Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 5

A gravity model for global value chains | VOX, CEPRs Policy Portal

VOX

http://www.voxeu.org/article/gravity-model-global-value-chains

Create account | Login | Subscribe

CEPR's Policy Portal

Research-based policy analysis and commentary from leading economists

Columns
By Topic

Vox Views
By Date

People

By Reads

ePubs

Debates

Events

JMP Vox

WWI

Jobs

About

By Tag

Gravity chains: Estimating bilateral trade flows


when parts and components trade is important
Richard Baldwin, Daria Taglioni 10 June 2012
Global value chains are transforming world trade patterns. This column argues that the standard gravity
formulation cannot be applied to trade flows where parts and components are important. This is because GDPs
in origin and destination countries are poor proxies for supply and demand for parts and components. It shows
that the standard model performs poorly on such flows and suggests an alternative specification.

Richard Baldwin
Professor of International
Economics, Graduate Institute,

65

Geneva; Director of CEPR;


VoxEU.org Editor-in-Chief

International supply chains are transforming the world.


They revolutionised development options facing poor nations now they can join supply
chains rather than having to invest decades in building their own.
Astoundingly fast industrialisation is the result for developing nations who have chosen the right
policies and have a high-tech neighbour.
Offshoring of labour-intensive manufacturing stages and the attendant international mobility of
firm-specific technology launched era-defining growth in emerging markets.
Historic income gaps are narrowing as the North de-industrialises and the South industrialises
(Deband 2006) -- a reversal of fortunes that constitutes perhaps the most momentous global
economic change in the last 100 years. As Figures 1 and 2 show, this is happening very quickly.

Daria Taglioni
Senior Economist at the World
Bank

Don't Miss
Figure 1. Reversal of the big income divergence

Rethinking macroeconomic
policy: Introduction
Blanchard
New CEPR Report: A New
Start for the Eurozone:
Dealing with Debt
Editors
Catalyst? TTIPs impact on
the Rest
Evenett, Low
The myth of Europes Little
Ice Age
Kelly, Grda
Robots, productivity, and
jobs
Michaels

Source: World Databank from 1960; Maddison pre-1960.


Note: Pre-1960, G7=W Europe, US, Canada, Australia & N Zealand

Figure 2. G7 share of global manufacturing

Oil prices and the value of


oil currencies
Btzer, Habib, Stracca
Capital taxation in the 21st
century
Auerbach
ECB minutes: What they
really tell us
Wyplosz
Greece: No escape from the
inevitable
Feld, Schmidt, Schnabel,
Weigert, Wieland
Brief history of middle-class
economics

1 of 5

23/04/2015 2:12 CH

A gravity model for global value chains | VOX, CEPRs Policy Portal

http://www.voxeu.org/article/gravity-model-global-value-chains

Furman

Averting a Greek train wreck


Burda
Premature
deindustrialisation in the
developing world
Rodrik
Capital in the 21st Century
Attanasio, Besley, Haldane,
ORourke, Piketty, Ventura
Combatting Eurozone
deflation: QE for the people
Muellbauer

Source: UN online database, unstats.un.org

Macroprudentialism A new
Vox eBook
Schoenmaker

Note: HQ economies = G7; other factory economies = Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, Singapore, India, Indonesia, Brazil,

Larry Summers on Secular


Stagnation

Mexico, and Turkey.

The rise in global supply chains is also transforming international trade patterns, as trade in
intermediates becomes more and more important. This change in trade patterns requires a
rethinking of the standard workhorse model to understand trade flows, i.e. the gravity model.

The gravity model


A standard tool in assessing bilateral trades causes and effects is the gravity model. In a recent
paper (Baldwin and Taglioni 2011), we show that the gravity equation is not valid for trade flows
where trade in parts and components is important.
The basic point is simple.
The standard gravity equation is derived from a consumer expenditure equation with the
relative price eliminated using a general equilibrium constraint (Anderson 1979, Bergstrand
1985, 1989, 1990).
As such the standard formulation and empirical application (Anderson and van Wincoop 2003)
is best adapted to explaining trade in consumer goods.
When consumer trade dominates, the GDP of the destination nation is a good proxy for consumer
demand; the GDP of the origin nation is a good proxy of its total supply.
When international trade in intermediate goods dominates, the use of GDPs for the supply
and demand proxies is less appropriate.
Consider, for instance, the determinants of Thai imports of auto parts from the Philippines. The
standard formulation would use Thai GDP to explain Thailands import demand, however, the
underlying demand for parts is generated by Thai gross production of autos, not its value-added in
autos. As long as the ratio of local to imported content does not change, value added is a
reasonable proxy for gross output, so the standard regression is likely to give reasonable results.
However, for regions where production networks are emerging, value added can be expected to be
a poor proxy for consumer demand.
We use the Krugman and Venables (1996) model to explore the impact of allowing intermediates
trade in the gravity model. The key differences show up in the definition of the economic mass
variables since purchases are now driven both by consumer demand (for which income is the
demand shifter) and intermediate demand (for which total production is the demand shifter).

