice. In the
and among community-based organizations. studied village, only one member had sufficient
Job workers and beneficiary committees were literacy and numeracy skills to effectively check
by and large honest, and may only occasionally muster rolls and measurement sheets. The job
have taken a little advantage of their position, worker NS admitted that the others ‘‘were not
1936 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

able to sign without my help.’’ 28 With the councilors appeared to be more difficult, and
increasing strength of the political opposition leakage from gram panchayat schemes seemed
and more open challenges to CPI-M dom- much lower. For example, gram panchayat
ination in some parts of Debra, however, records showed cases in which a few hundred
politically mixed beneficiary committees had rupees left over from one project were immedi-
become more common and constituted about ately spent on additional micro-projects rather
half of the committees in the block. The BDO than diverted.
received an increasing number of allegations Apart from direct project-related payments,
of irregularities mostly from such mixed benefi- professional builders were expected to make
ciary committees. Although many of these alle- ‘‘party donations’’ at particular times. For
gations were based on scant evidence and were example, they were asked to donate Rs. 5,000
perhaps quite strategically employed to gain to finance a party-organized ‘‘cultural’’ event
political mileage, they indicate that cover-ups during Hul, an adivasi festival in May, which
had become more difficult than in entirely was used to represent the CPI-M as the bene-
CPI-M controlled beneficiary committees. In factor of the local Santal and Bhumij communi-
some cases, complaints were substantiated, ties and less subtly as a platform for political
and this encouraged accused councilors, con- speeches.
tractors and government officers to put the The development funds diverted into party
works right before an official inquiry was coffers were spent to finance election campaigns
launched. and the party machinery more generally. Inter-
The organization of corruption in Debra in- estingly, the CPI-M also used these funds to
cluded an element of spatial management that support their pradhans and top up their low
also made the diversion of government funds honorariums provided by the state government.
more ‘‘orderly’’ than in Old Malda. The block This additional remuneration made it possible
administration and council set up two ways of for many pradhans to focus on their work in
implementing schemes: non-road schemes were public office and without searching for addi-
implemented by the gram panchayat and exe- tional income from private economic activities.
cuted by local job workers; road schemes were It is ironic that the institutionalized and con-
implemented by the block council with the help trolled diversion of decentralized funds from
of contractors. Gram panchayat-level employ- the central government in some ways helped
ees and councilors were made to believe that to strengthen local governance and effective
this practice adhered to the official guidelines. political decentralization. Corruption in this
It is true that bigger and technically more particular case (which is admittedly not the
demanding projects needed to be implemented norm) was perhaps not a form of ‘‘bad gover-
by the block because of their superior technical nance’’ altogether.
capacities and expertise. The use of profes-
sional builders as opposed to local job work-
ers—though formally prohibited—can be 7. CONCLUSIONS
justified on technical grounds as well, but pri-
vate builders also received publicly tendered Democratic decentralization is no panacea
contracts for small and technically less for reducing corruption even when local com-
demanding road schemes. In these block munities are formally included in implementing
schemes the contractors acted as the conduit and monitoring policies, programs and
for leakage, 29 and it is suspected that profits schemes. As economic and political interests
were shared with the Sub-Assistant Engineer vary within communities, some factions are
and the CPI-M representatives. But the pol- ready to build a nexus with bureaucrats and
itical and bureaucratic actors embedded in politicians and become willing participants in
separate vertical accountability systems also corruption networks. The impact of participa-
checked on each other, and so kept the diver- tory decentralization on the levels of corruption
sion of development funds within ‘‘reasonable’’ is therefore ambiguous.
limits. Recently, the relationship between con- The underlying social structures can also
tractor, political party and civil servant had inhibit participation of the poor and mar-
been increasingly disturbed more profoundly ginalized, and thus render democratic decen-
by the less partisan beneficiary committees. tralization and community-based monitoring
Diversion of development funds through local less effective. These findings are in line with
job workers and under the supervision of local Bardhan and Mookherjee’s deductive model
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1937

which predicts that under unequal or clientelist In parallel, ‘‘corrupt decentralization’’—or


