Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 19

The Economic History of Major League Baseball

Michael J. Haupert, University of Wisconsin La Crosse

The reason baseball calls itself a game is because its too screwed up to be a business
Jim Bouton, author and former MLB player

Origins
The origin of modern baseball is usually considered the formal organization of the New
York Knickerbocker Base Ball Club in 1842. The rules they played by evolved into the
rules of the organized leagues surviving today. In 1845 they organized into a dues paying
club in order to rent the Elysian Fields in Hoboken, New Jersey to play their games on a
regular basis. Typically these were amateur teams in name, but almost always featured
a few players who were covertly paid. The National Association of Base Ball Players was
organized in 1858 in recognition of the profit potential of baseball. The first admission
fee (50 cents) was charged that year for an All Star game between the Brooklyn and New
York clubs. The association formalized playing rules and created an administrative
structure. The original association had 22 teams, and was decidedly amateur in theory, if
not practice, banning direct financial compensation for players. In reality of course, the
ban was freely and wantonly ignored by teams paying players under the table, and
players regularly jumping from one club to another for better financial remuneration.

The Demand for Baseball

Before there were professional players, there was a recognition of the willingness of
people to pay to see grown men play baseball. The demand for baseball extends beyond
the attendance at live games to television, radio and print. As with most other forms of
entertainment, the demand ranges from casual interest to a fanatical following. Many
tertiary industries have grown around the demand for baseball, and sports in general,
including the sports magazine trade, dedicated sports television and radio stations, tour
companies specializing in sports trips, and an active memorabilia industry. While not all
of this is devoted exclusively to baseball, it is indicative of the passion for sports,
including baseball.

A live baseball game is consumed at the same time as the last stage of production of the
game. It is like an airline seat or a hotel room, in that it is a highly perishable good that
cannot be inventoried. The result is that price discrimination can be employed. Since
the earliest days of paid attendance teams have discriminated based on seat location,
sex and age of the patron. The first ladies day, which offered free admission to any
woman accompanied by a man, was offered by the Gotham club in 1883. The tradition
would last for nearly a century. Teams have only recently begun to exploit the full
potential of price discrimination by varying ticket prices according to the expected
quality, date and time of the game.
Baseball and the Media
Telegraph Rights

Baseball and the media have enjoyed a symbiotic relationship since newspapers began
regularly covering games in the 1860s. Games in progress were broadcast by telegraph to
saloons as early as the 1890s. In 1897 the first sale of broadcast rights took place. Each
team received $300 in free telegrams as part of a league-wide contract to transmit
game play-by-play over the telegraph wire. In 1913 Western Union paid each team
$17,000 per year over five years for the rights to broadcast the games. The movie
industry purchased the rights to film and show the highlights of the 1910 World Series for
$500. In 1911 the owners managed to increase that rights fee to $3500.

Radio

It is hard to imagine that Major League Baseball (MLB) teams once saw the media as a
threat to the value of their franchises. But originally, they resisted putting their games
on the radio for fear that customers would stay home and listen to the game for free
rather than come to the park. They soon discovered that radio (and eventually
television) was a source of income and free advertising, helping to attract even more
fans as well as serving as an additional source of revenue. By 2002, media revenue
exceeded gate revenue for the average MLB team.

Originally, local radio broadcasts were the only source of media revenue. National radio
broadcasts of regular season games were added in 1950 by the Liberty Broadcasting
System. The contract lasted only one year however, before radio reverted to local
broadcasting. The World Series, however has been nationally broadcast since 1922. For
national broadcasts, the league negotiates a contract with a provider and splits the
proceeds equally among all the teams. Thus, national radio and television contracts
enrich the pot for all teams on an equal basis.

In the early days of radio, teams saw the broadcasting of their games as free publicity,
and charged little or nothing for the rights. The Chicago Cubs were the first team to
regularly broadcast their home games, giving them away to local radio in 1925. It would
be another fourteen years, however, before every team began regular radio broadcasts
of their games.

