Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 140

ECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS

FOR SUSTAINABLE
URBANIZATION
A STUDY ON THREE-PRONGED APPROACH

PLANNED CITY EXTENSIONS, LEGAL FRAMEWORK,


AND MUNICIPAL FINANCE
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach: Planned City Extensions, Legal
Framework, and Municipal Finance

Copyright United Nations Human Settlements Programme, 2017


All rights reserved

United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-Habitat)


P.O. Box 30030, Nairobi 00100, GPO KENYA
Telephone: +254-20-7623120 (Central Office)
www.unhabitat.org

HS Number: HS/059/16E

By Serge Salat, Loeiz Bourdic, Marco Kamiya

Urban Economy Branch, UN-HABITAT/


Urban Morphology Institute and Complex Systems, Paris

Extended Preface by Dr. Joan Clos

Part 1 by Serge Salat

Part 2 by Loeiz Bourdic and Marco Kamiya

Design and Layout: Eric Omaya


ECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS
FOR SUSTAINABLE
URBANIZATION
A STUDY ON THREE-PRONGED APPROACH

PLANNED CITY EXTENSIONS, LEGAL FRAMEWORK,


AND MUNICIPAL FINANCE
2
Table of Contents
Extended Preface by Dr. Joan Clos.................................................................................................................... 8

Introduction..................................................................................................................................................... 17

I. Part 1: A New Approach to Urban Value Creation, by Serge Salat........................................................ 19

1. Planning Patterns...................................................................................................................25
1.1 The Compact City Pattern......................................................................................................26
1.2 The Articulated Density Pattern: FARs....................................................................................26
1.3 The Transit-Oriented Development Pattern.............................................................................30
2. Transportation Network Patterns............................................................................................33
2.1 Random Car-Oriented Patterns and Sprawl............................................................................34
2.2 Core and Branches Subway Patterns and Agglomeration Economies......................................34
2.3 Grid-like Subway Patterns and Compact Polycentric Cities.....................................................34
3. Community Design Patterns for Urban Vitality.......................................................................35
3.1 Density Patterns.....................................................................................................................35
3.2 Street Patterns: The Leaf Pattern............................................................................................35
3.3 The Fine Grain Urban Fabric Pattern.......................................................................................38
3.4 Public Places Patterns: Designing the Space of Human interaction..........................................40
3.5 Green Spaces Patterns...........................................................................................................41
3.6 Diversity Patterns...................................................................................................................41
3.7 Land Lots Patterns.................................................................................................................42
3.8 Summary of key benchmarks for enhancing value at community scale...................................43
4. Financial Patterns: The Positive Feedback Loop of Value Creation...........................................44
4.1 Value Creation.......................................................................................................................45
4.2 Value Realization...................................................................................................................46
4.3 Value Capture.......................................................................................................................46
4.4 Local Value Recycling.............................................................................................................47
Leaf Patterns: The Resilient Way of Urban Growth.................................................................47
II. Part 2: The Technical Framework of the Three-Pronged Approach, by Loeiz Bourdic and .
Marco Kamiya ....................................................................................................................................... 49

1. Urban productivity.................................................................................................................50
1.1. Economies of scale and urban productivity.............................................................................51

3
1.2. Economies of scope and urban productivity...........................................................................51
1.3. Urbanization and localization economies and urban productivity............................................52
1.4. Agglomeration economies and urban productivity.................................................................52
1.5. Negative externalities of urban agglomerations......................................................................53
2. The Three-Pronged Approach................................................................................................54
2.1. Exploiting the potential of urbanization.................................................................................54
2.2. Three essential components for sustainable planned city extension........................................55
2.2.1. Urban planning..............................................................................................................55
2.2.2. Financial framework and governance.............................................................................58
Expenditure....................................................................................................................59
Revenue.........................................................................................................................61
2.2.3. The legal framework......................................................................................................63
Examples........................................................................................................................66
3. Methodology: applying the three-pronged approach.............................................................70
3.1. Measuring urban productivity................................................................................................70
The model of land prices in mono-centric cities...............................................................70
3.2. Assessing the performance on the components of the Three-Pronged Approach...................72
Scales of urban assessment.............................................................................................73
3.3. Assessing urban design..........................................................................................................74
Intensity indexes.............................................................................................................74
Accessibility indexes........................................................................................................75
Indexes on street network connectivity and walkability...................................................77
Indexes on urban diversity and mixed use.......................................................................78
3.3.1. Assessment of the efficiency of the legal framework and governance.............................79
Legal and governmental efficiency..................................................................................79
Potential for adaption/Flexibility of the legal framework..................................................81
3.3.2. Assessment of the financial management.......................................................................81
Budgeting.......................................................................................................................81
Feasibility and sustainability of public investments...........................................................82
Exploitation of revenue potential....................................................................................83
4. Empirical evidence.................................................................................................................84
4.1. On the productivity advantages of urban agglomerations......................................................84
The spatial distribution of productivity advantages..........................................................84
The (de)correlation of urbanization and economic development......................................85

4
4.2. Urban design.........................................................................................................................86
4.2.1. The Floor Area Ratio (FAR)..............................................................................................86
4.2.2. Residential density..........................................................................................................89
4.2.3. Job density.....................................................................................................................91
4.2.4. Transit accessibility.........................................................................................................94
4.2.5. Street network connectivity............................................................................................97
4.2.6. The job-housing ratio.....................................................................................................99
4.2.7. Land use diversity.........................................................................................................100
4.3. Financial management.........................................................................................................103
4.4. The legal framework............................................................................................................104
Land use flexibility........................................................................................................104
4.5. The impact of urban planning characteristics on the productivity level..................................108
4.5.1. Density and urban productivity.....................................................................................108
4.5.2. Accessibility and urban productivity..............................................................................110
4.5.3. Accessibility and urban productivity..............................................................................113
4.5.4. Transit accessibility contributes to agglomeration economies........................................114
4.5.5. Walkability indexes and urban productivity...................................................................114
4.5.6. Land use diversity and urban productivity.....................................................................120
5. Annex: modeling PCE characteristics on urban productivity..................................................123
5.1. The model...........................................................................................................................123
5.2. Modeling urban framework.................................................................................................124
5.3. Modeling urban productivity................................................................................................127
5.4. Modeling capital and operational expenditures....................................................................128
References..................................................................................................................................................... 129

5
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Authors

Serge Salat
President, Urban Morphology & Complex System Institute Paris

A practicing architect, urban planner and designer. His most creative designs have been
exposed in prestigious places and featured by major media. He is recognized as a leading
expert and central figure in the field of urban morphology, urban policy and complexity
science. Salat advises leading international institutions in the field of urban planning and ur-
ban policy, among them the United Nations, the Global Platform for Sustainable Cities, the
International Resource Panel, GEF, IPCC, CDC and AFD. As a project director, he supervised
large projects such as international airports, high speed train stations and eco-cities. He is
the author of major books on urban morphology, has published numerous articles and is a
frequent keynote speaker at international conferences. He is a graduate of cole Polytech-
nique and ENA and holds three PhDs; in Economics, Architecture and in Art History.

Loeiz Bourdic
Executive Director and Data Specialist, Urban Morphology & Complex System Institute Paris

An engineer and economist. As a co-founder of the Urban Morphology Institute, he works


on the development of tools and methods to support data-driven urban policies. He is the
author of several peer-reviewed papers defining innovative sets of urban indicators. More
recently, his work focuses on the transposition of urban big data analyses into urban invest-
ment strategies. He holds a Master in Engineering from cole Polytechnique and a Master of
Science in Environmental Economics & Policy from Imperial College, London.

Marco Kamiya
Head of the Urban Economy and Finance Branch, UN-Habitat

Leads the Urban Economy and Finance work at UN-Habitats headquarters in Nairobi, Kenya.
In addition to working on field projects, Kamiya conducts research on municipal finance,
the economics of urban expansion and local infrastructure investment policy. Prior to joining
UN-Habitat, he worked at the Development Bank of Latin America (CAF), the Inter-American
Development Bank and was director of international development projects with PADECO
Co. Ltd, a consulting firm from Japan based in Tokyo. He has co-edited with Le-Yin Zhang
the handbook Finance for City Leaders (UN-Habitat and University College London), and has
co-authored the Urban Economy Chapter of the World Cities Report 2016 (UN-Habitat). He
studied International Development at Harvard University.

6
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization

Appreciation

We hope that this publication will help city leaders to design urban policies integrating
finance, planning and legal frameworks, so plans and programmes become more effective
and long lasting, providing cities with strong economic fundamentals.

Though the responsibility is of the authors, many people assisted with this publication. First,
thanks to UN-Habitats Executive Director Dr. Joan Clos for providing the intellectual basis for
the three-pronged approach for urbanization and insisting that planning, legal framework
and municipal finance are necessary conditions for sustainable urbanization.

Thanks to Gulelat Kebede, former Urban Economy Branch coordinator, for full support to
this project. To the participants of the Preparatory Conference for Habitat III in April 2015 in
Nairobi Kenya, to the participants of the Global Urban Futures Project of the Urban Econom-
ics Seminar at the New School in New York City in November 2015 and its Director Michael
Cohen and coordinator Martha Jaimes for valuable comments.

The preliminary draft benefited from a senior panel on Sustainable Urbanization, during the
Habitat III conference in Quito, Ecuador in October 2016 led by Serge Salat and with contri-
butions from Pedro Ortiz, Michael Cohen, Le-Yin Zhang and Cynthia Goytia.

Thanks to the UN-Habitat Urban Economy and Finance Branch team of research assistants
that worked in this project providing high quality inputs. We had Moges Beyene and Juan
Luis Arango with major inputs and contributions, following earlier efforts by Henrika Lan-
gen and Sarah Ivey. Hazel Kuria and Elizabeth Glass led the project coordination during the
different stages of the study.

To UN-Habitat colleagues: Raf Tuts the Programme Director, Laura Petrella, Christophe
Lalande, Robert-Lewis Lettington, Elkin Velazquez, Eduardo Moreno, Gianluca Crispi, Anne
Klein and many more that join our field and normative work every day with cities all over
the world.

7
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Extended
Preface
On Sustainable Urbanization
and the New Urban Agenda

The year 2016 saw the launch of a crucial for sustainable development through ur-
debate in sustainable urbanization with ban planning and design.
Habitat III: the UN International Confer-
ence on Housing and Sustainable Urban At UN-Habitat, the UN agency at the fore-
Development, in Quito, defining the New front of sustainable urban development,
Urban Agenda. our mission is to develop and provide ur-
banization policies and best practices that
Jane Jacobs once said that whenever promote sustainable, equitable and inclu-
and wherever societies have flourished sive urban development.
and prospered rather than stagnated and
decayed, creative and workable cities Our approach to achieving sustainable ur-
have been at the core of the phenom- ban development is founded on a policy
enon. In fact, the positive correlation triangle comprised of good governance,
between economic growth and the rate urban planning and design, and a model of
of urbanisation is well recognized now- municipal finance that provides a founda-
adays. Indeed, the adoption of Agenda tion for sustainable urbanization. If urban-
2030 for Sustainable Development recog- ization that is well planned and designed
nized for the first time in the history of has the capacity to generate wealth ex
development the transformative power of novo, what are the factors that increase ur-
urbanization as a tool for economic devel- ban value generation?
opment as reflected in Sustainable Devel-
opment Goal 11. While there is no magic recipe to urbaniza-
tion, let me share with you the three ele-
However, the debate on urban value ments that, in our opinion, contribute to
generation through urban planning and increasing urban value generation: gover-
design continues to lack concrete recom- nance, design and finance.
mendations and multidimensional policy
solutions. The New Urban Agenda, signed I. Municipal Finance
at Habitat III, will be an extraordinary op-
Urbanization is expensive. It requires cen-
portunity to strengthen and consolidate a
trally planned infrastructure such as electrical
unified vision of urbanization as the driver

8
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

grids, power stations, roads and highways, local revenue streams. For example, there is
water-supply networks and sewage, tele- room to improve tax-collection efficiency in
communications networks and railways and developing countries, where such revenue
airports in addition to public and private remains well below that in developed coun-
services such as schools, hospitals, markets tries. However, in cities where municipal
and so on. authorities lack the capacity to boost reve-
nue, improving such efficiency may not be
In high-income countries, central gov- enough to significantly improve their ability
ernments finance the majority of urban to invest in and maintain local infrastructure
infrastructure. Cities in developing coun- while also providing public services.
tries also finance a significant portion of
infrastructure projects with financial re- Facing deficits, local authorities usually turn
sources provided by central governments. to revenue sources that are beyond their
However, the responsibility of linking roads capabilities. When experts from my office
to regional networks and maintaining re- visit cities in developing countries, we are
gional infrastructure interlinked with that frequently requested to support bond issu-
at the local level is unclear in many coun- ing or accessing funds from international
tries. Often, it lacks requisite financing. In financial markets.
high-income countries, urban revenue is
generated primarily through taxes, public While municipal bonds and access to in-
assets such as public land and other public- ternational financial markets are important
ly-owned property and central government financial tools, it has to be borne in mind
transfers to municipal authorities. that bonds require creditworthiness, a credit
history that signals the likelihood of repay-
The more economically developed the ment by the local government. This may be
city, the less it tends to depend on inter- expensive to acquire and, even if obtained,
governmental transfers. In cities such as it is still a debt that must be repaid in the
New York, Stockholm, Seattle and Tokyo, future.
locally-based revenues are more than USD
3,000 per capita each year. Such cities are Meanwhile, many countries asking these
better equipped at attracting multination- questions are missing an important first step:
al corporations that benefit from strong taking advantage of their own domestic
property rights and contribute to munici- wealth or what we call endogenous sources
pal and national revenue streams. of finance. This years Habitat III conference
and its outcome, the New Urban Agenda, is
In many cities in the developing world, an opportunity to refocus the global discus-
locally generated urban yearly revenue sion on endogenous sources of finance.
ranges from USD 100 to USD 500 per
inhabitant. And in smaller cities in Africa Yet, while the Habitat III preparatory doc-
and South Asia, it is not unusual for some uments that will support the draft for the
municipalities to receive less than USD 50 New Urban Agenda do mention this issue,
per resident. they do not do so strongly enough. Habitat
III needs to adopt as a priority the need for
The size of a city is not the only variable local governments to understand and lever-
that matters in determining the volume of age their own assets and wealth. After all,

9
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

these are the resources that are within cities How the city is configured its transpor-
immediate reach. tation system, public space and more is
directly connected to its capacity to improve
Three priority revenue sources are land assets, productivity and expand wealth. Look at the
productive capacities, and financial expertise. example of mobility: cities with improper
transportation infrastructure cannot con-
Land assets: Municipalities need to improve nect people to jobs, and firms are unable
property rights via land registration. In addi- to compete and generate sufficient income.
tion, local governments must have a system Thus, municipalities lose revenue, hamper-
that enables them to periodically update in- ing their ability to provide public goods. In
formation on asset and property ownership. contrast, cities that offer a good environ-
Such a system requires a basic level of techni- ment in which to live and an efficient urban
cal expertise, an electronic network and an ac- layout in which to produce can attract peo-
counting system. By reinforcing property rights ple and firms, creating sustainable sources
through a central system that monitors and of income.
updates public and private land assets, munic-
ipal governments can establish a foundation Financial management expertise: This
for land-value sharing. In turn, this enables all varies broadly among municipalities de-
interested parties such as residents and local pending on the level of revenue, region and
governments to apply urban planning tools to country. In non-metropolitan municipali-
renew and expand cities, improve neighbour- ties, it may be important to improve basic
hoods and increase property values. financial capacity, ranging from accounting
rules, capital investment plans, sustainabili-
Cities that apply these tools are able to gen- ty financial ratios and rules for expenditures
erate more revenue from property taxes and and revenue.
betterment levies, and to direct those re-
sources toward improving housing for res- Improving financial management top to
idents and compensating proprietors with bottom can have significant benefits. As
income. This creates a virtuous circle for city demonstrated by UN-Habitat projects in Asia
renewal and expansion. Indeed, land-value and Africa, understanding accounting princi-
sharing has been very successful in cities in ples, training on capital investment plans and
Japan, the Netherlands and other countries, helping to set up basic electronic govern-
where such systems have been in place for ment systems have immediate results. Later,
more than a century. support must be given to improve technical
knowledge of more complex financial instru-
Productive capacities: Improving and ex- ments such as bonds, credit ratings, loans,
panding the layout of cities enhances pro- green financing and others.
ductive capacity and the mobility of people
and goods, so urban areas can generate An alternative source of funding is local and
more income from the private sector. This international commercial banks but these
dimension is usually considered part of the institutions are often too risk averse to pro-
strategy around local economic develop- vide local financing. Moreover, commercial
ment, and such policies will need to be up- banks usually have more profitable and less
dated in order to support productive econo- risky investment options. Private investors
mies that prioritize liveability and equity as are another source of finance but typically
well as higher urban revenues. are able to finance only small local projects.

10
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Financing the Gap: One potential solution In Africa, the situation is even more com-
is a national municipal corporation. This can plicated. For the most part, African govern-
be an umbrella department housed in a na- ments allow bonds to be issued only at the
tional ministry that supports municipalities national level, with just a few cases of such
with technical cooperation and consulting actions at the sub-national level - including
expertise. In some cases, it could also offer in Dakar, where the process remains in lim-
loans or guarantees that encourage pooled bo. The financing of bonds requires tech-
investment schemes. nical expertise, credit ratings and a proper
legal framework. And still bonds are not
For example, development banks can of- a panacea: like any loan, they constitute a
fer credit directly to the municipal corpo- debt and must be repaid.
ration, which could act as a guarantor for
all municipalities. As cities get bigger and One form of classical bonds is what is known
become more metropolitan, they can create as a pay-for-success contract, also called a
their own municipal corporation that serves social-impact bond. These dont require a
smaller municipalities. credit rating and can be implemented by a
municipality through an external institution
Another financing mechanism is local infra- that manages the issuing of the bond and
structure funds, where municipalities create pays all parties if and when the social policy
an external investment body to manage lo- is achieved.
cal infrastructure. Such funds can be adapt-
ed to local conditions and provide funding In order for a city to prosper, a minimum
to develop a project pipeline or, eventually, level of financial sustainability and auton-
to co-finance local infrastructure projects. omy is needed. Still, finance is a necessary
but not a sufficient condition. According to
Such a fund would require proper oversight what UN-Habitat calls the Three-Pronged
to guarantee transparency and expertise. Approach, finance is joined by design and
But, by encouraging private sector con- governance as one of the three elements
sulting and investment, local governments required for prosperity. While urban plan-
can generate capacity around incremental ning requires rules and regulations for ur-
financing. There are several such examples ban expansion and finance to pay for city
in cities in the United States, Canada (On- extensions, municipal finance requires plan-
tario is a particular case study) and Western ning and good city layout, as well as a policy
Europe but also in Africa and Asia. Those framework that supports land-value sharing
funds can also have a climate change com- and private investment in public projects.
ponent and attract bilateral donors.
II. Urban Planning and
Financial markets can also be strengthened Design
through the use of bonds, though signifi-
These are: urban layout and supply of
cant challenges remain in this area. In Latin
chains, a mixed use, adequate density and
America, Rio de Janeiro, Bogot, Belize and
urban competitiveness.
others have issued bonds but, at less than
ten years, the bond maturity tends to be too
Urban Layout and Supply Chains: urban
short for the lifecycle of an infrastructure
planning and design that supports urban val-
project, which typically runs for more than
ue-generation requires that we examine the
two or three decades.

11
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

transactions costs imposed by inefficiencies ondary use buildings and/or spaces. While
resulting from poor urban design at both primary uses can be thought of as a neigh-
the neighbourhood and city level. We begin bourhoods anchor, secondary uses serve
by looking at how urban layout can support people drawn in to the neighbourhood by
supply chain development and promote eco- the primary use. Primary and secondary uses
nomic diversification and growth. include buildings and/or spaces that serve
residential, commercial, public, or industrial
Supply chains are comprised of different firms purposes. When the primary use or uses of
in distinct locations each of which performs a neighbourhood are effectively combined
activities necessary to the production of a fi- with secondary uses, further entrepreneurial
nal good or provision of services. Cities with activity is support-ed setting the stage for
diverse and efficient supply chains often be- continued urban growth.
come self-sustaining entities that facilitate
innovation and growth in other industries. Cities that feature many mixed use neigh-
For example, many successful international bourhoods attract people from different
companies producing a variety of goods that socio-economic backgrounds, regions and
require advanced technology, skilled labour, countries, thus fostering internal capac-
and collaborative urban environments are ity for creating new industries, activities
located in hubs where transit systems are ef- and livelihoods for their residents. Mixed
ficient and human capital endowments are use also has social benefits such as, in the
high. Not only are these firms able to hire case of residential use, mixing middle and
the most qualified candidates, but they also high-income housing with low-income
reduce their production costs by locating in housing. This helps create neighbourhoods
cities where transportation infrastructure conducive to inclusive growth whereby
maximizes the mobility of people and goods. low-income residents are incorporated into
the economic fabric of a city, thus providing
However, efficient supply chains cannot op- economic mobility and income gains.
erate in any city environment; they require
an urban layout that minimizes the costs of Adequate Density: urban design that pro-
transportation, collaboration and knowl- motes value generation considers density as
edge sharing. Investing in adequate and ap- one of the leading indicators. When cities
propriate transportation infrastructure and have a high concentration of people (in the
street design is essential to minimizing the realm of 15,000 people per km) they are
transactions costs imposed by slow and in- able to maximize the benefits associated
efficient transit systems that limit the mobil- with mixed land use while supporting urban
ity of individuals and the transport of goods. supply chain development and minimizing
the costs associated with low density urban
Mixed Use: in addition to lowering trans- infrastructure. Urban sprawl not only kills
actions costs through better urban trans- the economic and social vitality of neigh-
portation infrastructure and design, urban bourhoods, but also produces ghost cities
planning should include diverse neighbour- where urban residents mobility is limited
hoods with mixed use spaces. due to the distance from the urban centre.
Urban sprawl often results in abandoned
Mixed use neighbourhoods are character- neighbourhoods due to the prohibitively
ized by the presence of primary and sec- high cost of transport and logistics.

12
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

By the same token, limiting land use spe- III. Legal Framework
cialization prevents neighbourhoods from
suc-cumbing to the economic stagnation Cities need rules, governance, and legislation
associated with homogenous single-use to unlock the benefits of urbanization. Walk-
neighbour-hoods. ing through cities in Latin America, Africa and
Asia, you see common features in most of the
Density also provides a strong tool for lo- developing world: slums are next to formal
cal governments to plan and design better settlements, high rise buildings are surround-
cities, facilitating regeneration, reordering ed by low income neighbourhoods and hous-
streets and parks, extending roads, provid- ing complexes are sometimes empty when
ing metro lines, highways and train. people need decent housing. When you dig
into the cities, typical problems are that local
Urban Competitiveness: if value gener- governments lack proper sustainable finance,
ation is supported by vibrant communities they are permanently in defi-cit and not able
and cities that foster economic activities to capture value from their neighbourhoods.
and the production of goods for export, Furthermore, city planning is usually absent
then productive diversification is essential. or improper and rules and regulations are not
Urban competitiveness means that it is working. All of these symptoms are indicators
easier for people to move and meet (urban that cities are unable to integrate municipal
form), to exchange ideas, and implement finance, planning and legal framework, in or-
them so entrepreneurship and economic der to achieve sustainable urbanization. Why
activities increase. Lively neighbourhoods then is the legal framework one of the essen-
(mixed use and density) permit to get tial components for cities to prosper?
the best of the local residents and attract
foreign talent, expanding innovation and Legal Framework and Urbanization: the
knowledge. legal framework determines how the game
is played; though everybody can kick a ball,
For a city or country to be competitive, playing a soccer match requires rules, time
multiples factors are at play including and arbiters, and the players and public
trade rules, economic planning, industrial must understand that. Building shelter and
policies, education, health, geography and houses is one thing but mixed-use housing
perhaps history. Urbanization and how the and urban expansion requires coordinated
city is designed clearly have a major role in actions and regulations known and agreed
urban value gener-ation. to by all parties. In all instances of urban de-
velopment, a proper legal framework needs
We see that urban value generation rules and regulations, governance and insti-
through urban planning and design has tutions and property rights.
the capacity to foster sustainable, inclusive
and efficient urban environments. This is Rules of the Game: Rules and regulations,
more than just an architectural approach; a lack or an excess of them prevent or bur-
when city design is well conceived and den economic transactions. Ronald Coase,
strategic, the economic power of urban- who believed that markets are imperfect
ization is unleashed even at a neighbour- and have frictions, indicated that once
hood level. A city is ultimately a combina- transaction costs - the costs of dealing and
tion of vibrant neighbourhoods. exchanging things in a market economy -

13
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

are taken into account, contractual arrange- remains for 100 years, with buildings stay-
ments are not always possible because they ing from 20 to 150 years and roads lasting
may cost more than the gain they produce. for 200 years. Certain layouts and patterns
This is of course when arrangements are not have survived historical eras as is the case in
too complex, but usually in practice in our several cities in Europe where the layouts in
societies clear rules are necessary. place come from the Roman or the Ottoman
Empires. Thus, cities badly designed have the
Lack of rules and regulations make it hard ability to adversely affect generations.
or impossible to produce sustainable urban-
ization. In Africa almost 60 per cent of cities Strong institutions come together with
are composed of slums which tend to be good governance. In developing countries,
close to the Central Business Districts (CBDs) urban infrastructure such as water manage-
where land is more expensive. Nairobi, ment systems, roads, electricity are either
where the largest slum in Africa, Kibera, is oversupplied or scarce and this is a symptom
located, is an example with slums scattered of fragmentation of governance structures,
all across the city with local governments with government layers with unclear man-
unable to renew or upgrade land because dates at local, regional and national levels,
rules for conversion or expropriation are not and ministries and agencies with competing
in place promoting instead an informal con- and overlapping responsibilities.
trol network that feeds corruption. Kibera,
if converted to formal land, would produce Legal Property: property rights or legal
almost USD 1billion in value and revenue property define how resources are owned
gains for the county and central government. and used. Legal property helps to reduce
informality allowing local governments, res-
According to the Doing Business Database idents and firms to plan cities and obtain re-
by the World Bank, in low-income countries sources from land and property. Lack of legal
simple things such as registering properties titles and ownerships explain dead capital
or obtaining a construction permits take which the Peruvian economist, Hernando de
more than 100 days, whereas in most OECD Soto, estimates as USD 9.3 trillion of poten-
countries that is done in less than ten days. tial but unrealized wealth, because people
There is a clear relationship between trans- who cannot use property as collateral remain
action time and growth. poor, since they are unable to get loans and
scale up their properties and capital.
Institutions for Urbanization: institutions
design and improve laws, providing a sta- Legal property provides people and institu-
ble framework for incremental governance tions with protection; increases incentives
development and technical evolution. With- for landowners to invest long term; and
out institutions, self-adjustment and social makes it possible to use assets as guar-
learning is stopped or regressive. antees for financing capital formation or
expansion. Land and property titles are
Institutions are key in the design of rules and usually conditions for citizens and firms to
regulations and in the necessary application have creditworthiness and access to loans
and enforcement for cities to plan long-term. and use complex financial instruments. In-
Interventions in infrastructure require good secure property rights increases transaction
institutions since urban structure typically costs since exchanges need non-traditional

14
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

guarantee mechanisms to support market housing conditions become available. Since


exchanges leading to informality and cor- housing is not a public good and requires a
ruption. Consequently, in the absence of financially-sustainable solution there needs
proper titling and proof of ownership, sim- to be proper incentives for the private sec-
ple processes such as buying property and tor to build and a mortgage market to make
selling or renting a house can become ex- it sustainable. However, at times, local gov-
tremely complex. ernments, wanting to act on their own, end
up building houses themselves and crowd-
Legal Framework and Efficient Markets: ing out the private property development
as as legal framework is the basis for proper industry or, worse, multiplying subsidies
functioning markets, lack of it causes mar- that make social housing unsustainable. On
ket failure. This occurs when transactions the other hand, other cities just leave slums
are prevented from taking place and reach- to take care of the problems.
ing an efficient outcome. And so, public in-
tervention is necessary to fix markets. In ur- Financial Markets must support conditions
ban planning, weak legal frameworks affect for housing mortgages and the financing of
three major markets -land, housing and fi- properties through land acquisition or expro-
nance which are all closely inter-connected. priation by the government, which should
compensate landowners with the lands mar-
For proper land markets, local governments ket price to avoid negatively affecting private
must be able to implement planning poli- sector sustainability. Several financial instru-
cies, providing affordable access to com- ments must be in place for housing afford-
mercial properties and housing while main- ability according to the different income lev-
taining appropriate densities and mixed els of the population. Finance is also related
land uses. Public authorities must be able to to land value finance, which is allowing local
act responsively to readjust land and have governments, residents and private sectors
access to suitable areas for economic pur- to obtain a return from renewal and urban
poses. This implies that several things are in expansion. Multiple distortions affect finan-
place: recording tenure rights, implement- cial urban markets such as subsidies that are
ing planning, avoiding illegal and improper provided for political ends rather than techni-
use of land, having a mechanism for land cal solutions. Inflation, which depends on the
valuation and raising income from land tax- countrys monetary policy, can also destabi-
ation. Currently, lack of property rights are lize rent and mortgage markets and result in
the norm due to the weak technical capac- speculation and segregation.
ity of local governments to record and up-
date land registration, and forced eviction. Cities are not able to function properly in
large part because proper legal frameworks
Providing housing for all citizens through are not in place. With slums and informality
proper housing markets must be a policy becoming the rule rather than the excep-
priority. Ideally, housing must be available tion, cities become dual economies where,
for different income segments of popula- in the formal sector, markets exist to some
tions, and alternatives should exist com- extent but in the informal sector there are
prising housing through a mortgage system no rules or regulations, institutions are ab-
and social housing for low-income popula- sent and property rights do not exist. Having
tions, which must be temporary until better dual economies, one formal and connected

15
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

to modernity and another backward and IV. In Conclusion


constrained, is the main cause of inequal-
ity and the origin of potential social crisis, When we zoom out of cities to regions
with serious economic and political conse- and countries a clear pattern emerges as
quences. Fortunately, fixing and improving efficient neighbourhoods are clustered
the legal framework is possible. Based on and well connected to each other leading
our work at UN-Habitat, we have developed to more productive regions and countries.
a set of principles to support cities. First, it This provokes the philosophical ques-
is important to understand that providing tion of which factors drive development?
a legal framework is not state building, so While dozens of theories and hundreds of
interventions should not pretend to change approaches have traditionally emerged in
cities overnight; as cities evolve, institutions addressing this, we cannot deny the fore-
must be strengthened in parallel with in- most role of urban layout, planning, and
creased technical capacity. Second, improv- design in driving economic growth and
ing the legal framework is incremental and development based on years of field work
there are formal and informal rules and in- and technical analysis all over the world.
stitutions in place that must be identified
and leveraged as a continuum. Land titling Working in neighbourhoods to improve
and tenure is an important example that ba- urban design, planning, regulations, and
sic registration is the first of many steps that finance is the essential starting point for
progress into more complex cadastral sys- scaling up to cities, regions and countries.
tems and must be done with a participatory As we continue to support the implemen-
approach. Third, cities belong to a country tation of smart urban design policies, we
and therefore they cannot improve further are also enhancing our understanding of
if limitations come from their nations con- how urban value is generated and sus-
straints, rules, financing, technical expertise tained in cities. Urban planning and design
and titling which are all linked to the capac- creates urban value.
ity of the central government.

Dr. Joan Clos

Secretary General of Habitat III


Executive Director, UN-Habitat

Introduc-
tion
16
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Introduction
UN-Habitats priority is to support city lead- In order to measure the impact of a citys
ers to achieve sustainable urbanisation by performance in financial, legal and urban
providing urban planning methods and planning matters on urban productivity, ro-
systems to address current urbanization bust indicators are needed for both quan-
challenges such as population growth, ur- titative and qualitative analysis. This study
ban sprawl, poverty, inequality, pollution sets the basis to select a set of metrics and
and congestion as well as urban biodiversi- indicators which are reliable and can be
ty, urban mobility and energy. Internation- measured and monitored to put figures
al experience shows that cities and local on the generic Three Pronged-Approach
governments can support productive activ- framework and to provide a model of how
ities through suitable investments in urban the performance on these indicators affects
planning, infrastructures and institutions. urban productivity in the long run.