conditions, existing local elites are able to cap- the distortion of community-based monitoring
ture the local state so that decentralization relo- systems—occurred in Old Malda and Debra,
cates corruption to the locally powerful and in both cases caused not by a resisting bureau-
leads to the ‘‘decentralized corruption’’ of our cracy or ‘‘higher’’ levels of government but by
title. In contrast to that model, however, our councilors and local political cadres. In Old
empirical study indicates that social structures Malda, this distortion took the form of with-
should not be regarded as given: decentraliza- holding information from villagers and not
tion itself may produce and reproduce them. employing local job workers and beneficiary
In Old Malda, for example, the introduction committees. This made the diversion of devel-
of the panchayat system and the decentralized opment funds easier. In Debra, the bending of
implementation of poverty-alleviation schemes rules, particularly the appointment of politi-
created the conditions for a new class of politi- cally biased job workers and beneficiary com-
cal entrepreneurs to emerge that eventually mittees, also allowed more leakage. However,
captured substantial parts of state benefits. the diverted funds mostly ended in party coffers
These political entrepreneurs do not necessarily and were in part used to strengthen local gov-
belong to the traditional elites and include ernment. The term ‘‘corrupt decentralization’’
political brokers and local councilors who have ironically gets an additional meaning here; that
strong roots in local communities. The bound- is, decentralization made stronger through cor-
aries between local political society and local ruption. Corruption is therefore not always
communities are blurred, and it is unhelpful ‘‘bad governance’’ or a ‘‘symptom of the state’s
to locate rent-seeking neatly and clearly outside fundamental weakness.’’
the realm of ‘‘communities.’’ The findings from the two case studies sug-
Elite capture also took place in Debra, but gest that the strength of upward accountability
the net effects on corruption were fairly posi- (especially to political parties) is at least as
tive. Mid-level cadres of the CPI-M largely con- influential as downward accountability to com-
trolled the implementation of the EAS and munities. When these vertical accountabilities
effectively checked on formal community insti- are weak, horizontal accountability structures
tutions, local councilors and bureaucrats. The designed into community-based monitoring
capture of decentralized poverty-alleviation systems can degenerate into corruption net-
schemes by elites who are committed to pro- works between community representatives,
poor development obviously generates more local elected officials and local government offi-
positive effects than the capture by political cers. This, in turn, reinforces the argument that
entrepreneurs who are largely unconstrained effective decentralization paradoxically depends
in privately looting government development on strong centralized government institutions
funds. or a strong centralized political party.

NOTES

1. Pranab Bardhan provides a good review of the dominant partners in corrupt exchange while in the
debate on the effects of corruption on economic clientelist settlement, well-organized social groups are
efficiency. He challenges the notion that corruption capable of challenging the (property) rights that are
would be the ‘‘much-needed grease for the squeaking of weakly defined and enforced by the state. Corrupt
wheels of a rigid administration’’ (1997, p. 1322), transactions under the more prevalent clientelist settle-
because corruption does not necessarily mitigate market ment normally lead to inefficient outcomes. Because of
distortions. Schleifer and Vishny (1993) distinguish the interests of the existing powerful clients, rights will
between centralized bribery (to one independent monop- not be reallocated even if this had socially desirable
olist) and decentralized bribery (to more than one outcomes and if it helped the officials to maximize their
monopolist) and show that the former involves more bribes (Khan, 1996; see also Khan & Jomo, 2000). For a
predictability and certainty for the bribe-giver and thus comprehensive collection of key articles on corruption,
entails less adverse economic effects. Khan (1996) see also Heidenheimer, Johnston, and LeVine (1989).
introduces a more precise typology of corruption that
is based on the political settlement between the patron 2. Olivier de Sardan (1999) provides an interesting
(state actors taking bribes) and the bribe-paying clients. critique of the political–economy approach to corruption
In the patrimonial settlement, state actors are the and anti-corruption. Without falling into the traps of
1938 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