Television

1939 was also the year that the first game was televised on an experimental basis. In
1946 the New York Yankees became the first team with a local television contract when
they sold the rights to their games for $75,000. By the end of the century they sold
those same rights for $52 million per season. By 1951 the World Series was a television
staple, and by 1955 all teams sold at least some of their games to local television. In
1966 MLB followed the lead of the NFL and sold its first national television package,
netting $300,000 per team. The latest national television contract paid $24 million to
each team in 2002.
Table 1: MLB Television Revenue, Ticket Prices and Average Player Salary 1964-2002

(real (inflation-adjusted) values are in 2002 dollars)

Total TV revenue(millions of $) Average ticket price Average player salary


Year
nominal real nominal real nominal real
1964 $ 21.28 $ 123 $ 2.25 $13.01 $ 14,863.00 $ 85,909
1965 $ 25.67 $ 146 $ 2.29 $13.02 $ 14,341.00 $ 81,565
1966 $ 27.04 $ 149 $ 2.35 $12.95 $ 17,664.00 $ 97,335
1967 $ 28.93 $ 156 $ 2.37 $12.78 $ 19,000.00 $ 102,454
1968 $ 31.04 $ 160 $ 2.44 $12.58 $ 20,632.00 $ 106,351
1969 $ 38.04 $ 186 $ 2.61 $12.76 $ 24,909.00 $ 121,795
1970 $ 38.09 $ 176 $ 2.72 $12.57 $ 29,303.00 $ 135,398
1971 $ 40.70 $ 180 $ 2.91 $12.87 $ 31,543.00 $ 139,502
1972 $ 41.09 $ 176 $ 2.95 $12.64 $ 34,092.00 $ 146,026
1973 $ 42.39 $ 171 $ 2.98 $12.02 $ 36,566.00 $ 147,506
1974 $ 43.25 $ 157 $ 3.10 $11.25 $ 40,839.00 $ 148,248
1975 $ 44.21 $ 147 $ 3.30 $10.97 $ 44,676.00 $ 148,549
1976 $ 50.01 $ 158 $ 3.45 $10.90 $ 52,300.00 $ 165,235
1977 $ 52.21 $ 154 $ 3.69 $10.88 $ 74,000.00 $ 218,272
1978 $ 52.31 $ 144 $ 3.98 $10.96 $ 97,800.00 $ 269,226
1979 $ 54.50 $ 135 $ 4.12 $10.21 $ 121,900.00 $ 301,954
1980 $ 80.00 $ 174 $ 4.45 $9.68 $ 146,500.00 $ 318,638
1981 $ 89.10 $ 176 $ 4.93 $9.74 $ 196,500.00 $ 388,148
1982 $ 117.60 $ 219 $ 5.17 $9.63 $ 245,000.00 $ 456,250
1983 $ 153.70 $ 277 $ 5.69 $10.25 $ 289,000.00 $ 520,839
1984 $ 268.40 $ 464 $ 5.81 $10.04 $ 325,900.00 $ 563,404
1985 $ 280.50 $ 468 $ 6.08 $10.14 $ 368,998.00 $ 615,654
1986 $ 321.60 $ 527 $ 6.21 $10.18 $ 410,517.00 $ 672,707
1987 $ 349.80 $ 553 $ 6.21 $9.82 $ 402,579.00 $ 636,438
1988 $ 364.10 $ 526 $ 6.21 $8.97 $ 430,688.00 $ 622,197
1989 $ 246.50 $ 357 $ 489,539.00 $ 708,988
1990 $ 659.30 $ 907 $ 589,483.00 $ 810,953
1991 $ 664.30 $ 877 $ 8.84 $11.67 $ 845,383.00 $ 1,116,063
1992 $ 363.00 $ 465 $ 9.41 $12.05 $1,012,424.00 $ 1,296,907
1993 $ 618.25 $ 769 $ 9.73 $12.10 $1,062,780.00 $ 1,321,921
1994 $ 716.05 $ 868 $ 10.62 $12.87 $1,154,486.00 $ 1,399,475
1995 $ 516.40 $ 609 $ 10.76 $12.69 $1,094,440.00 $ 1,290,693
1996 $ 706.30 $ 810 $ 11.32 $12.98 $1,101,455.00 $ 1,263,172
1997 $ 12.06 $13.51 $1,314,420.00 $ 1,472,150
1998 $ 13.58 $14.94 $1,378,506.00 $ 1,516,357
1999 $ 14.45 $15.61 $1,726,282.68 $ 1,864,385
2000 $ 16.22 $16.87 $1,987,543.03 $ 2,067,045
2001 $1,291.06 $ 1,310 $ 17.20 $17.45 $2,343,710.00 $ 2,378,093
2002 $ 17.85 $17.85 $2,385,903.07 $ 2,385,903

Notes: 1989 and 1992 national TV data only, no local TV included. Real values are calculated using Consumer Price Index.

