Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 63

Shumba600@yahoo.co.

uk
Investment and Portfolio Management
Session 1
Nature and scope of investment
What is investment?
Investment is the sacrifice of certain present value for (possibly uncertain) future
value. It deals with financial markets and security pricing. Investment fields
comprise the buy and the sell side. The buy side include management of pension
funds, insurance companies, mutual funds as well as providing advice and
management of individuals retirement funds and other savings. A manager of a
pension fund for example may participate in determining how much of the fund
should be invested in stocks and bonds, which stocks and bonds should be
purchased, and when specific stocks and bonds should be sold.
The sell side includes security analysis which requires analysing economic,
market and financial information and brokerage related tasks which involve
selling securities and executing trades for customers. A security analyst for
example may specialize in a particular focus on the major firms in that industry.
Using economic market and company specific information, the analyst may
evaluate the performance of a particular companys stock and make forecasts
with respect to the companys future earnings.
Investment vs. savings
Savings represent forgone consumption, with the former restricted to real
investment of the sort that increases national output in the future. While this
definition may prove useful in other contexts, it is not especially helpful for
analysing the specifics of particular investments for even large classes of
investment media. A deposit in a savings account at a bank is investment in the
eyes of the depositor. Even cash stored in the mattress can be viewed as
investment: one yielding a dollar for every dollar invested (or less in the event of
fire or theft)
Real VS Financial Investment
Some investments are simply transactions among people. Others involve nature.
The latter are real investment; the former are not.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

Buy a bond/loan

Buy factory

Financial investment

Real investment

In a complex modern economy, much investment is of the financial rather than


the real variety. But highly developed institutions for financial investments greatly
facilitate real investment. By far and large, the two forms are complimentary, not
competitive.

Investment Speculation and Gambling


Investmen to commit (money) in order to earn a financial return.
t
To assume a business risk in hope of gain; especially to buy
speculate or sell in expectation of profit from market fluctuations
To bet on an uncertain outcome.
gamble

All the three definitions fall within the scope of investment as defined.
The term speculate is sometimes used to identify the horizon of the investor, e.g.
someone who buys a piece of land on which to build a house in which to live
might be termed an investor, while a real estate agent also buys the land and
builds a house for almost immediate resale might be termed a specular. The
former - direct benefits - the later - others evaluate of those benefits (i.e. price
at the onset).
A speculator trades on the basis of information she believes is not yet known to
or properly evaluated by others. An investor makes no such assumption.
Some people use the term speculative to refer to high risk investments, possibly
without commensurately high return. e.g. a new stock issue may be denoted a

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
speculative investment. A final use of the term speculative is simply to denote
activities of which you disapprove. ones friends are investors, ones enemies are
speculators.
Gamble
A person might be considered a gambler if he or she takes on a risk that is
greater than commensurate with expected return. e.g. playing lotto the risk is
great, yet on average the players return is negative. Investment at he stock
market is also risk but the return is positive on average.
FOCUS OF THE OUTLINE
- Investment Environment and the part if plays in successful decision
making.
o Characteristic of investment assets and markets in which they are
traded. We summarise the general nature of financial investments
how the markets for them operate.
o Summary measures of the returns the investment have generated
in the past.
- Capital Market Theory
o Develop an integrative theory of optimal decision making and
shows how prices are formed in competitive financial markets in a
way that reflects the expectations and preferences of all markets
participants.
o Models how rational investors make decision in an uncertain
environment.
- Valuation of Securities
o Valuation of instruments e.g. stocks, bonds, options
o Characteristics that determine value of securities
o Forecasting, financial planning and portfolio choice and
performance measurement.
CAREERS IN INVESTMENT FILED
1. Securities Analyst analyse and report on companies and industries
considering economic and market conditions, making recommendations that
assist investors with their investment decisions.
2. Portfolio Review Associate review the performance o f mutual funds
portfolios and present the review to clients.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
3. Financial Planner analyse and advice clients on asset allocation and
investment selection to help them achieve their investment goals.
4. Hedging and Arbitrage Manager for fixed investment securities create a
profit centre through trading and hedging in fixed income securities and
derivatives.
5. Options Specialist identify and analyse option hedging strategies that
include listed options, commodities options, commodities and stock options.
6. Pension Fund Portfolio Manager - manage assets held by the pension fund
for the future benefit if employees, determining the assets allocation and
selection of securities appropriate for the investment objectives and policies of
the pension funds.
7. Stockbroker advise clients regarding potential investments and execute
clients trade orders to buy or sell investment.
Session 2
FINANCIAL MARKETS
A financial market is a market where financial assets are exchanged (i.e. traded).
Although the existence of a financial market is not a necessary condition for the
creation and exchange of a financial asset, in most economies financial assets
are created and subsequently traded in some type of organised financial market
structure.
Properties of Financial Assets
Financial assets have certain properties that determine or influence their
attractiveness to different classes of investors. The ten properties of financial
assets are
1. moneyness
2. divisibility and denomination
3. reversibility
4. term to maturity
5. liquidity
6. convertibility
7. currency
8. cash flow and return predictability
9. complexity
10. tax status.
Each property will be described below.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

Moneyness- some financial assets are used as a medium of exchange or in


settlement of transactions. These assets are called money. In Zimbabwe they
consist of currency and all forms of deposits that permit cheque writing. Other
financial assets, although not money, are very close to money in that they can be
transformed into money at little cost, delay, or risk. They are referred to as near
money. In Zimbabwe, these include time and savings deposits and a security
issued by the government with a maturity of three months called a three-month
Treasury Bills. Moneyness is clearly a desirable property for investors.
Divisibility and denomination divisibility relates to the minimum size at
which a financial asset can be liquidated and exchanged for money. The smaller
the size, the more the financial asset is divisible. A financial asset such as a
deposit at a bank is typically infinitely divisible (down to the penny), but other
financial assets have varying degrees of divisibility depending on their
denomination, which is the dollar value of the amount that each unit of the asset
will pay at maturity. Thus many bonds come in $1 00 denominations. In general,
divisibility is desirable for investors.
Reversibility reversibility refers to the cost of investing in a financial asset
and then getting out of it and back into cash again. Consequently, reversibility is
also referred to as round-trip cost.
A financial asset such as a deposit at a bank is obviously highly reversible
because usually there is no charge for adding to or withdrawing from it. Other
transaction costs may be unavoidable, but these are small. For financial assets
traded in organized markets or with market makers, the most relevant
component of round- trip cost is the so called bid-ask spread, to which might be
added commissions and the time and cost, if any, of delivering the asset. The bidask spread is the difference between the price that a market maker is willing to
sell a financial asset for (i.e., the price it is asking) and the price that a market
maker is willing to buy the financial asset for (i.e., the price it is bidding). For
example, if a market maker is willing to sell some financial asset for $70.50 (the
ask price) and buy it for $70.00 ( the bid price), the bid ask spread is $0.50. The
bid ask spread is also referred to as the bid offer spread.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The spread charged by a market maker varies sharply from one financial asset to
another, reflecting primarily the amount of risk the market maker is assuming by
making a market. This market making risk can be related to two main forces. One
is the variability of the price as measured, say, by some measure of dispersion of
the relative price over time. The greater the variability, the greater the probability
of the market maker incurring a loss in excess of a stated bound between the
time of buying and reselling the financial asset. The variability of prices differs
widely across financial assets. Three-month treasury bills, for example have a
very stable price, while a common stock generally tends to exhibit much larger
short run variations.
The second determining factor of the bid-ask spread charged by a market maker
is what is commonly refereed to as the thickness of the market which is
essentially the prevailing rate at which buying and selling orders reach the market
maker (i.e. the frequency of transactions). A thin market is one which has few
trades on a regular or continuing basis. Clearly, the greater the frequency of
orders coming into the market for the financial asset (referred to as the order
flow), the shorter the time that the financial asset will have to be held in the
market makers inventory, and hence the smaller the probability of an
unfavourable price movement while held.
Thickness also varies from market to market. A three month Treasury bill is easily
the thickest market in the world. In contrast, trading in stock of small companies
is said to be thin. Because treasury bills dominate other instruments both in price
stability and thickness, the bid ask spread tends to be the smallest in the market.
A low round trip cost is clearly a desirable property of a financial asset, and as a
result, thickness itself is a valuable property. This explains the potential
advantage of a large over smaller markets (economies of scale), and a markets
endeavour to standardise the instruments offered to the public.
Term to maturity the term to maturity is the length of the interval until the
date when the instrument is scheduled to make its final payment, or the owner is
entitled to demand liquidation. Often, term to maturity is simply referred to as
maturity, and this is the practice that we will follow in this course.
Instruments for which the creditor can ask for repayment at any time, such as
checking accounts and many savings accounts, are called demand instruments.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Maturity is an important characteristic of financial assets such as debt
instruments and in the Zimbabwe can range from one day to 100 years. Many
other instruments, including equities, have no maturity and are thus a form of
perpetual instruments.
It should be understood that even a financial asset with a stated maturity may
terminate before its stated maturity. This may occur for several reasons including
bankruptcy or reorganisation, or because of provisions entitling the debtor to
repay in advance, or the investor may have the privilege of asking for early
repayment.
Liquidity liquidity is an important and widely used notion, although there is at
present no uniformly accepted definition of liquidity. A useful way to think of
liquidity and illiquidity proposed by Professor James Tobin, is in terms of how
much sellers stand to lose if they wish to sell immediately as against engaging in
a costly and time consuming search.
An example of a quite illiquid financial asset is the stock of a small corporation or
the bond issued by a small school district, for which the market is extremely thin,
and one must search for one of a very few suitable buyers. Less suitable buyers
including speculators and market makers, may be located more promptly, but will
have to be enticed to invest in the illiquid financial asset by an appropriate
discount in price.
For many other financial assets, liquidity is determined by contractual
arrangements. Ordinary deposits at a bank, for example, are perfectly liquid
because the bank has a contractual obligation to convert them at par on demand.
In contrast, financial contracts representing a claim on a private pension fund
may be regarded as totally illiquid, because these can be cashed only at
retirement.
Liquidity may depend not only on the financial asset but also on the quantity one
wishes to sell(or buy). While a small quantity may be quite liquid, a large lot may
run into illiquidity problems. Note that liquidity is again closely related to whether
a market is thick or thin. Thinness always has the effect of increasing the round
trip cost, even of a liquid financial asset. But beyond some point it becomes an