cultural essentialism or modernization theory, he sees esis. In South Korea local part-time farmers, who could
corruption in the African contexts as ‘‘socially embedded be monitored easily by the village community, were
in [post-colonial cultural] ‘logics’ of negotiation, gift- appointed for the maintenance of irrigation canals. This,
giving, solidarity, predatory authority, and redistributive as well as better communication and supervision systems
accumulation’’ (Olivier de Sardan, 1999, p. 25). within the bureaucracy, made the governmental service
delivery more effective than in India where local irriga-
3. See Myrdal (1968), Noorani (1973), Sahai (1995), tion officials were accountable to their seniors in the
Mitra (1998), Visvanathan and Sethi (1998), and Gill bureaucracy rather than to the end users (Wade, 1997).
(1998) for more general assessments of administrative
and political corruption in India. While Myrdal 7. In a recent empirical study of poverty-alleviation
acknowledged the ‘‘legacy from traditional society’’ programs in 89 villages in West Bengal, Bardhan and
(1968, p. 950) of strong loyalties to caste and kin that Mookherjee found supportive evidence for their theo-
would facilitate nepotism, he was concerned that corrupt retical conclusions: low leakage and proper targeting to
practices would start entering higher levels of bureau- the poor was best in villages with equal land distribu-
cracy and polity. Adding to Myrdal’s analysis, Noorani tion, higher literacy rates among the poor and contested
(1973) was able to trace back modern India’s roots of local elections. They explain these results with limited
high-level corruption to the fact that Nehru seemed to accountability of gram panchayats in situations of high
tolerate the corrupt practices of some of his ministers. socioeconomic and political inequality at the local level
Expanding on these views, recent observers state that (Bardhan & Mookherjee, 2003).
ever-increasing corruption now has penetrated all levels
of society and has become all-pervasive. Indeed, cor- 8. A crude typology of individuals in relation to
ruption and bribery are a constant in India’s current corruption networks could distinguish between the
public and media discourses. Parry (2000), however, primary agents or instigators, willing participants,
cautions us that the popular impression of ever-increas- reluctant participants and non-participants.
ing corruption may be less based on actual experience
than on an increased commitment to the values of an 9. Contra a cultural relativist viewpoint, we found that
impersonal state, including the demarcation of public the villagers had similar conceptions of corruption and
and private (see also Gupta, 1995). of what constitutes a corrupt practice to our own. The
Bengali brasthachar and the more colloquially used
4. In our research sites, levels of everyday corruption in durniti are more or less synonymous with the English
education, for example, through teachers’ failure to give word corruption. Niti means the ‘‘social conduct to
classes and consequent need for private tuition, were make a humane society’’ or, put more simply, ‘‘policy.’’
higher than the amounts diverted in the more occasional Niti can go wrong or bad and then becomes durniti. This
EAS projects and other poverty-alleviation schemes. vernacular interpretation of corruption is surprisingly
This observation corresponds with a survey from close to the current ‘‘Western’’ views found in the ‘‘good
Transparency International that suggests that Indians governance’’ literature. We therefore share Jonathan
pay an annual total of Rs. 267 billion (c. US$ 6 billion, Parry’s belief that ordinary Indians have ‘‘to some extent
or US$ 6 per person) in the form of bribes while the internalised the universalistic and impersonal values
health, education and power sectors account for the associated with modern bureaucracy’’ (2000, p. 29).
most of this (Times of India, December 17, 2002).
Unfortunately, the study only assesses bribery in line 10. For example, we were able to engage our local
departments so that a comparison of programs imple- landlord in Old Malda, who was a major player in the
mented by local governments cannot be made. But contractor business, in a conversation on corruption at a
studies on developmental and poverty-alleviation pro- time when he was planning to move out of this business.
grams show that West Bengal’s panchayats were able to He was therefore willing to explain to us the corruption
direct a significant portion of government benefits to the network with its institutionalized ‘‘cuts’’ (percentages),
poor (see Bardhan & Mookherjee, 2003). and vented his frustration with political leaders and
bureaucrats. (He later revised his plans to change
5. In our field-level research, we did not come across profession and stopped being so candid about the
any cases of corruption that had been dealt with in the corruption networks in place.)
courts. If the judiciary is underrepresented in our study,
it is a result of our research focus on poor people’s 11. Collecting sufficient quantitative data on local
interactions with the state and low-level corruption. corruption for detailed statistical comparisons is noto-
riously difficult (and potentially misleading, if the
6. Robert Wade’s comparative study on irrigation indicators used are decontextualized or subject to local
system in South Korea and India supports this hypoth- variation). The approach we describe here—using a
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1939