As the importance of local media contracts grew, so did the problems associated with
them. As cable and pay per view television became more popular, teams found them
attractive sources of revenue. A fledgling cable channel could make its reputation by
carrying the local ball team. In a large enough market, this could result in substantial
payments to the local team. These local contracts did not pay all teams, only the home
team. The problem from MLBs point of view was not the income, but the variance in
that income. That variance has increased over time, and is the primary source of the gap
in payrolls, which is linked to the gap in quality, which is cited as the competitive
balance problem. In 1962 the MLB average for local media income was $640,000
ranging from a low of $300,000 (Washington) to a high of $1.2 million (New York
Yankees). In 2001, the average team garnered $19 million from local radio and television
contracts, but the gap between the bottom and top had widened to an incredible $51.5
million. The Montreal Expos received $536,000 for their local broadcast rights while the
New York Yankees received more than $52 million for theirs. Revenue sharing has
resulted in a redistribution of some of these funds from the wealthiest to the poorest
teams, but the impact of this on the competitive balance problem remains to be seen.

Franchise values

Baseball has been about profits since the first admission fee was charged. The first
professional league, the National Association, founded in 1871, charged a $10 franchise
fee. The latest teams to join MLB, paid $130 million apiece for the privilege in 1998.

Early Ownership Patterns

The value of franchises has mushroomed over time. In the early part of the twentieth
century, owning a baseball team was a career choice for a wealthy sportsman. In some
instances, it was a natural choice for someone with a financial interest in a related
business, such as a brewery, that provided complementary goods. More commonly, the
operation of a baseball team was a full time occupation of the owner, who was usually
one individual, occasionally a partnership, but never a corporation.

Corporate Ownership

This model of ownership has since changed. The typical owner of a baseball team is now
either a conglomerate, such as Disney, AOL Time Warner, the Chicago Tribune Company,
or a wealthy individual who owns a (sometimes) related business, and operates the
baseball team on the side perhaps as a hobby, or as a complementary business. This
transition began to occur when the tax benefits of owning a baseball team became
significant enough that they were worth more to a wealthy conglomerate than a family
owner. A baseball team that can show a negative bottom line while delivering a positive
cash flow can provide significant tax benefits by offsetting income from another
business. Another advantage of corporate ownership is the ability to cross-market
products. For example, the Tribune Company owns the Chicago Cubs, and is able to use
the team as part of its television programming. If it is more profitable for the company
to show income on the Tribune ledger than the Cubs ledger, then it decreases the
payment made to the team for the broadcast rights to its games. If a team owner does
not have another source of income, then the ability to show a loss on a baseball team
does not provide a tax break on other income. One important source of the tax
advantage of owning a franchise comes from the ability to depreciate player salaries. In
1935 the IRS ruled that baseball teams could depreciate the value of their player
contracts. This is an anomaly since labor is not a depreciating asset.
Table 2: Comparative Prices for MLB Salaries, Tickets and Franchise Values for
Selected Years

Nominal values
year Salary ($000) Average franchisevalue
Average ticketprice
minimum mean maximum ($millions$)
1920 5 20 1.00 0.794
1946 11.3 18.5 1.40 2.5
1950 13.3 45 1.54 2.54
1960 3 16 85 1.96 5.58
1970 12 29.3 78 2.72 10.13
1980 30 143.8 1300 4.45 32.1
1985 60 371.2 2130 6.08 40
1991 100 851.5 3200 8.84 110
1994 109 1153 5975 10.62 111
1997 150 1370 10,800 12.06 194
2001 200 2261 22,000 18.42 286
Real values (2002 dollars)
year Salary ($000) Average franchisevalue
Average ticketprice
minimum mean maximum ($millions)
1920 44.85 179.4 8.97 7.12218
1946 104.299 170.755 12.922 23.075
1950 99.351 336.15 11.5038 18.9738
1960 18.24 97.28 516.8 11.9168 33.9264
1970 55.44 135.366 360.36 12.5664 46.8006
1980 65.4 313.484 2834 9.701 69.978
1985 100.2 619.904 3557.1 10.1536 66.8
1991 132 1123.98 4224 11.6688 145.2
1994 131.89 1395.13 7229.75 12.8502 134.31
1997 168 1534.4 12096 13.5072 217.28
2001 202 2283.61 22220 18.6042 288.86