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
obstacle to the formation of a market, and has a direct effect on the illiquidity of
the financial asset
Convertibility An important property of some financial assets is that they are
convertible into other financial assets. In some cases, the conversion takes place
within one class of financial assets, as when a bond is converted into another
bond. In other situations, the conversion spans classes. For example, a corporate
convertible bond is a bond that the bondholder can change into equity shares.
There is preferred stock that may be convertible into common stock. The timing,
costs, and conditions for conversion are clearly spelled out in the legal
descriptions of the convertible security at the time it is issued.
Currency most financial assets are denominated in one currency, such as
dollars or yen or deutsche marks, and investors must choose them with that
feature in mind. Some issuers, responding to investors wishes to reduce foreign
exchange risk, have issued dual currency securities. For example, some pay
interest in one currency but principal or redemption value in a second. Further,
some bonds carry a currency option which allows the investor to specify that
payments of either interest or principal be made in either one of two major
currencies.
Cash flow and return predictability as explained earlier, the return that an
investor will realise by holding a financial asset depends on the cash flow that is
expected to be received. This includes dividend payments on stock and interest
payments on debt instruments, as well as the repayment of principal for a debt
instrument and the expected sale price of a stock. Therefore, the predictability of
the expected return depends on the predictability is a basic property of financial
assets, in that it is a major determinant of their value. Assuming investors are risk
averse, as we will see in later chapters, the riskness of an asset can be equated
with the uncertainty or unpredictability of its return.
In a world of non-negligible inflation, it is further important to distinguish between
nominal expected return and the real expected return. The nominal expected
return considers the dollars that re expected to be received but does not adjust
those dollars to take into consideration changes in their purchasing power. The
real expected return is the nominal expected return but after adjustment for the
loss of purchasing power of the financial asset as a result of inflation.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
For example, if the nominal expected return for a one year investment of $1 000
is 6%, then at the end of one year, the investor expects to realize $1060,
consisting of interest of $60 and the repayment of the $1 000 investment.
However, if the inflation rate over the same period of time is expected to be 4%,
then the purchasing power of $1060 is only $1019.23 ($1060 divided by 1.04).
Thus the return in terms of purchasing power, or real expected return, is 1.9%. In
general, the real expected return can be approximated by subtracting from the
nominal expected return the expected inflation rate. In our example, it is
approximately 2% (6% minus 4%).
Complexity - some financial assets are complex in the sense that they are
actually combinations of two or more simpler assets. To find the true value of
such an asset, one must decompose it into its component parts and price each
component separately. We will encounter numerous complex financial assets
throughout this book. Indeed, there have been many innovations involving debt
instruments since the early 1990s that have resulted in complex financial assets.
Most complex financial assets involve a choice or option granted to the issuer or
investor to do something to alter the cash flow. Because the value of such
financial assets depends on the value of the choices or options granted to the
issuer or investor, it becomes essential to understand how to determine the value
of an option.
Tax status an important feature of any financial asset is its tax status.
Governmental codes for taxing the income from the ownership or sale of financial
assets vary widely if not wildly. Tax rates differ from year to year, country to
country, and even among municipal units within a country (as with state and local
taxes in the Zimbabwe). Moreover, tax rates may differ from financial asset to
financial asset, depending on the type of issuer, the length of time the asset is
held, the nature of the owner, and so on.

The role of financial Assets


Financial markets have two principal economic functions. The first is to transfer
funds from those who have surplus funds to invest to those who need funds to
invest in tangible assets. The second function is transferring funds in such a way

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
as to redistribute the unavoidable risk associated with the cash flow generated by
tangible assets among those seeking and those providing the funds. However,
the claims held by the final wealth holders are generally different from the
liabilities issued by the final demanders of funds because of the activity of entities
operating in financial markets, called financial intermediaries, who seek to
transform the final liabilities into different financial assets which the public prefers.
Financial markets provided three additional economic functions. First the
interactions of buyers and sellers in the financial market determine the price of
the traded asset; or equivalently, the required return on a financial asset is
determined. The inducement for firms to acquire funds depends on the required
return that investors demand, and it is this feature of the financial markets that
signals how the funds in the economy should be allocated among financial
assets. This is called the price discovery process.
Second, financial markets provide a mechanism for an investor to sell a financial
asset. Because of this feature, it is said that a financial market offers liquidity, an
attractive feature when circumstances either force or motivate an investor to sell.
In the absence of liquidity, the owner will be forced to hold a debt instrument until
it matures and an equity instrument until the company is either voluntarily or
involuntarily liquidated. While all financial markets provide some form of liquidity,
the degree of liquidity is one of the factors that characterize different markets.
The third economic function of a financial market is that it reduces the search and
information costs of transacting. Search costs represent explicit costs, such as
the money spent to advertise the desire to sell or purchase a financial asset, and
implicit costs, such as the value of time spent in locating a counterpart. The
presence of some form of organized financial market reduces search costs.
Information costs are those entailed with assessing the investment merits of a
financial asset, that is, the amount and the likelihood of the cash flow expected to
be generated. In an efficient market, prices reflect the aggregate information
collected by all market participants.
Classification of financial markets
There are many ways to classify financial markets. One way is by the type of
financial claim. The claims traded in a financial market may be either for a fixed
dollar amount or a residual amount. the former financial assets are referred to as
debt instruments, and the financial market in which such instruments are traded

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
is referred to as the debt market. The latter financial assets are call equity
instruments and the financial market where such instruments are traded is
referred to as the equity market. Alternatively, this market is referred to as the
stock market. Preferred stock is an equity claim that entitles the investor to
receive a fixed dollar amount. Consequently, preferred stock shares
characteristic of instruments classified as part of the debt market and the equity
market. Generally, debt instruments and preferred stock are classified as part of
the fixed income market. The sector of the stock market that does not include
preferred stock is called the common stock market. These classifications are
summarized in figure 1-2.
Classification of Financial Markets by Type of Claim.
Fixed dollar amount claim

Debt instrument

Fixed income market

Debt market

Residual or equity claim

Preferred stock

Common stock

Equity (stock)
market

Common stock
market

Another way to classify financial markets is by the maturity of the claims. For
example, there is a financial market for short-term financial assets, called the
money market and one for longer maturity financial assets, called the capital
market. The traditional cut off between short term and long term is one year.
That is a financial asset with a maturity of one year or less is considered short
term and therefore part of the money market. A financial asset with a maturity of
more than one year is part of the capital market. Thus, the debt market can be
divided into those debt instruments which are part of the money market and part
of the capital market depending on the number of years to maturity. Since equity

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
instruments are generally perpetual, they are classified as part of the capital
market. This is depicted in figure 1-3.
Figure 1 - 3
Classification of Financial Markets by Maturity of Claim
Debt instruments

Maturity one year or


less

Money market

Common stock & preferred


stock
Maturity greater than one
year

Capital market

A third way to classify financial markets is by whether the financial claims are
newly issued or not. When an issuer sells a new financial asset to the public, it is
said to issue the financial asset. The market for a newly issued financial asset is
called the primary market. After a certain period of time, the financial asset is
bought and sold, (i.e. Exchanged or traded) amongst investors. The market
where this takes place is referred to as the secondary market.
Finally, a market can be classified by its organisational structure. These
organisational structures can be classified as auction markets, over the counter
markets and intermediate markets.
Globalisation of financial markets.
Globalisation means the integration of financial markets throughout the world
into an international financial market. Because of the globalisation of financial
markets, entities in any country seeking to raise funds need not be limited to
their domestic financial market. Nor are investors in a country limited to the
financial assets issued in domestic market.
The factors that have led to the integration of financial markets are: deregulation
or liberalisation of markets and the activities of market participants in key
financial centres of the world, technological advances for monitoring world

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
markets, executing orders and analysing financial opportunities, and increased
institutionalisation of financial markets. These factors are mutually exclusive.
Global competition has forces governments to deregulate or liberalise various
aspects of their financial markets so that their financial enterprises can compete
effectively around the world. Technological advances have increased the
integration and efficiency of the global financial market. Advances in
telecommunication systems link market participants throughout the world with the
result that orders can be executed within seconds. Advances in computer
technology, coupled with advanced telecommunication systems allow the
transmission of real time information on security prices and other key information
to many participants in many places. Therefore, many investors can monitor
global markets and simultaneously assess how this information will impact the
risk/reward profile of their portfolios. Significantly, improved computing power
allows the instant manipulation of real time market information so that attractive
investment opportunities can be identified. Once these opportunities are
identified, telecommunication systems permit the rapid execution of orders to
capture them.
The shifting of the roles of the two types of investors, retail and institutional
investors, in financial markets is the third factor that has led to the integration of
financial markets. Figure 1-4: Classification of Global Financial Markets

Internal market
(also called national market)

Domestic market

External market
(also called international
market, offshore market
and Euro market)

Foreign market

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The foreign market of a country is where the securities of issuers not domicile in
the country are sold and traded. The rules governing the issuance of foreign
securities are those imposed by regulatory authorities where the security is
issued. The external market, also called the international market includes
securities with the following distinguishing features: at issuance they are offered
simultaneously to investors in a number of countries, and they are issued out side
the jurisdiction of any single country. The external market is commonly referred to
as the offshore market or more popularly the Euro market (even though this
market is not limited to Europe, it began there).
Derivative markets
Some contracts give the contract holder either the obligation or the choice to by
or sell a financial asset. Such contracts derive the value from the price of the
underlying financial asset. Consequently these contracts are called derivative
instruments. The array of derivative instruments include options contracts, future
contracts, forward contracts, swap agreements, cap and floor agreements.
The existence of derivative instruments is the key reason why investors can more
effectively implement investment decisions to achieve their financial goals and
issuers can more effectively raise funds on more satisfactory terms.
As with any financial asset, derivative instruments can be used for speculative
purposes as well as for accomplishing a specific financial or investment
objective. Unfortunately, there have been several financial fiascos that have
involved the use of derivative instruments. As a result, some regulators and
lawmakers have been concerned with derivative instruments, viewing them as
the product of the devil. The problem with the derivative instruments is not with
the instruments per se but the lack of understanding of their risk/return
characteristics by some users. Hopefully, the discussion in this book will help
dispel the misconceptions associated with derivative instruments.
RISK AND RETURN THEORIES 1
Objectives
- How to calculate the historical single period investment return for a security or
portfolio of securities.
- The different methods for calculating the return over several unit periods.
- What is meant by an efficient portfolio.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
-

How to calculate the expected return and risk of a single asset and portfolio of
assets.
Why the expected return of a portfolio of assets is a weighted average of the
expected return of the assets included in the portfolio.
How the portfolio theory assumes that investors make investment decisions.
The difference between systematic risk and unsystematic risk.
The impact of diversification on total risks.
The importance of the correlation of two assets in measuring a portfolios risk.
What is meant by a feasible portfolio and a set of feasible portfolios.
What is the Markowitz efficient frontier.
What is meant by an optimal portfolio and how an optimal portfolio is selected
from all the portfolios available on the Markowitz efficient frontier.