combination of qualitative materials, carefully triangu- narrow definition of a poverty line was used in the study
lated—provides insights into the underlying processes to categorize a population from which a sample could be
and relationships of corruption, but leaves out questions drawn for more in-depth research. We acknowledge, of
about the degree to which these findings are more course, that income and assets are not the only impor-
broadly representative. Our confidence that they are tant dimensions of poverty.
stems in part from the detailed discussion of our analysis
of the operation of EAS in a series of workshops held in 15. The situation was less harmonious in neighboring
West Bengal in December 2000 and January 2001 (for Keshpur block where conflicts between the CPI-M and
details see Véron, Williams, Sarkar, Srivastava, & the Trinamool Congress caused hundreds of people to
Corbridge, 2001; Williams, Srivastava, Corbridge, & be temporarily displaced in 2000. The violence caused 43
Véron, 2003). In these workshops, a range of politicians, deaths between January and October.
civil servants and academics were able to comment on
our methods and findings: although our methods were 16. Part of the difference in visible quality of roads
treated with some skepticism by social scientists built under the EAS also has to be explained with
schooled in a strong quantitative tradition, our analysis geological and climatic factors. In the alluvial delta of
was broadly viewed to highlight issues of accountability Old Malda, roads are more likely to be washed away
important across the state, and not just within the than on the lateritic soils in Debra.
specific field areas of our study. Generally, there are only
a very few ethnographic studies that focus on corruption 17. ‘‘Profit’’ (rather than the Bengali labh) was used to
at the local level in India. The more sensational high- describe the extent of diversion of government funds
level corruption involving larger amounts of money is into private pockets.
more often the subject of academic and journalistic
writings. Exceptions are Parry (2000), Gupta (1995) and 18. Only one fifth of the voters in Old Malda have ever
Wade (1982). attended a gram sansad meeting. In Debra, more than
half of the people remembered to have attended such a
12. A more radical interpretation—following Ferguson meeting in the past.
(1990) and Scott (1998)—could view the inclusion of
local communities in implementing and monitoring 19. We elaborated elsewhere (Véron et al., 2003) on the
poverty-alleviation schemes as an attempt of the state politics in Malda district that is conducted with little
to extend its control over them by instilling the govern- sustained reference to ‘‘development.’’
ment’s criteria of successful development projects and
making communities accomplices in the state’s modern- 20. Interview, October 29, 1999.
ist project.
21. Interview, November 23, 1999.
13. After the 73rd and 74th Constitutional Amend-
ments that required the creation of local elected 22. At ‘‘higher’’ levels of governance in Malda, tradi-
governments (panchayats, and their municipal counter- tional social and economic elites were more prevalent,
parts) across the whole of India, various states have particularly in the Indian National Congress, which is
attempted to use gram sabhas or equivalent meetings as strong here compared with other areas in West Bengal.
mechanisms for achieving public accountability. For The longstanding Member of (the national) Parliament
reviews of how these meetings have worked in practice, from Malda, Abi Ghan Choudhuri from the Congress
see Alsop et al. (2001), Deshpande and Murthy (2002), party, is the son of the biggest landowning, and former
Nambiar (2001). A more radical form of social audit is zamindar, family of the area. A descendant from a minor
the public hearings in Rajasthan led by the NGO zamindar family was the Member of (the state)
Mazdoor Kisan Shakti Sangathan (MKSS) (see Bhatia Legislative Assembly from the urban area of Malda.
& Drèze, 1998). The partial decline of the Congress at the expense of the
BJP and TC, whose leaders come from a new and
14. We defined a poverty line around a household that growing economic elite of businesspeople and profes-
depends solely on unskilled labor, but has full employ- sionals, is a further indication that traditional elites are
ment and a favorable ratio of income earners to losing political power. There are a few surviving leaders
dependants. Equivalents for ownership of land and of the anti-colonial struggle in the communist parties of
animals, access to income from skilled jobs and under- the district. However, their role in the district leadership
employment were set in order to categorize the house- has become representational at best. One well respected
holds of the studied villages as either poor or non-poor. ‘‘veteran’’ and member of the CPI(M), for example, is
Given the low wages for unskilled labor, this poverty shown around during visits of party uppers from
line is comparatively strict, and tends to fall below Kolkata, but he spends his everyday life working in a
India’s official consumption-based poverty line. This garage.
1940 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

23. When politics occasionally was put before individ- 26. Such ‘‘party donations’’ by contractors are not the
ual rent-seeking, it could take violent, even criminal only source of income for political parties in India that is
forms. During the severe floods of 1998, for example, a needed to pay the high election expenses. Parties raise
dam badly needed repair to protect a huge settlement. money in a ‘‘market for public office’’ in which bureau-
But politicians forced the appointed contractor to crats, for example, pay bribes to politicians for transfers
further damage the dam with the objective of harming into (or avoidance of) particular posts (see also Wade,
the nearby village, which is an INC stronghold. In this 1982).
way, the CPM leaders hoped to demonstrate the
powerlessness of the political opposition. 27. It was beyond the scope of the research to study the
party-political or administrative diversion of develop-
ment funds at the state and national levels.
24. Group interviews, November 11, 1999.