The most significant change in the value of franchises has occurred in the last decade as
a function of new stadium construction. The construction of a new stadium creates
additional sources of revenue for a team owner, which impacts the value of the
franchise. It is the increase in the value of franchises which is the most profitable part
of ownership. Eight new stadiums were constructed between 1991 and 1999 for existing
MLB teams. The average franchise value for the teams in those stadiums increased
twenty percent the year the new stadium opened.

The Market Structure of MLB and Players Organizations

Major League Baseball is a highly successful oligopoly of professional baseball teams.


The teams have successfully protected themselves against competition from other
leagues for more than 125 years. The closest call came when two rival leagues, the
established National League, and a former minor league, the Western League, renamed
the American League in 1900, merged in 1903 to form the structure that exists to this
day. The league lost some of its power in 1976 when it lost its monopsonistic control
over the player labor market, but it retains its monopolistic hold on the number and
location of franchises. Now the franchise owners must share a greater percentage of
their revenue with the hired help, whereas prior to 1976 they controlled how much of
the revenue to divert to the players.
The owners of professional baseball teams have acted in unison since the very beginning.
They conspired to hold down the salaries of players with a secret reserve agreement in
1878. This created a monopsony whereby a player could only bargain with the team that
originally signed him. This stranglehold on the labor market would last a century.

The baseball labor market is one of extremes. Baseball players began their labor history
as amateurs whose skills quickly became highly demanded. For some, this translated
into a career. Ultimately, all players became victims of a well-organized and obstinate
cartel. Players lost their ability to bargain and offer their services competitively for a
century. Despite several attempts to organize and a few attempts to create additional
demand for their services from outside sources, they failed to win the right to sell their
labor to the employer of their choice.

Beginning of Professionalization

The first team of baseball players to be openly paid was the 1869 Redstockings of
Cincinnati. Prior to that, teams were organized as amateur squads who played for the
pride of their hometown, club or college. The stakes in these games were bragging
rights, often a trophy or loving cup, and occasionally a cash prize put up by a
benefactor, or as a wager between the teams. It was inevitable that professional players
would soon follow.

The first known professional players were paid under the table. The desire to win had
eclipsed the desire to observe good sportsmanship, and the first step down the slope
toward full professionalization of the sport had been taken. Just a few years later, in
1869, the first professional team was established. The Redstockings are as famous for
being the first professional team as they are for their record and barnstorming
accomplishments. The team was openly professional, and thus served as a worthy goal
for other teams, amateur, semi-professional, and professional alike. The Cincinnati
squad spent the next year barnstorming across America, taking on, and defeating, all
challengers. In the process they drew attention to the game of baseball, and played a
key part in its growing popularity. Just two years later, the first entirely professional
baseball league would be established.

National Association of Professional Baseball Players

The formation of the National Association of Professional Base Ball Players in 1871
created a different level of competition for baseball players. The professional
organization, which originally included nine teams, broke away from the National
Association of Base Ball Players, which used amateur players. The amateur league folded
three years after the split. The league was reorganized and renamed the National
League in 1876. Originally, professional teams competed to sign players, and the best
were rewarded handsomely, earning as much as $4500 per season. This was good money,
given that a skilled laborer might earn $1200-$1500 per year for a 60 hour work week.