The main objective of this study is to It is meant as a practical tool as it provides


provide local governments and planning the methodology for measuring the eco-
departments with a rational approach to nomic impacts of different decisions in
Planned City Extension (PCE)1 by integrat- spatial planning, urban financial manage-
ing the three fundamental principles be- ment and legislation. It supports the pro-
hind sustainable urbanization proposed motion of a comprehensive integrated ur-
by UN-Habitats Three-Pronged Approach: ban planning agenda among policy mak-
good planned city extension, efficient ers and urban managers; strengthens the
municipal finance and proper legal frame- understanding of present and future gaps
work. Through a quantitative and quali- in urban strategies and creates a scientific
tative assessment of how these principles methodology for developing and manag-
affect urban productivity, it aims at mak- ing urban space, creating a comprehen-
ing the demonstration that: sive legal and institutional framework,
prioritizing investments and evaluating the
Well-planned cities have higher urban impact of long-term spatial planning deci-
productivity in the long run sions and infrastructure investments.

Financial and legal factors are key for This model is meant to encompass the
a successful implementation of plans dynamic process in urban environments.
and for creating an urban ecosystem Urban planning is not a once and for all
with steady and resilient value creation process; it is a dynamic process of urban
patterns evolution instead. The initial general plan
for a Planned City Extensions is the result
of a planning process within a legal frame-
work and under budgetary restrictions. The
1 See UN-Habitat (2015) Planned City Extensions: Anal-
ysis of Historical Examples, and Urban Lectures: Principles of initial general plan of the Planned City Ex-
Urbanisation http://unhabitat.org/tag/three-legged-approach/ tensions is meant to evolve over time to fos-
[Accessed 29dec2015]

17
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

ter processes of urban intensification such the Three Pronged approach to urbani-
as the densification of human activities, sation discussing key patterns: planning,
diversification of economic activities and transit oriented, community design, and
consolidation of land markets. To support financial patterns. The first section inves-
these dynamic processes of intensification, tigates the concept of urban productivity
diversification and consolidation, local gov- and the socio-economic mechanisms that
ernments have to provide the following make cities more productive: economies
fundamental basis of: of scale, economies of scope and agglom-
eration economies. This section addresses
An appropriate initial general plan, that the negative externalities that also might
gives room to further evolution arise. The second part, by Loeiz Bourdic
and Marco Kamiya is structured as follows;
An appropriate legal framework that
It presents the elements of integrated ur-
allows the initial general plan to be banization, the Three-Pronged Approach
implemented and that allows urban and the three essential components it rests
evolution processes to take place upon: urban planning, appropriate finan-
An appropriate financial framework to cial frameworks and governance and, fi-
nally, appropriate legal frameworks. The
finance the implementation of the plan
third section provides a methodology to
and feed and support the process of
measure urban productivity and assess the
urban evolution
performance of the components of the
The major objective of this model is to high- Three-Pronged Approach, using a compre-
light the benefits of a Three-Pronged Ap- hensive set of indicators. The fourth section
proach on urban productivity. Increases of present empirical evidence and case stud-
urban productivity result from a complex ies that highlight the links between urban
web of processes, including economies of planning, legal and financial indicators and
scale, economies of range and economies of urban productivity; urban planners, ur-
agglomeration induced by cost savings, loca- ban economists and practitioners can find
tion advantages, specialization premiums, or broad case studies supporting integrated
the higher intensity of interactions between approaches to urbanization and can rely on
people and companies. The concept of urban these cases to defend policy interventions.
productivity will be investigated into details in The fifth section is an annex that provides a
the second part of this report. The assump- theoretical economic model linking Planned
tion however that this study aims at demon- City Extensions characteristics and urban
strating, is that increases in urban productiv- productivity; non-mathematical readers can
ity can be achieved through following the safely skip this annex though it is important
fundamental principles of the Three-Pronged to highlight that this model can help to sup-
Approach in Planned City Extensions. port future approaches to measure a citys
productivity and can help to design impact
This study is structured as follows. The first evaluation schemes.
part by Serge Salat is a broad overview of

18
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

I Part 1

A new approach to
urban value creation
Serge Salat

19
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

In 2008, for the first time in human histo- Three-Pronged Approach from a strategic
ry, half of the worlds population lived in planning perspective for mayors, policy
urban areas, with two thirds in low-income makers, infrastructure investors, decision
and middle-income nations. This is estimat- makers, developers and more generally for
ed to rise to 60 per cent in 2030, and 70 practitioners who face the difficult task of
per cent in 2050 to a total of 6.2 billion. making cities grow, while financing infra-
Fast-growing cities face challenges of popu- structure and housing needs and creating
lations to shelter, huge infrastructure needs economic wealth and social inclusiveness.
to finance, a changing climate to adapt to
and the imperative to thrive in an evolv- Dr. Joan Clos, UN-Habitat Executive Direc-
ing and competitive global economy. How tor, has, with great insight, clarified the tri-
it meets these challenges will determine a angle of urban development in a simple and
citys success and quality of life. Accelerat- elegant manner, which should be an inspi-
ed urbanization is confronted by the triple ration for all policy makers. This triangle is
challenge of speed, scale and the scarcity of as follows:
resources. This can be summarized in simple
figures: in the coming 20 years, 1 million
Design
people per week will be urbanised with USD
10,000 per household on average. To this
constraint should be added the threats of
climate change and of resource exhaustion.

The present book, The Economics of the


Three-Pronged Approach to Urbanization:
Planned City Extension, Legal Framework,
and Municipal Finance, developed jointly by
UN-Habitat and The Urban Morphology and
Complex Systems Institute, addresses the Finance Governance
issues of urban governance, finance and
planning for urban transformation with an
Once this is understood the key planning
economic perspective. It is rich in econom-
problem becomes how to make this trian-
ic and institutional analysis based on sound
gle work in a dynamic way, how to create
scientific methodology. This introduction
positive feedback loops that self-reinforce
will not attempt to summarize its wealth
and create value and local development. In-
of results. It will build upon UN-Habitats
tegrated planning with highly efficient pat-
terns is the answer. The patterns explained
below set in motion UN-Habitats Three-
Pronged Approach. They are the generative
grammar of more competitive cities, with
In 2008, for the first time in
high quality neighbourhoods, lower infra-
human history, half of the worlds structure costs and lower CO2 emissions.
population lived in urban areas, These cities have lower transportation and
with two-thirds in low-income and housing costs for their residents. They are
resilient to natural hazards. They are partly
middle-income nations. self-financing by capturing value added.

20
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Because of the complexity2 of cities, of their patterns create value, while some damp-
unpredictable emerging3 properties, of the en it and some destroy it. So we need to
lock in effects of early infrastructure deci- understand which patterns initiate positive
sions, we need to plan and design our cities feedback loops that generate more value
in an integrated way with a long-term plan- and human well-being. For this, we can
ning vision of their development. Planning build upon the newly developed science of
often works in silos optimized by different cities as complex systems5 and upon suc-
agencies but urban reality never works in cess stories of cities that have implement-
this way and separate optimizations may ed these successful patterns early in their
lead to sub-optimal results. Integrated plan- development, or at moments where they
ning4 is the strategic process that allows needed to reinvent themselves. As this in-
cities to shape a common shared vision of troduction targets policy makers and prac-
their development, an overarching frame- titioners, it will develop more urban suc-
work to integrate a multiplicity of actions cess stories than theoretical explanations,
and initiatives that will reinforce each other. while building a framework for a more in
depth understanding of the new urban
It focuses on the physical, economic and pattern language.
social city, the functionality of its infrastruc-
ture for liveability and economic growth: We will show that integrated planning
housing that is too often too expensive and based on UN-Habitats Three-Pronged Ap-
not affordable for the urban poor, people proach can be summarized in a few inte-
sheltered from storms but too far away grative cross-cutting patterns. In a series of
from jobs, large inequalities in access to ed- four books6, UN-Habitat has started to bring
ucation and health across the urban space, together planning strategies and bundle
neighbourhoods that need more play- policies under the generic name of Urban
grounds, aged water and power systems Patterns for a Green Economy. This series
overdue for upgrade and congested streets covers themes such as working with nature,
with poor air quality threatening the health leveraging density, optimizing infrastructure,
of the most fragile. If these challenges re- and clustering for competitiveness. This in-
main unaddressed, they will undermine a troduction explains how this approach can
citys economy and its quality of life. become transformational when based on
the most recent discoveries of complexity
Successful integrated planning can be science applied to cities. The work done by
based on the recognition that some urban the Urban Morphology and Complex Sys-
tems Institute, starting by the publication of
2 Examples of complex systems are as diverse as the glob-
al economy: the human nervous system, ecosystems, the climate Cities and Forms, On Sustainable Urbanism,
system and the Earth system. This implies in particular that urban in 2011, followed by a series of papers on
variables are strongly interdependent and that changes can have
unintended consequences. More generally, complex systems can- mathematical regularities in efficient cities
not be broken down analytically into separate variables. This makes
it difficult to know exactly which inputs contribute to an observed
output, and the extent of each factors contributions.
3 An emergent behaviour or emergent property can appear
when a number of simple entities (agents) operate in an environ- 5 See: Serge Salat; with Franoise Labb and Caroline
ment, forming more complex behaviours as a collective. Nowacki, Cities and Forms. On Sustainable Urbanism, Hermann,
2011. Michael Batty, The New Science of Cities, MIT Press, 2013.
4 See: Serge Salat, Integrated Sustainable Urban Planning.
Nikos Salingaros, Principles of Urban Structure, Vajra Books, 2014.
A Preliminary Approach. Draft Conference Paper Prepared for the
Global Platform for Sustainable Cities (GPSC) Conference, Singa- 6 http://unhabitat.org/series/urban-patterns-for-a-green-
pore, March 2016. economy/

21
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

spatial structures7, has lifted the veil on Regulatory planning patterns may foster
the underlying structure of successful ur- an efficient city form or an inefficient dis-
ban patterns. This body of work allows a tribution of densities.
more in depth understanding of urban pat-
terns that work. We have a deeper under- Network patterns may agglomerate den-
standing of the concept of pattern today, sities in an efficient way matching public
40 years after the publication of Christo- transportation accessibility or disperse
pher Alexanders seminal book. A pattern them in the fragmented and diffuse spatial
is a discernible regularity in the world. As expansion called sprawl.
such, the elements of a pattern repeat in
a predictable manner. Abstract patterns in Community design patterns may create
science, mathematics, language, and ur- liveable and healthy communities with
ban space may be observable by analysis. positive continuous flow of public places
Patterns have an underlying mathemat- for people or endlessly repetitive accumu-
ical structure. Mathematics can be seen lations of identical disconnected buildings
as the search for regularities. Similarly, in separated by infrastructures.
the sciences, theories explain and predict
regularities in the world. Thus a science of Financial patterns may create positive
cities looks for explaining regularities, or feedback loops of value creation and cap-
patterns, in urban space. Understanding ture or destroy value.
urban patterns that work helps us to plan
cities in a more integrated way as patterns We need a new pattern language because
are by definition integrative. cities are complex systems that, like any
complex system, cannot be broken down
Because cities are complex adaptive sys- into separate elements for analytical pur-
tems8 highly dependent on initial condi- poses. They exhibit emerging properties
tions, on initial plans, on initial financial that cannot be predicted by simple regres-
patterns, on governance patterns, we have sions because the variables that describe
a lot to learn from regulatory patterns that them are interdependent. Urban space is
work, from network patterns that connect also not flat but bumpy and even spiky:
people to people through scales while it exhibits concentration in a few square
creating agglomeration economies that kilometres of very high values in a spike
increase productivity, from the pattern lan- and a long tail of low values on hun-
guage of liveable and healthy community dreds or thousands of square kilometres.
design, from financial patterns that create This is true for many urban characteristics
positive feedback loops of value creation. from demographic and jobs densities, to
networks connectivity, to land lots, to ur-
7 See among the most recent papers: Serge Salat, The
Break-Even Point. Impact of Urban Densities on Value Creation, ban economics, to energy productivity9.
Infrastructure Costs and Embodied Energy. SBE Turin Conference We will limit ourselves to a list of striking
Papers, http://sbe16torino.org/papers/SBE16TO_ID068.pdf.
examples. Within a city, 20 per cent of the
Serge Salat, A Systemic Approach of Urban Resilience. Power urban land produces 80 per cent of the
Laws and Urban Growth Patterns, International Journal of Urban
Sustainable Development, Special Issue Linking Urban Resilience citys GDP. Inner London with 20 per cent
and Resource Efficiency.
8 The notion of complex adaptive systems creates a unified 9 Serge Salat, The Break-Even Point. Impact of Urban Den-
method of studying disparate urban systems that elucidates the sities on Value Creation, Infrastructure Costs and Embodied Ener-
processes by which they operate and by which they increase or gy. SBE Turin Conference Papers, http://sbe16torino.org/papers/
dampen value creation. SBE16TO_ID068.pdf.

22
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

of Greater London area produces 70 per bell-shaped distribution clustered around


cent of its GVA10 and concentrates 56 per an average, with ~68 per cent of the data
cent of all Greater London private sector within one standard deviation of the av-
jobs. This is due to strong agglomeration erage, 95 per cent within two standard
and localization economies. Office space deviations, and 99 per cent within 3 stan-
in Manhattan (66 km) corresponds to dard deviations. As urban variables are not
60 per cent of the entire New York City distributed according to Gaussian laws
office space while NYC spans 780 km of around averages, this questions the use
emerged land with 8.5 million inhabitants. of averages in urban studies. Actual ur-
This office space is concentrated in only 6 ban distributions comprise heavy tails,
km of plots, which roughly correspond to where those outcomes that are far away
9 km of urban land. In Inner London (309 from the average are more likely than they
km), 29 per cent of office space is concen- would be in a Gaussian distribution. More
trated in less than 1 per cent of the urban generally, the shape of urban values distri-
area, in the City of London (450,000 jobs bution, their distribution pattern, is much
in 2.9 km with a growth of 30 per cent more important than their average.
during the last decade). These extreme
concentrations peak at 150,000 jobs/km
and are made liveable by high quality pub-
lic space like in Londons Canary Wharf or
in the project of Hudson Yards in Manhat-
tan. The Square Mile of the City of London
(2.9 km, 10 per cent of Central London,
1per cent of Inner London, and less than
0.2 per cent of Greater London) concen-
trates a disproportionate part of econom-
ic power in an extreme spike. The Square
Mile of the City of London generates 45
billion in economic output in 2014, equiv-
Inverse power laws are the hidden order of spiky economic landscapes,
alent to 14 per cent of Londons output
its pattern. People, jobs, and economic densities, office space density,
and 3 per cent of the UKs total GDP. The accessibility to jobs, rents, subway network centralities, and so on, across
cascade of spikes within spikes, the City the urban space follow skewed distributions that are modelled by inverse
power laws known in economy for a long time under the name of Pareto
of London spiking extremely high within distributions11. They comprise a few large and very large values (in green
the high spike of Inner London, points to on the left) and a long tail of small values on the right.

a fundamental property of urban economy


spatial patterns: there is no characteristic
scale; urban economic space is scale-free.

This requires some explanation. Most ur-


ban values are not distributed around
averages. They do not follow Gaussian
distributions. A Gaussian distribution is a

10 In 2009, Outer London produced 83 billion GVA and In-


ner London 186 billion . Source: Regional and sub-regional GVA 11 Serge Salat, A Systemic Approach of Urban Resilience. Power Laws and Urban
estimates for London, UK Office for National Statistics Briefing Growth Patterns, International Journal of Urban Sustainable Development, Special Issue
Note, 2009. Linking Urban Resilience and Resource Efficiency.

23
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

The new science of networks has shown tion, share the same mathematical form
that this scale free property is the intrin- with the same mathematical parameters.
sic order to the number, size, and shape of What can be similar between feudal land
the various attributes of networks12. And tenure in Medieval Paris, late 19th centu-
then in turn there is an intrinsic order of ry intense real estate speculation by the
spaces and places that depend on urban emerging French bourgeoisie of the Sec-
networks. As summarized by Michael Bat- ond Empire, Lower Manhattan Wall Street,
ty, in essence, the distribution of elements or Hong Kong? Surprisingly, what is similar
that compose the city - the hubs or nodes is the way land is distributed in parcels of
that sustain them - present us with highly different sizes. The frequency of land lots
skewed distributions, reflecting the essen- of different sizes follows an inverse power
tial economic processes of competition that law with the same exponent, - 0.5, in ex-
drive a citys functions and determine its tremely different cities14. And even more
form and structure13. These distributions surprising is the fact that this exponent
usually describe large number of small ob- -0.5 characterizes the random fragmenta-
jects and small number of large, following tion of the plan, as if, throughout different
what are called scaling laws that, in turn, historical trajectories and economic and
are usually configured as power laws, also social conditions, urban land markets fol-
called Pareto distributions in economy. lowed universal patterns rather than spe-
cific economic circumstances.
Power laws reflect processes that scale,
that in some sense are self-similar, and this These patterns of ordered complexity that
signature of a systems function implies have shaped cities across centuries and in
that the systems subsystems, components, some cases millennia of evolution are what
elements, are ordered hierarchically. These physicists call universality classes15. What
scaling processes generate urban growth these universality classes point towards
and underpin the citys evolutionary archi- is that the patterns of organization of re-
tecture, opening up our theory and model source efficient and resilient complex urban
of urban economy to the world of com- systems (their systemic architecture) are a
plexity theory, to forms that associate a long term limit that is an attractor stron-
high level of order in their macro-structure ger than the historical, social or economic
with a high level of diversity and random- specificities of each city or network. Univer-
ness in their details. sality classes are the signature of resource
efficient and resilient patterns selected by
The similar mathematical form of the reg- urban evolution. They reflect a process of
ularities behind these examples raises the
14 Salat, Serge (2015). Paris / New York 1215-1811-2015.
veil on the hidden fundamental nature of Huit sicles de hirarchie dchelle dans les parcellaires urbains.
urban space. Cities distant in time and Donnes Urbaines 7, Economica, Marie-Flore Mattei et Denise Pu-
main (Ed). Salat, Serge. (2015). Paris/New York 1215-1811-2015.
space such as Medieval Paris or Lower Eight centuries of hierarchies of scale in urban land lots Territorio
Manhattan or Hong Kong, phenomena Italia.

as different as some forms of centralities 15 In statistical mechanics, a universality class is a collection


of mathematical models, which share a single scale invariant limit.
in subway networks and jobs concentra- While cities, such as Paris, London, and New York, may differ dra-
matically at small scales, their behaviour will become increasingly
12 Albert-Laszlo Barabasi, 2014, Linked:How Everything Is
similar as the limit scale is approached. In particular, asymptotic
Connected to Everything Else and What It Means for Business,
phenomena such as critical exponents will be the same for all cities
Science, and Everyday Life,Basic Books.
in the class. In physics and in biology, they characterize complex
13 Michael Batty, 2013, The New Science of Cities, MIT Press. systems and phase transitions.

24
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

emerging order from the chaos of a myriad vent it. To make cities again both engines
of decisions, which become synchronized of economic growth and places of well-be-
by a flexible but mathematically precise ing for their inhabitants, we must under-
pattern of efficient systemic architecture. stand which patterns work and which do
not work in order to initiate urban spatial
It is not the purpose of this introduction transformation through critical changes in
to develop further on the fascinating in- design, finance and governance.
sights of this new science of cities and of
the new science of networks so the inter- These patterns, and in particular the artic-
ested reader can refer to Cities and Forms, ulation of densities, are extremely efficient
On Sustainable Urbanism16, and to a series for decoupling economic growth and re-
of my recent papers about cities as com- source use as demonstrated by an incom-
plex systems17 as well as to the papers and ing Report of UNEP International Resource
books of Michael Batty. Panel on Resource Requirements of Future
Urbanization18
It is the planning, designing, connecting,
financing patterns that work that we will Like Christopher Alexanders patterns, when
briefly now describe in further detail in this these new urban patterns are taken togeth-
introduction. These patterns have in com- er, they begin to form a kind of language,
mon that they embody in their configura- each pattern forming a word or thought of
tion planning recommendations done in a true language rather than being a pre-
this book or by UN-Habitat during the last scriptive way to design or solve an urban
years and during the preparation phase of problem. As the authors of the original Pat-
Habitat III. Instead of being isolated met- tern language write: Each solution is stat-
rics, they have a tremendous transforma- ed in such a way that it gives the essential
tive power when combined into patterns field of relationships needed to solve the
and bundled into integrated policies. problem, but in a very general and abstract
These patterns have worked in real success wayso that you can solve the problem for
stories of cities, such as New York at the yourself, in your own way, by adapting it to
beginning of 19th century, Tokyo, Seoul, your preferences, and the local conditions at
Singapore, Hong Kong, which in one gen- the place where you are making it19.
eration or two have moved from some-
times extreme poverty and urban chaos
to wealth, prosperity and a complex and 1. Planning Patterns
vibrant urban order with highly liveable
communities. We will also describe pat-
Integrated urban planning patterns are key
terns that dampen urban success or pre-
to create urban value. To transform con-
nectivity and accessibility enhancements
16 Serge Salat; with Franoise Labb and Caroline Nowacki,
Cities and Forms. On Sustainable Urbanism, Hermann, 2011. into GDP increases, into enhancement in
17 See in particular: Serge Salat, The Break-Even Point. Im-
pact of Urban Densities on Value Creation, Infrastructure Costs and 18 Co-lead authors: Maarten Hajer (IRP Member), Mark Swill-
Embodied Energy. SBE Turin Conference Papers, http://sbe16tori- ing (IRP Member), Anu Ramaswami (IRP Member), Sangwon Suh
no.org/papers/SBE16TO_ID068.pdf. (IRP Member), Serge Salat (IRP Member), Tim Baynes, Josephine
Musango, Resource Requirements of Future Urbanization, UNEP
Serge Salat, A Systemic Approach of Urban Resilience. Power
IRP, 2017.
Laws and Urban Growth Patterns, International Journal of Urban
Sustainable Development, Special Issue Linking Urban Resilience 19 Alexander, Christopher (1977). A Pattern Language: Towns,
and Resource Efficiency. Buildings, Construction. Oxford University Press, USA.

25
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

jobs accessibility and jobs opportunities non-renewable resource consumption


for the urban poor, while decreasing en- per household21.
vironmental pressure, it is essential to de-
Higher population and economic
velop compact city patterns, to articulate
densities with highly variable FARs with thresholds, which also means increased
fine granularity, and to develop neighbour- accessibility to services and amenities
hoods according to Transit-Oriented Devel- as higher economic thresholds are
opment patterns while coordinating inten- achieved within any given area, viable
sity of land use around public transporta- and effective public transport provi-
tion stations with their economic potential. sion based on sustainable population
thresholds to support the service.

1.1 The Compact City Harnessing of agglomeration advantages.


Pattern Reduction of time and cost spent travel-
Compact city patterns and planned (versus ling due to shortened distances to desti-
unplanned) urban extension can support nations.
sustainable urban patterns that benefit
the functioning of developed as well as Increased social inclusiveness and
developing world cities. Properly managed reduction in social segregation through
and appropriately applied, compaction ef- designing quality mixed-use areas.
forts can positively enhance the life of the
city dweller and support related strategies 1.2 The Articulated Density
aimed at promoting a green economy and Pattern: FARs
sustainable urban settlements. Compact
Planning the growth of cities to achieve ap-
city patterns aim to increase built area and
propriate densities and providing alternative
residential population densities to an ap-
forms of mobility to private vehicles help to
propriate level depending on the context
slow urban expansion onto ecologically sen-
and on locations; to intensify urban eco-
sitive land, and can reduce citizens demand
nomic, social and cultural activities, and
for scarce resources by sharing them more
to shape urban size, form and structure
efficiently.
in search of the environmental, social and
global sustainability benefits, which can be
This can be achieved only if high but rea-
derived from concentration of urban func-
sonable demographic densities are articu-
tions20. Within both the developed and the
lated according to efficient patterns with
developing world, the benefits of a com-
fine grain variation according to uses and
pact city have been proven to be:
public transportation accessibility while
jobs densities combine both strong ag-
Greater efficiency in the use of land and
glomeration in a few fast growing cores
so a positive impact on a citys spatial efficiently linked and a good jobs/housing
and ecological footprint, which also ratio in vibrant communities.
means reduction in reliance on cars,
lower impacts of urban growth on
rural and agricultural lands, and lower 21 UN-Habitat (2009). Planning Sustainable Cities, Global Re-
port on Human Settlements. London: Earthscan. Jenks, M; Burton,
20 Jenks, M and Burgess, R. (2000). Compact Cities. Sustaina- E; Williams, K (eds.) (1996), The Compact City. A sustainable urban
ble urban forms for developing countries. London: Spon Press. form? London: E&FN Spon.

26
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

International experience and the universal of inner subway network and suburban
patterns that we have described in the in- rail (termed between-central stations24)
troduction of this text suggest that intensity as they concentrate passenger flows and
of land use should not be evenly distributed have thus a high growth potential.
across urban space. Quite the opposite, it
should present strong variations and peak Beyond high spikes of economic agglomer-
where accessibility to jobs is at maximum. ation, there remains still two-thirds of jobs
More specifically, firms locate preferentially for creating a sufficient level of mixed use
where they can increase their productivity in stations that are not fast-growing core
through agglomeration and localization ef- stations. This appears in the maps of Lon-
fects. Advanced services providers location- don, Copenhagen, Stockholm, Hong Kong,
al decisions are particularly influenced by Tokyo, where there is a concentration of
the number of firms of the same type they jobs and social activity at close proximity
can access in short times. Highly dense con- of public transportation stations along the
centrations of economic activity foster local branches radiating from the core of the sub-
economic development through economies way network.
of urbanization and of localization22, which
attract skilled workers, as well as more pro- While an average density of 15,000 peo-
ductive entrepreneurs and firms23. ple per square km is efficient and can be
considered a desirable target at the scale
In highly competitive cities, such as New of about 10 million inhabitants on about
York and London, the highly dense con- 600 km of urban land (Tokyo 23 wards
centration of jobs peaks at 150,000 jobs/ and Seoul Special City are good examples),
km with one third of the jobs (1.5 million) what matters the most is the articulation of
agglomerated in 15 km. The urban form is densities. To reap the opportunities created
both compact and polycentric with several by investments in public transportation net-
fast growing sub-centres efficiently linked works, it is important to coordinate inten-
by public transportation: such as Midtown sity of land use and economic policies by:
and Lower Manhattan to which other sub- (1) encouraging development in the major
CBDs should be added like Hudson Yards, interchanges, in the most accessible stations
Brooklyn Downtown, Long Island City; or of the network and in the stations that are
such as the City and Canary Wharf in Lon- major articulations of the network; (2) mod-
don (which will be at 6 minutes by subway erating development in the areas that are
after Elisabeth line (Crossrail) opening in- less accessible within the network and (3)
stead of 21 minutes today). Tokyo Yaman- discouraging development in areas that are
ote line is a ring of fast growing sub-cen- more than 1 km from a subway station. The
tres concentrating highly productive activ- regulatory instrument to manage this artic-
ity along a 33 km long circle line. Network ulation of densities is Floor Area Ratio (FAR).
analysis shows the benefits of developing Floor area ratio (FAR) (also floor space ratio
sub-centres in stations at the articulation (FSR), floor space index (FSI), site ratio and
plot ratio) is the ratio of a buildings total
22 Rosenthal, S. & W. Strange, Evidence on the nature and
sources of agglomeration economies in V. Henderson and J. Thisse
24 Salat Serge and Ollivier Gerald. 2016. The 3V Framework:
(eds.) Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, (2004).Vol. 4.
Maximizing Economic Opportunities in TOD Station Areas by Match-
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 21192171.
ing Place, Node, and Market Potential Values. World Bank, Wash-
23 Productive Cities: Sorting, Selection, and Agglomeration, ington, DC. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO
Journal of Political Economy, (2014) 122 (3), pp. 507-553.

27
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

floor area (gross floor area) to the size of the sector to adjust intensity of development to
piece of land upon which it is built. market needs. This has been applied in Lon-
dons Kings Cross with margins of flexibility
Zoning policies can be fine-tuned to ac- between uses up to 20 per cent, which in-
cessibilities within public transportation creases the marketability of real estate op-
networks (subways, urban rail or Bus Rap- erations in developments that take years to
id Transports) to coordinate in an efficient be completed. This margin of flexibility can
way public transportation infrastructure also be used to capture part of the value
provision and land use development. First, created by real estate development to fi-
it is encouraged that FAR be set at differ- nance public transportation infrastructure
ent levels depending on uses and on ac- provision, public space and affordable hous-
cessibility such as in the example below in ing. For example, adapted zoning in Hud-
Seoul. Manhattan East Midtown rezoning son Yards sets varied FAR for predominantly
is also based on adjacency to public trans- commercial (FAR 10 to 33), mixed-use (FAR
portation. It includes a FAR of 24 for highly 6.5 to 12) and predominantly residential (6
accessible areas directly around Grand Cen- to 15) with a range between base and max-
tral Terminal, 21.6 FAR along Park Avenue, imum FAR, in order to introduce flexibility
and 18/14.4 FAR in other areas to the east and capture value26. Seoul has successfully
and west25. Second, it is recommended that shaped its urban form by setting FARs to en-
FARs include a margin of flexibility both for courage high-density development around
transferring FAR between uses according public transportation nodes as explained in
to market changes and for allowing private the box below.

25 Proposed East Midtown text amendment, 2013, NYC 26 Developers who want to build over base FAR and up to
maximum FAR (for example between base FAR 10 and maximum
FAR 33 for commercial use in the densest blocks), can do so by
paying bonus payments into the zoning-based District Improve-
ment Fund. This creates an additional real estate opportunity and
allows for demand-driven development. The District Improvement
Fund can be used to finance subway lines extensions, public space
and inclusionary housing, creating a positive feedback loop of de-
velopment from the initial rezoning at higher density, and social
mix within a Grade A mixed-use business district.

28
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Seoul zoning regulations encourage high-density development


around major public transportation nodes

Seoul zoning regulations set FARs as high as 10 for commercial uses around the most connected
and central public transportation stations, of between 2 and 4 for mixed residential and business
areas and between 1 and 2 for residential uses; uses are defined with a fine granularity depend-
ing on proximity to and importance of public transportation stations. This creates a varied city
juxtaposing quiet small residential neighbourhoods in close proximity to thriving business districts.

Seoul variations in FSI are linked to the location of metro stations and to the network of main streets. Source of the 3 pictures:
Alain Bertaud. Alain Bertaud. Used with the permission of Alain Bertaud. Further permission required for reuse.