Introduction to the Portfolio theory


Valuation is the process of determining the fair value of a financial asset. The
fundamental principle of valuation is that the value of any financial asset is the present
value of the cash flow expected. The process requires two steps: estimating the cash flow
and determining the appropriate interest rate that should be used to calculate the present
value. The appropriate interest rate is the minimum interest rate plus a risk premium. The
amount of the risk premium depends on the risk associated with realizing the cash flow.
Determination of the appropriate risk premium is done by demonstrating the theoretical
relationship between risk and expected return that should prevail in capital markets.
The development of the theoretical relationship between risk and expected return is built
on two economic theories: portfolio theory and capital market theory. Portfolio theory
deals with the selection of portfolios that maximise expected returns consistent with
individually acceptable levels of risk. Capital market theory deals with the effects of
investor decisions on security prices. More specifically, it shows the relationship that
should exist between security returns and risk, if investors constructed portfolios as
indicated by portfolio theory.
Together portfolio and capital market theories provide a framework to specify and
measure investment risk and to develop relationships between risk and expected return
(and hence between risk and the required return on an investment). These theories have
revolutionalized the world of finance, by allowing portfolio managers to quantify the
investment risk and expected return of a portfolio and allowing corporate treasures to
quantify the cost of capital and risk of a proposed capital investment.
In this session, we begin with the basic concepts of portfolio theory and then build upon
these concepts in the next session to develop the theoretical relationship between the
expected return of an asset and risk. Because the risk and return relationship indicates
how much an assets expected return should be given its relevant risks, it also tells us
how an asset should be priced. Hence the risk and return relationship is also referred to
as an asset pricing model.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Prior to the development of the theories we present, investors would often speak of risk
and return, but the failure to quantify these important measures made the goal of
constructing a portfolio of assets highly subjective and provided no insight as to the
return investment should expect. Moreover, investors would focus on the risks of
individual assets without understanding how combining them into a portfolio can affect
the portfolios risk. The theories we present here quantify the relationship between risk
and expected return. in October 1990, as confirmation of the importance of these theories,
the Nobel Prize in Economic Science was awarded to Professor Harry Markowitz, the
developer of portfolio theory and to Professor William Sharpe, who is one of the
developers of capital market theory.
Measuring Investment Return
Before proceeding with the theories, we will explain how the actual investment return of
a portfolio should be measured. The return on an investors portfolio during a given
interval is equal to the change in value of the portfolio plus any distributions received
from the portfolio, expressed as a fraction of the initial portfolio value. It is important that
any capital or income distributions made to the investor be included, or the measure of
return will be deficient.
Another way to look at return is as the amount (expressed as a fraction of the initial
portfolio value) that can be withdrawn at the end of the interval while maintaining the
initial portfolio value intact. The return on the investors portfolio, designated
RP

v1 v0 D
V0

Where v1 portfolio market value at the end of the internal


v0 the portfolio market value at the beginning of the interval
D the cash distributions to the investor during the interval
The calculations assumes that any interest or dividend income received on the portfolio
of securities and not distributed to the investors is reinvested in the port (and thus
reflected in V1 ). Further, the calculation assumes that any distributions occurs at the end
of the interval. If the distributions were reinvested prior to the end of the interval, the
calculation would have to be modified to consider the gains or losses or the amount
reinvested. The formula also assumes no capital inflows during the interval. Otherwise,
the calculation would have to be modified to reflect the increased investment base.
Capital inflows at the end of the interval (or held in cash until the end), however, can be
treated as just the reverse of distributions in the return calculation.
Thus, given the beginning and ending portfolio values, plus any contributions from or
distributions to the investor (assumed to occur at the end of an interval), For example, if
the XYZ pension fund had a market value of $100 million at the end of June, benefit
payments of $5 million made at the end of July, and an end of July market value of $103
million the return for the month would be 8%.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
RP

103,000,000 100,000,000 5,00,000


0.08
100,000,000

In principle, this sort of calculation of returns could be carried out for any interval of
time, say, for one month or ten years. Yet there are several problems with this approach.
First, it is apparent that a calculation made over a long period of time, say, more than a
few months, would not be very reliable because of the underlying assumption that all
cash payments and inflows are made and received at the end of the period. Clearly if two
investments have the same return but one investment makes cash payment early and the
other late, the one with early payment will be understated. Second, we cannot rely on the
formular above to compare return on a one month investment with that on a ten year
portfolio. For purpose of comparison, the return must e expressed per unit of time say
per year.
In practice, we handle these two problems by first computing the return over a
reasonably short unit of time. Perhaps a quarter of a year or less. The return over the
relevant horizon, consisting of several unit periods, is computed by averaging the return
over the unit intervals. There are three generally used methods of averaging: (1) the
arithmetic average rate of return, (2) the time weighted rate of return (also referred to as
the geometric rate of return), and (3) the dollar-weighted return. the averaging produces a
measure of return per unit of time period. The measure can be converted to an annual or
other period return by standard procedures.
Arithmetic Average Rate of Return
The arithmetic average rate of return is an unweighted average of the returns achieved
during a series of such measurement intervals. The general formula is:
RA

RP1 RP 2 .... RPN


N

RA the arithmetic average return


R pk the portfolio return in interval k as measured
by Equation (8.1), k 1,...., N

N the number of intervals in the performance evaluation period.

For example, if the portfolio returns were 10%, 20% and 5% in July, August, and
September respectively, the arithmetic average monthly return is 5%.
The arithmetic average can be thought of as the mean value of the withdrawals
(expressed as a fraction of the initial portfolio value) that can be made at the end of
each interval while maintaining the initial portfolio value intact. In the example
above, he investor must add 10% of the initial portfolio value at the end of the first
interval and can withdraw 20% and 5% of the initial portfolio value per period.
Time weighted rate of return

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The time weighted rate of return measures the compounded rate of growth of the
initial portfolio during the performance evaluation period, assuming that all cash
distributions are reinvested in the portfolio. It is also commonly referred to as the
geometric rate of return. It is computed by taking the geometric average of the
portfolio returns computed from Equation (8.1). The general formula is:
RT (1 R P1 )(1 RPN )

1 / N 1

Where RT is the time weighted rate of return and R PK and N are as defined
earlier.
For example, if the portfolio returns were 10%, 20%, and 5% in July, August and
September, as in the example above, then the time weighted rate of return is:

RT (1 ( 0.10))(1 0.20)(1 0.05)


(0.90)(1.20)(1.05)

1/ 3

1/ 3

1 0.043

As the time weighted rate of return is 4.3% per month, one dollar invested in the
portfolio at the end of June would have grown at a rate of 4.3% per month during the
three month period.
In general, the arithmetic and time weighted average returns do not provide the same
answers. This is because computation of the arithmetic average assumes the initial
amount invested to be maintained (through additions or withdrawals)at its initial
portfolio value. The tie weighted return on the other hand, is the return on a portfolio
that varies size because of the assumption that all proceeds are reinvested.
We can use an example to show how the two averages fail to coincide. Consider a
portfolio with a $100 million market value at the end of 19992, a $200 million value
at the end of 1993 and a $100 million value at the end of 1994. The annual returns
are 100% and 50%. The arithmetic return is 25%, while the time-weighted average
return is 0%. The arithmetic average return consists of the average of the $100 million
withdrawn at the end of 1993 and however, the 100% in 1993 being exactly offset by
the 50% loss in 1994 on the larger investment base. In this example, the arithmetic
average exceeds the time weighted average return. this always proves to be true,
except in the special situation where the returns in each interval are the same, in
which case the averages are identical.
Dollar-Weighted Rate of Return
The dollar weighted rate of return (also called the internal rate of return) is computed
by finding the interest rate that will make the present value of the cash flows from all
the interval periods plus the terminal market value of the portfolio. The internal rate
of return calculation, as explained in earlier chapters, is calculated exactly the same
way the yield to maturity on a bond is. The general formula for the dollar-weighted
return is:

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

v0

c
(1 R D

C VN
C2
..... N
(1 R D )
(1 R D ) n

where R D the dollar weighted rate of return


V0 the initial market value of the portfolio
V N the terminal market value of the portfolio
C K the cash flow for the portfolio (cash inflows minus cash outflows)
for interval k , k 1,..., n
for example, consider a portfolio with a market value of $100 million at the end of
1990, capital withdrawals of $5 million at the end of 1991, 1992 and 1993 and a
market value at the end of 1993 of $110 million. Then
V0 $100,000,000; N 3; C1 C 2 C 3 $5,000,000;V3 $110,000,000 and
R D is the interest rate that satisfies the equation:
$110,000,000

$5,000,000 $5,000,000 $5,000,000 $110,000,000

(1 R D )1
(1 RD ) 2
(1 R D ) 3

It can be verified that the interest rate that satisfies this expression is 8.1%. This is
the dollar-weighted return.
Under the special conditions, both the dollar weighted return and the time weighted
return produce the same result. This will occur when no further additions or
withdrawals occur when no further additions or withdrawals occur and all dividends
are reinvested. Throughout this chapter, the rate of return is generally used to refer to
an appropriately standardised measure.