Four principles for an


effective state
Tirole

Most Read
This Month

All TIme

The myth of Europes Little


Ice Age
Kelly, Grda

How did the ECB save the


Eurozone without spending a
single euro?
Microeconomic origins of
macroeconomic tail risks
Acemoglu

A historical look at deflation


Borio, Hofmann

Demographic structure and


the macroeconomy

Vox A/V
Capital in the 21st
Century

Besley, 28 January 2015


Listen | Open Player

More Vox A/V

Subscribe
@VoxEU
RSS Feeds
Weekly Digest

This observation generates a number of testable hypotheses.


The estimated coefficient on the GDPs should be lower for nations where parts trade is
important, and should fall as the importance of parts trade rises.
As vertical-specialisation trade has become more important in recent years, the GDP point
estimates should now be lower.
In those cases where the GDPs of the trade partners lose explanatory power, bilateral trade
should be increasingly well explained by demand in third countries.
For example, Chinas imports should shift from being explained by Chinas GDP to being explained
by its exports to, say, the US and the EU. There are two ways of phrasing this hypothesis. First,
Chinas imports are a function of its exports rather than its own GDP. Second, Chinas imports are a
function of US and EU GDP rather than its own, since US and EU GDP are critical determinants of

2 of 5

23/04/2015 2:12 CH

A gravity model for global value chains | VOX, CEPRs Policy Portal

http://www.voxeu.org/article/gravity-model-global-value-chains

their imports from China.

Gravity when parts-and-components trade is important


To examine these conjectures empirically, we estimate the standard gravity model for different sets
of countries and sectors for a panel that spans from 1967 to 2007, allowing for yearly interaction
terms. The results for Factory Asia countries, displayed in Figure 3, show the GDP coefficients
falling over time, with two clear breaks in the estimated coefficients, 1985 and 1998. The timing and
direction of these structural changes are very much in line with the literature on the
internationalisation of production.
Figure 3. GDP coefficients for Factory Asia countries, 1967-2008

Notes: Estimated mass-elasticity coefficients with year interactions and pair fixed effects (as in 10). High and low bars
show plus/minus 2 standard errors; Factory Asia countries: Japan, Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, and
Taiwan.

These results are highly suggestive. On data that is known as being dominated by parts and
components trade, we find the mass-variable coefficient moving in the expected direction. However,
on data where this sort of production fragmentation is not widely viewed as having been important,
we find that that mass point-estimates are stable over time.
Whats more, when we include the ratio of intermediates to total trade as a regressor, both on its
own and more importantly as an interaction with the economic mass variable, we find importer
GDP matters less for countries that import a larger share of intermediates).

A search for mass proxies when intermediates are important


Theory suggests that the perfect solution would require data on total costs to proxy for demand for
intermediates imports. If the economy is reasonably competitive, gross sales would be a good proxy
for the total costs. Unfortunately, such data are not available for a wide range of nations especially
the developing nations where production fragmentation is so important. On the mass variable for
the origin nation, theory suggests that we use gross output rather than value added. Again such
data are not widely available.
To find a proxy, we start with the destination nations mass variable. The total flow of goods is the
sum of consumer goods, whose demand depends upon the importing nations GDP and
intermediate goods whose demand depends upon the total costs of the sector buying the relevant
intermediates. This suggests a first measure that adds imports of intermediates to GDP .
To proxy for supply inthe origin nation, we are trying to capture gross output. Our proposed measure
for output size adds purchases of intermediate inputs from all sources (except from itself due to a
lack of data) to value added in manufacturing.
Using these proxies we are able to fit the data more precisely that with standard gravity equations
The R-squares, which measure the share of the data that can be explained by the model, increase
from to etc etc

Why do incorrectly-specified mass variables matter?