This system, however, proved to be problematic. Teams competed so fiercely for players
that they regularly raided each others rosters. It was not uncommon for players to jump
from one team to another during the season for a pay increase. This not only cost team
owners money, but also created havoc with the integrity of the game, as players moved
among teams, causing dramatic mid-season swings in the quality of teams.
Beginning of the Reserve Clause, 1878-79

During the winter of 1878-79, team owners gathered to discuss the problem of player
roster jumping. They made a secret agreement among themselves not to raid one
anothers rosters during the season. Furthermore, they agreed to restrain themselves
during the off-season as well. Each owner would circulate to the other owners a list of
five players he intended to keep on his roster the following season. By agreement, none
of the owners would offer a contract to any of these reserved players. Hence, the
reserve clause was born. It would take nearly a century before this was struck down. In
the meantime, it went from five players (about half the team) to the entire team (1883)
and to a formal contract clause (1887) agreed to by the players. Owners would
ultimately make such a convincing case for the necessity of the reserve clause, that
players themselves testified to its necessity in the Celler Anti-monopoly Hearings in
1951.

In 1892 the minor league teams agreed to a system that allowed the National League
teams to draft players from their teams. This agreement was in response to their failure
to get the NL to honor their reserve clause. In other words, what was good for the
goose, was not good for the gander. While NL owners agreed to honor their reserve lists
among one another, they paid no such honor to the reserve lists of teams in other
organized, professional leagues. They believed they were at the top of the pyramid,
where all the best players should be, and therefore they would get those players when
they wanted them. As part of the draft agreement, the minor league teams allowed the
NL teams to select players from their roster for fixed payments. The NL sacrificed some
money, but restored a bit of order to the process, not to mention eliminated expensive
bidding wars among teams for the services of players from the minor league teams.

The Players League

The first revolt by the players came in 1890, when they formed their own league, called
the Players League, to compete with the National League and its rival, the American
Association (AA), founded in 1882. The Players League was the first and only example of
a cooperative league. The league featured profit sharing with players, an abolition of
unilateral contract transfers, and no reserve clause. The competing league caused a
bidding war for talent, leading to salary increases for the best players. The war ended
after just one season, when the National League and American Association agreed to
allow owners of some Players League teams to buy existing franchises. The following
year, the NL and AA merged by buying out four AA franchises for $130,000 and merging
the other four into the National League, to form a single twelve-team circuit.

Syndicates

This proved to be an unwieldy league arrangement however, and some of the franchises
proved financially unstable. In order to preserve the structure of the league and avoid
bankruptcy of some teams, syndicate ownership evolved, in which owners purchased a
controlling interest in two teams. This did not help the stability of the league. Instead,
it became a situation in which the syndicates used one team to train young players and
feed the best of them to the other team. This period in league history exhibits some of
the greatest examples of disparity between the best and worst teams in the league. In
1899 the Cleveland Spiders, the poor stepsister in the Cleveland-St. Louis syndicate,
would lose a record 134 out of 154 games, a level of futility that has never been
equaled. In 1900 the NL reduced to eight teams, buying out four of the existing
franchises (three of the original AA franchises) for $60,000.

Western League Competes with National League

Syndicate ownership was ended in 1900 as the final part of the reorganization of the NL.
It also sparked the minor Western League to declare major league status, and move
some teams into NL markets for direct competition (Chicago, Boston, St. Louis,
Philadelphia and Manhattan). All out competition followed in 1901, complete with roster
raiding, salary increases, and team jumping, much to the benefit of the players.
Syndicate ownership appeared again in 1902 when the owners of the Pittsburgh franchise
purchased an interest in the Philadelphia club. Owners briefly entertained the idea of
turning the entire league into a syndicate, transferring players to the market where they
might be most valuable. The idea was dropped, however, for fear that the game would
lose credibility and result in a decrease in attendance. In 1910 syndicate ownership was
formally banned, though it did occur again in 2002, when the Montreal franchise was
purchased by the other 29 MLB franchises as part of a three way franchise swap involving
Boston, Miami and Montreal. MLB is currently looking to sell the franchise and move it to
a more profitable market.

National and American Leagues End Competition

Team owners quickly saw the light, and in 1903 they made an agreement to honor one
anothers rosters. Once more the labor wars were ended, this time in an agreement that
would establish the major leagues as an organization of two cooperating leagues: the
National League and the American League, each with eight teams, located in the largest
cities east of the Mississippi (with the exception of St. Louis), and each league honoring
the reserved rosters of teams in the other. This structure would prove remarkably
stable, with no changes until 1953 when the Boston Braves became the first team to
relocate in half a century when they moved to Milwaukee.