29
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

1.3 The Transit-Oriented and road gasoline consumption per capita de-
Development Pattern clined by about 10 per cent.

Transit-Oriented Development (TOD) is a At the scale of functional urban regions and


planning and design strategy to ensure com- at city scale, TOD aligns urban growth with
pact, mixed-use, suitably dense, pedestrian transit accessibility thanks to integrated plan-
and two-wheeler friendly urban develop- ning of public transportation and land use. At
ment organized around public transportation network scale, TOD develops public transpor-
stations. It embraces the idea that locating tation corridors and station areas according to
amenities, employment, retail shops and the importance of lines and centrality of sta-
housing around public transportation hubs tions within the network. At community scale,
promotes public transportation usage and TOD develops mixed-use residential and com-
non-motorized travel. Well-planned TOD is mercial communities designed to maximize
inclusive in nature and integrates considera- access to public transport, improve quality of
tions of resilience to natural hazards. life and avoid the need for private motorized
transport. TOD incorporates features to en-
Transit-oriented cities enhance access and courage public transportation ridership and
mobility, and provide higher access to jobs to improve walking and cycling opportunities.
with lower transport and housing costs: for TODs generally are located within a radius of
example, in Hong Kong, 83 per cent of jobs one-quarter to half a mile (400 to 800 m) from
and 75 per cent of people are within 1 km of a a public transportation stop, as this is consid-
mass transit station; in the USA, residents near ered to be an appropriate scale for pedestri-
Transit-Oriented Development stations spend ans, thus solving the last mile problem. TOD
37 per cent of their income on transport plus is a pattern of urban development that should
housing against 51 per cent for other people. be planned at three levels:
Transit-oriented cities are more competitive
through agglomeration effects: doubling job At metropolitan/city level, TOD coor-
density increases economic productivity by 5
dinates economic, land use and trans-
to 10 per cent; in the most competitive global
port plans in order to achieve the best
city, New York, 60 per cent of office space
outcomes in terms of urban efficiency.
is agglomerated on only 9 km (1 per cent
of New York City land area). High-quality At network level, TOD plans transit
neighbourhoods lower infrastructure costs lines and human densities surrounding
and CO2 emissions. They offer opportunity to stations to achieve the highest levels of
reinvent urban space with public space and accessibility.
green areas while capturing economic value
through high returns on investments in urban At local level, TODs emphasis on density
quality. These cities are partly self-financing and a variety of land uses and social
by capturing value created: Hong Kong Rail mix around high-capacity public trans-
plus Property model allowed Hong Kong portation can be harnessed to create
government to derive about HKD 140 billion vibrant, liveable, inclusive and sustain-
gain (1980-2005) while unlocking land for able communities.
600,000 public housing units. Hong Kong in-
There is no one single pattern to be duplicat-
creased Gross Value Added (GVA) per capita
ed as a blueprint for developing areas around
of 50 per cent between 1993 and 2011 while
public transportation stations. Intensity of
CO2 emissions for transportation per capita

30
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

development and planning strategies should healthcare, of type of urban develop-


be adapted to the economic potential of each ment, of local accessibility to daily needs
station. This should be done in a dynamic way, by walking and biking, of quality of
leveraging on changes in regulatory planning the urban fabric around the station, in
and investment in connectivity in underutilized particular its pedestrian accessibility, the
urban assets, in order to create financial val-
small sizing of urban blocks and the fine
ue that can be captured. To create a positive
mesh of connected streets that create
feedback loop of urban value creation based
vibrant neighbourhoods, and the mixed
on the planning and design/finance/govern-
pattern of land use that creates diversity.
ance triangle, it is important to understand
what defines value in different urban locations Market potential value describes the
and how to create and capture value. To do market potential of stations areas, that
so, a recent methodology developed by the is the relationship between market
World Bank27, The 3V Framework: Maximizing
demand and market supply, which can
Economic Opportunities in TOD Station Areas
be determined by various approach-
by Matching Place, Node, and Market Poten-
es, including: human density (that is
tial Values, has built a typological approach for
residents plus jobs densities) with fore-
clustering station neighbourhoods according
to three values: casted increases, which will attract real
estate development; number of acces-
Node value describes the importance of sible jobs within 30 minutes by public
a station derived from its passenger traffic transportation, which drive people and
volume, inter-modality, and centrality firms locational choices; FARs, and
within the network. land opportunities for development and
market vibrancy. The approach should be
Place value describes the urban quality
looking forward rather than being static
of a place and its attractiveness to resi-
or looking backward.
dents in terms of amenities, schools and

Market Potential Value

Left: 3V framework. Right:


Synchronization of high
peaks of node value (major
Place Value connecting hubs) with
high quality place making
Node Value creates spikes of market
potential value.

Source: Salat Serge and Ollivier Gerald. 2017. The 3V


Framework: Maximizing Economic Opportunities in TOD

27 Salat Serge and Ollivier Gerald. 2017. The 3V Frame-


work: Maximizing Economic Opportunities in TOD Station Areas by
Matching Place, Node, and Market Potential Values. World Bank,
Washington, DC. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0
IGO Station Areas by Matching Place, Node, and Market
Potential Values. World Bank.

31
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

The 3V Framework allows the capturing of 1. Building a typology of stations, which


the potential of development created by the classifies the hundreds of stations of a
interplay of these values. This framework mass transit network into sub-groups
provides an analytical method to classify for applying different development
public transportation stations according to strategies.
their potential to foster economic concen-
tration and land value increases. It aims at 2. Determining the imbalances between
strategizing about ways to encourage the connectivity, accessibility, place quality
development of high-performing commu- and market potential values in the same
nities around public transportation stations station. These imbalances create a high
and to build transit systems that maximize potential for economic value creation,
development potential. Additional policies such as creating place value around an
should also address gentrification potential important connective node or bringing
and ensure a social mix.
additional connectivity to a booming
area (see Section 4 of this text)
The 3V Framework presents two main inter-
ests for policy makers: Several levers are available to increase node,
place and market potential value as summa-
rized in the table below.

Node Value Place Value Market Potential Value

Increase number of hubs and Increase compactness (proximity to Increase residential density
number of lines/modes they existing urban activity and short travel
Increase job density
connect to time to main destinations)
Increase human density
Interlink neighbouring stations Increase diversity of uses
into clusters Increase diversity of land parcels to create a vibrant
Increase concentration of commercial,
land market
Increase accessibility within the cultural and education amenities
network for all Increase social diversity
Design neighbourhoods that promote
walking and biking Allow for vertical separation of development rights
Create a vibrant public realm Increase FARs

32
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

2. Transportation trality) while other networks are random


and flat. The striking structural differenc-
Network Patterns es between a random network and one
presenting a high level of hierarchy in the
The layout of public transportation net- pattern of its connections are best seen by
works is key for urban forces of agglomera- comparing a road map with an airline rout-
tion and densities distributions across urban ing map. On a road map, cities are the nodes
space. Cities are networks from which loca- and the highways connecting them the
tions emerge. Transportation networks give links. This is a fairly uniform network: each
shape and structure to cities. They can have major city has at least one link to the high-
a strong lock in effect as they reinforce den- way system and there are no cities served
sity patterns with positive feedback loops. by hundreds of highways. Most nodes are
fairly similar with roughly the same number
Locations are the product of interactions. of links. Such uniformity is an inherent prop-
Cities are networks of interactions and their erty of random networks with a Gaussian
density patterns derive from their network degree distribution. The airline routing map
patterns28. Thus, we can use the new sci- differs drastically. The nodes of this network
ence of networks29 to study cities. Urban sys- are airports connected by direct flights be-
tems vary over time and from place to place tween them. This network has a few major
but some network patterns are so general hubs and the vast majority of airports are
that they transcend time and place30. These tiny nodes with at most a few links connect-
network patterns explain the numbers of ing them to one or several hubs. In a similar
people travelling between different origins way, subway networks have a few major
and destinations in the city and the hierar- hubs connecting many lines in the city core.
chy of centralities in subway networks, that
is the ranking of subway stations according Explaining how centralities in public trans-
either to their number of direct connections portation networks can be defined and
to other stations (degree centrality) or to measured with concepts such as degree cen-
the number of shortest paths through the trality, closeness centrality and betweenness
network that go through them (between centrality, derived from social sciences, and
centrality). how these measures can become a powerful
tool for assessing the development potential
Some networks, such as subway or airlines of specific station areas and the structure of
networks, present highly ordered patterns, connective values across an urban transpor-
structured around hubs (high degree cen- tation network (node values) goes beyond
the limited scope of this introduction. Inter-
28 Both are structured spatially by power laws (see introduc- ested readers may refer to Salat Serge and
tion).
Ollivier Gerald, 2017, The 3V Framework:
29 Albert-Laszlo Barabasi, 2014, Linked:How Everything Is
Connected to Everything Else and What It Means for Business, Maximizing Economic Opportunities in TOD
Science, and Everyday Life, Basic Books. Station Areas by Matching Place, Node, and
30 An urban system is constituted of related parts or compo- Market Potential Values.
nents. These components are connected by a network, or structure,
that may be of more interest than the components. Actually, the
equally simple laws that we have discovered in urban networks For simplicitys sake, we are going to divide
characterize most complex networks. They are behind the networks
the complex typology of urban networks
of actors in Hollywood, the linkages between mathematicians, the
distribution of citations in physics journal, the interaction of mole- into three pattern types and describe briefly
cules within the cell, the connections of neurons within the brain.

33
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

their impact on people and economic densi- subway patterns in global cities tend to con-
ties patterns: random car-oriented patterns verge towards a similar layout characterized
and sprawl; core and branches subway pat- by a core and branches structure31. The core
terns and agglomeration economies; grid- of a radius about 5 km is densely connected
like subway patterns and compact polycen- with a constant density of stations, highly
tric cities. interconnected by crisscrossing lines, and
ensures high levels of accessibility for peo-
ple and companies. The structure changes
2.1 Random Car-Oriented for branches, with a density of stations de-
Patterns and Sprawl creasing sharply,32when moving away from
As random car-oriented road networks do the city core. Thus, levels of accessibility de-
not embed a hierarchy of nodes, they lead crease sharply when crossing the core limit.
to uniform density distributions, that is to The core and branches layout has a strong
American suburbia types of development. impact on local development potential.
Quite the opposite are the street patterns Once established, this core and branches
of European cities, which embed a hier- structure determines the long-term trajec-
archy of nodes (think of Paris Haussmann tory of densities.
boulevards star-like patterns) and a hierar-
chy of connectivity (measured, for example,
2.3 Grid-like Subway
by the number of streets that a given street
connects). Although seemingly a uniform
Patterns and Compact
grid, New York streets pattern presents a Polycentric Cities
major asymmetry in connectivity: while the
More grid-like subway patterns may pro-
11 avenues each connect with about 135
duce different densities and economic
streets, each street connects with about 11
growth spatial distributions. The Seoul sub-
avenues. This means that avenues are 13
way network pattern, which was designed
times more connective than streets. This
at a later stage of development (the first
break of symmetry in the streets pattern
line was inaugurated in 1974, 90 years af-
has been enough to create strong forces of
ter Londons Circle line) for a city planned
economic concentration in Midtown. While
at a wider scale of 600 km for 10 million
random networks disperse urban growth,
inhabitants, has a layout less concentrated
hierarchically structured networks, such as
towards a core and more grid-like, encour-
historical streets and subways, concentrate
aging thus the emergence of fast growing
urban growth.
sub-centres such as Gangnam-gu.

2.2 Core and Branches


Subway Patterns
and Agglomeration
31 Camille Roth, Soong Moon Kang, Michael Batty et
Economies Marc Barthelemy, A long-time limit for world subway networks,
Journal of the Royal Society, J. R. Soc. Interface doi:10.1098/
The pattern of transit networks has impor- rsif.2012.0259, 2012.
tant implications on levels of transit acces- 32 The sharp decrease in density of stations with distance to
city centre follows an inverse power law of the form R. - 1.6. See:
sibility of the different urban areas. Inter- Serge Salat and Loeiz Bourdic, Lconomie spatiale du Grand Paris.
national experience suggests that efficient Connectivit et cration de valeur, Urban Morphology and Com-
plex Systems Institute and Caisse des Dpts. 2015.

34
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

3. Community Design 3.1 Density Patterns


Patterns for Urban Density patterns should be appropriate to
the context. Occurring at the same time
Vitality as agglomeration in the core, which hap-
pens naturally as a network effect under
Patterns should not be looked at in isolation market forces, Transit-Oriented Develop-
as they are interlinked. Together, they form ment planning encourages intensification
a new urban pattern language for fostering of human density (people plus jobs) with
urban vitality. Since every project is part of a good job/housing mix around the most
the overall urban fabric, how projects con- connected transit stations outside the core,
nect to each other and to the city is a central while preventing development in the less
tenet of urban design. Streets, public transit, accessible areas between the branches. In
bike-ways and connected green space tie complement to the core, polycentric centres
the city together, as underlined by Dr. Joan linked via public transportation with a suf-
Clos, who said: The proportion of urban ar- ficient mixed-use in terms of combination
eas dedicated to streets and public spaces is of jobs and housing avoid creating one-way
a crucial feature of the spatial plans of cities. flows at peak work hours. UN-Habitat35 rec-
Indeed cities that have adequate street and ommends that the job-resident ratio (the
public spaces and greater connectivity are number of people employed divided by the
more liveable and productive33. Creating number of residents) should be between
more direct connections with a fine mesh of 0.5 and 0.7 over every commuting district,
streets shortens travel time, which effective- which should have a spatial area that is no
ly brings people closer to their destinations. more than 15 km.
With more available connections, commu-
nity residents can get to schools, retail cen-
tres and parks. The smaller the blocks, the 3.2 Street Patterns: The Leaf
greater number of intersections, the more Pattern
storefronts, the more diversity, the more As stated by Dr. Joan Clos: The relevance
choice of routes, the more chances for ser- of street patterns and public space re-
endipity. All this leads to more urban vitality. quires planning at the initial stage of urban
Actually, the vibrancy of mixed-use streets growth. Otherwise, if urbanization happens
and neighbourhoods, cannot be achieved if spontaneously, the introduction of pub-
the underlying urban fabric remains coarse, lic space afterwards becomes very difficult
that is large and monotonous. The follow- and expensive, both politically and eco-
ing patterns provide the framework for vi- nomically. This paradox of the public space
brant communities, which are the building is that we need to design it in advance of
blocks of living cities. They are described in the growth36. The street system provides
more detail in the book Cities and Forms, the connectivity matrix for the city, which
On Sustainable Urbanism34. is fundamental not only for urban mobility
but also for inclusiveness, economic vibran-
33 Joan Clos, The value of public space in urban areas and cy and people interactions.
street patterns in cities a case of spatial fix, in UN-Habitat
Working Paper, The relevance of street patterns and public space in
urban areas, April 2013. 35 Issue and Policy Paper on Spatial Planning in preparation of
Habitat III, 2015.
34 Serge Salat; with Franoise Labb and Caroline Nowacki,
Cities and Forms. On Sustainable Urbanism, Hermann, 2011. 36 Ibid.

35
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

As underlined by Dr. Joan Clos, the effi- cation between the citizens. In that sense,
ciency of mobility is a determinant for urban it defines the cultural and political quality
economic productivity. Secondly, the street of city life. Fourthly, the walkability of the
pattern also provides the matrix for the spaces, the safety of the sidewalks and the
layout of urban basic services, mainly ener- form and location of shops along the street
gy, water supply and sanitation, drainage, determines the quality and quantity of
transportation, parking slots and other ser- street life. When safety and security issues
vices. The affordability of these urban ser- arise, public space is abandoned and gated
vices is related also to the quality of street communities emerge as a form of protec-
patterns. Thirdly, the street pattern, includ- tion against the rest of the city. This results
ing plazas and public gardens, is the key ele- in the failure in the function of cultural life
ment of personal interaction and communi- of the street.37

Left. Eco-neighbourhood based on a traditional urban texture in the Shanghai area with Franoise Labb the architect. Size of
square: 800 metres. The plan of the eco-district combines geometric and organic patterns. Its form is generated by dynamic forces.
It grows organically with the patterns of a leaf. The plant comes from a single cell and develops organically according to a very
precise geometry. It is at the same time one and multiple. Source: Serge Salat et al., Cities and Forms. On Sustainable urbanism.
Right: The veins in a leaf contain loops that arise to handle damage and the fluctuations in nutrient needs

37 Ibid.

36
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Urban connectivity leads to urban vitality. This traditional fine mesh street pattern dif-
Street patterns must be easily navigable and fuses automobile traffic onto several nar-
lattice like, with blocks that are not too big rower roads at slower speeds. Traditional
and intersections that are not too far apart. street meshes follow a pattern widely used
In planned cities, streets are typically laid by nature to optimize variable flow diffusion
out on a grid plan, so that city blocks are and resist to damage: leaf patterns. One of
square or rectangular. Using the perimeter the most resilient network structures is that
block development principle, city blocks of leaves. Hierarchical trees in nature, or in
are developed so that buildings are locat- many systems such as engineered roads ac-
ed along the perimeter of the block, with cording to American standards, are entirely
entrances facing the street and semi-private disconnected on a given scale: even if two
courtyards in the rear of the buildings. This twigs are spatially close, if they do not be-
arrangement provides good social interac- long to the same branch, to go from one to
tion among people. the other implies moving down and then up
all the hierarchy of branches. Urban high-
The spacing of streets in grid plans varies ways, car-oriented infrastructures, central-
widely among cities, or even within cities. ized energy infrastructures are trees: they
Many cities around the Mediterranean, separate urban elements and do not con-
were originally founded as Roman military nect them at local scales. Leaves are quite
settlements, and often preserve their orig- the opposite.
inal grid layout around two main orthogo-
nal axes. Notable examples are Turin, Flor- Katifori and Magnasco38 modelled the veins
ence and Bologna with their 70-metre side of a leaf, called xylem, as a network of
blocks. Japan has an even thinner mesh of pipes with varying flow and pressure. Giv-
streets with an average distance between en limited amounts of pipe, they asked how
intersections of 50 metres. The standard the pipe should be distributed to minimize
block in Manhattan is about 60m 260m. drops in water pressure and to make

Street network model design: Dense street patterns encourage


efficient traffic, sustainable accessibility, social interaction,
public safety and access to amenities. The figure shows a simple
street network model. In an area of one km, nine vertical and
nine horizontal streets are designed to form a street grid. The
distance between two adjacent streets is 111m, and the total
street length is 18km and the number of intersections per km is
100. In this street network model, recommended by UN-Habitat,
both street hierarchy and block size are considered. This simple
model demonstrates the balance between street and other land
uses. City management and urban planners could adjust the
design pattern of the street network to the topography of the
site or create rectangular patterns like in New York and most
North American cities but a street density level similar to the one
recommended in the model should be maintained.

38 Eleni Katifori, Gergely J. Szllsi, and Marcelo O. Magnasco,


Damage and Fluctuations Induce Loops in Optimal Transport Net-
works, Phys. Rev. Lett. 104, 048704 (2010), January 29, 2010.

37
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

the system as resilient as possible to dam- interweaving of social, economic and phys-
age? Hierarchically nested loops patterns ical connections. Like textiles, traditional
meaning loops within loops within loops urban fabric came in many different types
are most resistant to damage. Loops and weaves. These different ways of weav-
make the network redundant. If you have ing the physical and social space of cities
damage, water can be rerouted to other is what gave them their singularity and
channels. Loop networks can also better uniqueness. While traditional urban fabrics
handle fluctuations in fluid flow as envi- can be multiple and diverse in the same city,
ronmental conditions change. Francis Cor- reflecting climates, time, evolution, culture
son39 of Rockefeller University in New York and societies, while they are fine tuned to
used computer models to examine why local conditions and while their generative
these loops exist. By studying fluctuations grammar has led to endless variations, with
in demand, he discovered one purpose of pure types and hybrids, modernist super-
the loops: they allow for a variable delivery blocks have imposed a universal way of
system. Flows can be rerouted through the building cities identical from South America
network in response to local pressures in the to India to China.
environment, such as different evaporation
rates in different parts of a leaf. When time For simplicitys sake, we are going to divide
variations or fluctuations are allowed for, urban fabrics into two broad pattern types:
a class of optimal patterns different from coarse grain and fine grain or, put another
trees is found: they share the hierarchical way, modernist superblocks and traditional
organization of trees yet they contain loops. small blocks.40

These results are relevant not only to biolo- Superblock urban fabric characterizes 20th
gy but also to constructed urban networks Century Modernist planning principles. It is
that distribute goods over roads or electrical actually an anti-fabric as it unweaves the
power over wires. Counteracting the vul- continuity of urban space, separates build-
nerability of contemporary cities requires a ings, designed as giant simplified structures
paradigm reversal and a shift from a mo- with no detail, and infrastructures. It has
no-scale conception to a scale-free concep- been invented by Le Corbusier in the 1920s,
tion of cities. Only multi-connected scale- and showcased in projects such as The City
free structures, similar to natural leaves, can for Three Million Inhabitants, the Radiant
secure optimal efficiency and resilience of City, or Plan Voisin, designed between 1922
variable flow networks, while limiting the and 1925, with the explicit aim of razing
propagation of local perturbations. Paris to the ground, and replacing its fine
grain urban fabric inherited from 1,000
years of urban history with modernist super-
3.3 The Fine Grain Urban blocks, 400-metre side, separated by giant
Fabric Pattern highways 100 metres wide.
Urban fabric is the physical form of towns
and cities. Urban fabric is not just the built The Radiant City was to emerge from a tab-
form, however; it also reflects the delicate ula rasa: it was to be built on nothing less
40 A city block, urban block or simply block is a central ele-
ment of urban planning and urban design. A city block is the small-
39 Francis Corson, Fluctuations and Redundancy in Optimal
est area that is surrounded by streets. City blocks are the space for
Transport Networks, Phys. Rev. Lett. 104, 048703 (2010), January
buildings within the street pattern of a city, and form the basic unit
29, 2010
of a citys urban fabric.

38
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

than the grounds of demolished vernacular compared to UN-Habitats recommenda-


European cities. The new city would contain tions of between 80 to 100 intersections/
identical high-density skyscrapers, spread km, and has been considerably reduced
across a vast green area and arranged in during the past decade. Street intersection
a Cartesian grid, allowing the city to func- density presents high variations. It is high in
tion as a machine. Within superblocks, the city core where it corresponds to interna-
buildings are no more to be aligned along tional benchmarks (over 80) and it decreas-
streets (We must kill the street, wrote Le es sharply when moving to the suburbia to
Corbusier in his book Urbanism). Building reach less than ten on most municipality
types are radically reduced to identical out land area. This density has considerably de-
of proportion cruciform towers (220-metres creased from 33 in 2000 to 13 in 2010 be-
high with a 190-metre span in the original cause urban expansion (almost doubling of
Le Corbusier prototype) or 1-kilometre or built area from 1,147 km in 2000 to 2,196
more long slabs (redents) spanning several km in 2010) has occurred in the form of
superblocks. Though radical, strict and to- superblocks with low connectivity.
talitarian in its order, symmetry and stand-
ardization, Le Corbusiers proposed princi- Contrary to what is often thought, sprawl
ples had an extensive influence on modern is not an undesirable effect of lack of plan-
urban planning and led to the development ning. It is a highly planned form of urban
of new housing types widely used in the re- expansion based upon the distances and
construction period in Europe in the 1960s speed scales for the automobile. Suburban
and which are still very influential in the ur- subdivisions planning in the United States,
banization of fast-growing cities. for example, prescribes a strict command hi-
erarchy classification of access roads based
Most of 20th Century city planning has on highway engineering with no less than
been based on superblocks, either in the 300 metres between road crossings. Urban
highly-repetitive Le Corbusier model, lead- sprawl based on superblocks is the direct
ing to the endless alignments of identical outcome of road planning in China with
high rise towers in Chinese cities landscapes low FARs and strictly mono-functional zon-
created during the past 20 years, or in di- ing on dozens of square kilometres of land.
verse sprawl variations.41 Shanghais recent
urban expansion, for example, combines In a residential area of a suburb, the inte-
sprawl with towers-in-a-park superblocks. rior of the superblock is typically served
Recent World Bank and Chreod Ltd. studies by dead-ended or looped streets. The dis-
have shown a spectacular decrease in den- continuous streets served the automobile
sities and in street densities in Shanghai. In as longer distances, and the extra fuel re-
ten years, from 2000 to 2010, Shanghai has quired to go between destinations, was not
built with an urban pattern of superblocks a concern. However, at the pedestrian scale,
an additional land area equal to 125 per the discontinuity of the roads added to the
cent of the area of New York City and to distance that must be travelled. The discon-
two-thirds the area of Greater London. Av- tinuity inside the superblock meant car de-
erage street intersection density in Shanghai pendency, discouraged walking and forced
is very low, (13 intersections/km in 2010) more traffic onto the fewer continuous
streets. This increased demand for through
41 Superblocks are often found in suburbs or planned cities, or
are the result of urban renewal of the mid-20th Century, where a streets, which led ultimately to these streets
street hierarchy has replaced the traditional grid.

39
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

having more travel lanes added for cars, quent and, as a result, so are storefronts.
thereby making it more difficult for any pe- This offers many opportunities for discovery
destrian to cross them. In this way, super- and exploration. There are almost no va-
blocks cut up the city into isolated units, ex- cant lots or surface parking. Also, as there
panded automobile dominance and made are more intersections, traffic is slower and
it impossible for pedestrians and cyclists to safer. Fine grained urban fabric evolves over
get anywhere outside of the superblock. time by responding to what came before
and adapting to what will come afterwards.
We know today that superblocks create This evolutionary process creates places
social alienation. They do not give oppor- that are not frozen in the era when they
tunities for connecting people to people; were built, but are dynamic and reflective
such an urban pattern is inhospitable to of a neighbourhoods changing needs. This
interaction. Such places are not street ori- creates an urban fabric that can seamlessly
ented; instead, they turn inward and fortify evolve over time from lightly developed res-
themselves against the imagined dangers of idential areas to mixed-used retail to dense
the outside. Superblocks patterns are also urban core, according to the dynamic in-
highly energy intensive, as demonstrated in terplay of three values describes in the 3V
the Chinese context by the MIT and the En- Framework. In this way, they are far more
ergy Foundation. Most new developments resilient than mega projects which, when
in China are built on superblocks 400-800 they lose a single tenant, often fail.
metres long that are two to four times less
dense (in spite of their high rise towers-in-
a-park form of development) and two times 3.4 Public Places Patterns:
more energy intensive per household than Designing the Space of
any other urban forms found in China as Human interaction
demonstrated by a MIT study in Jinan com- Public space gives vibrancy to urban life and
paring operational, transportation, and em- it is intimately linked to the sizing, scaling
bodied energy per household for four urban and to the rhythm of urban fabric. We can-
fabric types in 27 neighbourhoods across not design good public places independent-
the city.42 ly of fine grain urban fabric. Modernist
layouts, with their repetitive architectural
The opposite of superblocks is tradition-
objects in an empty space and their ur-
al small perimeter blocks that have been
ban space segregated into built form and
re-discovered as the optimal pattern of sus-
unbuilt form, are actually the negation of
tainable cities first by Jane Jacobs and by
urban fabric and of public space. The map
the New Urbanism movement. Although
of Roma drawn by Giambattista Nolli in
extremely diverse, fine grain urban fabric
1748, for example, does not create a divi-
follows a common pattern. It consists of
sion between interior and exterior spaces or
several small blocks close together. Within
between solid masses and empty spaces, as
each block are several buildings, most with
we would do today, but rather between, on
narrow frontages, frequent store fronts and
the one hand, the continuous public space
minimal setbacks from the street. Streets
of streets, squares, large churches and in-
and opportunities to turn corners are fre-
terior palace courtyards and, on the other
42 Designing Clean Energy Cities. New Approaches to Urban hand, the compact mass of private build-
Design and Energy Performance. MIT, Tsinghua University, The En-
ings. The continuity of public space, encom-
ergy Foundation, 2010.

40
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

passing outside and inside, is fundamental itive space, that is space with an identifia-
in the traditional European city. ble shape and direction. Alexander, Ishikawa
and Silverstein say that: an outdoor space
The primordial figure of public space stands is positive when it has a distinct and definite
out against the backdrop of continuous shape, as definite as the shape of a room,
building facades, interior as well as exte- and when its shape is as important as the
rior, creating a feeling of enclosure. Ca- shapes of the buildings that surround it44.
thedral vaults become skies and the sky This positive space traditionally comprised
above squares becomes the ceiling over a not only streets and sequences of squares
big outdoor lounge. Urban public space is and gardens but also the interior of large
the stage of urban rituals. The modernist buildings, such as courtyards of palaces and
movement undid urban syntax and all ur- interiors of churches. There was no separa-
ban rituals by destroying public space. In Le tion between street and buildings but rather
Corbusiers projects, positive public places a continuum of public space, which was the
were replaced by a formless empty space stage of urban life.
between buildings a space divested of
its positivity and which thereby becomes In liveable cities, the largest public spaces
pure negativity. Form and ground were re- are the size of a small block (they are an
versed. In traditional cities, public places empty block carved out the continuity of
were a meaningful form framed by building the urban fabric) and public space is en-
facades. In modernist planning, buildings dowed by urban design qualities.
become forms isolated in an empty ground.

Numerous perceptual qualities affect the 3.5 Green Spaces Patterns


individual reactions to a place, the walking
A hierarchical, interconnected system of
experience, the sense of safety, the sense of
natural spaces, ranging from a regional
comfort, the level of interest and, thus, the
greenbelt to a pocket play park, should,
value of a location. To achieve overall walk-
from a landscape ecology perspective, pro-
ability, urban designers should create urban
vide the main structuring elements of urban
qualities, such as spirit of place, enclosure,
settlements. This principle reflects the im-
human scale, layering of space, complexity,
portance of identifying natural systems and
coherence, legibility and linkage.43 Urban
strategic landscape patterns, which protect
design is subtler and complex than metrics
valuable ecosystem services and biodiver-
as it shapes human perception of places
sity hotspots, of designing the city around
and of sequences of spaces in a positive
these, and of linking these systems when
or negative manner. Negative spaces are
they are fragmented.
empty spaces left between buildings. They
are spaces without shape, sense of direction
and purpose. They will not sustain human 3.6 Diversity Patterns
interest even if benches and amenities are
provided. Good urban design provides pos- Diversity patterns comprise a fine grain of
mixed uses with varying housing typology
43 For a detailed explanation see Chapter 4 in: Salat Serge and options, economic opportunities, multi-func-
Ollivier Gerald. 2016. The 3V Framework: Maximizing Economic
Opportunities in TOD Station Areas by Matching Place, Node, and 44 Alexander, C., S. Ishikawa, and M. Silverstein, A Pattern Lan-
Market Potential Values. World Bank, Washington, DC. License: guage: Towns, Buildings, Constructions, Oxford University Press,
Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO New York, 1977.

41
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

tional green spaces and social facilities. A support them. Diversity patterns imply
better way of looking at mixed use is diver- creating neighbourhoods that build au-
sity. This was advocated by Jane Jacobs45 thentic places through multiple uses that
in her classic book, The Death and Life of are intimately related, interconnected and
Great American Cities. Mixed use means interdependent. True urban diversity comes
more than mixing residential and commer- from the relationships between uses, ten-
cial. It also means proximity to other uses ants and the organizations within a place.
such as schools/universities, parks, muse-
ums, courthouses, industries, train stations
and so on. Not every building needs to have 3.7 Land Lots Patterns
multiple uses or tenants but each block City blocks may be subdivided into any
should and each neighbourhood must. number of smaller land lots usually in pri-
These kinds of destinations help to define vate ownership, though in some cases, it
a citys or a neighbourhoods identity. They may be other forms of tenure. These land
do so through the variety of uses and pub- lots are the basic unit of land markets.
lic spaces that highlight local assets and Diversity of land parcel sizes can meet fu-
unique talents and skills of the community ture demand and create an adaptive city.
-educational, cultural and commercial - that However, Chinese current urban develop-
are all open and available to all visitors to ment, is quite the opposite and is based
enjoy for free. on large superblocks (400-metre side)
that are the current unit of land sales to
Such neighbourhoods allow residents to vis- developers. This contrasts strongly with
it, become involved and stay awhile. They the 80 times smaller unit of land sales
are not defined by architecture but rather (200m2), which was the original basis of
by the uses that are front and centre and by Manhattan land market.
the buildings and design elements that

Manhattan plot consolidation principle. Left: Manhattan original plot subdivision in 1811. Average land lot size:
205 m. Middle: Manhattan Intermediary lot consolidation. Average lot size: 255 m. Right: Manhattan Extreme
lot consolidation. Average lot size: 6,100 m.
Source: Urban Morphology and Complex Systems Institute.

45 It is fatal to specialize the more diverse we are in what


we can do the better. (Jane Jacobs).

42
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Manhattan today shows a huge diversifica- Good-quality pedestrian connections


tion of land lot sizes and lot intensity of de- such as sidewalks and street crossings.
velopment. On an area of 60 km (the size of
Traffic calming, traffic and parking
Manhattan), taking into account the much
larger road surface in Chinese urban plan- management.
ning, there would be initially 300,000 units Density levels over an 800-metre area
of land for sale in Manhattan compared to within walking distance of a station
250 in a Chinese New Town. The fine grain depend on the magnitude of transit
of lot and land market fosters an active land
investment. UN-Habitat recommends
market with a great potential of future mixed
densities of at least 15,000 per km for
use. Over time, land lots in Manhattan have
sustainable neighbourhoods47.
consolidated but still 40 per cent remain
with the initial sizing of two centuries ago, Mixed land use that will attract occu-
while very few occupy whole urban blocks. pants, create an attractive environment
(services, amenities, public infrastruc-

3.8 Summary of key ture and design qualities), and produce

benchmarks for substantial public transportation rider-

enhancing value at ship specific mix will vary depending

community scale on location in region, local context, and


connectivity.
Key benchmarks recommended by UN-Habi-
tat for implementing the above patterns can At least 40 per cent of floor space
be summarized as follows: should be allocated for economic use
in a sustainable neighbourhood48.
Local accessibility based on small blocks
Limited land-use specialization. This
and on dense and connected street
is to limit single function blocks or
patterns with at least between 80 to
neighbourhoods; single function blocks
100 street intersections/km.
should cover less than 10 per cent of
Adequate space for streets. Based any neighbourhood49.
on international benchmarks of effi-
Social mix. The availability of houses in
cient, inclusive, and sustainable cities,
different price ranges and tenures in a
UN-Habitat recommends46 that the
neighbourhood should accommodate
street network occupies at least 30 per
different incomes; 20 per cent to 50
cent of the land and with at least 18 km
per cent of the residential floor area
of street length per km.
should be for low cost housing and
High-quality public space. each tenure type should be not more
than 50 per cent of the total.50

47 Ibid
48 Ibid
49 Ibid
46 A new strategy of sustainable neighbourhood planning: five
principles, UN-Habitat, Discussion note 3, May 2014. 50 Ibid

43
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

4. Financial Patterns: The Positive Feedback


Loop of Value Creation
Feedback mechanisms have been described as a threshold concept for understanding com-
plex systems. A feedback loop is a mechanism by which a variable change results in either
an amplification (positive feedback) or a dampening (negative feedback) of that change. The
positive feedback loop of value capture is captured in the following chart:

Net private
sector profit

iii) Value capture (Public) Increased public sector


returns or assets

Private sector gross


profit

iii) Value capture (Private)

Asset with actual


increased value after
private investment

ii) Value realisation

Asset with potential


for increased value Public led Public led
after public sector re-investment re-investment
intervention

i) Value creation

Under-used asset
(land/structure)

An idealized Value Capture Finance feedback loop. Source ULI. ULI. Used with the permission of ULI.
Further permission required for reuse.