Different Type Risk


With any financing or investment decision, there is some uncertainty about its
outcome. Uncertainty is about not knowing exactly what will happen in the future.
There is uncertainty in almost everything we do as financial managers because
no one knows precisely what changes will occur in such things as tax laws,
consumer demand, the economy, or interest rates. Though the terms "risk" and
"uncertainty" can be used to mean the same, there is a distinction between them.
Uncertainty is about not knowing what's going to happen. Risk is how we

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
characterize how much uncertainty exists: the greater the uncertainty, the greater
the risk. Thus risk can be defined as the degree of uncertainty. In financing and
investment decisions there are many types of risk we are going consider in this
module.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

Types of risk
The types of risk a financial manager faces include:
cash flow risk; reinvestment risk; interest rate risk; purchasing power risk and
currency risk.

Cash Flow Risk


Cash flow risk is the risk that the cash flows of an investment will not materialize
as expected. For any investment, the risk that cash flows may not be as expected
in timing, amount, or both is related to the investment's business risk.
Business Risk
Business risk is the risk associated with operating cash flows. Operating cash
flows may not be certain because neither do the revenues nor the expenditures
may comprise the cash flows. Regarding revenues: depending on economic
conditions and the actions of competitors, prices or quantity of sales (or both)
may be different from what is expected (sales risk).
Regarding expenditures: operating costs are comprised of fixed costs and
variable costs. The greater the fixed component of operating costs, the less
easily a company can adjust its operating costs to changes in sales.

We refer to the risk that comes about from the mixture of fixed and variable costs
as operating risk. The greater the fixed operating costs, relative to variable
operating costs, the greater the operating risk.
Let us take a look at how operating risk affects cash flow risk. Remember back in
economics when you learned about elasticity? That is a measure of the

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
sensitivity of changes in one item to changes in another. We can look at how
sensitive a firm's operating cash flows are to changes in demand, as measured
by unit sales. We will calculate the operating cash flow elasticity, which we call
the degree of operating leverage (DOL).
The degree of operating leverage is the ratio of the percentage change in
operating cash flows to the percentage change in units sold. If a firm sells all its
output in one period then,

Suppose the price per unit is $30, the variable cost per unit is $20, and the total
fixed costs are $5,000. If we go from selling 1,000 units to selling 1,500 units, an
increase of 50% of the units sold, operating cash flows change from:
Item
Selling 1,000 units
Selling 1,500 units
Sales
$30,000
$45,000
less variable costs
20,000
30,000
less fixed costs
5,000
5,000
Operating cash flow
$ 5,000
$10,000
Operating cash flows doubled when units sold increased by 50%. What if the
number of units decreases by 25%, from 1,000 to 750? Operating cash flows
decline by 50%. What is happening is that for a 1% change in units sold, the
operating cash flow changes by two times that percentage, in the same direction.
So if units sold increased by 10%, operating cash flows would increase by 20%; if
units sold decreased by 10%, operating cash flows would decrease by 20%.
Both sales risk and operating risk influence a firm's operating cash flow risk. Both
sales risk and operating risk are determined in large part by the type of business
the firm is in.
Financial Risk

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Financial risk is the risk associated with how a company finances its operations.
If a company finances with debt, it is legally obligated to pay the amounts
comprising its debts when due. By taking on fixed obligations, such as debt and
long-term leases, the firm increases its financial risk. A company that finances its
business with equity does not incur fixed obligations. The more fixed-cost
obligations (debt) incurred by the firm, the greater its financial risk.
The sensitivity of the cash flows available to owners when operating cash flows
change is referred to as the degree of financial leverage (DFL).

.
The cash flows to owners are equal to operating cash flows, less interest and
taxes. If operating cash flows change, how do cash flows to owners change?
Suppose operating cash flows change from $5,000 to $6,000 and suppose the
interest payments are $1,000 and, for simplicity and wishful thinking, the tax rate
is 0%:
Operating cash flow

Operating cash flow

of $5,000
of $6,000
Operating cash flow
$ 5,000
$ 6,000
less interest
1,000
1,000
Cash flows to owners
$ 4,000
$ 5,000
A change in operating cash flow from $5,000 to $6,000 -- a 20% increase -increased cash flows to owners by $1,000 -- a 25% increase.
The greater the use of financing sources that require fixed obligations, such as
interest, the greater the sensitivity of cash flows to changes in operating cash
flows.
Default Risk

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
When you invest in a bond, you expect interest to be paid (usually semi-annually)
and the principal to be paid at the maturity date. But not all interest and principal
payments may be made in the amount or on the date expected: interest or
principal may be late or the principal may not be paid at all! The more burdened a
firm is with debt (required interest and principal payments) the more likely it may
be unable to make payments promised to bondholders and the more likely there
may be nothing left for the owners. We refer to the cash flow risk of a debt
security as default risk or credit risk.
Technically, default risk on a debt security depends on the specific obligations comprising
the debt. Default may result from:
failure to make an interest payment when promised (or within a specified period),
failure to make the principal payment as promised,
failure to make sinking fund payments (that is, amounts set aside to pay off the
obligation), if these payments are required,
failure to meet any other condition of the loan, or bankruptcy.
Financial managers need to worry about default risk because they invest their firms
funds in the debt securities of other firms and they want to know what default risk lurks
in those investments.. The greater the risk of a firm's securities, the greater the firm's cost
of financing. Default risk is affected by both business risk and financial risk. We need to
consider the effects operating and financing decisions have on the default risk of the
securities a firm issues, since the risk accepted through the financing decisions affects the
firm's cost of financing.
Reinvestment Rate Risk
Another type of risk is the uncertainty associated with reinvesting cash flows, not
surprisingly called reinvestment rate risk.
If we look at an investment that produces cash flows before maturity or sale, such
as a stock (with dividends) or a bond (with interest), we face a more complicated

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
reinvestment problem. In this case we are concerned not only with the
reinvestment of the final proceeds (at maturity or sale), but also with the
reinvestment of the intermediate dividend or interest cash flows (between
purchase and maturity or sale).
Two types of risk closely related to reinvestment risk of debt securities are
prepayment risk and call risk. In the case of mortgage-backed securities -securities that represent a collection of home mortgages -- a homeowner may
pay off her or his mortgage early. If paid off early, investors in mortgages get paid
off early -- so they will have to scramble to reinvest earlier than expected.
Therefore, investors in securities that can be paid off earlier than maturity face
prepayment risk-- the risk that the borrower may choose to prepay the loan -which causes the investor to have to reinvest the funds. Call risk is the risk that a
callable security will be called by the issuer. If you invest in a callable security,
there is a possibility that the issuer may call it in (buy it back). While you may
receive a call premium (a specified amount above the par value), you have to
reinvest the funds you receive.
There is reinvestment risk for assets other than stocks and bonds, as well. If you
are investing in a new product -- investing in assets to manufacture and distribute
it -- you expect to generate cash flows in future periods. You face a reinvestment
problem with these cash flows: What can you earn by investing these cash flows?
What are your future investment opportunities?
If we assume that investors do not like risk -- a safe assumption -- then they will
want to be compensated if they take on more reinvestment rate risk. The greater
the reinvestment rate risk, the greater the expected return demanded by
investors.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Reinvestment rate risk is relevant in our investment decisions no matter the asset
and we must consider this risk in assessing the attractiveness of investments.
The greater the cash flows during the life of an investment, the greater the
reinvestment rate risk of the investment. If an investment has a greater
reinvestment rate risk, this must be factored into our decision.
Interest rate risk
Interest rate risk is the sensitivity of the change in an asset's value to changes in
market interest rates. Market interest rates determine the rate we must use to
discount a future value to a present value. The value of any investment depends
on the rate used to discount its cash flows to the present. If the discount rate
changes, the investment's value changes.
Interest rate risk is present in debt securities. If you buy a bond and intend to hold
it until its maturity, you don't need to worry about its value as interest rates
change: your return is the bond's yield-to-maturity. But if you do not intend to hold
the bond to maturity, you need to worry about how changes in interest rates affect
the value of your investment. As interest rates go up, the value of your bond goes
down. As interest rates go down, the value of your bond goes up.
Purchasing Power Risk
Purchasing power risk is the risk that the price-level may increase unexpectedly.
If your firm locks in a price on its supply of raw materials through a long-term
contract and the price-level increases, it benefits from the change in the price
level and your supplier loses (the firm pays the supplier in cheaper currency). If a
firm borrows funds by issuing a long-term bond with a fixed coupon rate and the
price-level increases, the firm benefit from an increase in the price level and its

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
creditor is harmed since interest and the principal are repaid in a cheaper
currency.
Purchasing power risk is the risk that future cash flows may be worth less or
more in the future because of inflation or deflation, respectively, and that the
return on the investment will not compensate for the unanticipated inflation. If
there is risk that the purchasing power of a currency will change, investors - who
do not like risk -- will demand a higher return.
Currency Risk
If we are considering making an investment that generates cash flows in another
currency (some other nation's currency), there is some risk that the value of that
currency will change relative to the value of our domestic currency. We refer to
the risk of the change in the value of the currency as currency risk.
Consider a Zimbabwean firm making an investment that produces cash flows in
British pounds, . Suppose we invest 10,000 today and expect to get 12,000
one year from today. Further suppose that 1 = $1.48 today, so you are investing
$1.48 times 10,000 = $14,800. If the British pound does not change in value,
relative to the Zimbabwean dollar, you would have a return of 20%:

But what if one year from now the British pound is worth $1.30 instead? Your
return would be less than 20% because the value of the pound has dropped vis-vis the Zimbabwean dollar. You are making an investment of 10,000 , or
$14,800, and getting not $17,760, but rather $1.30 times 12,000 = $15,600 in
one year. If the pound loses value from $1.48 to $1.30, your return on your
investment is ($15,600-14,800)/$14,800 = 5.41%.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Currency risk is the risk that the relative values of the domestic and foreign
currencies will change in the future, changing the value of the future cash flows.
As financial managers, we need to consider currency risk in our investment
decisions that involve other currencies and make sure that the returns on these
investments are sufficient compensation for the risk of changing values of
currencies.
Expected Return of an asset
We refer to both future benefits and future costs as expected returns. The
expected return is a measure of the tendency of returns on an investment. This
does not mean that these are the only returns possible but just our best measure
of what we expect.
Suppose we are evaluating the investment in a new product. We do not know and
cannot know precisely what the future cash flows will be. But from past
experience, we can at least get an idea of possible flows and the likelihood -- the
probability -- they will occur. After consulting with colleagues in marketing and
production management, we figure out that there are two possible cash flow
outcomes, success or failure, and the probability of each outcome. Next,
consulting with colleagues in production and marketing for sales prices, sales
volume, and production costs, we develop the following possible cash flows in the
first year:

Scenario
Product success
Product flop

Cash Flow
$4,000,000
- 2,000,000

Probability of cash flow


40%
60%

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
But what is the expected cash flow in the first year? The expected cash flow is
the average of the possible cash flows, weighted by their probabilities of
occurring:
Expected cash flow = 0.40 ($4,000,000) + 0.60(-$2,000,000) = $400,000
The expected value is a guess about the future outcome. It is not necessarily the
most likely outcome. The most likely outcome is the one with the highest
probability. In the case of our example, the most likely outcome is -$2,000,000.
The general formula for any expected value is:
Expected value = E(x) = p1x1 + p2x2 + p3x3 +...+pnxn.
where
E(x) is the expected value;
n is the number of possible outcomes;
pi is the probability of the ith outcome; and
xi is the value of the ith outcome.
We can abbreviate this formula by using summation notation:
E(x)= pixi

.Applying the general formula to our example,


n = 2 (there are two possible outcomes)
p1 = 0.40
p2 = 0.60
x1 = $4,000,000
x2 = -$2,000,000
E(cash flow) = 0.40 ($4,000,000) + 0.60 (-$2,000,000) = $400,000.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Considering the possible outcomes and their likelihood, we expect a $400,000
cash flow.
Risk of an asset
The expected return gives us an idea of the tendency of the future outcomes -what we expect to happen, considering all the possibilities. But the expected
return is a single value and does not tell us anything about the diversity of the
possible outcomes. Are the possible outcomes close to the expected value? Are
the possible outcomes much different than the expected value? Just how much
uncertainty is there about the future?
Since we are concerned about the degree of uncertainty (risk), as well as the
expected return, we need some way of quantifying the risk associated with
decisions. Suppose we are considering two products, Product A and Product B,
with estimated returns under different scenarios and their associated
probabilities:
Product A
Scenario

Probability of

Outcome

Success
Moderate success
Failure

outcome
25%
50
25

24%
10
-4

Scenario

Probability of

Outcome

Success
Moderate success
Failure

outcome
10%
30
60

40%
30
-5

Product B

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
We refer to a product's set of the possible outcomes and their respective
probabilities as the probability distribution for those outcomes.
We can calculate the expected cash flow for each product as follows:

Product A
Scenario
Success
Moderate

Pi
0.25
0.50

Xi
0.24
0.10

Pi xi
0.0600
0.0500

0.25

-0.04

-0.0100
0.1000 or

Scenario
success
Failure
Expected return

10%

Product B
Scenario
Success
Moderate

Pi
0.10
0.30

Xi
0.40
0.30

Pixi
0.0400
0.0900

success
Failure
Expected return

0.60

-0.05

-0.0300
0.1000 or
10%

Both Product A and Product B have the same expected return. However the
possible returns for Product A range from -4% to 24%, where the possible returns
for Product B range from -5% to 40%. The range is the span of possible

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
outcomes. For Product A the span is 28%; for Product B it is 45%. A wider span
indicates more risk, so Product B has more risk than Product A.
But the range by itself doesn't tell us much about the possible cash flows at these
extremes or within the extremes. The range tells us nothing about the
probabilities at or within the extremes. A measure of risk that does tell us
something about how much to expect and the probability that it will happen is the
standard deviation. The standard deviation is a measure of dispersion that
considers the values and probabilities for each possible outcome. The higher the
standard deviation, the greater would be the dispersion of possible outcomes
from the expected value. The standard deviation considers the deviation, or
distance, of each possible outcome from the expected value and the probability
associated with it.
The standard deviation of possible returns, represented by (x), is given by
( x)

p (x
i

E ( x ))

Standard deviation is calculated in six steps as follows:


Step 1: Calculate the expected value.
Step 2: Calculate the deviation of each possible outcome from the expected
value
The deviation tells us how far each possible outcome is from the expected value.
Step 3: Square each deviation.
Step 4: Weight each squared deviation, multiplying it by the probability of the
outcome
Step 5: Sum these weighted squared deviations.
This is the variance of the possible outcomes, 2(x).
Step 6: Take the square root of the sum of the squared deviations.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
This is the standard deviation of the possible outcomes, (x).
Example
Let's calculate the standard deviation of the expected cash flows for Product A:
Step 1: Calculate the expected value
E(x) = [0.24 (0.25)] + [0.10 (0.50)] + [-0.04 (0.25)] = 0.10 or 10%
Step 2: Calculate the deviation of each possible outcome from the expected
outcome
Success: 0.2400 - 0.1000 = 0.1400
Moderate success: 0.1000 - 0.1000 = 0.0000
Failure -0.0400 - 0.1000 = -0.1400
Step 3: Square each of these deviations
Success: 0.14002 = 0.0196
Moderate success: 0.00002 = 0.0000
Failure -0.14002 = 0.0196
Step 4: Weight each of the squared deviations by multiplying the probability of the
outcome by the squared deviations
Success 0.0196 (0.25) = 0.0049
Moderate success: 0.0000 (0.50) = 0.0000
Failure 0.0196 (0.25) = 0.0049
Step 5: Sum these weighted squared deviations.
Variance = 0.0049 + 0.0000 + 0.0049

2(x) = 0.0098
Step 6: Take the square root of the sum of the squared deviations
Standard deviation = (0.0098)1/2

(x) = 0.0990 or 9.90% .

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The standard deviation Product A's returns is 9.90%.

The standard deviation for Products A and B are:

Product A
Product B

Expected return
10%
10%

Standard deviation
9.90%
18.57%

While the expected value of both products is the same, there is a different
distribution of possible outcomes for the two products. When we calculate the
standard deviation around the expected value, we see that Product B has a
larger standard deviation. The larger standard deviation for Product B tells us that
Product B has more risk than Product A since its possible outcomes are more
distant from its expected value.

Returns and the Tolerance for Bearing Risk


Which product investment do you prefer, A or B? Most people would choose A
since it provides the same expected return, with less risk. Most people do not like
risk -- they are risk averse. Risk aversion is the dislike for risk. Does this mean a
risk averse person will not take on risk? No -- they will take on risk if they feel
they are compensated for it.
A risk neutral person is indifferent towards risk. Risk neutral persons do not need
compensation for bearing risk. A risk lover likes risk -- someone even willing to
pay to take on risk. Are there such people? Yes. Consider people who play the
state lotteries, where the expected value is always negative: the expected value
of the winnings is less than the cost of the lottery ticket.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
When we consider financing and investment decisions, we assume that most
people are risk averse. Managers, as agents for the owners, make decisions that
consider risk "bad" and that if risk must be borne, they make sure there is
sufficient compensation for bearing it. As agents for the owners, managers
cannot have the "fun" of taking on risk for the pleasure of doing so.
Risk aversion is the link between return and risk. To evaluate a return you must
consider its risk: Is there sufficient compensation (in the form of an expected
return) for the investment's risk?

PORTFOLIO THEORY
In constructing a portfolio of assets, investors seek to maximise the expected return
from their investment given some level of risk they are willing to accept. Portfolios
that satisfy this requirement are called efficient portfolios. Portfolio theory tells us
how this should be done. Because Markowitz is the developer of portfolio theory,
efficient portfolios are sometimes referred to as Markowitz efficient portfolios.
To construct an efficient portfolio of risky assets, it is necessary to make some
assumption about how investors behave in making investment decisions. A reasonable
assumption is that investors are risk averse. A risk averse investor is one who, when
faced with two investments with the same expected return but two different risks, will
prefer the one with the lower risk. Given a choice of efficient portfolios from which
an investor can select, an optimal portfolio is the one that is most preferred.
To construct an efficient portfolio, it is necessary to understand what is meant by
expected return and risk. The latter concept, risk, could mean any one of many
types of risk.

Selecting among different investments


The two basic approaches that can be used to choose between investments in
individual assets are the mean variance criterion and the coefficient of variation
(C.V) approach.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Mean variance rule
According to Harry Markowitz investors can choose between investments based
on the expected returns (mean) and risk (variance) if the following assumptions
hold:
Investors are rational and seek to maximize the utility of wealth
Investors are risk averse, that is they aim to minimize risk
Returns of securities are normally distributed.
To me these assumptions are necessary but insufficient to come up with mean
variance efficient securities. To make the rule sufficient and for the purpose of
this study I will add other assumptions as follows:
Investment sets are complete, that is investors are able to compare between or
among assets
Investors choices are transitive, that is if asset X is preferred to asset Y and
asset Y is preferred to asset Z it therefore implies that asset X is better than asset
Z.
The mean variance rule states that:
If there are two assets X and Y asset X is preferred to asset Y if:
X has expected returns higher than or equal to that of Y and the risk of X is lower
than that of Y
i.e. E(x) E(y) and 2(x)< 2(y)
or
X has expected returns higher than that of Y and the risk of X is lower than or
equal to that of Y
i.e. E(x)> E(y) and 2(x) 2(y)

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Example
A firm is faced with the following investment alternatives that are mutually
exclusive.
Expected return
Variance
Product A
10%
9%
Product B
10%
17%
Of the two investments Product A is mean variance-efficient because it has the
lower risk though it yields the same expected return as that of B.

Coefficient of Variation (C.V).