Franchise Numbers and Movements

The location and number of franchises has been a tightly controlled issue for teams since
leagues were first organized. Though franchise movements were not rare in the early
days of the league, they have always been under the control of the league, not the
individual franchise owners. An owner is accepted into the league, but may not change
the location of his or her franchise without the approval of the other members of the
league. In addition, moving the location of a franchise within the vicinity of another
franchise requires the permission of the affected franchise. As a result, MLB franchises
have been very stable over time in regard to location. The size of the league has also
been stable. From the merger of the AL and NL in 1903 until 1961, the league retained
the same sixteen teams. Since that time, expansion has occurred fairly regularly,
increasing to its present size of 30 teams with the latest round of expansion in 1998. In
2001, the league proposed going in the other direction, suggesting that it would contract
by two teams in response to an alleged fiscal crisis and breakdown in competitive
balance. Those plans were postponed at least four years by the labor agreement signed
in 2002.
Table 3: MLB Franchise Sales Data by Decade

Average annual rate of


Average annual rate of Average tenure of
Average purchase price in return on DJIA (includes Number of franchise
Decade increase in franchise ownership of MLB
millions (2002 dollars) capital appreciation and sales
sales price franchisein years
annual dividends)

1910s .585(10.35) 6 6
1920s 1.02(10.4) 5.7 14.8 12 9
1930s .673(8.82) -4.1 - 0.3 19.5 4
1940s 1.56(15.6) 8.8 10.8 15.5 11
1950s 3.52(23.65) 8.5 16.7 13.5 10
1960s 7.64(43.45) 8.1 7.4 16 10
1970s 12.62(41.96) 5.1 7.7 10 9
1980s 40.7(67.96) 12.4 14.0 11 12
1990s 172.71(203.68) 15.6 12.6 15.8 14

Note: 2002 values calculated using the Consumer Price Index for decade midpoint

Negro Leagues

Separate professional leagues for African Americans existed, since they were excluded
from participating in MLB until 1947 when Jackie Robinson broke the color barrier. The
first was formed in 1920, and the last survived until 1960, though their future was
doomed by the integration of the major and minor leagues.

Relocations

As revenues dried up or new markets beckoned due to shifts in population and the
decreasing cost of trans-continental transportation, franchises began relocating in the
second half of the twentieth century. The period from 1953-1972 saw a spate of
franchise relocation: teams moved to Kansas City, Minneapolis, Baltimore, Los Angeles,
Oakland, Dallas and San Francisco in pursuit of new markets. Most of these moves
involved one team moving out of a market it shared with another team. The last team to
relocate was the Washington D.C. franchise, which moved to suburban Dallas in 1972. It
was the second time in just over a decade that a franchise had moved from the nations
capitol. The original franchise, a charter member of the American League, had moved to
Minneapolis in 1961. While there have been no relocations since then, there have been
plenty of examples of threats to relocate. The threat to relocate has frequently been
used by a team trying to get a new stadium built with public financing.

There were still a couple of challenges to the reserve clause. Until the 1960s, these
came in the form of rival leagues creating competition for players, not a challenge to
the legality of the reserve clause.

Federal League and the 1922 Supreme Court Antitrust Exemption

In 1914 the Federal League debuted. The new league did not recognize the reserve
clause of the existing leagues, and raided their rosters, successfully luring some of the
best players to the rival league with huge salary increases. Other players benefited from
the new competition, and were able to win handsome raises from their NL and AL
employers in return for not jumping leagues. The Federal League folded after two
seasons when some of the franchise owners were granted access to the major leagues.
No new teams were added, but a few owners were allowed to purchase existing NL and
AL teams.

The first attack on the organizational structure of the major leagues to reach the US
Supreme Court occurred when the shunned owner of the Baltimore club of the Federal
League sued major league baseball for violation of antitrust law. Federal Baseball Club
of Baltimore v the National League eventually reached the Supreme Court, where in
1922 the famous decision that baseball was not interstate commerce, and therefore was
exempt from antitrust laws was rendered.