44
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

New transit infrastructure provision or plan- Initiating a positive feedback loop of


ning decisions, such as rezoning at higher Value Capture Finance starts by identi-
values or investing in the public realm, in- fying imbalances in the different node,
creases land value around transit stations, place and market potential value53
which can be captured for starting a positive in a given location and thus assets which
feedback loop for financing infrastructures, are underutilized, either because an increase
enhancement of public realm and inclusion- in connectivity linked to public investment
ary housing. The unlocking of an increase in infrastructure calls for a redevelopment
in the potential value of under-used assets or because high place value calls for invest-
(land and/or structures) as a result of a pub- ment in connectivity to create a positive
lic sector intervention (rezoning or provision feedback loop for market growth. The 3V
of public transportation infrastructure) stim- framework54 allows the fine tuning of public
ulates demand from the private sector. investment to market response potential in
order to initiate these positive value capture
Subsequent investment and development feedback loops addressing the challenges of
from the private sector ensures that poten- financing the infrastructures of fast-grow-
tial asset value increase is realized. Value ing cities.
capture is the arrangements by the public
sector for the acquisition of a proportion
of private sector returns for local reinvest- 4.1 Value Creation
ment51. Local value recycling is the rein- Value creation strategies involve increases of
vestment of acquired monetary or in kind the three values (node reflecting connectivi-
contributions from the private sector within ty, place reflecting urban design quality and
the same development site or scheme. This market potential reflecting market demand
reinvestment can pay for the initial public and supply in the location) characterizing a
intervention but tends to fund further inter- location, each one supporting the others.
ventions. According to Joe Huxley52, Value In Londons Kings Cross for example55, en-
Capture Finance can therefore be defined hanced infrastructure provision will take the
as the appropriation of value, generated by form of future linkage of Kings Cross and
public sector intervention and private sector Euston Square into a single station, with
investment in relation to an underused as- HS1 and HS2, creating the biggest inter-
set (land and/or structure), for local reinvest- change across several geographical scales in
ment to produce public good and potential the UK (with High Speed Rail, National Rail,
private benefit. Value Capture Finance in- six subway lines, and 17 bus routes, con-
creases the incentive for both public inter- necting Europe, UK, and London). The plan-
vention and private investment by creating ning engine for redeveloping the site has
a win-win situation and shares the cost of been enhanced urban quality and image. A
urban development between the public and
private sectors without the public sector 53 For a detailed explanation see Chapter 3 in Salat Serge and
Ollivier Gerald. 2016. The 3V Framework: Maximizing Economic
necessarily undertaking a large amount of Opportunities in TOD Station Areas by Matching Place, Node, and
initial investment. Market Potential Values. World Bank, Washington, DC. License:
Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO
54 Ibid
51 This can take the form of monetary or in kind contributions
55 For a detailed analysis see Chapter 6 of Salat Serge and
from the private to public actors.
Ollivier Gerald. 2016. The 3V Framework: Maximizing Economic
52 Joe Huxley, Value Capture Finance. Making urban develop- Opportunities in TOD Station Areas by Matching Place, Node, and
ment pay its way, Urban Land Institute, 2009. Market Potential Values, op. cit.

45
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

lot of attention has been given to provision 4.2 Value Realization


of high-quality public space with twenty
Potential increased asset values are real-
connective new streets and ten high-quality
ized by private sector investment. Asset
squares and public gardens. Public invest-
values are tangibly increased and unlocked
ment in public parks will ensure that the
by private sector involvement and invest-
location becomes one of the most liveable
ment in a number of ways:
areas of London.

Similarly, for redeveloping the railyards site Direct investment.


in New Yorks Hudson Yards, public invest- Comprehensive master planning. In
ment in public space has been the key to both Hudson Yards and Kings Cross,
the strategy for creating value56. Three ma-
for example, innovative master plans,
jor New York parks (the third section of the
with high quality public space and
High Line, Hudson River Park and Hudson
local connectivity, have been designed
Park & Boulevard) will converge in Hudson
by developers with, in London, high
Yards. Market potential has been enhanced
by huge increases in people and jobs den- level of public participation, and, in
sities creating very dense mixed-use com- both cases, dialogue between public
munities. Regulatory planning interventions and private actors.
have taken the form of rezoning57 at higher Area promotion through enhanced
values, with mixed use and with margins
destination branding and marketing.
of flexibility to capture value between base
and maximum as well as for adapting to
market changes. Rezoning at higher FARs
4.3 Value Capture
levels creates high market potential values Increased asset values are captured for the
in well-connected areas, centrally located, public good and private profit. The inward
when there is a high demand at city scale. rate of return is secured as profit by the
Margins of flexibility between base FAR and private sector. This private value capture is
maximum FAR allow the capturing of part primarily via the rent or sale of new or en-
of this value creation. hanced housing, retail or office units. The
public sector uses then a range of mech-
Similarly, for redeveloping the anisms to capture enhanced asset values
realized by private actors. We provide be-
railyards site in New Yorks Hudson low a general list of value capture finance
Yards, public investment in public mechanisms, described as follows by Joe
space has been the key to the Huxley58:

strategy for creating value


Land transfers. Land held in private or
public ownership is provided to the
56 For a detailed analysis see Chapter 5 of Salat Serge and
public promoter for public use.
Ollivier Gerald. 2017.
57 Zoning is the planning instrument of the physical city. It aims Local taxation. Local general targeted
to promote an orderly pattern of development and to separate in-
compatible land uses, such as industrial uses and homes, to ensure a taxation and local real estate tax
pleasant envi-ronment. The Zoning Resolution is a legal instrument increments where revenues are
to regulate and establish limits on the use of land and building size,
shape, height and setback. Rezoning FARs at higher values is a plan- 58 Joe Huxley, Value Capture Finance. Making urban develop-
ning intervention that creates market potential value. ment pay its way, Urban Land Institute, 2009.

46
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

reinvested into the same area in which Private sector led re-investment. The
they were collected. public actor offers private actors the
opportunity to deliver community-
Fees and levies. Planning approval fees,
orientated infrastructure directly. This
development levies and infrastructure
further increases asset values and
tariffs.
positive social-economic impacts.
Debt servicing/Loan guarantees.
Securing loans against the increased Leaf Patterns: The Resilient Way of
or future increase value of the land. Urban Growth
Local service agreements. Private Living cities are dense patterns of connec-
actors agree to give priority to the
tions where everything is linked to everything
local community for access to new
else. The new science of cities has discov-
facilities, public space or to manage
ered that these dense webs follow underly-
basic public services.
ing efficient and resilient patterns captured
Private-led local infrastructure and by a few simple mathematical regularities.
amenity provision and enhancement. The patterns in the urban space economy
For example, provision of schools,
that we have discovered have deep impli-
community centres, affordable
cations for resilience, resource productivity
housing, transport links and utilities
and infrastructure investment.
provision and upgrade, were part
of the agreement between local First, the spatial distribution and the inten-
government and private developer for
sity of connections, be it for transportation
both Hudson Yards and Kings Cross.
or for energy, in an efficient and resilient
Operating revenue. city should obey a scale-free distribution.
The more scale-free the city networks
4.4 Local Value Recycling and the more connected within the same
The captured value (in monetary form or scale and through scales, the more they
credit to leverage in-kind contributions can absorb fluctuations and even build
from the private sector) can be recycled or new structures upon the perturbations to
reinvested in the same development scheme
which they are subjected, without letting
for the public good in two main ways:
them upset the stability of their structure.

Public sector led re-investment. It is in assimilating the fluctuations that an


Increased public revenues captured urban system becomes more complex and
from the private sector through more diverse. Hence, there is an ongoing
enhanced local taxation, fees and dialogue between the citys capacities of
levies pay for further government resilience and the constraints to which it is
interventions within the same subjected, between the fluctuations from
development area. This reinforces the outside environment and its building
asset values and positive social- structures to absorb these fluctuations.
economic impacts.

47
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Second, infrastructure investment, if it is to Cities planned with these efficient patterns


be resource efficient, should reinforce the reduce traffic congestion, promote busi-
emerging concentration properties of urban ness, improve public services and boost rev-
space rather than counteract them. Rather enues. These cities are more liveable, eco-
than levelling inequalities to reach a homoge- nomically competitive and environmentally
neous and amorphous urban space, it is more and socially sustainable. Finally, by creating
resource efficient to enable peaks of concen- and capturing higher land values around
tration of economic density and productiv- public transportation stations and corridors,
ity to grow, to encourage the formation of these cities can recoup some of the costs of
strong hubs in subway systems, to sharpen building, operating and maintaining mass
the hierarchy of accessibility, to shape and transit systems, as well as supporting tran-
articulate densities with high concentrations sit-oriented development in ways that make
around major hubs rather than a random dis- them more appealing places to live, work
tribution of urban growth across space. and do business.

48
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

II Part 2

The technical framework


of the three-pronged
approach
Loeiz Bourdic and Marco Kamiya

49
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

1. Urban productivity gues that concentrating production factors


leads to higher productivity. The theories on
economies of scale and scope argue that
Urban productivity can be defined as the ef-
increasing the production amount of one
ficiency of resource use the use of labour,
good or the range of goods, respectively,
capital, land, material, energy and informa-
can reduce the average cost per unit and
tion - in higher value added output of a city.
thereby also raise the productivity level.
Increases in productivity is the major source
These theories can be applied either on the
of economic growth at city and country level
level of a single firm but also on the macro
and these increases thereby potentially lead
level, which can be useful for the discussion
to raising living standards and prosperity.
of the productivity advantages of urban ag-
glomerations.
Productivity is also closely related to com-
petitiveness since cities, which are more
These theories not only offer explanations
productive in terms of goods and servic-
for the often observed correlation between
es production, are more competitive on a
characteristics of urban agglomerations and
global scale. Competitiveness is ultimately a
their urban productivity level but also for
revealed productivity of the city. Cities are
the correlation between urbanization rates
the result of multivariable and integrated
and the development of national produc-
factors working together and impacting on
tivity. They also provide indications on the
productivity and competitiveness59.
conditions which the urbanization process
has to fulfil so that the potentials of urban
The productivity advantages of cities and
agglomerations can be fully exploited.
urban clusters with a high density of com-
panies and workers have long since been
It will also be discussed why urbanization
perceived. Different theories have tried to
does not necessarily lead to higher produc-
explain why and under which conditions ur-
tivity levels without addressing both pos-
ban development is accompanied by rising
itive and negative externalities, generated
productivity levels. Some key theoretical ap-
due to urban agglomerations. This offers
proaches which can be applied for discuss-
the base for arguing that efficient, sustain-
ing the relation of urban development and
able and equitable urban development is a
productivity, namely the theories of agglom-
requisite for a city to fulfil its potential as
eration economies, economies of scope and
the engine of national economic growth.
economies of scale, as well as some further
Efficient cities can drive gains in economic
developments of these theories, are being
productivity and job creation, while sponta-
presented in this document.
neously growing inefficient cities can be a
drag on economic and productivity growth.
The theory of agglomeration economies ar-

Thereby, this section offers the theoretical


59 See the Global Competitiveness Report where competitive-
ness is computed based on 12 pillars that goes from education to
background to explain why a citys perfor-
infrastructure and classified in three main areas: Basic Require- mance on the components of the Three-
ments, Efficiency Enhancers, and Innovation and Sophistication
Pronged Approach is essential for success-
Factors [ http://www.weforum.org/ ]. On urban competitiveness
(Ni, Kresl and Liu 2013) develop a sustainable competitiveness fully exploiting the productivity-enhancing
index including social and cultural variables in addition to environ- potential of cities. To support the theoret-
ment, economic dynamics and global connections; an alternative
index incorporating value chain and supply chain as a base for ical implications, in the empirical section
competitiveness (Kamiya & Roberts 2015).

50
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

different cities are examined on how they planning of large cities or metropolises that
perform on the three components of the must be taken into account.
Three-Pronged Approach and on the effect
this performance has on urban productivity.
1.2. Economies of scope and
urban productivity
1.1. Economies of scale and
The theory on economies of scope states
urban productivity that production costs can be reduced
The theory on economies of scale states through producing a range of goods of a
that the greater the quantity of a good similar type together instead of producing
produced, the lower the average costs per each one on their own. By sharing central-
product unit. The underlying reasoning is ized functions, such as finance or market-
that the fixed costs occurring in the pro- ing, among the production processes for
duction process are shared over a larger different goods, the fixed costs arising for
number of goods if the volume of output the production of a single unit can be re-
increases. Economies of scale may also lead duced. Furthermore, interrelationships in
to a reduction of the variable costs per procurement, production and sale of dif-
product unit due to operational efficiencies ferent goods can be utilized to reduce the
and synergies. Producing a high volume of costs of business; such as opportunities to
one product type allows firms and workers cross-sell one product alongside another, or
to specialize in specific tasks and thereby using the outputs of one production pro-
achieve a high productivity level60. cess as the inputs of another. Transferred
to the macro level (for the purpose of this
The theory on economies of scale differen- study, to the city level), this theory explains
tiates between internal and external econo- the existence and growth of urban agglom-
mies of scale. The concept of internal econ- erations with the opportunities they offer
omies of scale focuses on explaining the for businesses to utilize the interrelations
cost-reducing effects of specialization and between the production processes of their
increases in the production of single prod- goods with those of other businesses. Cities
ucts through changes at the firm level. enable businesses to share centralized func-
tions in procurement, production and sale
The concept of external economies of scale, processes.
on the other hand, refers to the advantages
of a high output volume on a macro-scale, On the basis of this theory, it can be ar-
meaning at the inter-firm level. It explains gued that cities exist as the proximity of
how changing factors outside of an individ- firms in urban agglomerations, facilitating
ual firm can increase the productivity level factor specialization and sharing of indi-
of an entire industry, region or economy. visible inputs. In the following parts of this
This concept can be transferred onto the document, two further developments on
relation between city size and productivity the theory of external economies are pre-
level; however, for cities, this relationship sented, both of which offer explanations
is not mechanical since there are also dis- on the productivity advantages of urban
economies of scale due to governance and agglomerations. One approach argues that
60 Lobo et. al. (2014) from the Santa Fe Institute demonstrates the advantages of scale relate primarily to
empirically that in a typical city in the US Total Factor Productivity higher levels of activity in a particular indus-
in 11 per cent with each doubling in population.

51
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

try, with the benefits accruing to that indus- purchase of inputs, on the one hand, and
try. The other one relates more generally to for selling the final goods, on the other.
the overall scale of activity in a city which is Moreover, they provide an environment for
argued to affect the productivity of all firms innovation, transport and energy network
located there. infrastructures plus the opportunity for co-
operation with other local firms as suppliers
and customers.
1.3. Urbanization and
localization economies In the literature on economies of agglom-
and urban productivity eration, different factors are argued to
The theory on urbanization economies seeks cause productivity advantages in urban
to explain the relation between city size and agglomerations. Higher concentration and
productivity level. It suggests that urban di- scale of people, activities and resources in
versity and a large city size generate produc- urban areas foster economic growth (V.
tivity advantages for any business locating Henderson, Kuncoro, and Turner, 1995; Fu-
in an urban agglomeration and argues that jita and Thisse, 1996; Duranton and Puga,
the urban environment creates positive ex- 2004; Puga, 2010), innovation (Feldman
ternalities which benefit different industries. and Audretsch, 1999; Bettencourt et al.,
This theory is especially suitable for explain- 2007; Arbesman, Kleinberg, and Strogatz,
ing the high and growing productivity levels 2009), and increase efficiencies (Kahn 2009;
in cities with no single dominant industry. Glaeser and Kahn, 2010). The agglomera-
Regardless of their industry, firms locating tion economies made possible by the con-
in a large city can benefit from the common centration of individuals and firms make
physical resources such as roads, buildings cities ideal settings for innovation, job and
and power supply, and from access to a wealth creation (Rosenthal and Strange,
large diverse labour pool. 2004; Carlino, Chatterjee, and Hunt, 2007;
Knudsen et al. 2008; Puga, 2010).
The theory on localization economies, on
the other hand, discusses how the size of Several factors can explain the productivity
an industry in a city affects the productivity advantages of urban environments (Puga,
level of a particular activity. The productivity 2010): (1) large markets allow for an ef-
advantages of cities are seen to relate pri- ficient sharing of local infrastructure and
marily to higher levels of activity in a par- facilities, and bring together a variety of
ticular industry, with the benefits accruing intermediate input suppliers and a pool of
to that industry. (Jofre-Monseny, Marn- workers with similar skills; (2) large markets
Lpez, Viladecans-Marsal, 2012) allow for effective matching between em-
ployers and employees, buyers and suppli-
ers and between business partners and (3)
1.4. Agglomeration large markets can facilitate mutual learning
economies and urban and knowledge spillovers, by promoting the
productivity development and widespread adoption of
new technologies and businesses practices.
The theory on agglomeration economies
unifies ideas from the theories presented
Urban employment and services benefit
above. It states that urban economies of-
from the economies of agglomeration due
fer a diversified and large market for the

52
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

to cost savings and other advantages that 1.5. Negative externalities of


accrue to firms when they locate near oth- urban agglomerations
ers in the same industry. When businesses
co-locate near other economic activities, Besides the productivity advantage cities
they can take advantage of shared markets, offer, especially as compared to rural areas,
services, infrastructure, labour and informa- there are also negative externalities being
tion. Furthermore, due to the productivity generated in urban agglomerations. Nega-
advantages in cities, urban investment has a tive externalities, unpriced negative effects
strong multiplier effects in stimulating oth- that actors impose upon other actors, arise
er high-value activities. This benefit extends due to high levels of proximity and density
to rural areas, which needs access to urban in urban areas.
markets to expand and diversify both agri-
Land in urban areas is scarce; this leads to
cultural and non-agricultural production.
higher land prices in urban compared to ru-
Larger urban areas are the most productive ral areas and leaves room for speculation.
since they allow, greater specialization in la- Where there is a lack of public and private
bour, better matching of skills and jobs, and transport networks, urbanization is accom-
a wider array of consumption choices for panied by rising congestion, insecurity,
workers and ancillary services for producers. noise, high pollution levels and adverse en-
It is also in large cities where the vast ma- vironmental effects. These, as well as limited
jority of substantial innovations emerge. As interactive, recreational and cultural oppor-
long as this greater productivity outweighs tunities due to lack of public open space can
higher costs for land, labour, housing, and reduce the liveability of a city. Unless some
other necessities, a city can thrive. (World countering action is taken, spontaneous
Bank, 2003 and 2009). and uncontrolled urbanization can lead to
spatial segregation in gated communities or
An emerging approach associating urbani- neighbourhoods by income level and social
zation to productivity comes by linking val- status. This, again, can have self-accelerat-
ue chains and supply chains. As the urban ing effects, leading to high inequality of ed-
setting is the place where goods are pro- ucational, social and economic opportunity,
duced, and those goods are results of sev- as well as limiting the interaction and com-
eral inputs, goods and services, then the ur- munity building beyond social, generational
ban forms and the infrastructure that offers and cultural boundaries.
highways, roads, and information technolo-
gy are as important as human capital in the Negative externalities of urbanization on
production of final goods. Consequently, the urban economy are treated in the theory
supply chains which determine the channels of diseconomies. Diseconomies of scale (the
through which inputs are delivered to a pro- counterpart of economies of scale), are de-
duction hub can have impact on efficiency, fined as the forces in growing urban areas
competitiveness and ultimately in productiv- which cause increasing costs for businesses
ity. In this study, this approach is not ana- and residents. The potential of negative ex-
lysed, but it is an important research agenda ternalities due to rapid urbanization grows
regarding urbanization and productivity61. with the increasing size of a city. Once the
effects of diseconomies become too great,
larger cities may lose their edge in creating
61 Roads and productivity is a potential link (see Fernald,
1999). Another is proximity and access to jobs (see Bertaud 2002). jobs or improving the welfare of residents.

53
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

The effects of diseconomies can be over- quality of a Planned City Extension will also
come if businesses can shed those activities determine the level of inequalities within
that are more mature and standardized to urban centres and among rural and urban
smaller cities to make room for more inno- areas.
vative and higher value industries and ser-
vices and change the use of land. (World UN-Habitat promotes three fundamental
Bank, 2003) components that have to be considered
by local authorities in the process of plan-
The discussion on the theory of economies ning and implementing urban extension
of scale shows that a city has to generate programmes in order to achieve sustain-
more positive than negative externalities. able urbanization. Sound performance in
This means that the factors causing produc- these three areas is essential to exploit
tivity advantages have to be supported to the potential of a city to generate wealth,
create positive effects on the local economy, employment, coexistence and cultural in-
while the negative externalities of urban ag- terchange as discussed in the presented
glomerations have to be rooted out to the theories and to avoid the pitfalls of a spon-
greatest extent possible. taneous development.

In the following, the essential components


2. The Three-Pronged for a successful Planned City Extension,
namely urban design, financial manage-
Approach ment and rules and regulations, are pre-
sented in detail. They have to be seen as
supplementary, as failing to consider one of
2.1. Exploiting the potential these essential components can cause the
of urbanization urban authority to fail in its performance on
Many of the factors leading to productiv- the other two dimensions and can result in
ity advantages in urban agglomerations a Planned City Extension failure to create a
as discussed above are generated by the sustainable urban fabric. For a Planned City
proximity and density of workers and busi- Extension to succeed, UN-Habitat advises
nesses. Proximity, density, integration and local authorities to balance actions on all
accessibility, however, are not necessarily a three components and to avoid focusing on
given in every urban agglomeration and not optimal performance in only one or two of
automatically maintained during the urban the areas. It is advised to put similar effort
extension process. There are rather planning towards good performance in all three since
and regulatory activities, as well as strate- the action in one is complementary to the
gically-sound public investments necessary performance of the others. The three essen-
to ensure sustainable urban development. tial components of a successful Planned City
The quality of a Planned City Extension, and Extension are to be seen as the foundation
other regional policies accompanying it, for further action. To tackle successfully cen-
can be argued to determine the effect of tral issues in urban extension programmes
urbanization on the economic development such as urban youth issues and housing scar-
of a region by influencing various elements city, it is essential to create an appropriate
in the urbanization process. Besides having framework of good performance for each
a strong impact on urban productivity, the component of the Three-Pronged Approach.

54
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Any action of a Planned City Extension 2.2. Three essential


programme has to be implementable components for
in each of the three areas of the Three- sustainable planned city
Pronged Approach for the action to have
extension
positive consequences. Interventional ac-
tions to tackle any arising issue are difficult
to undertake without the existence of an
2.2.1. Urban planning
efficient legal framework. The provision of UN-Habitat promotes five key principles
any public service, any public property or for urban design62, as concepts for urban
institution requires a minimum of financial planning rather than economics. These
funding to keep on functioning or to be principles are empirical and pragmatic ad-
maintained. Any physical development or vice to good urbanization and provided
addition to the existing urban fabric also to policymakers when urban expansion
requires investment. Urban design, finally, plans are designed. Although these plans
is central and has to be taken into account are not derived from an abstract model,
as the development of a city requires plan- each principle should be applied consid-
ning activities to ensure the development ering the geographic, social and political
of a spatial layout that enables dense and context of a region63. These five principles
diverse development and the maintenance are:
or improvement of a citys accessibility,
liveability and environmental quality. Adequate space for streets and an
efficient street network. A street
In many contemporary Planned City Exten- network that not only serves private
sion programmes, urban design is seen as and public transport vehicles but also
the standalone component. This section, specifically aims to attract pedestrians
discussing the Three-Pronged Approach and cyclists. The street network should
components, shows that, apart from the occupy at least 30 per cent of the land

spatial planning matters, rules and regula- and at least 18 km of street length per
km.
tions as well as financial planning inevitably
have to be taken into consideration when High density. High concentration of
formulating and implementing Planned people and their activities. At least
City Extension programmes; only then the 15,000 people per km, that is 150
potential of a city to generate productivity people/ha or 61 people/acre

advantages can be exploited. Mixed land-use. Combination of


different residential, commercial,
The concept of scale is described later in industrial, office or other land use
this study but it is necessary to indicate that
in one neighbourhood. At least 40
approaches have to be different for neigh-
bourhoods, city-wide areas or metropolises,
62 UN-Habitat (2014) A New Strategy of Sustainable Neigh-
since the size of the area determines what bourhood Planning: Five principles Urban Planning Discussion
kind of tools would be used to implement Note 3. Nairobi, Kenya.

the Three-Pronged Approach in terms of 63 For example, public space of 50 per cent of the area is not
to be intended for slums where upgrading must be incremental
planning, financial and legal frameworks. but would be so for established cities or cities which are being
planned.

55
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

per cent of floor space should be spontaneous growth has to be prevented


allocated for economic use in any through urban planning from the initial
neighbourhood. stage of urban expansion.

Social mix. The availability of houses To prevent urban sprawl and promote sus-
in different price ranges and tenure tainable urban extension, it is necessary to
types in any neighbourhood to achieve high density of residents as well
accommodate residents from different as economic activity. Compared with low
backgrounds and with different density, high density has economic, so-
income level. Twenty to 50 per cent cial and environmental benefits. Efficient
of the residential floor area should be land use slows down urban sprawl be-
for low cost housing; each tenure type cause high-density neighbourhoods can
accommodate more people per area. It is
should be not more than 50 per cent
through high-density development that
of the total.
costs for public services, such as police and
Limited land-use specialization. emergency response, school transport,
Reduced amount of single function roads, water and sewage can be reduced.
blocks or neighbourhoods. Single High-density development also leads to
function blocks should cover less than high walkability and accessibility, there-
10 per cent of any neighbourhood. by reducing car dependency and parking
demand, and facilitating the provision of
The proportion of urban space dedicat- an efficient public transport network. This
ed to public use and the features of the increases energy efficiency and decreases
network of streets, commercial corridors pollution.
and sidewalks determine the walkability
of a city. They thereby determine a citys In the planning process, it is crucial to match
quality and intensity of street life and the efforts to increase urban density with the
interaction among citizens. The amount of needs for public space as discussed above.
space dedicated to streets and transport Therefore, the general plan on the urban
infrastructure also shapes the city in terms layout has to integrate considerations on the
of connectivity and accessibility, thereby present and future transportation and street
affecting the level of congestion and the infrastructure needs. Urban density must
air quality. A citys street network, more- not overwhelm infrastructure due to risks
over, functions as a layout for the provision of congestion. Reciprocally, under-using in-
of basic urban services. Its quality deter- frastructure because of low-density levels is
mines the affordability of various urban not economically efficient. Public transport
amenities and services. A sufficient, high hubs should be located in an advantageous
quality public space, on the other hand, place for capturing the peaks of urban den-
can significantly enhance a citys liveability, sity, services and urban amenities. It is there-
resulting in potential buyers to be willing fore important that densities are articulated
to pay more for urban land. It also allows across the metropolitan area and strategically
local authorities to plan for future devel- increased along key transit corridors.
opment by facilitating easier reordering
and reorganization of plotting areas and Recent literature on urban planning propos-
roads. Thus, to ensure the development of es a general plan combined with rules and
quality street patterns and public space,

56
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

regulations rather than a detailed master More efficient use of space and build-
plan that is conceptualized in the early stage ings,
of a development programme. A Planned
Lower infrastructure and service costs
City Extension based on a general plan with
supplementing rules and regulations allows Support for small business
for evolution and adaption to changes in
Raise in property value
economic or environmental circumstances.
The definition of the street network is the Increase in local tax revenue
key element of a general plan. This is be-
Increase in economic activity and
cause the street network, as the backbone
of a city, determines the layout of a city. development

The notion of mixed use is not new, as Jane


The development of productive urban ex- Jacobs advocated, but its addition to urban
tensions relies on the capacity of stake- planning is a relatively new development in
holders to integrate spatial planning and contemporary urbanism theory. Since the
all essential urban infrastructure policies end of the 19th century, with the introduc-
at different levels, from those conceptual- tion of modern urban planning concepts,
ized at a metropolitan scale to neighbour- the land-use zoning approach was applied
hood-scaled development policies. Very of- frequently and single-function areas came
ten in rapidly-urbanizing countries, master into existence in cities all over the world.
plans focus on the large scale but lack the By promoting land use specialization, many
fine grain level of detail that is essential to single-function neighbourhoods have been
urban productivity. For example, the diver- created through zoning policies, which are
sity of land plot sizes is essential to support seen to be the source of many contempo-
a vibrant and sustainable land market. As, rary urban challenges. Urban sprawl has in-
plots are constitutive of land sale processes creased, the quality and vitality of many ur-
and structure land property, they are one of ban centres have declined and car depend-
the basic bricks on which urban economic ence and traffic congestion have increased
markets rest upon. However, due to the lack as the urban population had to commute
of human and technical resources, or due to between different districts to be able to un-
different artistic and design concepts, most dertake all required activities.
of the current urbanization process in devel-
oping countries and emerging economies To avoid these problems, new urbanism
is based on massive plots: the superblocks theories promote the core concept of mixed
which result in an urban fabric lacking den- land use. Mixed land use requires some
sity and diversity. combination of residential, commercial, in-
dustrial, office, or other land use. For differ-
According to the OECD (2015), the eco- ent economic and residential activities to be
nomic benefits of diversification of land use mixed in one neighbourhood, they have to
are multiple. They include: be made compatible and be integrated in a
well-balanced manner by careful design and
Lower transport costs management.
Higher productivity due to shorter
According to the Intergovernmental Panel
travel time for workers
on Climate Change (IPCC, 2014) however,

57
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

concepts of fostering diversity and mixed use place-based stigma can be overcome and re-
are ambiguous. They must be conceptual- newal/regeneration initiatives for the provision
ized, implemented and evaluated at the right of additional services can be attracted to less
spatial scale as indicators at a city scale can wealthy neighbourhoods.
hide whether large urban areas are dedicated
to one single use. Usually, mixed-use incen-
tives must be implemented at a neighbour-
2.2.2. Financial framework and
hood scale (typically 500 x 500m areas) and governance
at a block and building scale (IPCC, 2014). A The second essential pillar for successful
neighbourhood should provide a smart mix Planned City Extensions is a sound financial
of housing buildings, office buildings, shops plan, meaning proper budgeting, revenue
and urban amenities, as this has positive im- generation and expenditure management.
pacts on transportation patterns by decreas- Municipal finance authorities must be able to
ing the average travel distances (McCormack, translate urban development policies into a
Scott Rutherford, and Wilkinson, 2001). sound financial plan and generate the reve-
nues required for their implementation. Care-
The only situation where zoning could be de- ful budgeting is essential to guarantee the
sirable at a city scale is when a specific activity maintenance and development of public insti-
is incompatible with the others; such as heavy tutions programmes and infrastructure. Munic-
industry which is generally incompatible with ipal finance activities should aim at preventing
housing (Angotti and Hanhardt, 2001) and liquidity risks and reducing the dependency on
may be separated from other activities in transfers from the central government.
the city. In this case, conventional zoning
practices could be adjusted by combining For the successful implementation of a
compatible land uses into one block and Planned City Extensions programme, ade-
neighbourhood; alternatively, mixed land-use quate financial frameworks and governance
zoning that respects market demand and cit- schemes must be in place, including:
ies urban by-laws and regulations could be
introduced. 1. The financial capacity of the municipality
to finance and deliver infrastructures and
Social mix provides the basis for healthy so-
plans
cial networks, which, in turn are the driving
force of city life. Social mix and mixed land 2. The financial knowhow of the
use are interdependent and promote each municipality to implement and monitor
other. Mixed land use and appropriate poli- infrastructure delivery and plans
cy guidance lead to social mixing. In a mixed
3. Effective institutions with clear roles and
land-use neighbourhood, job opportunities
are generated for residents from different adequate human and financial capacity
backgrounds and with different income lev- to perform them
els. People live and work in the same neigh- 4. Fiscal capacity of the municipality to
bourhood and form a diverse social network. raise revenues such as through land and
Social mix is a socio-spatial concept, with
property taxes
the following objectives: through fostering
social mix more social interaction and social 5. High degree of freedom of municipalities
cohesion across groups can be promoted; with regard to central governments

58
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Throughout history, the role of the govern- questions still in the air: how to apply these
principles? In addition, who should apply
ment has been highly discussed. How much
them? The answer to that question is not
responsibility they have to take is the big
straightforward, and actually, there are two
question; one which has not yet been solved theories that have to be taken in consider-
and which probably will never get solved ation to solve the question. The subsidiarity
because it comes down to a matter of pref- principle (Barnett, 1977) is the theory and
erence. But in terms of local government re- states that the efficient provision of services
sponsibilities, the path has been narrowed, requires that decision making should be car-
ried out by the level of government that is
according to the Guide to Municipal Finance
closest to the individual citizen. The second
(2009). This guide states that the major role
theory has to do with the fiscal decentraliza-
assigned to local governments is to provide tion; it is a concept developed for transferring
goods and services within a particular geo- the financial responsibility from central gov-
graphic area to residents who are willing to ernments to local governments forcing local
pay for them. They should not carry out a governments to deliver and fund an increas-
ing number of services.
stabilization policy because they do not have
access to monetary instruments and they
The two theories mentioned above suggest
should not have redistribution as primary dividing the financial framework in two parts,
focus because it will result in a non-general as usually reflected in budgetary planning:
equilibrium policy, with people moving from the revenues and the expenditures. Both por-
one place to another. Finance plays a huge tions of the financial framework should fol-
low both principles mentioned before but in
role in this discussion. Responsibilities have
particular, the revenue has to follow the theo-
a cost and, relative to the society, the gov-
ry of fiscal decentralization while the expend-
ernment has to figure out a way to obtain iture has to follow the subsidiarity principle.
the amount of money to fulfil those respon-
sibilities. At the same time, the government Expenditure
has to determine a way of spending the re-
Each government, without taking geo-
sources they get. There are six public finance
graphical scale into account, should cover
principles that shape a framework on how to
the minimum needs of its citizens. As it was
obtain money and how to spend it, namely:
mentioned before, the minimum a govern-
1. Economic efficiency ment should cover is a subject that has been
2. Fairness (equity) in discussion throughout history. For reasons
of simplicity, we are going to suppose that
3. Accountability
the more the government covers, the better
4. Adequacy and stability
it is for its citizens. This follows the non-sati-
5. Autonomy
ation principle broadly used by economists.
6. Ease and cost of administration
But the question in this sense is: what are
The six principles above set the path for de- the expenditures and investments for which
signing an appropriate financial framework a local government should be responsible?
at a metropolitan level, but there are two
They are shown in Figure 1.