C.V measures risk per each unit of expected return. When investments are of
different scale it is sometimes proper to use C.V which is a relative risk measure.
C.V=

s tan dard deviation


100
exp ected value

Based on C.V we prefer an investment with lower C.V i.e. lower risk per each unit
of expected value.
Example
Of the two products which one is preferred in terms of C.V?
Expected return
Standard deviation
Product A
20%
40%
Product B
10%
30%
Product A is preferred to B because its C.V is lower than that of B
i.e. C.VA=200% and C.VB=300%
Activity
Consider the following investments:
Investment
A
B
C

Expected return
5%
7%
6%

Standard deviation
10%
11%
12%

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
D
6%
10%
Which investment would you prefer in terms of (a) mean variance rule and (b)
coefficient of variation

Diversification and Risk


In any portfolio, one investment may do well while another does poorly. The
projects' cash flows may be "out of synch" with one another. Let's look at the idea
of "out-of-synchness" in terms of expected returns, since this is what we face
when we make financial decisions.
Expected Portfolio Return
The expected return is simply the weighted average of a possible outcomes where the
weights are the relative chances of occurrence. In general, the expected return on the
portfolio, denoted E ( R P )1 is given by:
E ( R P ) P1 R1 P2 R2 ..... Rn Pn
n

E ( R P ) Pj R j
j 1

where R j s are the possible returns, the Pj s the associated probabilities, and

n the

number of possible outcomes.


Consider Investment C and Investment D and their probability distributions:

Scenario

Probability of

Return on

Return on

Boom
Normal
Recession

Scenario
30%
50
20

Investment C
20%
0
-20

Investment D
-10%
0
45

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
We see that when Investment C does well, in the boom scenario, Investment D
does poorly. Also, when Investment C does poorly, as in the recession scenario,
Investment D does well. In other words, these investments are out of synch with
one another.
Now let's look at how their "out-of-synchness" affects the risk of the portfolio of C
and D. If we invest an equal amount in C and D, the portfolio's return under each
scenario is the weighted average of C & D's returns, where the weights are 50%:
Scenario
Boom
Normal
Recession

Probability
0.30

Weighted average return


[0.5 ( 0.20)] + [0.5 (-0.10)] = 0.0500 or

0.50

5%
[0.5 ( 0.00)] + [0.5 ( 0.00)] = 0.0000 or

0.20

0%
[0.5 (-0.20)] + [0.5 ( 0.45)] = 0.1250 or

12.5%
The calculation of the expected return and standard deviation for Investment C,
Investment D, and the portfolio consisting of C and D results in the following the
statistics,

Scenario

Boom
Normal
Recession
Expected return
Standard
deviation

Probability

Return on

Return on

of

Investment

Investment portfolio

Scenario

comprised of C

-10%
0
45
6%
19.97%

and D
5%
0
12.5
4%
4.77%

30%
50%
20%

20%
0
-20
2%
14.00%

Return on a

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The expected return on Investment C is 2% and the expected return on
Investment D is 6%. The return on a portfolio comprised of equal investments of
C and D is expected to be 4%. The standard deviation of Investment C's return is
14% and of Investment D's return is 19.97%, but the portfolio's standard
deviation, calculated using the weighted average of the returns on Investment C
and D in each scenario, is 4.77%. This is less than the standard deviations of
each of the individual investments because the returns of the two investments do
not move in the same direction at the same time, but rather tend to move in
opposite directions.
The portfolio comprised of Investments C and D has less risk than the individual
investments because each moves in opposite directions with respect to the other.
A statistical measure of how two variables -- in this case, the returns on two
different investments -- move together is the covariance. Covariance is a
statistical measure of how one variable changes in relation to changes in another
variable.
Covariance between X and Y is given by
CovXY=

P (x
i

E ( x ))( yi E ( y ))

Covariance in this example is calculated in four steps:


Step 1: For each scenario and investment, subtract the investment's expected
value from its possible outcome;
Step 2:For each scenario, multiply the deviations for the two investments;
Step 3: Weight this product by the scenario's probability; and
Step 4: Sum these weighted products to arrive at the covariance.
Scenario Probability Deviation of
Investment

Deviation of

Product

Weight the

Investment

of the

product by

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

Boom
0.30
Normal 0.50
Recessio 0.20

C's return

D's return

from its

from its

expected

expected

return
0.1800
-0.0200
-0.2200

return
-0.1600
-0.0600
0.3900

deviations the
probability

-.0288
.0012
-.0858

-0.00864
0.00060
-0.01716

n
covariance
=-0.02520
As you can see in these calculations, in a boom economic environment, when
Investment C is above its expected return (deviation is positive), Investment D is
below its expected return (deviation is negative). In a recession, Investment C's
return is below its expected value and Investment D's return is above its expected
value. The tendency is for the returns on these portfolios to co-vary in opposite
directions -- producing a negative covariance of -0.0252.
Let's see the effect of this negative covariance on the risk of the portfolio. The
portfolio's variance depends on:
(a) the weight of each asset in the portfolio;
( b) the standard deviation of each asset in the portfolio; and
(c) the covariance of the assets' returns.
Calculating Portfolio based on a probability for the return of the individual assets return.
in practice, the variance of a portfolios return - which we shall simply refer to as the
portfolios return which shall simply refer to as the portfolio variance is calculated
from historical data, generally monthly. It can be shown that the variance of a two asset
portfolio is:
2
2
Var ( R P ) Wi var( Ri ) W j var( R j )

2 wi wi std ( Ri ) std ( Ri )cor ( Ri , R j )

where var ( R P ) portfolio variance

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
= percentage of the portfolios funds invested in asset i
W j = percentage of the portfolios funds invested in asset j
var ( Ri ) = variance of asset i
var ( R j ) = variance of asset j
std ( Ri ) = standard deviation of asset i
std ( R j ) = standard deviation of asset j
cor ( Ri R j ) = correlation between the return for assets i and j
Wi

In words, equation (8.4) states that the portfolio variance sum of the weighted variances
of the two assets plus the weighted correlation between the two assets plus the weighted
correlation between the two assets. Given our earlier discussion, it should not be
surprising that the correlation between the two assets affects the portfolio variance.
Notice from the equation (8.4) that the lower the correlation between the return on two
assets, the lower the portfolio variance. The portfolio variance is the lowest if the two
assets have a correlation of 1.
The equation for the portfolio variance when there are more than two assets in the
portfolio is more complicated. The extension to three assets - i, j and k - is al follows:
var( R p ) wi2 var( Ri ) wl2 var(R j ) wk2 var( Rk )
2 wi w j std ( Ri ) std ( R j )cor ( Ri R j )
2 wi wk std ( Ri ) std ( Rk )cor ( Ri Rk )
2 w j wk std ( R j ) std ( Rk )cor ( R j Rk )

where wk = percentage of the portfolios funds invested in asset k


std ( Rk ) = standard deviation of asset k
cor ( Ri , Rk ) =correlation between the return for assets i and k
cor ( R j , Rk = correlation between the return for assets j and k
In words, Equation states that the portfolio variance is the sum of the weighted variances
of the individual assets plus the sum of the weighted correlations of the assets. Hence, the
portfolio variance is the weighted sum of the individual variances of the assets in the
portfolio plus weighted sum of the degree to which the assets vary together. The formular
for the portfolio variance of any size will involve the variances and standard deviations of
all the assets and each pair of correlations.
The portfolio standard deviation is:

.
We can apply this general formula to our example, with Investment C's
characteristics indicated with a 1 and Investment D's with a 2,

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
w1 = 0.50 or 50%
w2 = 0.50 or 50%
1 = 0.1400 or 14.00%
2 = 0.1997 or 19.97%
cov1,2 = -0.0252.
The portfolio variance is:
portfolio variance = 0.502(0.14002) + 0.502(0.19972) + 2 (-0.0252) 0.50 (0.50) =
0.002275
and the portfolio standard deviation is 0.0477 or 4.77%, which, not coincidentally,
is what we got when we calculated the standard deviation directly from the
portfolio returns under the three scenarios.
The standard deviation of the portfolio is lower than the standard deviations of
each of the investments because the returns on Investments C and D are
negatively related: when one is doing well the other may be doing poorly, and
vice-versa. That is, the covariance is

Example: The Portfolio Variance and Standard Deviation


Problem
Consider a portfolio comprised of two securities, F and G:
Statistic

Expected return

Standard deviation Percentage of

portfolio invested
Security F
10%
5%
40%
Security G
20%
8%
60%
The covariance between the two securities' returns is 0.002. What is the
portfolio's standard deviation?
Solution

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
variance =0.16 (0.0025) + 0.36 (0.0064) + [(2) (0.002) (0.40) (0.60)]
variance = 0.0004 + 0.0023 + 0.00096 = 0.00366
Portfolio standard deviation = 0.06050The investment in assets whose returns
are out of step with one another is the whole idea behind diversification.
Diversification is the combination of assets whose returns do not vary with one
another in the same direction at the same time.

Common Sense Diversification


Whereas the benefits of diversification can be achieved through random selection
of a number of stocks, a number of common sense procedures can be usefully
employed to construct a diversified portfolio. For example:
Diversify across industries: Investing in a number of different stocks within the
same industry does not generate a diversified portfolio since the returns of firms
within an industry tend to be highly correlated. Diversification benefits can be
increased by selecting stocks from different industries.
Diversify across industry groups: Some industries themselves can be highly
correlated with other industries and hence diversification benefits can be
maximized by selecting stocks from those industries that tend to move in opposite
directions or have very little correlation with each other.
Diversify across geographical regions: Companies whose operations are in the
same geographical region are subject to the same risks in terms of natural
disasters and state or local tax changes. Investing in companies can diversify
these risks whose operations are not in the same geographical region.
Diversify across economies: Stocks in the same country tend to be more highly
correlated than stocks across different countries. This is because many taxation

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
and regulatory issues apply to all stocks in a particular country. International
diversification provides a means for diversifying these risks.
Diversify across asset classes: Investing across asset classes such as stocks,
bonds, and real property also produces diversification benefits. The returns of
two stocks tend to be more highly correlated, on average, than the returns of a
stock and a bond or a stock and an investment in real estate.