Early Strike and Labor Relations Problems

The first player strike actually occurred in 1912. The Detroit Tigers, in a show of unison
for their embattled star Ty Cobb, refused to play in protest of what they regarded as an
unfair suspension of Cobb, refusing to take the field unless the suspension was lifted.
When warned that the team faced the prospect of a forfeit and a $5000 fine if they did
not field a team, owner Frank Navin recruited local amateur players to suit up for the
Tigers. The results were not surprising: a 24-2 victory for the visiting Philadelphia
Athletics.

This was not an organized strike against the system per se, but it was indicative of the
problems existent in the labor relations between players and owners. Cobbs suspension
was determined by the owner of the team, with no chance for a hearing for Cobb, and
with no guidance from any existing labor agreement regarding suspensions. The owner
was in total control, and could mete out whatever punishment for whatever length he
deemed appropriate.

Mexican League

The next competing league appeared in 1946 from an unusual source: Mexico. Again, as
in previous league wars, the competition benefited the players. In this case the players
who benefited most were those players who were able to use Mexican League offers as
leverage to gain better contracts from their major league teams. Those players who
accepted offers from Mexican League teams would ultimately regret it. The league was
under-financed, the playing and travel conditions far below major league standards, and
the wrath of the major leagues deep. When the first paychecks were missed, the players
began to head back to the U.S. However, they found no jobs waiting for them. Major
League Baseball Commissioner Happy Chandler blacklisted them from the league. This
led to a lawsuit, Gardella v MLB. The case was eventually settled out of court after a
Federal Appeals court sided with Danny Gardella in 1949. Gardella was one of the
blacklisted players who sued MLB for restraint of trade after being prevented from
returning to the league after accepting a Mexican League offer for the 1946 season.
While many of the players ultimately returned to the major leagues, they lost several
years of their careers in the process.
Player Organizations
The first organization of baseball players came in 1885, in part a response to the reserve
clause enacted by owners. The National Brotherhood of Professional Base Ball Players
was not particularly successful however. In fact, just two years later, the players agreed
to the reserve clause, and it became a part of the standard players contract for the next
90 years.

In 1900 another player organization was founded, the Players Protective Association.
Competition broke out the next year, when the Western League declared itself a major
league, and became the American League. It would merge with the National League for
the 1903 season, and the brief period of roster raiding and increasing player salaries
ended, as both leagues agreed to recognize one anothers rosters and reserve clauses.
The Players Protective Association faded into obscurity amid the brief period of
increased competition and player salaries.

Failure and Consequences of the American Baseball Guild

In 1946 the foundation was laid for the current Major League Baseball Players
Association (MLBPA). Labor lawyer Robert Murphy created the American Baseball Guild, a
players organization, after holding secret talks with players. Ultimately, the players
voted not to form a union, and instead followed the encouragement of the owners, and
formed their own committee of player representatives to bargain directly with the
owners. The outcome of the negotiations was changes in the standard labor contract. Up
to this point, the contract had been pretty much dictated by the owners. It contained
such features as the right to waive a player with only ten days notice, the right to
unilaterally decrease salary from one year to the next by any amount, and of course the
reserve clause.

The players did not make major headway with the owners, but they did garner some
concessions. Among them were a maximum pay cut of 25%, a minimum salary of $5000, a
promise by the owners to create a pension plan, and $25 per week in living expenses for
spring training camp. Until 1947, players received only expense money for spring
training, no salary. The players today, despite their multimillion-dollar contracts, still
receive Murphy money for spring training as well as a meal allowance for each day
they are on the road traveling with the club.

Facing eight antitrust lawsuits in 1950, MLB requested Congress to pass a general
immunity bill for all professional sports leagues. The request ultimately led to MLBs
inclusion in the Celler Anti-monopoly hearings in 1951. However, no legislative action
was recommended. In fact, the owners by this time had so thoroughly convinced the
players of the necessity of the reserve clause to the very survival of MLB that several
players testified in favor of the monopsonistic structure of the league. They cited it as
necessary to maintain the competitive balance among the teams that made the league
viable. In 1957 the House Antitrust Subcommittee revisited the issue, once again
recommending no change in the status quo.
Impacts of the Reserve Clause