59
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

FIGURE 1.
Local expenditure components

Administration

Land value capture tax Education

Tax increment
Health
financing

Regional Planning and Sanitation


Development (Environment)
Expenditure components

Housing Transport

Protection (Fire and


Recreation and Culture Police)

Resources
conservation and Social services
Development

Source: Authors

As it was mentioned before in the explana- or the national level. Those components are
tion of the subsidiarity principle, it is desira- usually shared by the different governmental
ble that the expenditure components listed levels within a country. Based on the theory
in the figure are done at the level of gov- developed by economists to explain the pref-
ernment that is closest to the individual citi- erences over a lottery involving its possible
zen. Which level of government this will be outcomes, the concept of the simplex was
varies between countries and context but it developed. In this case we have three options
is usually at the metropolitan or local lev- of responsibility for expenditure: national, re-
el. The 13 components of the expenditure gional/state, and local/metropolitan. Locating
portion of a financial framework are rarely these sources of the local expenditure com-
covered on a 100 per cent basis by the lo- ponents is possible on an equilateral triangle
cal or metropolitan level, even by the state with altitude 1 (see Figure 2).

60
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 2. nue collection in order to cover the local ex-


penditure components. Throughout history,
Governmental level simplex for
revenue at the governmental level has been
expenditure components
reinvented and, while taxes have been the
most predominant one new forms of reve-
nue for the different levels of government
Local/Metropolitan
have been developed.

Taxes are a major revenue source. This is


why tax sources such as property and labour
need to be formally registered. The data on
Q property value in particular must be updat-
ed regularly. Land values increase overtime
with the development of nearby infrastruc-
tures and services. Thus, regularly updating
data on land and property values is essential
Regional/State National as it helps to capture increases in values, en-
hancing overall tax revenue collection.

Source: Authors As mentioned before, taxes used to be


the main and possibly the only way of
covering expenses at the local level. A fi-
nancial plan for a Planned City Extension
In Figure 2, Q represents each one of the
should now, however, incorporate innova-
expenditure components: transport, social
tive financing options such public-private
services, and so on. Each perpendicular line
partnerships (PPPs) and land readjustment
is interpreted as the proportion of expendi-
schemes. Leveraging private finance and
ture each governmental level is allocating to
investment is increasingly important due
each one of Qs components. The arrows,
to the constraints on public sector resourc-
on the other hand, represent where it is de-
es. Public policies have to promote private
sirable to establish each one of the expendi-
investment and address the causes and
ture components. Following the subsidiarity
consequences of insufficient capital de-
principle, it is desirable that the expenses
voted to community economic develop-
are done at the smallest governmental lev-
ment.According to Weiss (2006), one of
el, in this case the local/metropolitan. The
the most essential policy approaches is to
simplex in this case will be seen as shown
strengthen the basic conditions that help
in Figure 2.
foster private market activity, such as pub-
Revenue lic investment in transportation and infra-
structure improvements to enhance busi-
Now that the expenses have been covered, ness activity, public funding of education
it is time to venture on to revenues in order and workforce development to increase
to ensure funding and sustain those expens- employment opportunities, and public
es. Similarly to expenses, there are three support for services, training, and techni-
possible governmental levels that could cal assistance that builds the managerial
achieve the coverage of the necessary reve- capacity of small and medium-sized enter-

61
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

prises (SMEs) and community-based organizations (CBOs). Direct public investment is


a necessary condition for further leveraging private capital towards urban regeneration.
Private investment must be recognized as a valuable tool to achieve these important
public policy objectives.

FIGURE 3.
Sources of revenue

Property tax

Land value capture tax Personal income tax

Tax increment
Corporatel income tax
financing

Development charges Payroll tax


Source of Revenue

Public-private General consumption


partnerships tax

Private capital Excise tax


Mobilization

Intergovernmental User fees


Transfers

Source: Authors

The different sources of revenues mentioned in Figure 1 are generated by the different
governmental levels. The sources of revenue have to be evaluated only if they fund any
of the expenditure components for the metropolitan level mentioned in Figure 3. Follow-
ing the fiscal decentralization principle, the N-dimensional simplex (in this case N being
3) could be applied. It is desirable for the financial framework of a city that the smallest
governmental level is in charge of the municipal revenue.

62
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

There has to be clarity regarding expenses Different experts consider diverse ele-
and revenues. Even though the desirable ments before determining if a law is good
level for both subjects is located at the local/ or if it is not. But there are values that
metropolitan level, the context and factors characterize a good law or a good legal
related with economies of scale should not framework. Those elements according to
be forgotten. As a result, the provision of Mousmouti and Crispi (2015) are efficacy,
services, such as transport, could be more effectiveness, efficiency and simplicity. Of
efficient if they are delivered by the metro- these characteristics, there is one which
politan government in collaboration with everyone agrees with; and that is effec-
the national government. tiveness. Where the legislation concerns
itself with urbanization, eight pillars have
Sound municipal finance requires regula- to be achieved for a law to be effective.
tory support and a strong legal framework Those pillars, according to the authors
which complies with the requirements de- mentioned before, are:
scribed in the next section.
1. It has to be attached to the urban reality
2.2.3. The legal framework 2. It has to be developed based on
Rules and regulations have the power to evidence
shape the form and character of the city by 3. Affected people should have a voice to
playing an essential role in the implemen- express their position
tation of urban plans. Depending on the
4. Legislation has to be simple and easy to
quality of rules and regulations supporting
comply with
the general plan of a Planned City Extension
and the quality of the local legal framework, 5. Legislation has to be easily accessible
the rules and regulation accompanying an 6. It has to be coherent and consistent
urban plan can either support or hinder its 7. Legislation must have a capacity to
implementation and evolution. A design
deliver results
following all the best practice of urban plan-
ning cannot be implemented if it does not 8. Make legislative quality a guiding
comply with the local legal framework. Thus, value in the process of developing and
first and foremost, special attention must be implementing legislation
given to legal feasibility and implementability In addition to the eight pillars, there are 21
of all components of an urban plan. Possible elements that compose an integral legal
rules and regulation that support the imple- framework for the urbanization process.
mentation of an urban plan are floor area ra- The 21 components are shown in Table 1.
tio regulations, setback rules and mixed-use
regulations, as well as regulations on plot
sizes, maximum distance between intersec-
tions, street design and so on.

63
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

TABLE 1.
Components for a legal framework
Support the establishment of a physical
and fiscal cadastre, with an efficient,
1 Develop mechanisms to share
up-to-date and publicly available
information system increases in land value due
to planning decision (urban
Develop a urban planning hierarchy
to rural, building potential, Allocate clear
that is adequate to the local needs,
7 valuable land use) and public 9 vertical development
2 plans are designed and implemented.
investments (streets, public rights

Buildability-Development
The planning instruments include a city

Land Based Financing


space, green areas, public
Land Management

street plan.
transport infrastructure, basic
Provide an efficient tenure system with infrastructure)
3 a legislation recognizing statutory and
customary right (stability and security)
Regulate land use to foster land use
4
diversity and mixed use Develop a property tax
Define the buildable
Regulate land-readjustment activities for legislation that allows a large
5 area (percentages,
urban extension and densification collection rate. It has to be
patterns, setbacks,
8 based on the value of the land 10
etc.) based on
and development. Progressive
desired densities and
6 Support the provision of social housing increase for undeveloped,
morphology
vacant land or empty houses.

Provide a regulatory mechanism for Define a minimum plot size for


11 16
private land acquisition residential use
Provide regulatory mechanism to
allocate adequate space to streets (e.g.
12 17 Define a maximum block size
coverage ratio, number of intersections,
width and length, street density)
Plots and Blocks

Building Codes
Public Space

Provide regulatory mechanisms to


Revise the building
allocate space to non-street public space Provide efficient mechanisms to 21
13 18 code
(e.g. green areas, play grounds, sport allow plot consolidation
facilities)
Assign clear responsibilities of owners Provide plot readjustments
14 relating to the maintenance of streets 19 mechanisms to allow flexibility
and public space in uses
Formulate design guidelines for building Provide efficient mechanisms to
15 20
facades allow plot subdivision
Source: Authors

64
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 4.
Venn diagram of the components for a legal framework
divided in financial framework and planning

Financial Framework Planning

2 6
8 9

10
1 12
13 14
7 15
3 4
16 17
11
5
18
19
20

21

Taking into consideration the elements that provide an effective legal framework, the principle
of subsidiary must be considered. Figure 5, shows this interplay before levels and hierarchies

FIGURE 5.
Desirable territorial and hierarchical level of laws

Desirable hierarchical level of laws

Territorial Level
Local Regional/State National
Constitution
Desirable hierarchical level of laws

Hierarchy of the norms

Treaties
Statues
Regulation

Source: Authors

65
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Even though it is desirable that the laws Examples


are established at the most immediate ter-
ritorial level, and that the norms could be Bogota, Colombia
easily modified according to the context,
Bogota is the capital city of Colombia,
this cannot always happen. It is important
with 7,980,000 inhabitants in the city and
to consider factors that could allocate cer-
9,285,300 in the metropolitan area. Bogota
tain authority to a level that do not fulfil the
is considered a special district, which means
expectations established by the subsidiarity
that it does not belong to a state (departa-
principle. Those factors could be economies
mento) or a region. It is subdivided political-
of scale, lack of development of the local
ly in locations, 20 in total, and the smallest
institutions in comparison to that of the na-
subdivision is the 1922 neighbourhoods. In
tional institutions and insufficient flexibility
Colombia the legal framework that regu-
of the norms, among others. To give a prac-
lates the planning process of a city is the
tical example, the establishment of a physi-
Land Use Plan (Plan de Ordenamiento Terri-
cal and fiscal cadastre, with an efficient, up-
torial). This is a technical and policy instru-
to date and publicly available information
ment for planning and managing for the
system, should be desirable at a local level.
long term and is made by a set of policies
However, the technological and physical
and actions in administrative and planning
infrastructure to fulfil this objective could
terms that will guide the development of
be very expensive if each local government
the municipal territory for the coming 12
acquires it individually. Consequently, phys-
years and that will govern the use, occupa-
ical and fiscal cadastre is often established
tion and transformation of urban and rural
at a national level because it represents ef-
space. In general terms, the Plan seeks to
ficiencies in terms of specialization for the
regulate subjects such as environment, pub-
country.
lic equipment, mobility, public space, public
An interesting exercise for the cities is to services and use of the land.
take each one of the 21 components men-
The tools that the mayor of a city in Colom-
tioned on Table 1 and locate them in Figure
bia could use for planning are:
4. The outcome of the exercise will give a
better understanding on how to improve
Plan with 12 years validity and three
the legal framework according to the sub-
sidiarity principle, the effectiveness require- administrative periods
ments, and determine if the non-desirable PDM (Municipal Development Plan)
outcomes are caused by reasons such as with four years validity and one
economies of scale.
administrative period

Even though it is desirable that the laws are established at the


most immediate territorial level, and that the norms could be easily
modified according to the context, this cannot always happen

66
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Budget with one years validity Resolution Agreement (Resolucin,


Acuerdo)
The hierarchy of laws in Colombia is as
follows: Memorandum (Circular)

Order from the superior (Orden del


Constitution (Constitucin Poltica de
Superior)
Colombia)
The regulation regarding the construc-
Law (Ley)
tion and the elements that the Land Use
Decree Law (Decreto Ley) Plan, Municipal Development Plan and the
budget should contain are regulated at a na-
Code (Cdigo)
tional level. The changes made to the Land
Decree (Decreto) Use Plan have to be accepted by the mu-
nicipal congress and have to be approved
Ordinance (Ordenanza)
by decree (decreto). According to the chart
Municipal Agreement (Acuerdo showed on the last section, graphically the
Municipal) Land Use Plan could be seen as shown in
Figure 6.

FIGURE 6.
Bogotas Land Use Plan seen on the desirable and hierarchical level of laws

Desirable hierarchical level of laws

Territorial Level
Local Regional/State National
Constitution

Regulation of POT
Desirable hierarchical level of laws

Law
Hierarchy of the norms

Decree
Law
Code
Decree

POT-POT
Modifications
Others

Source: Authors

67
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

FIGURE 7.

Venn diagram of the components for a legal framework


divided in City Level (POT) and National level

City City
LevelLevel(POT) National Level
National Level

2 1
4 5 3

9
10
12 6 8
11
13
14
15
16 7

17
18 19
20

21


Source: Authors

Egypt which was Law 119 of 2008. This is com-


posed of four parts:
Egypt is the most populous country in North
Africa and the Arab world, with more than Urban planning and development
90 million inhabitants.. This leaves Egypt
Urban harmony
on the scope of urbanization due to its big
population and its rapidly growing cities. Regulation of building works
The Egyptian legal system is based on Islam-
Maintenance of real properties
ic and Civil Law. Accordingly, the Egyptian
territory is divided into five institutions. In Even though the components mentioned in
order of size, these are national; governo- Table 1 are not covered completely by the
rates; regional cities; districts and, finally, Egyptian Building Law, it does not mean
the quarters. At the same level at which the that they are not regulated. Those elements
district is located you will find the villages have been regulated on an isolated basis
in rural areas with similar status to districts. by presidential or prime ministerial decrees.
Egypt is a country in which the legislation is The Building Law determines that there are
centralized; this means that almost all the four main levels of urban planning in Egypt:
urbanization regulations are done at the
presidential or prime ministerial level. 1. National strategic

2. Regional strategic
In regards to urbanization, the legal frame-
work of building plans for example, which 3. Governorate strategic
nowadays covers much of the building prac-
tices in Egypt, is set up by the Building Law, 4. Local

68
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

The Egyptian governments throughout his- lows us to understand the particularities


tory have made efforts to improve the legal that the Egyptian context offers in terms of
framework for urbanization purposes but the the legislative framework. The regulation
regulation remains centralized and the level for the construction of the legal framework
of particularity that is desired as part of the is done at a national level, using the consti-
subsidiarity principle has not been fulfilled. tution as a tool, but the mix is complicated
It is worth mentioning that there are certain since laws and regulation at national level
numbers of laws that overlap on the desire are also set by presidential decrees, prime
to regulate particular aspects of urbaniza- ministerial decrees and even ministerial de-
tion. The overlapping on the legal framework crees. For example, the Building Law (Law
means that locating the components of Table 119 of 2008) is legislation at the national
1 in Figure 6 was a tedious and long exercise, level, then this is covered by two different
with a lot of particularities. types of regulation: the fiscal cadastre legal
framework is at the national level and it is
The first component of Table 1, Support regulated by a law while the physical ca-
the establishment of a physical and fiscal dastre legal framework is regulated at the
cadastre, with an efficient, up-to-date and national level as well but in this case by a
publicly available information system, al- presidential decree (see Figure 8).

FIGURE 8.

Egypts local framework for the establishment of the physical and fiscal cadastre on the
desirable territorial and hierarchical level of laws
Desirable hierarchical level of laws

Territorial Level
Local Governorate Region National
Constitution

Regulation for the construction of the


legal framework

Building Law/ Support the establishment


Law

of a fiscal cadastre
Desirable hierarchical level of laws

Support the establishment of a physical


Presidential
Decrees
Hierarchy of the norms

cadastre
Ministerial
Decrees
Prime
Ministerial
Decrees
Subordinate
Authorities
Decrees of

Source: Authors

69
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

3. Methodology: Planned City Extension is able to produce


value with a scarce resource, namely land.
applying the three-
This report builds on the existing literature
pronged approach and will use the respective indicator used
when measuring the impact of the Three-
3.1. Measuring urban Pronged Approach components on urban
productivity productivity.

Productivity is commonly defined as a meas-


ure of the efficiency of production in an
The model of land prices in mono-
economy and usually expressed as a ratio of
centric cities
output to input used in the production pro- The standard model of land prices in mono-
cess. In other words, productivity measures centric cities is originally designated to
how efficiently human and physical pro- make theoretical predictions on how far
duction inputs are being used to produce a a city will extend. The theory is based on
given level of output (OECD, 2001). While how much the urban population is willing
there is no disagreement on this general no- to pay for piece of land depending on the
tion, a look at the productivity literature and accessibility to the urban centre. The will-
its various applications reveals very quickly ingness to pay increases with accessibility to
that there is no single measure of urban the centre, since people and companies pre-
productivity. The choice between the met- fer locations with better access to the eco-
rics depends on the purpose of productivity nomic opportunities in the centres and are
measurement and, in many instances, on willing to pay more for them (Ottensmann,
the availability of data. 1977; Alonso and others, 1964). As shown
in the following chart, this translates into a
Urban productivity can be measured either
decreasing gradient of land value as the dis-
as productivity per capita (or job), or as pro-
tance from the city centre rises.
ductivity per km. Both metrics provide com-
plementary information of the socio-eco- The price of agricultural land, on the oth-
nomic structure of the Planned City Exten- er hand, is assumed to be constant in this
sion. The productivity per capita, which is model. The outer radius R of potential
the classically-used standard in economic built-up urban area is then defined as the
literature, aims at capturing the economic intersection between the two curves. The
output with regard to the human capital, theoretical city limit is thus the result of a
and also reflects the impact of the econom- trade-off between urban land price and ag-
ic situation on wages and living standards. ricultural land price.
The productivity per km captures how a

70
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 9.

Urban land price and agricultural land price define the city size

1,000
900
800
Urban land price
Price of land per m2

700
600
500
400
300
200 Theoretical city limit
100 Agricultural land price
-
0 5 10 R 15 20
Distance from the city center

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

This concept can be used for more than The more economic advantages a city prom-
ises for workers and businesses and the
simply making theoretical predictions on
more liveable it is, the higher the willingness
the spatial limits of urban extension; the
to pay for land in the urban area. This gives
decreasing gradient of land value with in- an indication of the opportunity costs of liv-
creasing distance to the city centre also ing in the city. By integrating the regional
offers an indicator for the quality of urban agricultural land price as well, this indicator
development as well as of the density at cer- becomes comparable among areas of differ-
tain distance from the centre. It reflects the ent economic development levels.

desirability and profitability of a city, on the


The gradient of decreasing land value re-
one hand, and the quality of its infrastruc- flects how fast the accessibility decreases
ture on the other. with growing distance to the urban centre.
The better developed the public transport
The desirability and profitability of a city are and street network in a city, the slower the
reflected in the prices people and businesses accessibility of the urban centre degrades
are willing to pay, displaying the economic with increasing distance.
and commercial benefits of settling close to
the urban centre. The difference between Besides analysing the decrease of land val-
land value in the city centre and in the sur- ue with rising inaccessibility to the urban
rounding rural areas also gives an idea of the centre, the productivity per km can be
economic opportunities and the liveability examined, depending on the distance to
and attractiveness of the city compared to the city centre. Urban productivity per km
rural areas. can be defined as the Gross Value Added

71
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

(GVA) per km less the infrastructure costs sess and evaluate their performance in con-
per km. Beyond a certain distance from the ceptualizing and implementing Planned City
city centre (or the centre where production Extensions, it has tried to give the broadest
is mostly concentrated), this indicator for possible variety of potential indicators. The
urban productivity becomes negative. The study concentrates on presenting indicators
indicator reflects how fast the urban pro- that characterize the performance of local
ductivity advantages decrease with distance authorities in the areas of urban design,
to the centre. Again, the value of the gradi- financial management and legislature, as
ent gives an indication of the quality of the these areas have been discussed to build the
urban infrastructure. For example, as certain foundation for successful Planned City Ex-
activities require proximity, the agglomera- tensions. The study does not try to present
tion of activities provides higher productive indicators to assess a Planned City Extension
areas and, in those areas, better and more with regard to all its features. Indeed, the
sophisticated infrastructure is located. set of indicators given can be seen as a tool
for evaluating whether a Planned City Ex-
All indicators discussed by now, namely the tension is built upon a proper foundation;
different indicators for urban productivity, it helps to identify issues that could hinder
as well as the indicators for spatial distribu- the successful implementation or could lead
tion of land value and productivity, indicate to unfavourable outcomes. To evaluate a
how far the urban productivity advantages Planned City Extension with regard to spe-
are exploited. Cities can be examined over cific issues such as youth issues, housing
time using these indicators in order to as- scarcity and so on, the proposed indicators
sess the effects of Planned City Extension can be supplemented by specific metrics
programmes. These programmes and the which reflect the status quo and develop-
local government`s performance in the pro- ments on those issues.
cess of implementation, on the other hand,
can be assessed using the indicators which Not all of the metrics suggested in this
will be introduced in the following sections. methodology section are used extensively
The next section, in particular, shows how in the empirical part. By presenting them
conceptualization and implementation of a and illustrating how they can be interpret-
Planned City Extension programme can be ed, however, local authorities are offered a
evaluated with regard to the three compo- variety of options to evaluate their own per-
nents of the Three-Pronged Approach. formance and its presumable consequenc-
es, given the limitations in data availability
and the specificities of a city. The number
3.2. Assessing the of indicators which are proposed to assess
performance on a governments performance on the Three-
the components of Pronged Approach principles differs among
the Three-Pronged the three areas. This does not imply that
Approach the evaluation of a Planned City Extension
with regard to one area is more important
In the following section, different indica-
than the other. The number of indicators
tors to measure performance in the three
per Three-Pronged Approach component
areas of the Three-Pronged Approach are
varies due to the differences in complexity
introduced. As this study seeks to give an
and tangibility of the concepts they seek to
overview on how local authorities can as-

72
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

measure. To assess the performance of local aim at being implemented at the very local
authorities in the conceptualization and im- scale, such as at the neighbourhood and
plementation of a Planned City Extension, a block level. Thereby the issue of city- or dis-
balanced set of the indicators presented be- trict-wide average values obscuring trends
low - which reflects the three areas in their and the existence of spatial mismatch can
full complexity - is required. be circumvented.

A systematic approach for assessing a gov-


Scales of urban assessment ernments performance with regard to ur-
When dealing with urban parameters, the ban design should be based on data with
scale of observation and of analysis is essen- all parameters being measured on the same
tial. Cities and urban environments are by scale; therefore, the urban area could for ex-
nature highly heterogeneous areas, with in- ample be gridded to cells of 500m by 500m
tense concentrations and peaks of activities, which can be considered as the neighbour-
and a long tail of areas with a medium to hood scale. In the case studies provided in
low intensity. Average figures have thus to this report, the layout used is either based
be handled with care, as they can hide very on a 500m x 500m gridding (Johannes-
heterogeneous patterns of urban develop- burg), or 200m x 200m gridding in Paris and
ment. This study differentiates three scales the Census Output Areas in London.
on which a city can be assessed:
To assess a governments performance with
On the metropolitan scale, urban regard to financial management and the
assessment addresses the spatial efficiency of the legal framework, acquiring
extension of the city. Analyses on this data on a neighbourhood scale is not always
scale give an indication of the spatial possible or useful. Rules and regulations
normally do not differ among neighbour-
layout of a city by differentiating rural
hoods; there might, however, be differences
and urban land use and of human
between city districts. Municipal finance ac-
activities such as industries, offices and
tivities are often done on a higher scale than
housing and the way they are organized
neighbourhood level. The guiding principle,
and distributed on the territory. therefore, should be to acquire data for the
On the district scale, urban lowest possible and sensible scale. The in-
assessment addresses how streets and dicators provided seek to assess how well a
Planned City Extension is funded. Therefore,
transportation networks are organized,
they do not only capture characteristics of
as well as how urban amenities such
the conceptualization and implementa-
as parks, hospitals or schools are
tion of a Planned City Extension, but also
distributed within the city.
those components which constitute the
On the neighbourhood scale, urban framework for the Extension; this explains
assessment considers the form and the why some concepts of the areas of finan-
size of urban blocks and the way they cial management and legal framework are
measured on scales which are higher than
are divided into plots.
the neighbourhood level.
For measuring urban design matters, the
metrics and indexes proposed in this study

73
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

3.3. Assessing urban design Indicators on the level of accessibility of


economic and social opportunities by
The five principles for the urban design sug-
public transit
gested by UN-Habitat are accompanied by
benchmarks indicating good performance: Indicators for the assessment of
walkability and street network
Adequate space for streets and an effi- connectivity
cient street network: the street network
Indicators on the diversity of land use
should occupy at least 30 per cent of
and economic activities
the land and at least 18 km of street
length per km. In the following section the indices for in-
tensity, accessibility, walkability, connectivity
High density: a city should have a
and diversity are specified. The importance
density of at least 15,000 people of the street network as a central planning
per km, that is 150 people/ha or 61 tool is reflected in the choice of indicators as
people/acre. the majority of indicators are compiled from
Mixed land-use: at least 40 per cent data on characteristics of the street network.

of floor space should be allocated for


economic use in any neighbourhood. Intensity indexes
Social mix: between 20 per cent to 50 The indicators on the intensity of urban fab-
per cent of the residential floor area rics aim at capturing the spatial concentration
should be for low-cost housing and of the urban residents, of their activities and
of their exchanges. We prefer the term in-
each tenure type should be not more
tensity instead of density, as the density of
than 50 per cent of the total.
urbanites and businesses does not contribute
Limited land-use specialization: per se to value creation. What makes urban
single-function blocks should cover less environments productivity is not the density
than 10 per cent of any neighbour- of people, but the frequency and intensity
hood. of interactions and exchanges among them.
The concept of urban intensity captures both
The urban planning indexes supporting this
density of urbanites and business as well as
study aim at capturing the five principles
the frequency and intensity of interactions
to full extent by defining a wider range of
and exchanges among them.
urban planning indexes and metrics than
the above indicators with benchmarks. This Residential density
study proposes indicators, reflecting the
performance on urban design against the Residential density corresponds to the num-
backdrop of the five UN-Habitat principles ber of residents per km. High residential
which can be grouped into the following density results in well-populated streets,
categories: ensuring that urban places are lively, active,
vibrant and safe places where people want
Indicators on the intensity of popu- to live. High density delivers a large custom-
lation, jobs, economic activities and er base and labour pool for local businesses
social infrastructure that makes local commerce thrive and offers
productivity advantages for local businesses.

74
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Job density Floor area ratio (FAR)

Job density is the number of jobs per km. The Floor Area Ratio (FAR) (also Floor Space
Job density feeds on economic productivity, Ratio (FSR)) is an indicator capturing the land
as high concentration of economic activity use intensity. The FAR of a plot is calculated
in particular locations enables firms to reap by dividing the total gross floor area of the
economies of scale and scope and bring tal- buildings on the plot by the plot size. It can
ented people together to share ideas and also be calculated on the neighbourhood
innovate. The number of jobs in a given scale as the ratio of the total area of floor in
area also has an impact on the attractive- all buildings in a neighbourhood to the area
ness of the area for residents. This indicator of all plots in the neighbourhood. High FAR
gives an impression of the intensity of eco- levels can support a high density of residents
nomic activity and the level of opportunity and businesses. The indicator is often mistak-
in a neighbourhood. en for average building height, whereas there
is no equivalence between high rise and high
Business and social infrastructure density. A neighbourhood with medium-rise
densities urban fabrics can have a high building foot-
print ratio (built-up space divided by plot size)
Other indicators to assess urban intensities and can, therefore, have a higher FAR than a
are the densities of businesses and social neighbourhood with high rise buildings and a
infrastructures (such as health and educa- low building footprint.
tion facilities) within a neighbourhood. A
high density of businesses, defined by the
share of space in a neighbourhood occu- Accessibility indexes
pied by businesses, fosters the local pro- Accessibility is a function of the distance be-
ductivity. Businesses can benefit from the tween travel destination, origin and travel
effects of economies of agglomeration, time per unit of distance. High accessibility
scale and scope. A high density of busi- can be achieved through the provision of a
nesses, moreover, has a positive effect on multimodal transportation infrastructure.
the job density with the consequences de-
scribed above. The density of social infra- To exploit the urban productivity advantages,
structure, such as schools and healthcare it is key to ensure accessibility to jobs, eco-
institutions, can be measured as the share nomic opportunities and social infrastructures
of total floor space in a neighbourhood in a Planned City Extension. In highly acces-
dedicated to social infrastructure. A high sible neighbourhoods, lower daily commut-
density of social infrastructure makes the ing distances induce lower energy costs and
social institutions easily accessible for resi- emissions. For businesses, the higher the level
dents of a neighbourhood and thereby has of accessibility, the lower the transport costs
a positive effect on the liveability of that for materials. Moreover, a highly and easily
neighbourhood by reducing transporta- accessible pool of workers benefits compa-
tion costs, as well as improving education nies and businesses. As a result, as will be
standards and public health. This, again, shown later in this study, high accessibility
increases the land value of the neighbour- has a positive impact on the economic pro-
hood. ductivity of urban areas. Accessibility can be
measured through different indicators.

75
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Accessibility to transit stations Accessibility to jobs within 30 or 45


minutes by transit
The indicator Accessibility to transit sta-
tions aims at capturing the average dis- Accessibility to jobs is among the most power-
tance of residencies and jobs, respectively, ful drivers of urban productivity. The number
to transit facilities. Accessibility to a transit of jobs accessible in less than 30 or 45 minutes
station strongly influences whether people from a given location can be used as an indi-
use public transport for commuting and cator to quantify the accessibility of jobs. The
for other daily travels. Beyond a certain calculation of this index requires structured
distance between a piece of land and the transit data.64 The indicator reflects the at-
closest transit station, the influence of tran- tractiveness of a neighbourhood for residents
sit features on land value and land uses de- and companies. For residents, it is beneficial to
creases. The area surrounding a transit sta- have access to a variety of jobs, as it reflects a
tion, in which the existence of the station high level of opportunity; for businesses a high
has a significantly noticeable influence on score on this indicator also makes a neigh-
land value and land use, can be called the bourhood attractive as it reflects a high density
transit catchment area. of economic activities in the neighbourhood.
High job accessibility levels, therefore, are like-
ly to result in a high market value of land for
the respective neighbourhood.