A large number of gravity studies focus on variables that vary across country pairs say free trade

3 of 5

23/04/2015 2:12 CH

A gravity model for global value chains | VOX, CEPRs Policy Portal

http://www.voxeu.org/article/gravity-model-global-value-chains

agreements, cultural ties, or immigrant networks. The most recent of these studies employ
estimators that control for the mass variables with fixed effects. Such studies do not suffer from
mass-variable mis-specification and so are unaffected by our critique. There are however a number
of recent studies especially concerning the distance puzzle that do proxy for the production and
demand variables with GDP. It is these studies that our work speaks to.1
Since most of these studies are concerned with a broad set of nations and commodities, the
mis-specification of the mass variable probably has a minor impact on the results as the findings
of Bergstrand and Egger (2010) showed. More worrying, however, is the use by authors that focus
on trade in parts and components such as Athukorala and Yamashita (2006), Kimura et al (2007),
Yokota and Kazuhiko (2008), and Ando and Kimura (2009). These papers all use the consumer
good version of the gravity model to describe parts and components trade and thus have
mis-specified the mass variable.

Summary
We present empirical evidence that the standard gravity model performs poorly by some measures
when it is applied to bilateral flows where parts and components trade is important.
Our paper also provides a simple theoretical foundation for a modified gravity equation that is suited
to explaining trade where international supply chains are important. Finally we suggest ways in
which the theoretical model can be implemented empirically.
Our fix is a long way from perfect, but we hope it shows other researchers that it would be worth
looking for something that works even better!

References
Debande, Oliver (2006). De-industrialisation, European Investment Bank Papers, Volume 11 No 1.
Anderson, James and Eric van Wincoop (2003). "Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border
Puzzle," American Economic Review, vol. 93(1), pages 170-192,
Anderson, James (1979), The theoretical foundation for the gravity equation, American Economic
Review 69, 106-116.
Ando, Mitsuyo and Fukunari Kimura (2009). Fragmentation in East Asia: Further Evidence, ERIA
Discussion Paper Series, DP-2009-20, October.
Athukorala, P. and N. Yamashita (2006), Production Fragmentation and Trade Integration: East
Asia in a Global Context, The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 17, 3, 233-256.
Baldwin, Richard and Daria Taglioni (2007). Gravity for dummies and dummies for gravity
equations NBER WP 12516, published as "Trade effects of the euro: A comparison of estimators,
Journal of Economic Integration, 22(4), December, pp 780818. 2007.
Bergstrand, Jeffrey (1985), The Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some Microeconomic
Foundations and Empirical Evidence, Review of Economics and Statistics, 1985, 67:3, August, pp.
474-81.
Bergstrand, Jeffrey and Peter Egger (2010) A General Equilibrium Theory for Estimating Gravity
Equations of Bilateral FDI, Final Goods Trade and Intermediate Goods Trade, in S. Brakman and P.
Van Bergeijk (eds) The Gravity Model in International Trade: Advances and Applications,
Cambridge University Press, New York.
Grossman, Gene M. and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg (2008). "Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of
Offshoring," American Economic Review, vol. 98(5), pages 1978-97, December.
Kimura, F., Y. Takahashi and K. Hayakawa (2007), Fragmentation and Parts and Components
Trade: Comparison between East Asia and Europe, The North American Journal of Economics and
Finance, 18, 1, 23-40.
Kimura, Fukunari, Yuya Takahashi and Kazunobu Hayakawa (2007). "Fragmentation and parts and
components trade: Comparison between East Asia and Europe," The North American Journal of
Economics and Finance, vol. 18(1), pages 23-40.
Krugman Paul and Anthony Venables (1996) Intergration, specialisation, and adjustment
European Economic Review 40, pp. 959-967.
Yi, K-M (2003). Can Vertical Specialization Explain the Growth of World Trade? The Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 111, No. 1 (Feb.), pp. 52-102.

4 of 5

23/04/2015 2:12 CH

A gravity model for global value chains | VOX, CEPRs Policy Portal

http://www.voxeu.org/article/gravity-model-global-value-chains

Yokota, Kazuhiko (2008). Parts and Components Trade and Production Networks in East Asia -A
Panel Gravity Approach, Chapter 3 in Hiratsuka & Uchida eds., Vertical Specialization and
Economic Integration in East Asia, Chosakenkyu-Hokokusho, IDE-JETRO, 2008.

1For example, Rauch (1999), Brun et al (2005), Berthelon and Freund (2008), and Jacks et al (2008) use GDP as the
mass variable when they decompose the change in the trade flow into the effects of income changes and trade cost
changes; Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003) also use GDP as the mass variable in one of their estimation techniques.

65

Topics: International trade


Tags: Gravity, value chains, parts and components, bilateral flows
Log in or register to post comments

16,032 reads
Printer-friendly version

5 of 5

23/04/2015 2:12 CH

Вам также может понравиться