Correlation Coefficient
If the returns on investments move together, we say that they are correlated with
one another. Correlation is the tendency for two or more sets of data -- in our
case returns -- to vary together. The returns on two investments are:
positively correlated if one tends to vary in the same direction at the same time as
the other.
negatively correlated if one tends to vary in the opposite direction with respect to
the other.
uncorrelated if there is no relation between the changes in one with changes in
the other.
Statistically, we can measure correlation with a correlation coefficient. The
correlation coefficient reflects how the returns of two securities vary together and
is measured by the covariance of the two securities' returns, divided by the
product of their standard deviations:

By construction, the correlation coefficient is bounded between -1 and +1. We


can interpret the correlation coefficient as follows:

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
A correlation coefficient of +1 indicates a perfect, positive correlation between the
two assets' returns.
A correlation coefficient of -1 indicates a perfect, negative correlation between the
two assets returns.
A correlation coefficient of 0 indicates no correlation between the two assets
returns.
A correlation coefficient falling between 0 and +1 indicates positive, but not
perfect positive correlation between the two assets returns.
A correlation coefficient falling between -1 and 0 indicates negative, but not
perfect negative correlation between the two assets returns.
In the case of Investments C and D, the covariance of their returns is:

Therefore, the returns on Investment C and Investment D are negatively


correlated with one another.

By investing in assets with less than perfectly correlated cash flows, you are
getting rid of -- diversifying away -- some risk. The less correlated the cash flows,
the more risk you can diversify away -- to a point.
Let's see how the correlation and portfolio standard deviation interact. Consider
two investments, E and F, whose standard deviations are 5% and 3%,
respectively. Suppose our portfolio consists of an equal investment in each; that
is, w1=w2=50%.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

If the correlation between

... this means that the

and the portfolio's

the assets' returns is ...

covariance is ...

standard deviation

is ...
+1.0
+0.00150
4.00%
+0.5
+0.00075
3.50
0.0
0.00000
2.92
- 0.5
-0.00075
2.18
- 1.0
-0.00150
0.00
The less perfectly positively correlated are two assets' returns, the lower the risk
of the portfolio comprised of these assets.

Portfolio Size and Risk


The idea that we can reduce the risk of a portfolio by introducing assets whose
returns are not highly correlated with one another is the basis of Modern Portfolio
Theory (MPT). MPT tells us that by combining assets whose returns are not
correlated with one another, we can determine combinations of assets that
provide the least risk for each possible expected portfolio return.
Though the mathematics involved in determining the optimal combinations of
assets are beyond this module, the basic idea is provided in Exhibit 3. Each red
colored point in the graph represents a possible portfolio that can be put together
comprising different assets and different weights. The points in this graph
represent every possible portfolio. As you can see in this diagram:
some portfolios have a higher expected return than other portfolios with the same
level of risk;
some portfolios have a lower standard deviation than other portfolios with the
same expected return.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Since investors like more return to less and prefer less risk to more, some
portfolios are better than others. The best portfolios are those that are mean
variance efficient -- those that can't be better in terms of either the level of return
for the amount of risk or the amount of risk for the level of return. The locus of
mean variance efficient investment will make up what is called the efficient
frontier. If investors are rational, they will go for the portfolios that fall on this
efficient frontier. All the possible portfolios and the efficient frontier (shown in
green) are diagrammed in Exhibit 3.
Exhibit 3

So what is the relevance of MPT to financial managers? MPT tells us that we can
manage risk by judicious combinations of assets in our portfolios; and there are
some combinations of assets that are preferred over others.
Risky assets versus risk-free assets
It is important to distinguish between risk assets and risk-free assets. A risky asset is one
for which the return that will be realized in the future is uncertain. For example, suppose
an investor purchases the stock of Old Mutual today and plans to hold the stock for one
year. At the time she purchased the stock, she does not know what return will be realised.
The return will depend on the price of Old Mutual stock one year from now and the

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
dividends that the company pays during the year. Thus, Old Mutual stock, and indeed the
stock of all companies, is a risky asset.
Even securities issued by the government are risky assets. For example, an investor who
purchases a government bond that matures in 30 years do not know the return that will be
realised if this bond is to be held for only one year. This is because a change in interest
rates will affect the price of the bond one year from now and therefore the return from
investing in that bond for one year.
There are assets, however, in which the return that will be realized in the future is known
with certainty today. Such assets are referred to as risk-free or riskless assets. The riskfree asset is commonly defined as short-term obligations of the government. For example,
if an investor buys a government security that matures in one year and plans to hold that
security for one year, then there is no uncertainity about the return that will be realized.
The investor knows that in one year, on the maturity date of security the government will
pay a specific amount to retire the debt. Notice how this situation differs for the
government security that matures in 30 year securities are obligations of the government,
the former matures in one year so that there is no uncertainty about the return that will
pay at the end of 30 years for the 30 year bond he does not know what the price of the
bond will be one year from now.

Modern Portfolio Theory and Asset Pricing


Two Nobel Laureates in Economics, Harry Markowitz and William Sharpe
recognized the relation between portfolio returns and portfolio risk. Harry
Markowitz tuned us into the idea that investors hold portfolios of assets and
therefore their concern is focused upon the portfolio return and the portfolio risk,
not on the return and risk of individual assets. Is this reasonable? Probably. Not
many businesses consist of a single asset. Nor do investors invest in only one
asset.
The relevant risk to an investor is the portfolio's risk, not the risk of an individual
asset. If an investor holds assets in a portfolio and is considering buying an
additional asset or selling an asset from the portfolio, what must be considered is
how this change will affect the risk of the portfolio

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)


William Sharpe took the idea that portfolio return and risk are the only elements
to consider and developed a model that deals with how assets are priced. This
model is referred to as the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM).
The CAPM is a ceteris paribus model. It is only valid within a special set of
assumptions. These are:
Investors are risk averse individuals who maximize the expected utility of their
end of period wealth. Implication: The model is a one period model.
Investors have homogenous expectations (beliefs) about asset returns.
Implication: all investors perceive identical opportunity sets. This is, everyone has
the same information at the same time.
Asset returns are distributed by the normal distribution.
There exists a risk free asset and investors may borrow or lend unlimited
amounts of this asset at a constant rate: the risk free rate (r f).
There is a definite number of assets and their quantities are fixed within the one
period world.
All assets are perfectly divisible and priced in a perfectly competitive market.
Implication: e.g. human capital is non-existing (it is not divisible and it cant be
owned as an asset).
Asset markets are frictionless and information is costless and simultaneously
available to all investors. Implication: the borrowing rate equals the lending rate.
There are no market imperfections such as taxes, regulations, or restrictions.
All the assets in each portfolio, even on the frontier, have some risk. Now let's
see what happens when we add an asset with no risk -- referred to as the riskfree asset. Suppose we have a portfolio along the efficient frontier that has a

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
return of 4% and a standard deviation of 3%. Suppose we introduce into this
portfolio the risk-free asset, which has an expected return of 2% and, by
definition, a standard deviation of zero. If the risk-free asset's expected return is
certain, there is no covariance between the risky portfolio's returns and the
returns of the risk-free asset.
A portfolio comprised of 50% of the risky portfolio and 50% of the risk-free asset
has an expected return of (0.50) 4% + (0.50) 2% = 3% and a portfolio standard
deviation calculated as follows:
Portfolio variance = 0.502(0.03) + 0.502(0.00) + 2 (0.00) 0.50 (0.50) = 0.0075.
Portfolio standard deviation = 0.0075 = 0.0866.
If we look at all possible combinations of portfolios along the efficient frontier and
the risk-free asset, we see that the best portfolios are no longer along the entire
length of the efficient frontier, but rather are the combinations of the risk-free
asset and one -- and only one -- portfolio of risky assets on the frontier. The
combinations of the risk-free asset and this one portfolio is shown in Exhibit 4.
These combinations differ from one another by the proportion invested in the riskfree asset; as less is invested the risk-free asset, both the portfolio's expected
return and standard deviation increase.
Exhibit 4

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

William Sharpe demonstrates that this one and only one portfolio of risky assets
is the market portfolio -- a portfolio that consists of all assets, with the weights of
these assets being the ratio of their market value to the total market value of all
assets.
If investors are all risk averse -- they only take on risk if there is adequate
compensation -- and if they are free to invest in the risky assets as well as the
risk-free asset, the best deal lie along the line that is tangent to the efficient
frontier. This line is referred to as the capital market line (CML), shown in Exhibit
4.
If the portfolios along the capital market line are the best deals and are available
to all investors, it follows that the returns of these risky assets will be priced to
compensate investors for the risk they bear relative to that of the market portfolio.
Since the portfolios along the capital market line are the best deals, they are as
diversified as they can get -- no other combination of risky assets or risk-free
asset provides a better expected return for the level of risk or provides a lower
risk for the level of expected return.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The equation to this line which represents the possible sets of portfolios of the
riskless asset and portfolio is

where rf is the intercept and

is the slope of the line and represent

price of risk. We could also write

where E[rm]-rf is the risk premium.


The capital market line tells us about the returns an investor can expect for a
given level of risk. The CAPM uses this relationship between expected return and
risk to describe how assets are priced. The CAPM specifies that the return on
any asset is a function of the return on a risk-free asset plus a risk premium. The
return on the risk-free asset is compensation for the time value of money. The
risk premium is the compensation for bearing risk. Putting these components of
return together, the CAPM says:
Expected return on an asset = expected return on a risk free asset + risk
premium
or, return of any asset is given by a formula of the form:
E[ri] = rf + [Number of Units of Risk][Risk Premium per Unit]
We have established above that the appropriate measure of risk is cov(Ri, Rm)
and hence, the equation can be rewritten as:

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
We already know the details surrounding two points on this line. The riskless
asset has expected return of rf and covariance with the market portfolio of zero
(since rf is constant). The market portfolio has expected return E[rm] and
covariance with the market of

(the covariance of a variable with itself is its

variance). Since these two points must lie on the line, the equation to the line
must be:

Note that for the riskless asset this becomes:

and for the market portfolio it is

It is common to standardize the units of this equation by defining

and

rewriting the equation as

It is this equation that is known as the Sharpe-Lintner CAPM. The beta of the
market portfolio is one:

This provides a reference point against which the risk of other assets can be
measured. The average risk (or beta) of all assets is the beta of the market,
which is one. Assets or portfolios that have a beta greater than one have above
average risk, tending to move more than the market. For example, if the riskless

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
rate of interest (T-bill rate) is 5% p.a. and the market rises by 10%, assets with a
beta of 2 will tend to increase by 15%. If however, the market falls by 10%, assets
with a beta of 2 will tend to fall by 25% on average. Conversely, assets with betas
less than one are of below average risk and tend to move less than the market
portfolio. Assets that have betas less than zero tend to move in the opposite
direction to the market. These assets are known as hedge assets.