FIGURE 10.

Number of jobs accessible by transit in less than 30 minutes in Paris

Source: Urban Morphology Institute


64 e.g. generalized transit feed standards delivered by transit
agencies.

76
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Indexes on street network should occupy at least 30 per cent of the


land and that per km at least 18 km of
connectivity and walkability
street should be built. These metrics can be
Like other urban metrics, public space and supplemented by the indicators of intersec-
street network connectivity metrics should tion density and average distance between
be calculated at the local scale. The follow- intersections. International best practice
ing metrics can be used to assess public shows that an intersection density of about
realm and street networks connectivity: 100 intersections per square kilometre en-
hances accessibility.
Public space area per km
Walkability Index
Street length per km

Number of intersections per km The Walkability Index has been developed


by the Urban Morphology Institute to assess
Average distance between intersec-
how walkable a street network is. It is cal-
tions
culated by dividing the actual area reacha-
Walkability index (see Box below) ble in less than 12 minutes walking by the
area that would be reachable in less than
UN-Habitat recommendations for Planned
12 minutes walking as a crow flies (a 1km
City Extensions are that the street network
radius circle).

Left: Highly walkable area in Paris, with a Walkability index of 0.9. Right: Non walkable area in the Parisian
suburb, with a Walkability index of 0.2, due to cul-de-sacs and street network disconnection.
Source: Urban Morphology Institute

The indicators on street network connectivity also give an impression of the walkability of a
Planned City Extension, meaning how pedestrian friendly it is. To assess the walkability of a
Planned City Extension, the degree to which public realm and the street network are dense
and connected has to be captured; therefore, it is necessary to measure how direct travels
are from one point to another within the city. It captures the number and diversity of paths
which go from one point to another in the city, which makes the network more resilient.

77
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

A poorly-connected street network with ing ratio being similar to the share of the
many culs-de-sac connected to few arterials economically active population in a city. This
provides less accessibility than a well-con- means a job-housing ratio of 0.5, or one job
nected network, such as a grid (Litman, for every two residents. In close proximity to
2013). transit, the job-housing ratio can be higher
than 0.5, between 0.8 and 1, as is the case
An alternative measure of walkability: in successful transit-oriented cities, where
Walk Score around transit facilities the concentration
of jobs is higher than the concentration of
Walk Score measures the walkability of housing units.
any address. For each address, Walk Score
analyses the walking routes of hundreds of Land use diversity and mixed use
addresses to nearby amenities. Points are
awarded based on the distance to ameni- The two most common metrics to assess
ties in each category. Amenities within a diversity are the Simpson index and the
five-minute walk are given maximum points. Shannon-Wiener entropy. Both capture the
A decay function is used to give points to diversity within a set of elements. For an
more distant amenities, with no points giv- ecosystem, the score on the diversity index-
en for amenities reached after a walk of 30 es is maximal when the abundance of each
minutes or more. Walk Score also measures species is the same. In an urban context,
pedestrian friendliness by analysing popula- such as for measuring the diversity of land
tion density and road metrics such as block use, the diversity indexes are maximal when
length and intersection density. Walk Scores each type of land use is found in the same
ranges from 0 (car-dependent neighbour- amount within a given area. The Simpson
hood) to 100 (a walkers paradise). diversity index is considered a dominance
index, as it gives more weight to dominant
land uses. In economic science, the Simpson
Indexes on urban diversity and
index is known as the Herfindahl-Hirschman
mixed use index and measures the concentration or
Job-Housing Ratio market power in an industry. For a given
urban area, the Simpson diversity index is
The level of job-housing mismatch can be calculated using the proportion p of each
assessed using the job-housing ratio, which type i of the N land uses found in the area
is the number of jobs divided by the number such as residential, commercial, industrial
of inhabitants. Measured on a city scale, the and public infrastructure.
job-housing ratio corresponds approximate-
ly to the share of the economically active
population. The share of the economically !
active population can range under full
= !
employment - from 40 per cent to 50 per
cent which depends on the age structure in !!!
a city. It tends to be closer to 50 per cent in
countries benefiting from a youth dividend. Compared to the Simpson diversity index,
Measured on neighbourhood scale, a bal- the Shannon-Wiener entropy index is more
anced situation corresponds to a job-hous- of an index of the richness and diversity

78
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

than one of concentration. It is calculated autonomy allows for the local government
with the following formula: to introduce rules and regulations in accord-
ance with city specificities.
!
1
= !log (!) Compared to the metrics for the assess-
log ment of urban design, the characteristics on
!!!
which the legal framework can be evaluat-
The increase in one specific land use does ed are less tangible and may be more diffi-
not significantly change the value of the en- cult to quantify. The design of the indica-
tropy index. For an urban area, its score on tors for evaluating the legal performance of
the Simpson diversity index will be higher local authorities depends on the underlying
than on the Shannon entropy index with concept of the attribute of the legal frame-
less consideration to the relative contribu- work which is to be measured. Here, again,
tion to each land use type to the total num- it is important to distinguish city-level from
ber of activities that exist in a place (Kajtazi, regional and national boundaries where
2010). For this reason, the Shannon entropy different legal frameworks and rules and
index has to be preferred to assess the land regulations are applied. On each of the di-
use diversity of urban areas. mensions on which the performance of the
legislature can be evaluated, various studies
can be found which differ in how they de-
3.3.1. Assessment of the efficiency
fine the abstract concepts of the dimensions
of the legal framework and and on how they measure them.
governance
To evaluate the legal framework and the In this study a few common metrics are il-
governance system supporting a Planned lustrated but there are various alternatives
City Extension, three major categories of on how to measure any one of the dimen-
assessment can be distinguished. The urban sions in other studies. Often, more infor-
legal framework and the governance sys- mation can be extracted from assessing a
tem, as well as rules and regulations which governments performance on these indica-
are introduced in the context of a Planned tors over time, instead of only assessing the
City Extension, can be analysed based on status quo. This way, the development with
the criterion of efficiency. This, for example, respect to a topic can be evaluated and con-
requires an assessment of the level of bu- sequences of policies can be made visible.
reaucracy and corruption. Apart from this,
the regulations which define the layout of a Legal and governmental efficiency
Planned City Extension have to be evaluated
on how flexible and reactive they are. As dis- The best-known indicators on legal efficien-
cussed before, regulations which are highly cy have been developed by the World Bank
restrictive or do not allow for adaption to Group and the European Central Bank,
changing requirements and environments namely The Indicator of Government Effec-
can prevent optimal urban development tiveness and the Indicator of Public Sector
and the exploitation of the full potential of Efficiency. Both indicators are composed of
an urban agglomeration. The national legal a set of sub-indicators measuring the legal/
system can be examined on the degree of governmental performance on different di-
legal decentralization, as a higher level of mensions (Van de Walle, 2005).

79
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

In this study four sub-indicators are suggest- ed in order to obtain a complex image of
ed which can be found in different studies the perception of public sector corruption.
on legal and governmental efficiency. All in- (To see the full source description for the
dicators on legal and governmental efficien- construction of the Corruption Perception
cy discussed in this section give an impres- Index: Transparency International, 2014)
sion on whether the urban legal framework
provides a stable investment and business Many studies on the issue of corruption are
friendly atmosphere and whether it creates based on directly asking the population in
a secure environment for residents. surveys how they perceive the level of politi-
cal corruption, with the Americas Barometer
Level of bureaucracy survey as one example among many others
(Americas Barometer, 2014). These surveys
Following the methodology of the 2012 vary in size and complexity; some consist of
Global Cities Index and Emerging Cities one simple question on whether the inter-
Outlook the level of bureaucracy and pub- viewed person has paid a bribe to a public
lic administration processes are evaluated body in the past year (Global Corruption
through the eyes of businesses (AT Kear- Barometer by Transparency International),
ney, 2012). Administrative activities of local other studies confront the sample with a set
public bodies are evaluated based on the of questions on their perception of the cor-
bureaucratic hurdles for businesses and res- ruption situation. The results of repetitively
idents. It measures to what extent business- carried out one-question-surveys can form
es and residents are hindered through re- a particularly suitable and easily-accessible
source-consuming bureaucratic procedures. indicator for measuring the general devel-
opment of the corruption situation and con-
The indicator can be constructed from data sequences of anti-corruption policies.
on the average time and number of steps
necessary to complete different administra- Extent of the informal sector
tive procedures, from survey results or from
a combination of both. Potential compo- Like the other indicators on legal and gov-
nents could be the average time required ernmental efficiency discussed before, there
to get different licenses, to get permits ap- is no clearly identifiable data on the extent
proved or to get a new business started. of the informal economy. Again, there is the
need to consult experts on how they esti-
Level of corruption mate the extent of the shadow economy or
to carry out surveys among the urban popu-
An often-cited index on corruption is the lation. The extent of the informal sector can
Corruption Perception Index by Transparen- be used as an indicator for the efficiency of
cy International, which is published annually the legal framework as it reflects the quality
and captures how analysts, business-people of labour regulation and the functioning of
and experts perceive the level of political labour market institutions.
corruption in a country. The data published
is only available on the country level. Never- It can be measured as the share of urban
theless, the methodology of consulting ex- population employed in the informal sector
perts to assess the perception of corruption (for more information on alternative meth-
can also be applied at regional and urban ods to measure informal employment see
levels and sets of questions can be adopt- ILO, 2013) or the share of income from in-

80
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

formal economic activity, measured by total Planned City Extension could be the average
Gross Value Added. time required to change these rules and reg-
ulations. Thereby, the rules and regulations
Level of instability and insecurity - the adoption of which is subject to the lo-
cal body - can be examined as to how long
The measurements on the level of instabili- changes have been considered on average
ty and insecurity, crime and clearance rates before they were implemented. In addition,
and their development over time are impor- it would be useful to consider the share of
tant indicators. They can be supplemented discussed changes which have finally been
by surveys in the urban population and implemented and, retrospectively, the share
among business people to obtain the share of rules and regulations which have been
of criminal incidents reported, the general subject to change. All these indicators can
perception of the security and political sta- give an impression of how adaptive the reg-
bility situation and the trust in the legal and ulatory framework for the general plan of a
judicial institutions. Planned City Extension has been to chang-
ing circumstances.
Potential for adaption/Flexibility of
the legal framework 3.3.2. Assessment of the financial
Level of decentralization management
Indicators on the performance of financial
The level of legal decentralization gives an in- management are better quantifiable with
dication on the potential of local authorities to the municipal budget being an easily acces-
adapt to a citys specificities. Among various sible data source. Consequently, the finan-
indicators on the national level of decentrali- cial performance of a Planned City Exten-
zation, one which is often cited is the indica- sion can be analysed more tangibly. To eval-
tor of political decentralization by the World uate a local governments performance with
Bank Group. This indicator is comprised of regard to municipal finance, the size and
information on the numbers of government composition of the budget can be assessed
tiers existing at different levels and on wheth- while public investments can be analysed on
er the municipal and provincial governments whether they are feasible and sustainable.
are locally elected. (See: On the conceptual- This allows evaluation on the quality of the
ization of the Indicator: World Bank (2013c) expenditure management. A local authori-
and for data: World Bank (2013d)). While this tys performance concerning revenue gen-
indicator gives an impression on the potential eration, on the other hand, can be assessed
of adaption, it does not provide information by examining the extent to which the po-
on whether this potential has been exploited tential of different sources are exploited.
and to what degree. Therefore, the indicator
has to be supplemented by others to show
how adaptive the urban legal framework is. Budgeting
Different indicators are presented based on
Time for regulatory changes information that is directly extractable from
the municipal budget. Besides introducing
Another indicator to quantify the flexibility
indicators to analyse revenue and expend-
of the rules and regulations supporting a
iture management in more detail, the indi-

81
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

cators illustrated in this section give an in- own source revenue. A high score on this
dication of whether the municipal finance indictor could limit a municipalitys ability to
authority is able to plan, forecast and prior- borrow in the future. Moreover, paying debt
itize and whether it is capable of translating expenses ties up revenues. Rather than evalu-
policy decisions into financial plans. ating a municipalitys performance negatively
in the case of high debt repayment, the inter-
Budget projection accuracy est paid on long-term debt could be looked
at separately. (Adapted from: Government of
To measure how accurately the local body Nova Scotia, 2015)
planned its budget, there needs to be a
comparison between the planned and the
actual budget. Starting with a comparison Feasibility and sustainability of public
of the predicted amount of expenditures investments
and revenues with those that have actual- Expenditures for maintenance and
ly occurred, the analysis can go further into development
detail to examine in which areas the predic-
tions differ most significantly from the actu- With the ratio of operational expenditures and
al numbers. The data on budget projection expenditures for development and with its
accuracy gives an impression on the qual- trends over time, an indicator is given to assess
ity of budget planning and on future risks how far a municipality has used and still uses
for illiquidity and excessive indebtedness. its financial capacity to invest in further devel-
Moreover, it can give an indication whether opment. A high score can give the indication
a Planned City Extension can be completed that some existing infrastructures or services
as originally planned or how projects similar are unsustainable. A high score may also in-
to ones that have already been fully imple- dicate that the municipality is suffering from a
mented, can be scheduled for the future. general lack of funding resources.

Liquidity and debt coverage trends To create a second indicator, the repair and
maintenance expenses can be put in relation
A governments performance in liquidity and to the fixed assets. On this indicator, a low
debt matters can be measured through as- score is desirable. An increase in the score
sessing the status quo and trends of its score over time can be indicative of ageing infra-
on various indicators. To quantify a munici- structure, of infrastructure being pushed to
palitys liquidity, its short-term operating as- its operating capacity limits or of increasing
sets can be divided by its total short-term investments in unsustainable, low-quality in-
liabilities. This score gives an impression of frastructure.
the short-term financial performance of a
municipality. A score below 1 signifies that a The structure of infrastructure costs
municipality has less cash and assets that can
easily be converted to cash than the amount Proxies, such as infrastructure costs in the form
required to pay current obligations which can of street, water and drainage network per km
indicate a problem of cash flow. or per resident can be assessed over time to
get an estimate on how expenditures increase
To assess the long-term financial perfor- with population growth or urban sprawl and
mance, the principal and interest paid on on whether the investment in infrastructure
long-term debt can be divided by the total

82
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

and public assets increased. By additionally generated through innovative financing


measuring the development of the estimated methods such as land value capture can be
value of public assets and infrastructure per measured. It is also interesting to measure
km or residents respectively, information can the share of investments financed through
be obtained on whether the quality of public PPPs. These indicators provide information
assets has improved through the investments, on the extent to which the municipal fi-
meaning whether the investments have been nance authority exploits the potential of
sustainable. The costs or the estimated value innovative financing methods. Again, this
of infrastructure and public assets can be com- indicator can be analysed over time or com-
pared between different neighbourhoods in pared among cities in a country as they are
a city. By assessing the spatial distribution of subject to the same legal constraints from
the costs and value, an impression is given on the central government.
whether the investments have an equalizing
character, whether they increase or whether Share of property registered
they reduce inter-neighbourhood differences.
This indicator, of course, cannot be exactly
obtained but has to be estimated based on
Exploitation of revenue potential
existing GIS data, surveys or interviews with
Reliance on inter-governmental
experts. It gives an impression of the extent
transfers
to which property taxation is exploited as a
The share of revenues from inter-governmen- revenue source. Moreover, the amount of
tal transfers depends heavily on the level of additionally registered properties per year
fiscal decentralization of a country. Neverthe- can be assessed to measure how munici-
less, the inter-governmental transfers as share pal finance authority improves in exploiting
of total revenues can be compared among cit-
property taxation as a source of revenue.
ies in a country. A high share of transfers in
a municipality can result from a high amount
Uncollected Taxes
of capital transferred from the central govern-
ment and/or from a small amount of other Based on the estimation on the share of
revenues generated by the municipal finance non-registered property, the amount of un-
authority. However, it is important to note that collected property taxes can be assessed.
it is advisable to not only compare the share Moreover, the amount of lost revenues due
of transfers but also the transfers per resident to the non-taxability of the informal sector
among cities in a country. Moreover, the posi- can be estimated. The potential tax revenues
tion of a city among the others with regard to the local government misses by not being
reliance on transfers can be analysed over time able to collect these taxes, together with
to identify increasing or decreasing trends in the losses from not exploiting other sources
the reliance on transfers. of tax revenues, form the indicator of un-
collected taxes. They can be expressed as a
Share of conventional and innovative
percentage of the actually collected tax rev-
financing methods
enues to get an impression on the revenue
generation potential the local government
In addition to assessing the share of inter-gov-
is not exploiting. Again, the indicator can be
ernmental transfers, the share of revenues
assessed over time to identify changes.

83
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

4. Empirical evidence a random outcome or if they merely


reflected underlying differences across

This section analyses selected Planned City space leading to comparative advantage
Extension programmes which are represent- Spatial patterns in wages and land rents
ative of contemporary urban development reflect productive advantages in dense
practice as well as programmes with best urban environments
practice character in different cities using
the Three-Pronged Approach framework. There are systematic variations in
productivity across urban space

4.1. On the productivity The spatial distribution of


advantages of urban
productivity advantages
agglomerations
In Hong Kong, banana and orange crops are
The correlation between national urbani-
the most profitable activity on rural land, with
zation and productivity level has been ex-
returns of approximately USD 240,000 per
amined in various empirical studies. The
km per year on average. In comparison, con-
studies show that transitions from agrarian
verting and selling 1km of rural land to de-
and rural societies to urbanized ones largely
velopers generates USD 80 million, an amount
coincide with a countrys level of industri-
likely to provide an annual income of USD 4.8
alization and economic development (Tis-
million with a 6 per cent interest rate, which is
dale, 1942; Jones, 2004). This correlation
a revenue 20 times higher than that of most
is reflected through increasing trends in the
productive agricultural uses. If reinvested in
share of the Gross Value Added generated
residential or industrial development, it can
by industry and services and the proportion
generate revenues up to 20 per cent per year.
of the workforce employed in these sectors
During the speculative phase of the 1990s in
which accompany increases in the level of
Hong Kong, some pieces of land generated an
urbanization (Satterthwaite, 2007; World
annual return of more than 50 per cent in the
Bank, 2009).
residential real estate market (Jenks and Bur-
gess, 2000).
Urban economies generate more than 90
per cent of global gross value added (Gut-
The results of an analysis of the spatial distri-
man, 2007). In 2007, 600 cities generated
bution of the productivity advantages within a
60 per cent of global GDP while 23 global
sample of cities can be seen below. It has been
megacities generated 14 per cent of global
analysed how the Gross Value Added/km
GDP (McKinsey Global Institute, 2011).
decreases with increasing distance from the
urban core. The graphs also show the devel-
According to Puga, 2010) evidence for the
opment of infrastructure costs with distance to
existence and magnitude of agglomeration
the centre. The decrease in population densi-
economies is given through the following
ties when moving away from the urban core
empirical observations:
induces higher infrastructure costs per capita
(Mller et al., 2013). As a result, urban land
Productive activities are much more
is less and less economically productive and
clustered than would be expected
more and more costly in terms of infrastruc-
if location was simply the result of
tures when moving away from the urban core.

84
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 11.

Gross Value Added/km versus Infrastructure costs/km (Top)


and Gross Value Added and costs per capita (Bottom)
100
90
80 GVA per per capita
70
Urban productivity per capita

60
50
Cost per per capita
40
30
20
10
-
0 5 10 R* 15 20 25
Distance from the city center (km)

100

90

80 GVA per
per capita
70
Urban productivity per capita

60
Cost per
50
per capita
40

30

20

10

-
0 10 20
Distance from the city center (km)

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

The (de)correlation of urbanization and tion of per capita income (Spence, Annez,
and Buckley, 2008).
economic development
Globally, a positive correlation between Kenya today has an urbanization level of
the level of economic development and 25 per cent (World Bank Data). As shown
the level of urbanization can be observed. in the graph below, the urbanization trend
Some countries, especially in Africa, howev- in Kenya is not accompanied by economic
er, have not experienced economic growth growth. It has to be noted, however, that in
despite the increasing share of people living many countries urbanization rates and GDP/
in urban agglomerations. Instead, the rapid capita moved together until a certain level
urbanization rate is accompanied by stagna- of urbanization was reached, apart from

85
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

which the GDP/capita expanded much more rapidly. In the case of the USA, for example,
the urbanization level which induced a rapid take off of the GDP/capita was 60 per cent;
in China, however, the rapid take off took place from an urbanization rate of 30 per cent
and Brazil experienced a pattern more similar to the United States with a strong growth in
productivity starting in the 1960s while urbanization stood at about 50 per cent (Spence,
Annez, and Buckley, 2008).

FIGURE 12.
Urbanization and per capita GDP in Kenya

GDP per capita urbanization


1960: $1,179 1960: 7%
2003: $1,218 2003: 20%

300

250

200
index

150

100

50

0
1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2003
year

percent of population living in urban areas


per capita GDP in constant prices (chain series)

Source: Spence, Annez, and Buckley 2008

This shows that there is not one threshold certain conditions, so that the potential of
for urbanization to bring along a rapid take urban agglomerations to create productivity
off in economic growth; for most coun- advantages can be fully realized.
tries there can be periods of faster urban-
ization than identified economic growth,
independent of the stage of economic 4.2. Urban design
development. This reveals that there is no
causality between urbanization and eco- 4.2.1. The Floor Area Ratio (FAR)
nomic development. This also support the The Floor Area Ratio (FAR) in traditional
theoretical considerations described above European urban fabrics composed of me-
that the urbanization process has to fulfil dium-rise buildings with internal courtyards

86
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

is often higher than in many recent mod- cent to 10 per cent, having the characteris-
ern high-rise developments with low build- tic of a tower in a park. Those urban fab-
ing footprints (less than 15 per cent of the rics must have six to 12 times taller buildings
ground). The continuous medium-rise ur- on average (50 to 100 floors) to reach the
ban fabric (five to 10 floors high) with high same floor density as an urban fabric of sev-
building footprint (50 per cent to 60 per en-floor high with a building footprint of 60
cent of the ground) and compact continu- per cent such as in the centre of some Euro-
ous urban street blocks of many European pean cities which have a FAR of 3 to 5. As a
cities results in a FAR of 3 to 5. Contempo- result, most high-rise developments, such as
rary urban planning in many fast urbanizing in Chinese new towns, present a gross built
countries features urban fabrics with build- density between 1 and 2 despite an average
ings with a low building footprint of 5 per building height of 40 to 50 stories.

CASE STUDY:

FAR and street width in Paris

In Paris, France, the Plan local durbanisme prescribes buildings heights according
to street width and the districts. The height of the faade is comprised between
W+2 and W+3m with W being the street width. The height of the building under
eaves must be between W+6 and W+8m. A maximal height is also given according
to the district: 25m in central districts and 31m in peripheral districts. Alignment on
the street is compulsory. Through predicating the allowed building height on street
width, the development of dark and unpleasant streets is avoided without setting a
uniform restriction for building heights for a whole neighbourhood, which can lead
to unnecessarily low density.

87
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

CASE STUDY:
FAR and urban infrastructure in Manhattan and Mumbai

Manhattans density zones are typically to overwhelm infrastructure. Rather than


small and vary with street width, infra- increasing densities, new urban devel-
structure capacity and land use (commer- opments have been pushed out to new
cial office districts have higher FAR than towns and suburban industrial estates.
residential ones). In contrast, Mumbais But this strategy ignores the opportuni-
density zones are large, uniform across ty to increase FAR to finance better and
the city and generally low. Local urban higher-capacity infrastructures (World
planners justify such low densities as not Bank, 2013b).

Maps of FAR regulations in Manhattan (left) and Mumbai (right)


Source: World Bank, 2013a

88
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

4.2.2. Residential density

CASE STUDY:
Comparing density of residents in Paris and Johannesburg

The following figures display the spatial variability of residential density within urban areas.
With a 200m x 200m gridding, the residential density in the Grand Paris area varies from
fewer than 5,000 to more than 50,000 inhabitants per km. On average, the density of the
urban core (Paris intramurros) is above 24,000 inhab/km over an 87km area.

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

The second figure shows the distribution of densities in the City of Johannesburg, South
Africa, using a 500m x 500m gridding. It shows a much different density pattern, with pock-
ets of medium to high residential density in Soweto, the inner city and Alexandra (higher
than 5,000 inhab/km), and low densities in the rest of the city. The second chart highlights
the span of residential densities in 10 neighbourhoods in Johannesburg, ranging from very
low densities in wealthy areas (below 2,000 inhab/km), to very high residential densities in
deprived areas (above 100,000 inhab/km).

89
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

CASE STUDY...CONTINUED

Residential density in the City of Johannesburg, using a 500x500m gridding

Residential density (inhab/km)


0 - 1000
1000 - 2500
2500 - 5000
5000 - 7500
7500 - 10000
10000 - 12500
12500 - 15000
15000 - 20000
20000 - 25000
25000 - 30000
30000 - 50000
More than 50000

0 5 10 15 20 km

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

Residential densities in 10 districts in Johannesburg

60000
51685
50000 44519
Population density (Inhab/km)

40000

30000

20000 15722
11991
9950
10000 3145
1496 1445 1045 1137
0
rch

te

te

to

lle

w
dr
to

din

en

ro
sta

ta

we

rvi
eA

an
nd

on

llb
es
Ri

he
ne

So

ex
Sa

Hi
ab
os

on
rth

fis
fer

Al
elr

M
ht

am
No
M

yn

ug

Br
Da

Ho

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

90
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

CASE STUDY...CONTINUED

120000

104099
100000
Population density (Inhab/km)

80000

60000
51685
Paris(peaks) 44519
40000
Paris(average)
20000 Public transit threshold 15722
9950 11991
1496 1445 1045 3145 1137
0
rch

te

te

to

lle

w
dr
to

din

en

an

ro
sta

ta

we

rvi
eA

an
nd

on

aS

llb
es
Ri

he
ne

So

ex
Sa

Hi
ab
os

on

Ky
rth

fis
fer

Al
elr

M
ht

am
No
M

yn

ug

Br
Da

Ho

4.2.3. Job density

CASE STUDY:

Comparing job density in London, UK, and Johannesburg, South Africa

The first figure shows the distribution of job densities in the Greater London area and
highlights the strong urban core. The second figure displays the spatial distribution of
formal jobs in the City of Johannesburg and shows that these are scattered in wealthy
Northern areas.

91
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

CASE STUDY...CONTINUED

Distribution of workplace densities in London, using census output areas

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

Formal job density in the City of Johannesburg, using a 500x500m grid.

Job density (jobs/km)


0 - 500
500 - 1250
More than 0.8
2500 - 3750
3750 - 5000
5000 - 6250
6250 - 7500
7500 - 10000
10000 - 12500
12500 - 15000
15000 - 25000
More than 50000

0 5 10 15 20 km

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

92
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

CASE STUDY:
Density of jobs, residents and floor in Johannesburg and New York

The following figure displays the FAR in Johannesburg with a dense urban core (inner
city) and high built densities in job-intensive urban areas, whereas residential areas
display low built density. The figures of the spatial distributions of floor density in Jo-
hannesburg (residential, job and built density) show that resting upon a unique index
of urban density can be misleading. This is particularly the case in emerging and fast
urbanizing countries, where these three densities (residential, jobs and businesses) can
be largely de-correlated. The second map displays floor area ratios in New York cities,
and exhibit two business districts (Wall Street and Midtown) with high FAR (20 to 40),
medium density in most of Manhattan island (4 to 8), and low density in the rest of
the city (lower than 2).

Gross built density in the City of Johannesburg, using a 500x500m gridding

Floor Area Ratio


0.0 - 0.2
0.2 - 0.5
0.5 - 1.0
1.0 - 1.5
1.5 - 2.0
2.0 - 3.0
3.0 - 4.0
4.0 - 5.0
More than 5.0

0 5 10 15 20 km

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

93
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

CASE STUDY...CONTINUED

Floor Area Ratio in New York City at plot scale

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

4.2.4. Transit accessibility


The following chart compares the share of people living and working less than 500m, 1km
and 2km from transit in four cities: London, New York, Copenhagen and Johannesburg. In
London, New York and Copenhagen, one-quarter of people live less than 500m from transit
and half live less than 1km. One-third to half of the jobs are located less than 500m from
transit, two-thirds less than 1km. In Johannesburg, which is representative of many cities
in fast-urbanizing countries, fewer than 5 per cent of the people and jobs are located less
than 500m from a transit station, 10 per cent less than 1km, and 17 per cent less than 2km
while 83 per cent of jobs and residents are located more than 2km from a transit station.

94
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 13.
Respective share of residents (left) and jobs (right) and proximity to
transit facilities in New York, Copenhagen, London and Johannesburg

More than 2km 22%


More than 2km 28%
1 to 2km 21%
New York

New York
1 to 2km 24%
23% 500m to 1km 21%
500m to 1km
Less than 500m 37%
Less than 500m 25%

More than 2km 18% More than 2km 13%


1 to 2km 1 to 2km 20%
London

London
29%
500m to 1km 31% 500m to 1km 24%
Less than 500m 22% Less than 500m 43%

More than 2km 16% More than 2km 13%


Copenhagen

Copenhagen
1 to 2km 27% 1 to 2km 26%
500m to 1km 32% 500m to 1km 32%
Less than 500m 25% Less than 500m 29%

More than 2km 83% More than 2km 83%


Johannesburg

Johannesburg

1 to 2km 7% 1 to 2km 7%
500m to 1km 5% 500m to 1km 5%
Less than 500m 6% Less than 500m 5%

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

95
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

CASE STUDY:
FAR in Seoul: Articulation of the built-up density with transit

Seouls spatial structure is compact as expansion is restricted by hills and by the northern
border, and polycentric, with a large CBD but many important sub-centres. A grid-like metro
system links the various sub-centres and the CBD. The FAR in Seoul is linked to the location
of metro stations and to the network of main streets: 10 in part of the CBD, 8 in the rest of
the CBD and sub-centres and 0.5 to 4 in residential areas. Seoul provides a best practice ex-
ample for transit oriented development. Through regulations on the FAR, the limited space
is used in the most efficient way as it fosters concentration of economic activity and resi-
dents close to transit stations. The resulting urban fabric enables a large share of residents
and businesses to benefit from the existing public transport infrastructure.

FAR distribution in Seoul, South Korea

Source: Bertaud 2008

96
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

4.2.5. Street network connectivity


In fast-urbanizing countries there is an identifiable trend towards street networks with a
large distance between intersections, often above 400 m, and a low density of intersections,
often below 50 intersections per km. This type of street network increases walking dis-
tances and produces car dependent cities, which eventually impacts on urban productivity
through congestion and energy costs. The following figures present different street connec-
tivity metrics in the City of Johannesburg, and show that the majority of the urban area is
much below international best practice benchmarks.

FIGURE 14.
Number of intersections per km(left) and street network length per
km(right) in the City of Johannesburg, using a 500x500m gridding

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

The case of Johannesburg is representative for contemporary urban development in rapid-


ly-urbanizing countries but is far from being the worst case. Nevertheless, the consequences
of the low level of walkability are easily perceptible. Johannesburg is a heavily car dependent
city which, according to the WHO, has the highest level of air pollution in South Africa. This
has a negative impact on the liveability of the city.

Japanese cities with an average distance between intersections of 50 m (even in modern To-
kyo) are highly pedestrian cities. European 19th Century cities, as well as the historical core

97
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

of American cities and some Asian cities like Hong Kong present average distances between
intersections from 100m to 150m. This is the sizing of sustainable, vibrant and intense urban
environments. Manhattan, for example, with urban blocks of 80m x 160m presents an aver-
age distance between intersections of 120m, identical to the hypercentre of historical Paris.
Small block sizes about 100m with vibrant edges (facades with businesses on the perimeter
of the block) promote more compact development and walkability.