28. Interview, September 1, 1999.


25. We have described the CPI-M’s methods to
ensure flow of information from below in a hierar- 29. We were not able to determine whether ‘‘profits’’
chical party organization elsewhere (Williams, Véron, were systemically built in to project estimates by
et al., 2003). inflating material and labor costs.

REFERENCES

Alsop, R., Krishna, A., & Sjoblom, D. (2001). Inclusion tality in India. Cambridge: Cambridge University
and local elected governments: The panchayat raj Press.
system in India. Social Development Paper 37. Crook, R., & Sverrisson, A. S. (2001). Decentralisation
Available from Social Development group, The and poverty-alleviation in developing countries: a
World Bank. comparative analysis, or is West Bengal unique? IDS
Azfar, O., Kähkönen, S., & Meagher, P. (2001). Con- Working Paper 130. Brighton: Institute of Develop-
ditions for effective decentralized governance: a ment Studies.
synthesis of research findings [mimeo]. Available Crook, R., & Manor, J. (1998). Democracy and decen-
from http://www.inform.umd.edu/IRIS/IRIS/PEG/ tralisation in South Asia and West Africa. Cambridge:
synthesis_paper.pdf. Cambridge University Press.
Bardhan, P. (1997). Corruption and development: a Deshpande, S. V., & Murthy, G. B. V. (2002). Pressures
review of issues. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, from below: decentralised governance in Karnataka.
1320–1346. Economic and Political Weekly, 37(May 4).
Bardhan, P., & Mookherjee, D. (2000). Decentralizing Dhareswar, A., Kauf, Dailami M., Kishor, N., Lopez,
anti-poverty program delivery in developing coun- R. E., Wang, Y., & Thomas, V. (2000). The quality of
tries [working paper]. Available from http://globe- growth. Oxford, & Washington DC: Oxford Univer-
trotter.berkeley.edu/macarthur/inequality/papers/ sity Press, & The World Bank.
decdelpov.pdf. Ferguson, J. (1990). The anti-politics machine: Develop-
Bardhan, P., & Mookherjee, D. (2001). Corruption and ment, depoliticization, and bureaucratic power in
decentralization of infrastructure delivery in devel- Lesotho. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
oping countries [working paper]. Available from Gill, S. S. (1998). The pathology of corruption. New
http://econ.bu.edu/dilipm/wkpap.htm/ddinf.pdf. Delhi: Harper Collins Publishers.
Bardhan, P., & Mookherjee, D. (2003). Poverty allevi- Gupta, A. (1995). Blurred boundaries: the discourse of
ation effort of West Bengal panchayats [working corruption, the culture of politics and the imagined
paper]. Available from http://globetrotter.berke- state. American Ethnologist, 22, 375–402.
ley.edu/macarthur/inequality/papers/BardhMookh- Harriss-White, B., & White, G. (1996). Corruption,
Panchayats.pdf. liberalization and democracy: editorial introduction.
Bhatia, B., & Drèze, J. (1998). For development and IDS Bulletin, 27(2), 1–5.
democracy. Frontline, 15(4), Available from http:// Heidenheimer, A. J., Johnston, M., & LeVine, V. T.
www.flonnet.com. (Eds.) (1989). Political corruption. New Brunswick:
Cartier-Bresson, J. (1997). Corruption networks, trans- Transaction.
action security and illegal social exchange. Political Humphrey, C. (2002). The unmaking of Soviet life:
Studies, 45, 463–476. Everyday economies after socialism. Ithaca: Cornell
Corbridge, S., & Kumar, S. (2002). Community, cor- University Press.
ruption, landscape: tales from the tree trade. Political Jha, S. N. (1999). Introduction. In S. N. Jha, & P. C.
Geography, 21, 765–788. Mathur (Eds.). Decentralisation and local politics:
Corbridge, S., Williams, G., Srivastava, M., & Véron, R. Readings in Indian government and politics (Vol. 2,
(2005). Seeing the state: governance and governmen- pp. 13–44). London: Sage.
DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION OR CORRUPT DECENTRALIZATION 1941