If we assume that investors hold well-diversified portfolios (approximating the


market portfolio), the only risk they have is non-diversifiable risk. If assets are
priced to compensate for the risk of assets and if the only risk in your portfolio is
non-diversifiable risk, then it follows that the compensation for risk is only for nondiversifiable risk. Let's refer to this non-diversifiable risk as market risk.
Since the market portfolio is made up of all assets, each asset possesses some
degree of market risk. Since market risk is systematic across assets, it is often
referred to as systematic risk and diversifiable risk is referred to as unsystematic
risk. Further, the risk that is not associated with the market as a whole is often
referred to as company-specific risk when referring to stocks, since it is risk that is
specific to the company's own situation -- such as the risk of lawsuits and labor
strikes -- and is not part of the risk that pervades all securities.

The risk that reflects an asset's

The risk that reflects an asset's

returns moving with asset returns in

returns not moving along with asset

general is referred to as ...


non-diversifiable risk
market risk
systematic risk

returns in general is referred to as ...


diversifiable risk
company-specific risk
Unsystematic risk

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The measure of an asset's return sensitivity to the market's return, its market risk,
is the asset's beta.
The expected return on an individual asset is the sum of the expected return on
the risk-free asset and the premium for bearing market risk. Let r i represent the
expected return on asset i, rf represented the expected return on the risk-free
asset, and i represent the degree of market risk for asset i. Then:

The term (rm - rf), is the market risk premium-- if you owned all the assets in the
market portfolio, you would expect to be compensated (r m - rf) for bearing the risk
of these assets. is measure of market risk, which serves to fine-tune the risk
premium for the individual asset. For example, if the market risk premium were
2% and the for an individual asset were 1.5, you would expect to receive a risk
premium of 3% since you are taking on 50% more risk than the market.
Security market line (SML)
For each asset there is a beta. If we represent the expected return on each asset
and its beta as a point on a graph, and we do the same for every asset in the
market, and connect all the points, the result is the security market line, SML, as
shown in Exhibit 5.
Exhibit 5

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
Assets that plot on the security market line are correctly priced (equilibrium).
Along the SML expected returns will be equal to required returns. In this case it
pays the individual to hold on to the security.
Assets that plot off the SML are mispriced (disequilibria). Above the SML
securities will be under-priced because expected returns are greater than
required returns. In this case it pays the investor to buy the security. On the other
hand asset that plot below the SML are overpriced because expected returns will
be lower than the required return and hence the investor will prefer to sell the
security.
As you can see in this graph:
The greater the , the greater the expected return.
If there were no market risk (beta = 0.0) on an asset its expected return would be
the expected return on the risk-free asset.
If the asset's risk is similar to the risk of the market as a whole (beta = 1.0), that
asset's expected return is the return on the market portfolio.
For an individual asset, beta is a measure of sensitivity of its returns to changes
in return on the market portfolio. If beta is one, we expect that for a given change
of 1% in the market portfolio return, the asset's return is expected to change by
1%. If beta is less than one, then for a 1% change in the expected market return,
the asset's return is expected to change by less than 1%. If the beta is greater
than one, then for a 1% change in the expected market return, the asset's return
is expected to change by more than 1%.

6.10 Portfolio Beta


The beta of an individual asset is:

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

Now consider a portfolio with weights wp. The portfolio beta is:

p = w1 1 + w22 + w33 + ... + wSS,

The beta of the portfolio is the weighted average of the individual asset betas
where the weights are the portfolio weights. So we can think of constructing a
portfolio with whatever beta we want. All the information that we need is the betas
of the underlying asset. For example, if I wanted to construct a portfolio with zero
market (or systematic) risk, then I should choose an appropriate combination of
securities and weights that delivers a portfolio beta of zero.
Suppose we have three securities in our portfolio, with the amount invested in
each and their security beta as follows:

Security
AAA
BBB
CCC
The portfolio's beta is:

Security beta
1.00
1.50
0.75

Amount invested
$10,000
$20,000
$20,000

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk

Criticism and reality of CAPM


The above is a world version of the Sharpe (1964) CAPM. There are, however,
potential problems with these tests.
The beta may not be constant through time.
The alpha may not be constant through time.
The error variance may not be constant through time (this is known as
heteroskedasticity).
The errors may be correlated through time (this is known as autocorrelation or
serial correlation).
Returns may be non-linearly related to market returns rather than the linear
relation that is suggested in the statistical model.
The returns on the market portfolio and the risk free rate may be measured
incorrectly.
There may be other sources of risk.
The world CAPM may not hold in all countries.
A beta is an estimate. For stocks, the beta is typically estimated using
historical returns. But the proxy for market risk depends on the method
and period in which is it is measured. For assets other than stocks, beta
estimation is more difficult.
The CAPM includes some unrealistic assumptions. For example, it assumes
that all investors can borrow and lend at the same rate.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
The CAPM is really not testable. The market portfolio is a theoretical and not
really observable, so we cannot test the relation between the expected
return on an asset and the expected return of the market to see if the
relation specified in the CAPM holds.
In studies of the CAPM applied to common stocks, the CAPM does not
explain the differences in returns for securities that differ over time, differ
on the basis of dividend yield, and differ on the basis of the market value
of equity (the so called "size effect").
Though it lacks realism and is difficult to apply, the CAPM makes some sense
regarding the role of diversification and the types of risk we need to consider in
investment decisions.

The multifactor CAPM


The CAPM described above assumes that the only risk that an investor is
concerned with is uncertainty about the future price of a security. Investors,
however, usually are concerned with other risks that will affect their ability to
consume goods and services in the future. Three examples would be the risks
associated with future labour income, the future relative price of consumer goods,
and future investment opportunities.
Recognizing these other risks that investors face, Robert Merton has extended
the CAPM based on consumers deriving their optimal lifetime consumption when
they face these extra-market sources of risk. These extra-market sources of risk
are also referred to as factors hence the model derived by Merton is called a
multifactor CAPM and is given below:
E ( R P ) R F P , M E ( R M ) R F P , F 1 E ( R F 1 ) R F P , F 2 E ( R F 2 ) R F ...

P , Fk E ( R Fk ) R F

where

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
= The risk free return
F1 , F2 , Fk
= factors of extra-market sources of risk, 1 to k
K = number of factors or extra market sources of risk
B P ' FK = the sensitivity of the portfolio to the k
E ( R FK ) = the expected return of factor k
RF

The total extra-market sources of risk is equal to:


P , F 1 E ( RF 1 ) RF P , F 2 E ( RF 2 ) R ... P , Fk E ( RFk ) RF k

this expression says that investors want to be compensated for the risk
associated with each source of extra-market risk, in addition to market risk. Note
that if there are no extra market sources of risk, then equation reduces to the
expected return for the portfolio as predicted by the CAPM:

E ( R P ) R F P E ( RM ) R F
In the case of the CAPM, investors hedge the uncertainty associated with future
security prices by diversification. This is done by holding the market portfolio
which can be thought of as a mutual fund that invests in all securities based on
their relative capitalizations. In the multifactor CAPM, in addition to investing in
the market portfolio, investors will also allocate funds to something equivalent to
a mutual fund that hedges a particular extra market risk. While not all investors
are concerned with the same sources of extra market risk, those that are
concerned with a specific extra market will basically hedge them in the same way.
We have just described the multifactor model for a portfolio. How can this model
be used to obtain the expected return for an individual security? Since individual
securities are nothing more than portfolios consisting of only one security,
equation below must hold each security, i . That is:
E ( Ri ) R F i , M E ( RM ) R F ) i , F 1 E ( R F 1 ) R F ) i , F 2 E ( R F 2 ) R F ) ...

i , FK E ( R FK ) R FK )

The multifactor CAPM is an attractive model because it recognizes non-market


risks. The pricing of an asset by the market place, then must reflect risk
premiums to compensate for these extra market risks. Unfortunately, it may be

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
difficult to identify all the extra market risk and to value each of these risks
empirically. Furthermore, when these risks are taken together , the multifactor
CAPM begins to resemble the arbitrage pricing theory model described next.

The Arbitrage Pricing Model


An alternative to CAPM in relating risk and return is the Arbitrage Pricing Model.
The Arbitrage Pricing Model developed by Stephen Ross, is an asset pricing
model that is based on the idea that identical assets in different markets should
be priced identically.
While the CAPM is based on a market portfolio of assets, the Arbitrage Pricing
Model doesn't mention a market portfolio at all. Instead, the Arbitrage Pricing
Model states that an asset's returns should compensate the investor for the risk
of the asset, where the risk is due to a number of economic influences, or
economic factors. Therefore, the expected return on the asset i, r i, is:
ri = rf + 1f1 + 2f2 + 3 f3+ ...
where each of the 's reflect the asset's return's sensitivity to the corresponding
economic factor, f. The Arbitrage Pricing Model looks much like the CAPM, but
the CAPM has one factor -- the market portfolio. There are many factors in the
Arbitrage Pricing Model.
What if an asset's price is such that it is out of line with what is expected? That's
where arbitrage comes in. Any time an asset's price is out of line with how market
participants feel it should be priced -- based on the basic economic influences -investors will enter the market and buy or sell the asset until its price is in line
with what investors think it should be.

Shumba600@yahoo.co.uk
What are these economic factors? They are not specified in the original Arbitrage
Pricing Model, though evidence suggests that these factors include:
unanticipated changes in inflation;
unanticipated changes in industrial production;
unanticipated changes in risk premiums; and
unanticipated changes in the difference between interest rates for short and longterm securities.
Anticipated factors are already reflected in an asset's price. It is the unanticipated
factors that cause an asset's price to change. For example, consider a bond with a
fixed coupon interest. The bond's current price is the present value of expected
interest and principal payments, discounted at some rate that reflects the time value of
money, the uncertainty of these future cash flows, and the expected rate of inflation.
If there is an unanticipated increase in inflation, what will happen to the price of the
bond? It will go down since the discount rate increases as inflation increases. If the
price of the bond goes down, the return on the bond will decrease. Therefore, the
sensitivity of a bond's price to changes in unanticipated inflation is negative.

Вам также может понравиться