FIGURE 15.
Number of intersections per km in 10 districts in Johannesburg,
South Africa, much lower than international best practice
100
90 International best practice for high walkability
78
80
Number of intersections per km

70 65
60
50 52
49
50
42
38
40
30
22 22
20 13
10
0
rch

te

te

to

lle

w
dr
to

din

en

ro
sta

ta

we

rvi
eA

an
nd

on

llb
es
Ri

he
ne

So

ex
Sa

Hi
ab
os

on
rth

fis
fer

Al
elr

M
ht

am
No
M

yn

ug

Br
Da

Ho

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

CASE STUDY:
Street network sizing and setback rules in China

Over-sizing of the street grid in greenfield urban to 150m from an already oversized road width
developments is common in fast urbanizing coun- which results in distances of 300m to 450m be-
tries. In China, for instance, the regulatory sizing tween buildings on opposite sides of the road.
of the grid prescribes a main road every 500 me- Such an urban fabric is not designed on a hu-
tres and an even wider road (often an eight-lane man scale for pedestrians. Setbacks which are
highway) every kilometre for high-speed traffic too large also prevent a reduction in the size of
and which cannot be crossed on foot. This wide the urban block; if the urban block was smaller
grid leads to a disrupted urban fabric and an over- than 400m after deduction of the setbacks there
sizing of urban blocks while the network middle would be very little land left for the building foot-
and narrow streets are missing. print. The consequences of the oversized street
grid and setback regulation are the prevention
Setback regulations in China are variable. In of walking and non-motorized transport modes
extreme cases, the built front is set back 100m which locks cities into a car-dependent path.

98
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

4.2.6. The job-housing ratio


In best practice transit oriented cities, such as Tokyo, Seoul, New York City or Portland, the
job housing ratio in the areas close to transit stations is, with 0.8 to 1.0 higher than the av-
erage of a city. This means that close to the transit station the concentration of jobs is higher
than the concentration of housing units. This urban layout results in high accessibility of jobs
with positive effects for both workers and businesses.

FIGURE 16.
Job-housing ratio in greater London

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

The spatial mismatch between residents and economic opportunities is a common pattern
in fast urbanizing countries. In Shanghai, for instance, households are resettled in peri-urban
locations where residential property is affordable but where the transit system, the local
feeder bus services and the infrastructures for non-motorized travel are badly developed.
Households, therefore, tend to become dependent on private vehicle and/or accept long
commuting times. In South African cities, the spatial mismatch between the residents and
job opportunities, which is inherited from the Apartheid period, has a very significant impact
on the urban productivity.

99
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

FIGURE 17.

Job-housing ratio in the City of Johannesburg

Job-housing Ratio
0 to 0.4 jobs for one resident
0.4 to 0.8 jobs for one resident
More than 0.8 jobs for one resident
Note: Only areas where residential
density is higher than 500 people per
km are displayed)

0 5 10 15 20 km

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

4.2.7. Land use diversity


In fast-urbanizing countries there is a trend towards statutory urban planning resting upon
rules inspired from zoning theories which prevents fine grain in mixed-use development.

CASE STUDY:
The Italian approach to promote mixed-use development

The Italian statutory urban planning obliges all first floors of buildings to be devoted
to commercial activities, thus encouraging a mix of uses within the same building,
distributing amenities, shops and restaurants everywhere in the city fabric, creating a
streetscape of activities for pedestrians, ensuring there are no 300m long blank faades
and preventing crime.

100
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

CASE STUDY:
Land use diversity in Johannesburg

The following maps display a land use analysis of a transit corridor in Johannesburg. The local
diversity of land use is calculated using an entropy formula, taking into account: commercial
use, community use (health, education and public services), residential use and industrial use.
The cells encompassing the four types of land uses display an index close to 1. The cells with
one single use display very low entropy, close to zero.

Land uses along Empire Perth Corridor, Johannesburg.

LANDUSE
Commercial
Community Etc
Industrial
Mining
Residential
Smallholding

0 1 2 3 4 km

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

Land use diversity index along Empire Perth Corridor, Johannesburg

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

101
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

A good urban design has to be supplement- A study of Salat and Bourdic (2014) on ur-
ed by an appropriate regulatory and fiscal ban extension projects in Johannesburg
framework, to result in sustainable urban led to opposite results. It shows that some
development. planned urban extensions in Johannesburg
(see Soweto Orlando East or Bram Fisher-
Cohen (2009) analysed the long-term im- ville) that also followed the concept of pro-
pacts of urban development projects of viding plots and housing have led to an in-
the World Bank Group in Senegal. The efficient urban fabric, with little if any con-
analysis revealed that, 40 years after their solidation of the platting system, very low
implementation, the urban extension pro- land use diversity in sizes and uses and un-
jects showed positive results. The urban sustainable land market. Salat and Bourdic
projects, implemented in the early 1970s, (2014) state that this land market failure has
followed the Sites-and-Services concept of mostly been produced by inappropriate reg-
providing the economically weaker with a ulatory and fiscal frameworks.
site equipped with basic utilities in order
to construct and maintain a house upon it. Another study by da Mata et al. (2005),
Today the project sites are characterized by resting upon an extensive analysis of Brazil-
high residential and commercial density and ian cities, shows that both a higher share of
a solid local economy. private sector industrial capital in the local
economy and better land use regulations
stimulates economic growth within cities.

102
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

4.3. Financial management

CASE STUDY:
Land fragmentation in Japan

Japan has witnessed a process of fragmen- (1) a consolidation process driven by PPP invest-
tation of very expensive land into small plots ment, merging small plots together to create
as shows the below comparison between the larger plots and (2) a small private investor -
same area of Edo in the 19th Century and pres- driven subdivision process, dividing large plots
ent-day Tokyo. This process has led to the cre- into smaller plots. Unlike the American plot,
ation of additional lanes to connect the inner the Japanese one is subdivided and becomes
parts of the former blocks divided into smaller more complex over time, creating an urban
blocks of 50m side on average. Two antagonist fabric where the land use testifies to a complex
schemes take place in Japanese cities, which socioeconomic structure.
contribute to create a very diversified land use:

Comparison of plot structure between the mid-19th Century Edo period (left) and the present (right)

Source: Salat, S., Cities and Forms, 2011

103
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

CASE STUDY:
4.4. The legal framework
Land price as revenue
Land use flexibility
source in China
In China, the basic unit for selling land to de-
Although this cannot be taken as an ex- velopers is 400m x 400m or 160,000 m. In
ample of best practice, many municipal- Manhattan, the basic unit for selling land es-
ities in China follow an unconventional tablished in the Commissioners Plan in 1811
practice of revenue generation by selling was 205 m, which is 780 times smaller than
urban land. This process is widely used the unit of Chinese urban development. The
by municipalities and local authorities for fine grain of plot and land market fosters an
financing themselves. In Guangzhou in active land market with great potential of
2006, 55 per cent of municipal finances future mix use. Through appropriate regula-
originated from land sale and this was 80 tions and incentives, some plots of land can
per cent in Shenzhen in the 1990s (Merk be consolidated over time for large investors,
et al., 2012). whereas others keep a small size and provide
opportunities for medium and small investors
such as SMEs and housing.

CASE STUDY:
Land use flexibility in Manhattan

Compared to urban fabrics with large mo- and commercial (pink)), appropriate legal
no-functional urban blocks, such as slabs and financial frameworks make it possible
or towers, Manhattan is characterized by to generate a much more diversified urban
high flexibility of land use. The fine-grain fabric, with diversified plot sizes and diversi-
character of plot subdivisions makes Man- fied uses (public facilities in yellow).
hattans buildings highly adaptive and
flexible. The use of floor areas can easily Example of a successful process of urban di-
be changed from industry to commercial versification, subdivision and consolidation
or from offices to housing, to adapt to
changing economic circumstances. This
high level of flexibility gives Manhattan
a very high resilience in times of change.
Fine grain allows an intensification process
to happen: land sale is open to a whole
variety of investors and developers, from
individuals to large companies and institu-
tions that can merge several plots together
if needed. Superblock platting on the con-
trary is only open to large investors.

From a fine grain urban fabric with a lim-


ited diversity of uses (just residential (blue) Source: Urban Morphology Institute

104
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

CASE STUDY:
Comparing plot consolidation in New York City and Johannesburg

In 1811, the Commissioners Map overlaid a seemingly uniform grid of rectangles over the
rugged island of Manhattan. The grid was, above all, an easy format for the subdivision
and development of land. The grid system stripped the land of topographical markers and
specificity, and repackaged it as standardized building lots. Blocks were subdivided for
land sale into identical plots of 205m2 area, which, under the influence of market forces,
started to consolidate and create a differentiated platting ordered by combinations of the
same basic module very early in the process.

Process of plot consolidation in Manhattan.

Manhattan
Original plot subdivision
Average plot size: 205 m Fine grain platting allows
consolidation over time and
makes the city resilient, diverse
and adaptive to market
Residential
Manhattan
Intermediary plot consolidation
Average plot size: 255 m

Manhattan
Mixed use Extreme plot consolidation
Average plot size: 6,100 m

Large businesses

Source: Urban Morphology Institute. Salat, S., Cities and Forms, 2011

The following figures show that from an identical small-scale modular unit, plots in New
York City have adapted to the socio-economic environment. Around Madison Square
(left), only 40 per cent of the plots have kept the original platting of early 19th Cen-
tury, while the other 60 per cent have consolidated at various sizes. In more residential
Brooklyn (right), 80 per cent of the plot sizes date back to early 19th Century. In the
very first decades after the Commissioners Plan of 1811, Manhattans vibrant emerging
land market meant that the size and values of the plots began to diversify, leading to a
complex and diversified plot system.

105
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

CASE STUDY...CONTINUED

Diversity of plot sizes in New York: Madison square (left) & Brooklyn (right).

50
30

40

30 20
% of plots

% of plots
20
10

10
3%

250 to 500 m2 37%

250 to 500 m2 30%

500 to 1,000 m2 19%


Less than 100 m2 57%

250 to 500 m2 38%

1%

0%

0%

0%

Less than 100 m2 5%

1,000 to 2,000 m2 6%

2000 to 5,000 m2 3%

More than 5,000 m2 0%


0 0
250 to 500 m2

1,000 to 2,000 m2

2
500 to 1,000 m

2000 to 5,000 m

More than 5,000 m

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

The South African platting system is also made ing chart and map displaying characteristics
of the repetition of small plots. The original of Soweto, in which platting has not evolved
plot in Soweto is 200m on average. Howev- over a century. The distribution of plot sizes in
er, contrary to New York City, a series of finan- Hillbrow (inner city of Johannesburg), on the
cial, regulatory and fiscal barriers jeopardizes contrary, exhibits a diversification of the plot
consolidation and subdivision processes, and sizes. This plot subdivision, which has experi-
prevents the emergence of a sustainable and enced very little changes since the 1990s, tes-
efficient land market. A feedback loop is then tifies to the great vitality of land and property
created where the absence of an efficient markets before the 1990s in the inner city of
land market prevents the emergence of a di- Johannesburg.
versified platting. This is shown in the follow-

106
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

CASE STUDY...CONTINUED

Diversity of plot sizes in Johannesburg: Hillbrow (left) & Soweto (right).

40 70

60

30 50

40
% of plots

20

% of plots
30

10 20

10
250 to 500 m2 44%

250 to 500 m2 34%

500 to 1,000 m2 11%


Less than 100 m2 0%

1,000 to 2,000 m2 5%

2000 to 5,000 m2 4%

More than 5,000 m2 1%

250 to 500 m2 24%

250 to 500 m2 75%


0

Less than 100 m2 0%

500 to 1,000 m2 0%

1,000 to 2,000 m2 0%

2000 to 5,000 m2 0%

More than 5,000 m2 0%


0

Source: Urban Morphology Institute

A different example for diverse land use develop- The modernist typology of parallel slabs with emp-
ment can be found in Vietnamese cities. In Vietnam, ty space in between has been transformed into
social housing has been transformed spontaneously the much more complex typology of shop com-
and most of the time illegally. Therefore, these cities partments and commercial lanes where the street
can, of course, not be named as best practice cas- space is densely occupied by commercial or private
es for efficient legal frameworks. Nevertheless, the activities. People have re-urbanized the space be-
development of these cities shows that restrictive tween slabs and have partially privatized it. This is
zoning and land use regulations can prevent posi- where the principle of streets as places for people
tive natural development. It shows that, in the best and the issue of social inclusiveness and diversifi-
case, a functioning legal framework should allow cation of economy intersect.
for adaption and flexibility in land use.

107
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

4.5. The impact of urban nomic productivity of 1.063 to 1.07 with


planning characteristics regard to job density.
on the productivity level
Recent studies, however, state that these
4.5.1. Density and urban analyses overstate the role of density be-
productivity cause they do not account for the potential
biases introduced by sorting, whereby peo-
Various empirical studies on the impact of ple and firms with more valuable skills may
urban characteristics on productivity fol- locate themselves in denser places. Without
lowing an approach similar to the quanti- this potential bias, France, Combes et al.
tative model presented in this study - reveal (Combes et al., 2010) suggests an increase
that, among the urban planning indexes in productivity of 2 per cent to 3.5 per cent
examined, density has the greatest impact when job density doubles, which leads to
on the urban productivity of a Planned City an elasticity of the economic productivity of
Extension at city wide level (this is difficult 1.0285 to 1.050, with regard to job density.
to estimate at a neighbourhood level). The
level of residential, job and business densi- Low residential densities result in addition-
ty have an impact on Gross Value Added/
al costs to the community as it involves
km, CapEx/km and OpEx/km at the same
over-sizing of infrastructure networks. The
time65.
cost of automobile dependence related to
According to Ciconne and Hall (Ciccone urban sprawl in the United States is esti-
and Hall, 1996), over half of the variance mated at USD 184 billion per year, without
of output per worker across states within taking into account the costs of congestion
the United States can be explained by dif- and loss of tax revenue due to the space
ferences in the density of economic activity. used for traffic and parking (Osman, Nawa-
Cross-sectional analyses in the United States wi, and Abdullah, 2008). When comparing
indicate that a doubling of population den- a dense city such as Paris or Manhattan with
sity leads to a 6 per cent increase in income intra-muro 20,000 inhab/km, and a low
per capita, which corresponds to an elas- density city (5,000 inhab/km), per capita
ticity of 0.08466. The elasticity of income infrastructure costs increase sharply (World
per km with regard to density is thus equal Bank et al, 2014): they are multiplied by a
to 1.084. Models derived from aggregate factor of 4 for the road network, by 3 for
production functions and value-added data the waste water network, and increase by
for states in the USA and European regions 40 per cent for the water network. Resting
suggest that productivity increases by 4.5 upon a representative set of cities, the fol-
to 5 per cent when employment density is lowing charts provide a benchmark of the
doubled (Ciccone and Hall, 1996; Ciccone, elasticity of water, wastewater and street
2002), which leads to an elasticity of eco- networks lengths per capita with regard to
residential density:
65 CapEx is Capital Expenditures, OpEx is Operational Ex-
penditures
66 If the increase in productivity is 6% when density doubles,
the elasticity of productivity with regard to density is

108
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 18.
Infrastructure costs per capita and residential density
7
Water network per capita 2008

y = 37.111x-0.278
6
R = 0.48156
5
(m/cap)

0
0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000
Urban density (inhab/km)

18
16
Waste water network per capita

14
12
2008 (m/cap)

10
8
6 y = 3512.2x-0.792
4 R = 0.67526

2
0
0 5000 1000 15000 20000 25000
Urban density (inhab/km)

14

12
Road network per capita 1990 (m/cap)

10

4
y = 24005x-1.119
2 R = 0.86034
0
0 5000 10000 25000 20000 25000 30000
Urban density (inhab/km)

Source: Urban Morphology Institute and Muller et al. (2013)

Networks costs are assumed to be propor- Network costs per capita can be replaced
tional to network length, which leads to the by network costs per km using residential
following equations: density:

109
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

From these equations we derive the respective elasticity for the wastewater, water and street
network costs per km with regard to residential density: 0.722, 0.21 and -0.119.

FIGURE 19.
Energy use per capita for private transport and
residential density in a sample of 43 cities

70

60
Energy use per capita for private
transport 2000 (GJ/cap.y)

50

40

30

20 y = 17665x-0.823
R = 0.84667
10

*"
0 5000 10000 15000 20000 25000 30000 35000
Residential density (inhab/km)

Source: Bourdic 2011

4.5.2. Accessibility and urban productivity


The level of accessibility impacts the gross value added per km, the operational expendi-
tures per km and the capital expenditures per km. The impact of accessibility to transit
stations on residential land values can generally be seen across a relatively wide geographic
area with a radius of up to 2km to 4km from transit station (Steer Davies Gleave, 2011).
On the other hand, the impact on commercial and business property value is more limited
in space, with a radius of 500m to 1km (Steer Davies Gleave, 2011). This difference in land
value patterns around transit stations is shown in the following figures.

110
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 20.
Residential and commercial land value patterns around transit stations
erve.

station location
uilt land station location land
value value

y in

vidence residential commercial


and
or
Source: Steer Davies Gleace, 2011
dential
aphic
By figure 2.1 residential versus industrial land value patterns
A poor quality station and built environment can depress land values: while the evidence
generally supports a positive relationship between the presence of stations on land values, in
ation7, certain circumstances, the noise from trains and station users, pollution and the general un-
shows. sightliness of railway buildings can have a negative impact in the immediate station vicinity
(Steer Davies Gleave, 2011). Unattractive stations in the public realm with a lack of quality
investment tend to reduce land value in direct proximity to transit and, in certain cases,
cause crime to increase in the surrounding area. This leads to a volcano shaped pattern of
land values around stations, as shown in the following figure (Steer Davies Gleave, 2011).

FIGURE 21.
Volcano-shaped land value pattern around unattractive transit stations
nd to be
al property
alues in the
rty value: A
ally inflated. land station location
value
s004.
with all
result of the
ollution, noise
of station Page 37
her away from
much weaker,
tate values.

ys to be
ssibility
is pattern
particularly Source: Steer Davies Gleace, 2011
figure 2 volcano-shaped land value pattern
atic.

n can
targeted
111
pollution,
ether,
exist to
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

In a detailed review of literature on tran- For instance, the magnitude of this impact
sit accessibility, Wardrip (2001) shows that is likely to be greater in cities where transit
there is a general consensus that accessi- provides a clear benefit in terms of accessi-
bility to transit outweighs transit nuisance bility to economic opportunities. This is, for
and induces a premium on property prices example, the case in highly-congested cities
and rental value. However, there is no clear or cities with reliable and frequent transit
agreement on the magnitude of the impact systems (Agarwal, 2011). The following table
of transit accessibility on land value as it also presents several case studies quantifying the
depends on a number of exogenous factors. impact of transit accessibility on land value.

TABLE 2
Impact of transit accessibility on land value in four US cities

Goetz et al. (2010) Hiawatha Line in USD 5,229 premium for single-family homes within
Minneapolis half-mile radius catchment areas (4 per cent premium
on average). USD 15,755 for multifamily properties
(10 per cent on average)

McMillen and McDonald Midway transit line in 10 per cent premium on single family homes on the
(2004) Chicago long term
Knaap, Ding, and Hopkins Portland light rail line 31 per cent premium within half mile radius
(2001) catchment areas, 10 per cent within one mile radius
catchment areas

Immergluck (2009) Atlanta Beltline 15 per cent to 30 per cent increase in single family
homes prices within a quarter mile of transit,
compared to similar homes more than two miles from
transit.
(Des Rosiers, and Marius Commuter Rail Transit 1 per cent to 1.5 per cent for houses located less than
2012) in Montreal 1.5 km from the station.

Source: Authors

112
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

4.5.3. Accessibility and urban productivity

CASE STUDY
The impact of the Bus Rapid Transit TransMilenio
on property value in Bogot67
The TransMilenio is a Bus Rapid Transit scheme that was part of a broader, integrated
strategy to address mobility challenges, reclaim public spaces for pedestrians and in-
crease access to green space. The TransMilenio has been implemented in two phases,
with a first phase planned in 1998, built in 19992000 and launched in December
2000 along two corridors. Rodriguez and Mojica (2008) analysed the impact of this
first phase on property value, and show that properties served by TransMilenio ben-
efited from the extension: property prices increased more than the prices of control
properties in other locations (15 per cent to 20 per cent). The following figure shows
the evolution of property prices in Bus Rapid Transit-serviced areas and in control areas,
using a regression analysis to isolate the price variation identified from the effects of
inflationary pressures, differences in the supply of housing, or the impact of the Trans-
Milenio extension on housing prices.

Property price in Bus Rapid Transit-serviced areas and control areas

135

130

125
Property price (base 100 in 2001)

120

115

110

105

100

95

90

85

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Intervention areas Control areas

Source: ad. From Rodriguez and Mojica 2008

67 Adapted from Rodriguez and Mojica 2008

113
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

This study confirms the results of anoth- 4.5.4. Transit accessibility


er one by D. Rodriguez and Targa (2004), contributes to agglomeration
where the authors examined whether prop- economies
erty prices were related to proximity to the Last but not least, accessibility to transit im-
Bus Rapid Transit for 494 multi-family res- pacts on car ownership, annual mileage, en-
idential properties in a 1.5 km area of in- ergy consumption and household budgets,
fluence surrounding two TransMilenio cor- for the same level of services in terms of ac-
ridors. Rodriguez and Targa, 2004) show cess to economic opportunities, as shown in
a detailed review of the literature by Litman,
a premium of 6.8 per cent to 9.3 per cent
2013). In the United States, households
for every five minutes of walking time clos-
living within half-mile radius of the transit
er to a Bus Rapid Transit station. They also catchment areas own, on average, 0.9 cars
found that, for the properties located close per household , compared to 1.6 in US met-
to the busway but not close to TransMilenio ro regions. Additionally, those living within
stations, the negative externalities of the half-mile radius of the transit catchment
area commute, on average, only 54 per cent
transit infrastructure (noise and pollution)
by car, compared to 83 per cent in US metro
outweighed the accessibility benefits.
regions (America and Development, 2004).
Similarly, Goldstein, 2007) and Bailey, 2007)
Beyond the benefits in terms of land and
found that households living within walking
property value, several studies show that
distance of rail transit stations drive 30 per
transit accessibility contributes to agglom-
cent to 45 per cent less on average, saving
eration economies. According to Chat-
up to USD 1,920 of fuel per household per
mand and Noland, 2013), agglomeration
year. Similarly, McCann, 2000) finds that
economies induced by transit accessibility
households in car dependent urban areas
manifest themselves by significant impact
spend 50 per cent more for transportation
on wages and gross metropolitan product
than households benefiting from good ac-
per capita: Doubling transit service levels
cess to transportation. The figures are more
(using measures such as total seat capacity)
than USD 8,500 compared to less than USD
is associated with large increases in central
5,500 annually per household.
city employment density and consequent
wage increases ranging from 1.1 to 1.8 per
cent, or between USD 7 million and USD 4.5.5. Walkability indexes and urban
12 billion yearly per metropolitan area de- productivity
pending on the size of the workforce and
the starting average wage. Graham, 2007) The quality of public realm and the walk-
further investigates the links between ag- ing accessibility to a wide range of urban
glomeration economies and the provision amenities also has a great impact on the
of transport infrastructures and finds a posi- land value. In the US, the Transit Oriented
tive correlation, with elasticities of 0.119 for Development (TOD) index data released by
the economy as whole, 0.186 for the service Zillow makes it possible to analyze the evo-
sector and 0.077 for manufacturing. lution of home values between 1996 and
2013 around 4,400 stations across the US,
taking into account density, walkability and
proximity to urban amenities. Within the

114
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

4,400 stations across the US, three types realm and proximity to urban amenities on
of stations have been defined: Transit Ori- the growth of property values. For two sim-
ented Development, Hybrid and Transit Ad- ilar homes priced 100 in 1996, the home
jacent Development. Transit Oriented De- located in a Transit Oriented Development
velopment stations are characterized by a district is worth 400 in 2013, while a home
household density above 2,000 households/ located in a Transit Adjacent Development
km within the transit catchment area and a district is worth 225. This impact on rental
Walk Score above 70. Hybrid stations meet value is also very significant. For two simi-
at least one of these criteria, and Transit Ad- lar homes rented 100 in 2012, the increase
jacent Development stations do not meet in the rental value of the one located in a
either of these criteria. Transit Oriented Development district is of
18 per cent, while a home located in a Tran-
The following charts show the combined sit Adjacent Development district is of only
impact of density, walkability of the public 11 per cent.

FIGURE 22.
Average home value in the United States in transit oriented, hybrid and transit
adjacent areas, and national average, since 1996. Base 100 in April 1996.

400

350
Home value (per square foot)

300

250

200

150

100
Apr-96

May-97

Jun-98

Jul-99

Aug-00
Sep-01

Oct-02

Nov-03

Dec-04

Jan-06

Feb-07

Mar-08

Apr-09

May-10

Jun-11

Jul-12

Aug-13

Transit oriented Hybrid Transit adjacent

National average

Source: Urban Morphology Institute. Data: Zillow TOD index

115
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

FIGURE 23.
Average rental value in the United States in transit oriented, hybrid and transit
adjacent areas, and national average, since 1996. Base 100 in April 1996.

120
118
Rental value ($ per square foot per month)

116
114
112
110
108
106
104
102
100
Jan-12
Mar-12
May-12
Jul-12
Sep-12
Nov-12
Jan-13
Mar-13
May-13
Jul-13
Sep-13
Nov-13
Jan-14
Mar-14
May-14
Jul-14
Transit oriented Hybrid Transit adjacent

National average

Source: Urban Morphology Institute. Data: Zillow TOD index

Proximity to urban amenities also has a wide impact on household budgets, as shown in
the following chart. In Transit Oriented Districts, the budgets dedicated to housing and to
transportation are, respectively, 24 per cent and 13 per cent of the total household budget,
which amounts to a total cost of 37 per cent. In comparison, the households in transit adja-
cent districts spend respectively 27 per cent and 19 per cent of their budget for housing and
transportation, which amounts to 48 per cent of their total budget.

116
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 24.
Housing and transportation budget with regard to transit accessibility in US cities

Transit oriented 24% 13% 63%

Hybrid 24% 19% 57%

Transit adjacent 27% 22% 51%

Nation 33% 18% 49%

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

Average household budget percentage

Housing Transportation Other

Source: Urban Morphology Institute. Data: Zillow TOD index

Resting upon an extensive dataset for the US top 30 metros, Leinberger and Lynch (2014) pro-
vide a consolidated database that makes it possible to assess the impact of walkability on urban
productivity. Using office and retail data, as well as Walk Score, census data and economic data,
Leinberger and Lynch (2014) define walkable areas (WalkUP) in the 30 metros. The following
charts display urban productivity per capita and per km, with regard to the percentage of
office and retail space located in walkable areas. These figures show the correlation between
walkability and productivity, although the correlation with GDP per km is weaker.

FIGURE 25.
Urban productivity per capita (GDP/capita) and
walkability in the top 30 US metros.

80 y=72.003x + 36.686
R2 = 0.56475
70
per capta GDP (US$ thousand)

60
50
40
30
20
10
0
0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50%
% of office and retail space located in walkable areas

Source: Urban Morphology Institute. Data from (Leinberger and Lynch, 2014)

117
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

FIGURE 26.
Urban productivity per km (GDP/km) and walkability in the top 30 US metros.

180
160
140
GDP per km (US$ million)

y = 143.51x + 37.833
120 R = 0.2121
100
80
60
40
20
0
0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50%

% of office and retail space located in walkable areas

Source: Urban Morphology Institute. Data: Zillow TOD index

Compared to car-dependent urban environments, walkable Planned City Extensions induce


lower costs for the community. The following chart adapted from Litman (2009) shows the
additional costs for car dependent community compared to a community where walking is
possible, in terms of health, safety, traffic congestion, and pollution.

118
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

FIGURE 27.
Externalities of automobile compared to walking

Crashes

Parking

Traffic Congestion

Railway Facilities

Roadway Land Value

Municipal Services

Air Pollution

Noise

Resource Externalities

Barrier Effect

Land Use Impact

Water Pollution

Water Disposal

0.00 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.10 0.12 0.14


US$ per passenger-mile

Car - Urban peak Car - Average Walk

Source: Urban Morphology Institute, adapted from (Litman 2009).

Street design variables also have a significant hold true in developing country or rapidly
impact on vehicle kilometres travelled. This growing cities.
translates into energy costs for households
and can thus be considered as an important Building on the literature, the impact of
aspect of urban productivity per capita. street design variable on vehicle kilometres
travelled are as follows:
According to Ewing et al. (Ewing et al.,
2011), street design variables taken individ- Grid networks: a meta-analysis
ually have a limited impact on travel. How- conducted by Ewing and Cervero,
ever, the combined effect of all street design 2010) identifies three studies finding
variables on travel can be quite large. The a correlation between the percentage
last IPCC report on urban forms and climate of four-way intersections (grid-like
(IPCC, 2014) acknowledges that although
intersections) and vehicle kilometres
the literature is limited to developed or
travelled, with a weighted average
mature cities, there is robust evidence that
elasticity of -0.12. The proportion of
these conditions and relationships would

119
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

culs-de-sac within a street network Sidewalk coverage: For North American


also increases travel demand on arterial cities, the elasticity of walking with
roads by 75 per cent and on collector respect to sidewalk coverage or length
roads by 80 per cent, compared to a stands within the range of 0.09 to 0.27
43 per cent lower vehicle kilometres (Salon et al., 2012).
travelled with a gridded street design
Block size: Emrath et al., 2009)
(James Taylor Chair, 2001; Marshall and
show that the block size impacts on
Garrick, 2010).
walkability and commuting patterns.
Intersection density: Ewing and Households living in smaller blocks
Cervero, 2010) identify in six studies a walk and use transit 10 per cent more
correlation between intersection density for commuting than the average.
and vehicle kilometres travelled, with a
weighted average elasticity of -0.12. 4.5.6. Land use diversity and urban
In other terms, doubling the density productivity
of intersections leads to a decrease of
Several studies have shown the impact of
12 per cent in VKT (vehicle kilometre land use diversity on land and property val-
travelled). Network connectivity has a ue. Households are willing to pay more to
larger impact on VKT than density or live in neighbourhoods with other uses than
land use mix, between -0.06 and -0.26 residential, such as business services or lei-
(Ewing and Cervero, 2010; Salon et sure.
al., 2012). In Atlanta, the MARTRAQ
Project found that that doubling On the contrary, wholesale or manufactur-
current regional average intersection ing for instance, seem to have a negative
impact on land and property value. Studies
density, from 8.3 to 16.6 intersections
in the Netherlands (Koster and Rouwendal,
per square kilometre, would reduce
2012) show that households are willing to
average per capita weekday vehicle
pay up to 6 per cent more for a house in
travel by about 1.6 per cent, from
a mixed neighbourhood than for an other-
32.6 to 32.1 daily miles, all else held wise comparable house in a mono-function-
constant (Litman, 2013). In another al area.
meta-analysis Handy et. al., 2010)
found that the density of intersections But they also show that there is substan-
impacts on vehicle kilometres travelled tial heterogeneity in willingness to pay for
with an elasticity ranging from -0.06 mixed land use, depending on the housing
to -0.59. Marshall and Garrick show typology. For example, households living in
that holding other factors constant, apartments are willing to pay 25 per cent
more for mixed use than households living
increasing intersection density from
in detached housing (Koster and Rouwen-
31.3 to 125 intersections per square
dal, 2012). Song and Knaap, 2004) confirm
kilometre is associated with a 41 per
the contradictory impacts of mixed use on
cent decrease in vehicle travel, from
single family property value. Single family
44.7 to 26.5 daily vehicle-kilometres property value tends to increase with the
(Marshall and Garrick, 2010). amount of commercial land in the vicinity,

120
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

while it tends to decrease with the amount 2011, for different uses, from low density
of multi-family residential uses. In terms of mono-functional land to medium density
office property value, Cao and Cory, 1982) mixed use land.
suggest that mixed use contributes to prop-
erty value increases, while Sohn and Mou- In the first chart, the tax revenues per km
don, 2008) show a decrease in office prop- in absolute value range from USD 0.5million
erty values associated with an increase in per km for low density mono-functional
the proportion of retail uses. uses to more than USD 27million per km
for medium density mixed use neighbour-
Mixed use and diversity also significantly hoods. The second chart shows the same
impact municipal revenue, through the level figures, but calculated per floor area square
of property tax yielded. The two following metre, to remove the bias induced by the
charts compare the amount of property built density. In terms of property tax per
taxes raised by the municipality of Raleigh, m, 6 story mixed use yields 2.3 to 4.4 times
North Carolina, in the United States in more revenue than mono functional areas.