Khan, M. H. (1996). A typology of corrupt transactions Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and government:
in developing countries. IDS Bulletin, 27(2), 13–21. Causes, consequences and reform. Cambridge: Cam-
Khan, M., & Jomo, K. S. (Eds.) (2000). Rents, rent- bridge University Press.
seeking and economic development: Theory and evi- Sahai, S. B. (1995). Politics of corruption: The goddess
dence in Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University that failed. New Delhi: Gyan Publishing.
Press. Schleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Corruption.
Kohli, A. (1987). The state and poverty in India: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 599–617.
politics of reform. Cambridge: Cambridge University Scott, J. C. (1998). Seeing like a state: How certain
Press. schemes to improve the human condition have failed.
Krueger, A. O. (1973). The political economy of the New Haven: Yale University Press.
rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, Times of India (2002). Indians pay Rs. 26,728 cr as bribe
291–303. annually. (December 17).
Leach, M., Mearns, R., & Scoones, I. (Eds.) (1997). Véron, R., Corbridge, S., Williams, G., & Srivastava, M.
Community-based sustainable development: Consen- (2003). The everyday state and political society in
sus or conflict? IDS Bulletin, 28(4), 4–14. eastern India: structuring access to the Employment
Lieten, G. K. (1996). Development, devolution and Assurance Scheme. Journal of Development Studies,
democracy: Village discourse in West Bengal. New 39(5), 1–28.
Delhi: Sage. Véron, R., Williams, G., Sarkar, D., Srivastava, M., &
Mitra, C. (1998). The corrupt society: The criminalization Corbridge, S. (2001). Enhancing pro-poor gover-
of India from Independence to the 1990s. New Delhi: nance in West Bengal and Bihar, India (West
Viking. Bengal). Final Report to Department for Interna-
Mosse, D. (2001). People’s knowledge, participation and tional Development, United Kingdom.
patronage: operations and representations in rural Visvanathan, S., & Sethi, H. (1998). Foul play: Chron-
development. In B. Cooke, & U. Kothari (Eds.), icles of corruption, 1947–97. New Delhi: Banyan
Participation: The new tyranny? (pp. 16–35). London: Books.
Zed. Wade, R. (1982). The system of administrative and
Mukarji, N. (1999). The third stratum. In S. N. Jha, & P. political corruption: canal irrigation in south India.
C. Mathur (Eds.). Decentralisation and local politics: Journal of Development Studies, 18(3), 287–328.
Readings in Indian government and politics (Vol. 2, Wade, R. (1997). How infrastructure agencies motivate
pp. 70–82). London: Sage. staff: canal irrigation in India and in the Republic of
Myrdal, G. (1968). Asian drama: An enquiry into the Korea. In A. Mody (Ed.), Infrastructure strategies in
poverty of nations (Vol. 2). New York: The Twentieth East Asia (pp. 109–130). Washington DC: The
Century Fund. World Bank.
Nambiar, M. (2001). Making the Gram Sabha work. Williams, G., Srivastava, M., Corbridge, S., & Véron, R.
Economic and Political Weekly, 36(August 18). (2003). Enhancing pro-poor governance in eastern
Noorani, A. G. (1973). Ministers’ misconduct. Delhi: India: participation, politics and action research.
Vikas Publishing. Progress in Development Studies, 3(2), 159–178.
Olivier de Sardan, J. P. (1999). A moral economy of Williams, G., Véron, R., Corbridge, S., & Srivastava, M.
corruption in Africa?. The Journal of Modern African (2003). Participation and power: poor people’s
Studies, 37(1), 25–52. engagement with India’s Employment Assurance
Ostrom, E., Schroeder, L., & Wynne, S. (1993). Institu- Scheme. Development and Change, 34(1), 163–193.
tional incentives and sustainable development: Infra- World Bank (2000a). World Development Report 2000/
structure policies in perspective. Boulder: Westview 2001: Attacking poverty. Washington, DC: The
Press. World Bank.
Parry, J. (2000). The ‘‘crisis of corruption’’ and ‘‘the idea World Bank (2000b). Reforming public institutions and
of India’’: a worm’s eye view. In I. Pardo (Ed.), The strengthening governance: A World Bank strategy.
morals of legitimacy (pp. 27–55). New York and Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Oxford: Berghahn Press. World Bank (2001). Multi-pronged strategies for
Robbins, P. (2000). The rotten institutions: corruption in combating corruption [WWW page]. Available
natural resource management. Political Geography, from www1.worldbank.org/publicsector/anticorrupt/
19, 423–443. strategies.htm.

Вам также может понравиться