FIGURE 28.
Municipal tax revenue per kmand mixed use in Raleigh per km

Walmart 0.5

Single family residential 0.7

Crabtree Valley Mall 5.5

3-4 story residential 6.4

3 story office 7.4

6 story mixed use 27.3

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26

Municipal property tax yield in 2011 in Raleigh, NC (US$million per Km2)

Source: Adapted from (Fulton 2013)

121
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Beyond property value, Fillion et al., 2000) studies finding a correlation between land
suggest that mixed use centres in suburban use mix (entropy index) and VKT, with a
areas increase the potential and the dyna- weighted average elasticity of -0.09 and 4
mism of urban cores, making their case on finding a correlation between the job hous-
the Greater Toronto Area. Building on ex- ing ratio and vehicle kilometres travelled,
tensive data in the United Kingdom (8414 with a weighted average elasticity of -0.02.
onwards), Graham and Glaister, 2003) show Ewing et al. suggest that residents living in
that higher mixed use contributes to public neighbourhoods with high job housing ra-
health, by diminishing pedestrian casualties tios tend to have vehicle kilometres travelled
and fatalities. up to 15 per cent lower than the average
(Reid Ewing, DeAnna, and Li, 1996). In an-
Land use and the job-housing balance also other analysis, Frank and Pivo, 1994) show
contribute to decreasing travel distances that the trips having for destination a cen-
and the associated energy needs for trans- sus tracts with job housing ratios between
portation. The impact of mixed use on en- 0.8 and 1.2 (0.8 to 1.2 jobs per resident) ex-
ergy consumptions for transportation can hibited 29 per cent shorter trips than those
be even more important than that of ur- ending in census tracts with a less balance
ban density. The meta-analysis conducted job-housing ratio.
by Ewing and Cervero, 2010) identifies ten

122
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

5. Annex: modelling PCE characteristics on


urban productivity

5.1. The model


Some preliminary remarks must be made parameter is often in vain, and why the cor-
to define the scope and the area of validity relations between urban planning indexes
of this model. Although rooted in the aca- and urban productivity presented in this
demic field and building on a wide review report must always be understood as par-
of the literature, this model is not meant as tial correlation. This model is thus meant as
an academic one. It is not meant as a com- a tool to inform about policy making and
plete econometric model providing direct urban development. It aims at providing
and univocal correlation between planned quantitative evidence and basis on the rele-
city extension, legal framework, financial vance of urban planning, legal and financial
framework and urban productivity. Because frameworks on urban productivity.
cities and urban environment are complex
The benchmarks provided in this report do
physical and socioeconomic systems, the
not aim at being prescriptive but should fos-
correlations between urban planning in-
ter the policy-making and communication
dexes and urban productivity are never
process. Instead of exact target values, pre-
straightforward, as many factors which in-
scriptive ranges should be preferred.
tervene have an impact on productivity but
also have correlations among each other,
thereby inducing biases such as collineari-
FIGURE 29.
ty biases. According to Wagner (Wagner,
The necessary trinity of urbanization.
1999), the notion of causality can only be
meaningfully defined for systems with lin-
Legal
ear interactions among their variables. As Framework
cities are complex systems, the socioeco-
nomic and spatial variables examined in this
study are characterized through interaction The necessary
trinity of urban
among each other, through feedback loops
planning implies that
and non-linearities. legal framework, financial
framework and planned city
extension have to improve all together,
Furthermore, most of the urban planning
no one before another
indexes are correlated. As an example, cities
with high residential and job density often Planned City Financial
Extension Framework
display at the same time higher walkability
and transit accessibility. This is why trying
Source: Authors
to isolate the individual impact of a given

123
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

As this study aims at better understanding added per km in the area that has been
the benefits of the Three-Pronged Approach subject to the Three-Pronged Approach
on urban productivity, the model presented programme less the capital and operation-
in Figure 30 provides a framework to under- al expenditures per km and less the total
stand the importance of the three prongs over cost per km occurring in this area. The
that result on a necessary trinity for urban strength of this approach is that urban pro-
planning; this concept was inspired by the ductivity is decomposed into four compo-
impossible trinity concept derived from nents, on which the impact of each urban
monetary economics. The necessary trinity planning characteristic can be assessed.
for urban planning is a con-
cept that attempts to show
the importance of obtaining
=
2 2 2 2 2
parallel results in the three
prongs for the urban plan-
ning process.
The decomposition of urban productivi-
In practical terms, it means that the urbani- ty comes as follows, with the Gross Value
zation process is not going to be successful Added, the Capital Expenditure, Operation-
if there is a planned city extension and a fi- al Expenditures and Total Over cost occur-
nancial framework, but lacks the necessary ring according to augmented Cobb-Doug-
legal framework. If one of the three prongs las functions.
is missing or if one is relegated in compar-
ison to the other, even though it is difficult
to establish a homogeneous measure for 5.2. Modelling urban
the advancement for all of the prongs, the framework
urbanization development will not achieve In economic literature the Leontief produc-
the desirable level. The process has to occur tion function describes perfectly the nec-
in simultaneous stages for every one of the essary trinity explained on the section be-
components. fore. The Leontief production function was
derived from the utility function of perfect
As was mentioned before, it is the pur- complements; those are goods which utility
pose of this study to provide a framework is restricted by the goods that are consumed
to classify and measure the impact of dif- in the smaller proportion. In this case the
ferent characteristics of the Three-Pronged Urban Framework will be modelled by the
Approach on urban productivity. The urban Leontief function, the mathematical formal-
productivity is measured as the gross value ization of it is as follows:


= , ,
= Min ( , , )

124
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

The Liebigs law of the minimum is another theory that is adaptable to the Three Pronged Ap-
proach. The difference between the Leontief production function (complementary goods) and
the Liebigs law, is that Liebigs law states that growth is controlled not by the total amount of
resources available but by the scarcest resource (limiting factor). The two perspectives are useful
for modelling the outcome in terms of Urban Framework, both theories (Liebigs law and Leon-
tief production function) being described by a minimum function.

The graphical example with just two prongs will look as follow in Figure 30.

FIGURE 30.
Leontief function for two prongs, legal and financial framework.
Financial Framework

UF A

UF B

UF C

Legal Framework

Source: Authors

FIGURE 31.
Leontief functions for three prongs, planned
city extension, legal and financial framework.

As the model is designed for three


prongs, the Urban Framework has to
be visualised in three dimensions; still
Financial Framework

the Leontief function applies for this


case as the graphing axis are shown
in Figure 32.

n Legal Framework
nsio
Exte
ed City
n
Plan

Source: Authors

125
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Adapting the economical concept of preferences, we could assign two desirable properties
to the legal framework, the financial framework and the planned city extension. The prop-
erties assigned to the three prongs are complete68 and transitive69. In addition to that, we
are going to suppose that if an element A contained in any of the three prongs is at least as
preferred to an element B contained in any of the three prongs chosen before, then element
A is at least as expensive as element B. The assumptions mentioned before are formally seen
as follows:

As an example of the difference in costs we will consider the case of the legal framework:

( ) 0

In this particular case the outcome of the model is the Urban Framework, as it is modelled
by a Leontief function, the outcome will be determined by the function minimum.

Example 1

The government of the city AAA decided to improve its Urban Framework. For that they
hired an architectural firm to improve the Planned City Extension, turning it from a Planned
City Extension C to a Planned City Extension A. As the government of this city considers that
finance is a determining issue for applying the improvement in the Planned City Extension,
the government decides to upgrade the Financial Framework from C to B. The government
of city AAA considers the Legal Framework it already has is enough, so it leaves it as a Legal
Framework C.

After the investments, the consulting companys hand out its outcomes. The Urban Frame-
work will be described by the next equation:


, ) = Min ( , , )

The result of that equation will be an.

68 Completeness axiom: For every pair, either or both. An agent has complete preferences if he can compare any two objects.
69 Transitivity axiom: For every triple, if and then. An agent has transitive preferences if his preferences are internally consistent.

126
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

The additional costs are:

d =
=
= +

5.3. Modelling urban is important to note that with the elasticity


productivity only the positive effects can be expressed
which affect the value of the indicator has
The Yij, an urban capacity usage parameter, on the GVA, and not the negative effects
is the key in this model to link the Three- arising from it. The negative effects of char-
Pronged Approach to urban productivity, as acteristics of a 3PA programme will be tak-
it integrates the impact of all urban charac- en into account in the CapEx and OpEx and
teristics on urban productivity. The sub-in- Additional Costs
dex j stands for the urban region. Building
on the literature analysing urban produc- Job density for instance, which can be ar-
tivity (Sveikauskas, 1975; Carlino, Chatter- gued to have a positive correlation with the
jee, and Hunt, 2007; Abel, Dey, and Gabe, GVA, and to be an indicator of institutional
2012), we assume that the effects of urban capital, appears in the previous equation as
planning characteristics operate through follows:
the Hicks-neutral70 urban capacity usage
parameter as follows: ! ! !! !!
A!" = ! !" C! , !" C! , !"
!
! ! ! ! !
!" = ! !"! = ! C!"! C!,!"
!
C !"! C !"! Land use diversity for instance, which is a
!!!
component of institutional capital as well,
which also can be assumed to correlate pos-
with denoting the value of the technolo-
itively with the GVA, will appear in the pre-
gy parameter which is not related to urban
vious equation as follows:
planning matters, being the urban indica-
tor to characterize a 3PA programme i, in ! !! !
the urban region j, and being the elasticity A! = ! !"! land use diversity !" C!,!"
!

of GVA with respect to urban index . Even
though C is considered as one of the var- Abel et al. (2012) propose a model of urban
iables that compose the measurement of productivity of an urban region j to occur
urban productivity, another way of under- according to a human-capital augmented
standing C is interpreting it as one of the Cobb-Douglas production, this model was
many forms of capital: being K traditional the input for linking the gross value added
capital, H human capital, S social capital, I (GVA) to the technology parameter A which
institutional capital, and N natural capital. It contains the different forms of capital and
its positive impacts on the urbanization pro-
70 Following the Solow model, Hicks-neutral is a technical
change in the production function of a business or industry which cess. The function given is:
change does not affect the balance of labour and capital in pro-
duction function. Hicks-neutral urban capacity means that the citye GVA!" = Y!" Urban Framework !
ciechnical change keeps the share of labour and capital as given.

127
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Where Yij is a Hicks-neutral technology parameter, UF is the minimum function of planned


city extension, financial framework and legal framework, parameter represent the elastic-
ity of GVA with respect to UF.

For the sake of clarity, we will also assume that all the parameters will be brought to the
scale of 1km, which allows to switch from extensity variables such as the amount of jobs to
intensity variables such as the density of jobs.

5.4. Modelling capital and operational expenditures


As in the section above, a Cobb-Douglas function is used to model the impact of Three-
Pronged Approach on Capital (CapEx) and Operational Expenditure (OpEx) per km, as follows:

!
! !! !! ! !
CapEx!" = ! C !"! = ! C !" C !" C !"! C !"!
!!!
!
! !! ! ! !
OpEx!" = o! C !"! = ! C !" C!,!"
!
C !"! C !"!
!!!

with ! and o! denoting the factors with an impact on CapEx and OpEx, respectively. !"
denotes the characteristics of the 3PA programme i in the metropolitan region j with regard
to the urban indicator C; ! and o! represent the elasticity of CapEx and OpEx with respect
to the urban indicator C. !" As an example, the costs for the initial development of pave-
ment costs are taken into account as parts of CapEx, the maintenance costs for pavement
are added to the OpEx. Negative externalities such as congestion or energy consumption are
assigned monetary values and taken into account as parts of OpEx.

128
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

References
Abel, Jaison R., Ishita Dey, and Todd M. Scaling for Innovation in Cities. Physical
Gabe. 2012. Productivity and the Density Review E 79 (1): 016115. doi:10.1103/
of Human Capital*. Journal of Regional PhysRevE.79.016115.
Science 52 (4): 56286. doi:10.1111/j.1467-
Arzaghi, Mohammad, and J. Vernon
9787.2011.00742.x.
Henderson. 2008. Networking Off
Agarwal, Siddarth. 2011. The State of Madison Avenue. Review of Economic
Urban Health in India: Comparing the Poorest Studies 75 (4): 101138.
Quartile to the Rest of the Urban Population
AT Kearney 2012. Global Cities Index and
in Selected States and Cities. Environment
Emerging Cities Outlook. https://www.atke-
and Urbanization 23 (1): 1328.
arney.com/documents/10192/dfedfc4c-
Alonso, William, and others. 1964. Location 8a62-4162-90e5-2a3f14f0da3a.
and Land Use. Toward a General Theory of
Bailey, Linda. 2007. Public Transportation
Land Rent. Location and Land Use. Toward
and Petroleum Savings in the US: Reducing
a General Theory of Land Rent. http://www.
Dependence on Oil. ICF International. http://
cabdirect.org/abstracts/19641802976.html.
www.apta.com/resources/reportsandpubli-
America, Reconnecting, and Center for cations/documents/apta_public_transporta-
Transit-Oriented Development. 2004. tion_fuel_savings_final_010807.pdf.
Hidden in Plain Sight: Capturing the
Bertaud, Alain. 2002. Note on Urban
Demand for Housing Near Transit. Recon-
Transport and Cities Spatial Structures.
necting America.
ABDCE Conference April 2002.
Americas Barometer 2014. http://datasets.
Bettencourt, Lus M. A., Jos Lobo, Dirk
americasbarometer.org/database-login/
Helbing, Christian Khnert, and Geoffrey
index.html
B. West. 2007. Growth, Innovation,
Angotti, Tom, and Eva Hanhardt. 2001. Scaling, and the Pace of Life in Cities.
Problems and Prospects for Healthy Mixed- Proceedings of the National Academy of
Use Communities in New York City. Planning Sciences 104 (17): 73016. doi:10.1073/
Practice and Research 16 (2): 14554. pnas.0610172104.
doi:10.1080/02697450120077352.
Bourdic, Loeiz. 2011. Urban Density and
Arbesman, Samuel, Jon M. Kleinberg, and Private Transport Energy Consumption -
Steven H. Strogatz. 2009. Superlinear From Global Trends to Local Solutions.

129
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Center for Environmental Policy. London: Activity. American Economic Review 86


Imperial College. (1): 5470.

Carlino, Gerald A., Satyajit Chatterjee, and Cohen, Michael. 2009. Aid, Density, and
Robert M. Hunt. 2007. Urban Density and Urban Form: Anticipating Dakar. In Urban
the Rate of Invention. Journal of Urban Land Markets, edited by Somik V. Lall, Mila
Economics 61 (3): 389419. doi:10.1016/j. Freire, Belinda Yuen, Robin Rajack, and
jue.2006.08.003. Jean-Jacques Helluin, 38597. Springer
Netherlands. http://link.springer.com/
Cervero, Robert. 1996. Mixed Land-Us-
chapter/10.1007/978-1-4020-8862-9_15.
es and Commuting: Evidence from the
American Housing Survey. Transporta- Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Gilles Duranton,
tion Research Part A: Policy and Practice Laurent Gobillon, and Sbastien Roux.
30 (5): 36177. doi:10.1016/0965- 2010. Estimating Agglomeration Econ-
8564(95)00033-X. omies with History, Geology, and Worker
Effects. NBER Chapters. National Bureau of
Cervero, Robert, and Michael Duncan.
Economic Research, Inc. https://ideas.repec.
2008. Which Reduces Vehicle Travel
org/h/nbr/nberch/7978.html.
More: Jobs-Housing Balauce or Retail-Hous-
ing Mixing? http://escholarship.org/uc/ Da Mata, Daniel, Uwe Deichmann, J. Vernon
item/1s110395#page-1. Henderson, Somik V. Lall, and Hyoung Gun
Wang. 2005. Examining The Growth Patterns
Cervero, Robert, and K. Kockelman. 1997.
Of Brazilian Cities. World Bank Publications.
Travel Demand and the 3Ds: Density, Diver-
http://elibrary.worldbank.org/content/work-
sity and Design. World Transit Research,
ingpaper/10.1596/1813-9450-3724.
January. http://www.worldtransitresearch.
info/research/2186. OECD. 2015. OECD Green Growth Studies
Compact City Policies: Korea: Towards
Chatman, Daniel G., and Robert
Sustainable and Inclusive Growth. Paris:
B. Noland. 2013. Transit Service,
Organization for Economic Co-operation
Physical Agglomeration and Productiv-
and Development.
ity in US Metropolitan Areas. Urban
Studies, August, 0042098013494426. Duranton, Gilles, and Diego Puga. 2004.
doi:10.1177/0042098013494426. Micro-Foundations of Urban Agglomera-
tion Economies. In Handbook of Regional
Ciccone, Antonio. 2002. Agglomeration
and Urban Economics, edited by J. Vernon
Effects in Europe. European Economic
Henderson and Jacques-Franois Thisse,
Review 46 (2): 21327.
4:20632117. Elsevier.

Ciccone, Antonio, and Robert E. Hall. 1996.


Emrath, P, and N Sinianskaia. 2009. House-
Productivity and the Density of Economic
hold Type, Housing Choice, and Commut-

130
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

ing Behavior. Housing Economics. National Movement within Suburban Mixed-


Association of Home Builders. Use Centers: The Toronto Experience.
Journal of Urban Affairs 22 (4): 41938.
Ewing, R. 1998. Transportation and Land
doi:10.1111/0735-2166.00064.
Use Innovati. APA PRess.
Frank, L. D., and G. Pivo. 1994. Impact
Ewing, Reid, and Robert Cervero. 2010.
of Mixed Use and Density on Utilization
Travel and the Built Environment: A
of Three Modes of Travel: Singel Occupant
Meta-Analysis. Journal of the American
Vehicle, Transit, Walking. Transportation
Planning Association 76 (3): 26594.
Research Record, no. 1466.

Ewing, Reid, MaryBeth DeAnna, and


Fujita, M., and J.-F. Thisse. 1996. Econom-
Shi-Chiang Li. 1996. Land Use Impacts
ics of Agglomeration. Journal of the
on Trip Generation Rates. Transportation
Japanese and International Economies 10
Research Record: Journal of the Transporta-
(4): 33978. doi:10.1006/jjie.1996.0021.
tion Research Board, no. 1518: 16.
Fulton, W. 2013. Building Better Budgets
Ewing, R., M. Greenwald, M. Zhang, J.
| A National Examination of the Fiscal
Walters, M. Feldman, R. Cervero, L. Frank,
Benefits of Smart Growth Development.
and J. Thomas. 2011. Traffic Generated
Smart Growth America.
by Mixed-Use Developments-Six-Region
Study Using Consistent Built Environmental Glaeser, Edward L., and Matthew E. Kahn.
Measures. Journal of Urban Planning and 2010. The Greenness of Cities: Carbon
Development 137 (3): 24861. doi:10.1061/ Dioxide Emissions and Urban Develop-
(ASCE)UP.1943-5444.0000068. ment. Journal of Urban Economics 67 (3):
40418. doi:10.1016/j.jue.2009.11.006.
Feldman, M.P., and D.B. Audretsch. 1999.
Innovation in Cities: Science-Based Diver- Goldstein, David. 2007. Saving Energy,
sity, Specialization and Localized Compe- Growing Jobs: How Environmental Protec-
tition. European Economic Review tion Promotes Economic Growth, Profitability,
43 (2): 40929. doi:10.1016/S0014- Innovation, and Competition. Bay Tree Pub.
2921(98)00047-6.
Government of Nova Scotia (2015). Munic-
Fernald, John (1999) Roads to Prosperity? ipal Indicators Indicator Definition. http://
Assessing the Link between Public Capital novascotia.ca/dma/finance/indicator/defini-
and Productivity. The American Economic tions.asp?def=1.
Review. Vol. 89, No. 3 (Jun., 1999), pp.
Graham, Daniel J. 2007. Agglomeration
619-638
Economies and Transport Investment.
Filion, Pierre, Kathleen McSpurren, and OECD/ITF Joint Transport Research Centre
Nancy Huether. 2000. Synergy and Discussion Papers. Paris: Organisation for

131
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

Economic Co-operation and Development. Jean, Dub, Francois Des Rosiers, and
http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/content/work- Thriault Marius. 2012. Impacts of
ingpaper/234743465814. Commuter Rail Transit on Property Values
- The Montreal North Shore Case. ERES.
Graham, Daniel J., and Stephen Glaister.
European Real Estate Society (ERES). http://
2003. Spatial Variation in Road Pedestrian
econpapers.repec.org/paper/arzwpaper/
Casualties: The Role of Urban Scale, Density
eres2012_5f294.htm.
and Land-Use Mix. Urban Studies 40 (8):
15911607. doi:10.1080/0042098032000 Jenks, Michael, and Rod Burgess. 2000.
094441. Compact Cities: Sustainable Urban
Forms for Developing Countries. Taylor
Gutman, Pablo. 2007. Ecosystem
& Francis. https://books.google.fr/
Services: Foundations for a New Rural
books?hl=fr&lr=&id=ORmIB-l_nZ0C&oi=f-
urban Compact. Ecological Econom-
nd&pg=PR8&dq=compact+cities+-
ics 62 (3-4): 38387. doi:10.1016/j.
sustainable+urban+forms+for+devel-
ecolecon.2007.02.027.
oping+countries&ots=wtqCogMHM -
r&sig=C72kNeodneSH_tnX6eBA55_a3xg.
Henderson, Vernon, Ari Kuncoro, and Matt
Turner. 1995. Industrial Development in
Jofre-Monseny, Jordi; Marn-Lpez, Raquel;
Cities. Journal of Political Economy 103
Viladecans-Marsal, Elisabet 2012. What
(5): 106790. doi:10.1086/262013.
underlies localization and urbanization
economies? Evidence from the location
ILO 2013. Measuring informality: A statis-
of new firms. Universitat de Barcelona &
tical manual on the informal sector and
Institut dEconomia de Barcelona (IEB)
informal employment.

Kahn, Matthew E. 2009. Urban Growth and


IPCC. 2014. Chapter 12: Human Settle-
Climate Change. Annual Review of Resource
ments, Infrastructure and Spatial Planning,
Economics 1 (1): 33350. doi:10.1146/
In Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of
annurev.resource.050708.144249.
Climate Change.

Kajtazi, Bekim. 2010. Measuring Multi-


Irwin, Elena. 2004. Market Forces and
functionality of Urban Area: Advanced GIS
Urban Expansion. In James Taylor Chair.
Analysis for Measuring Distance, Density,
2001. Transportation and Community
Diversity and Time of Urban Services. Saar-
Design: The Effects of Land Use, Density
brcken: LAP LAMBERT Academic Publishing.
and Street Pattern on Travel Behaviour.
Technical Bulletin, no. 11.
Kamiya, Marco & Brian Roberts. Enhanc-
ing the Competitiveness of Cities, Discus-
Jacobs, Jane, 1961. The Death and Life
sion Paper No.3, Urban Economy Branch,
of Great American Cities. Vintage Books,
UN-HABITAT. Nairobi, Kenya. http://
New York.
unhabitat.org/enhancing-the-competitive-

132
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

ness-of-cities-discussion-paper-3/ tute. www.vtpi.org.

Knudsen, Brian, Richard Florida, Lobo, Jos; Bettencourt, Luis; Strumsky,


Kevin Stolarick, and Gary Gates. Deborah & Geoffrey B. West. 2011. The
2008. Density and Creativity in U.S. Economic Productivity of Urban Areas:
Regions. Annals of the Association of Disentangling General Scale Effects from
American Geographers 98 (2): 46178. Local Exceptionality SFI Working Paper:
doi:10.1080/00045600701851150. September 2011. California US.

Koster, Hans, and Jan Rouwendal. 2012. Marshall, Wesley E., and Norman W.
The Impact of Mixed Land Use on Residen- Garrick. 2010. Effect of Street Network
tial Property Values. SSRN Scholarly Paper Design on Walking and Biking. Trans-
ID 2177172. Rochester, NY: Social Science portation Research Record: Journal of the
Research Network. http://papers.ssrn.com/ Transportation Research Board 2198 (-1):
abstract=2177172. 10315. doi:10.3141/2198-12.

Lee, Chanam, and Anne Vernez Moudon. McCann, Barbara. 2000. Mean Streets
2006. The 3Ds+R: Quantifying Land Use 2000: Pedestrian Safety, Health and Federal
and Urban Form Correlates of Walking. Transportation Spending.
Transportation Research Part D: Trans-
McCormack, Edward, G. Scott Ruther-
port and Environment 11 (3): 20415.
ford, and Martina Wilkinson. 2001. Travel
doi:10.1016/j.trd.2006.02.003.
Impacts of Mixed Land Use Neighbour-
Leinberger, Christopher B., and Patrick hoods in Seattle, Washington. Transpor-
Lynch. 2014. Foot Traffic Ahead: tation Research Record 1780 (1): 2532.
Ranking Walkable Urbanism in Americas doi:10.3141/1780-04.
Largest Metros. http://trid.trb.org/view.
McKinsey Global Institute. 2011. Urban
aspx?id=1314064.
World: Mapping the Economic Power of
Litman, Todd. 2009. Transportation Cost Cities. McKinsey Global Institute.
and Benefit Analysis. Victoria Trans-
Merk, O, S Saussier, C Staropoli, E Slack,
port Policy Institute 31. http://www.
and J-H Kim. 2012. Financing Green Urban
researchgate.net/profile/Todd_Litman/
Infrastructure. OECD regional develop-
publication/235360398_Transportation_
ment working paper 2012/10.
Cost_and_Benefit_Analysis_Techniques_
Estimates_and_Implications/links/544a-
Metrolinx. 2013. Land Value Capture
94ca0cf2d6347f401152.pdf.
Discussion Paper.

. 2013. Land Use Impacts on Trans-


Mller, D.B., G. Liu, A.N. Lovik, R. Modaresi,
port. How Land Use Factors Affect Travel
S. Pauliuk, F.S. Steinhoff, and H. Brattebo.
Behavior. Victoria Transport Policy Insti-
2013. Carbon Emissions from Infra-

133
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

structure Development. Nature Climate Rodriguez, Daniel, and Felipe Targa. 2004.
Change. Value of Accessibility to Bogotas Bus Rapid
Transit System. Transport Reviews 24 (5):
Mousmoti, Maria and Crispi, Gianluca.
587610.
2015. Good Legislation as a Means
of Ensuring Voice, Accountability, and the Rosenthal, Stuart S., and William C. Strange.
Delivery of Results in Urban Development. 2004. Evidence on the Nature and Sources
The World Bank Legal Review Volume 6 of Agglomeration Economies. In Handbook
Improving Delivery in Development: The of Regional and Urban Economics, edited by
Role of Voice, Social Contract, and Account- J. Vernon Henderson and Jacques-Franois
ability. : 257-269. Thisse, 4:211971. Amsterdam; New York:
North-Holland; New York, N.Y., U.S.A.:
Ni, Pengfei; Kresl, Peter & Wei Liu (2013)
Elsevier. http://linkinghub.elsevier.com/
The Global Urban Competitiveness Report
retrieve/pii/S1574008004800063.
2013. Edward Elgard. Cheltenham, UK.
Salat, S, and L Bourdic. 2014a. Land Use
OECD. 2001. Measuring Productivity -
Intensification in Fine Grain Cities. Urban
OECD Manual. Paris: Organisation for
Morphology Institute Working Paper.
Economic Co-operation and Development.
http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/content/ Salat, S, and L Bourdic 2014b. Transform-
book/9789264194519-en. ing Johannesburg. Urban Morphology
Institute.
Osman, Shahriza, Abdul Nawawi, and
Jamalunlaili Abdullah. 2008. Urban Sprawl Salon, Deborah, Marlon G. Boarnet, Susan
and Its Financial Cost: A Conceptual Frame- Handy, Steven Spears, and Gil Tal. 2012.
work. Asian Social Science 4 (10): 3950. How Do Local Actions Affect VMT? A
Critical Review of the Empirical Evidence.
Ottensmann, John R. 1977. Urban Sprawl,
Transportation Research Part D: Trans-
Land Values and the Density of Develop-
port and Environment 17 (7): 495508.
ment. Land Economics, 389400.
doi:10.1016/j.trd.2012.05.006.

Puga, Diego. 2010. The Magnitude and


Satterthwaite, David. 2007. The Tran-
Causes of Agglomeration Economies.
sition to a Predominantly Urban World
Journal of Regional Science 50 (1): 20319.
and Its Underpinnings. Urban Change
doi:10.1111/j.1467-9787.2009.00657.x.
No. 4. Human Settlements Working
Papers Series. London: IIED. http://
Rodriguez, Daniel A., and Carlos H. Mojica.
pubs.iied.org/10550IIED.html?k=Ur-
2008. Land Value Impacts of Bus Rapid
ban-change&s=HSWP&b=d.
Transit: The Case of Bogotas TransMilenio.
Land Lines, April. http://trid.trb.org/view.
Sohn, Dong-Wook, and Anne V. Moudon.
aspx?id=850940.
2008. The Economic Value of Office

134
Planned City Extensions, Legal Framework, and Municipal Finance

Clusters An Analysis of Assessed Property Note 3. Nairobi, Kenya. http://unhabitat.


Values, Regional Form, and Land Use Mix org/a-new-strategy-of-sustainable-neigh-
in King County, Washington. Journal of bourhood-planning-five-principles/
Planning Education and Research 28 (1):
Van Cao, Than, and Dennis C. Cory. 1982.
8699. doi:10.1177/0739456X08321795.
Mixed Land Uses, Land-Use Externalities,
Song, Yan, and Gerrit-Jan Knaap. 2004. and Residential Property Values: A Reeval-
Measuring the Effects of Mixed Land Uses uation. The Annals of Regional Science 16
on Housing Values. Regional Science and (1): 124.
Urban Economics 34 (6): 66380.
Van de Walle, Steven 2005. Measuring
Spence, Michael, Patricia Clarke Annez, and Bureaucratic Quality in Governance Indica-
Robert M. Buckley, eds. 2008. Urbanization tors. Paper for the 8th Public Management
and Growth. Washington, DC: World Bank Research Conference Los Angeles.
Publications.
Wagner, Andreas. 1999. Causality in
Steer Davies Gleave. 2011. The Value of Complex Systems. Biology and Philosophy
Station Investment. 14 (1): 83101.

Sveikauskas, Leo. 1975. The Productivity of Wardrip, Keith. 2001. Public Transits
Cities. The Quarterly Journal of Economics Impact on Housing Costs: A Review of the
89 (3): 393413. doi:10.2307/1885259. Literature. Center for Housing Policy.

Transparency International 2014. Corrup- World Bank. 2003. World Development


tion Perceptions Index 2014: Full Source Report 2003: Sustainable Development in a
Description. http://files.transparency.org/ Dynamic World - Transforming Institutions,
content/download/1842/12378/file/2014_ Growth, and Quality of Life - Overview.
CPISources_EN.pdf 24711. The World Bank.

Turok, Ivan. 2013. Unleashing the Economic World Bank. 2009. World Development
Potential of Agglomeration in African Report 2009: Reshaping Economic Geogra-
Cities. doi:10.13140/2.1.2434.9447. phy. World Development Report. Washing-
ton, D.C.: World Bank.
UN-HABITAT, 2015 Planned City Exten-
sions: Analysis of Historical Examples. World Bank. 2013a. Planning, Connecting,
Nairobi, Kenya. http://unhabitat.org/books/ and Financing Cities--Now: Priorities for City
planned-city-extensions-analysis-of-histori- Leaders. Washington, DC: World Bank.
cal-examples/
World Bank. 2013b. Urbanization beyond
UN-HABITAT, 2014. A New Strategy of Municipal Boundaries: Nurturing Metropol-
Sustainable Neighbourhood Planning: itan Economies and Connecting Peri-Urban
Five principles Urban Planning Discussion Areas in India, February. https://openknowl-

135
Economic Foundations for Sustainable Urbanization: A Study on Three-Pronged Approach

edge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/13105. World Economic Forum (2015) Global


Competitiveness Report. Davos, Switzerland.
World Bank 2013c. The World Bank Inter-
[ http://www.weforum.org/ ]
governmental Relations and Subnational
Finance Thematic Group Decentralization World Bank, International Bank for Recon-
Indicators. struction and Development, and Develop-
ment Research Center of the State Council,
World Bank 2013d. Database of Politi-
P.R. China. 2014. Urban China: Toward
cal Institutions 2012. http://siteresourc-
Efficient, Inclusive, and Sustainable Urban-
es.worldbank.org/INTRES/Resourc-
ization. Washington DC
es/469232-1107449512766/DPI2012.xls

136
HS Number: HS/059/16E

United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-Habitat)


P.O. Box 30030, Nairobi 00100, KENYA
Telephone: +254-20-7623120, Fax: +254-20-7624266/7
Email: infohabitat@unhabitat.org

www.unhabitat.org

Вам также может понравиться