Simon Rottenberg was the first economist to seriously look into professional baseball
with the publication of his classic 1956 article The Baseball Players Labor Market. His
conclusion, not surprisingly, was that the reserve clause transferred wealth from the
players to owners, but had only a marginal impact on where the best players ended up.
They would end up playing for the teams in the market in the best position to exploit
their talents for the benefit of paying customers in other words, the biggest markets:
primarily New York. Given the quality of the New York teams (one in Manhattan, one in
the Bronx and one in Brooklyn) during the era of Rottenbergs study, his conclusion
seems rather obvious. During the decade preceding his study, the three New York teams
consistently performed better than their rivals. The New York Yankees won eight of ten
American League pennants, and the two National League New York entries won eight of
ten NL pennants (six for the Brooklyn Dodgers, two for the New York Giants).

Foundation of the Major League Baseball Players Association

The current players organization, the Major League Baseball Players Association, was
formed in 1954. It remained in the background, however, until the players hired Marvin
Miller in 1966 to head the organization. Hiring Miller, a former negotiator for the U.S.
steel workers, would turn out to be a stroke of genius. Miller began with a series of
small gains for players, including increases in the minimum salary, pension contributions
by owners and limits to the maximum salary reduction owners could impose. The first
test of the big item the reserve clause reached the Supreme Court in 1972.

Free Agency, Arbitration and the Reserve Clause


Curt Flood

Curt Flood, a star player for the St. Louis Cardinals, had been traded to the Philadelphia
Phillies in 1970. Flood did not want to move from St. Louis, and informed both teams
and the commissioners office that he did not intend to leave. He would play out his
contract in St. Louis. Commissioner Bowie Kuhn ruled that Flood had no right to act in
this way, and ordered him to play for Philadelphia, or not play at all. Flood chose the
latter and sued MLB for violation of antitrust laws. The case reached the Supreme Court
in 1972, and the court sided with MLB in Flood v. Kuhn. The court acknowledged that the
1922 ruling that MLB was exempt from antitrust law was an anomaly and should be
overturned, but it refused to overturn the decision itself, arguing instead that if
Congress wanted to rectify this anomaly, they should do so. Therefore the court stood
pat, and the owners felt the case was settled permanently: the reserve clause had once
again withstood legal challenge. They could not, however, have been more badly
mistaken. While the reserve clause never has been overturned in a court of law, it would
soon be drastically altered at the bargaining table, and ultimately lead to a revolution in
the way baseball talent is dispersed and revenues are shared in the professional sports
industry.

Curt Flood lost the legal battle, but the players ultimately won the war, and are no
longer restrained by the reserve clause beyond the first two years of their major league
contract. In a series of labor market victories beginning in the wake of the Flood
decision in 1972 and continuing through the rest of the century, the players won the
right to free agency (i.e. to bargain with any team for their services) after six years of
service, escalating pension contributions, salary arbitration (after two to three seasons,
depending on their service time), individual contract negotiations with agent
representatives, hearing committees for disciplinary actions, reductions in maximum
salary cuts, increases in travel money and improved travel conditions, the right to have
disputes between players and owners settled by an independent arbitrator, and a limit
to the number of times their contract could be assigned to a minor league team. Of
course the biggest victory was free agency.

Impact of Free Agency Salary Gains

The right to bargain with other teams for their services changed the landscape of the
industry dramatically. No longer were players shackled to one team forever, subject to
the whims of the owner for their salary and status. Now they were free to bargain with
any and all teams. The impact on salaries was incredible. The average salary
skyrocketed from $45,000 in 1975 to $289,000 in 1983.

Table 4: Maximum and Average MLB Player Salaries by Decade

(real values in 2002 dollars)

Period Highest Salary Year Player Team Aver


Nominal Real Nominal
1800s $ 12,500.00 $ 246,250.00 1892 King Kelly Boston NL $ 3,054
1900s $ 10,000.00 $ 190,000.00 1907 Honus Wagner Pittsburgh Pirates $ 6,523
1910s $ 20,000.00 $ 360,000.00 1913 Frank Chance New York Yankees $ 2,307

1920s $ 80,000.00 $ 717,600.00 1927 Ty Cobb Philadelphia Athletics $ 6,992

1930s $ 84,098.33 $899,852 1930 Babe Ruth New York Yankees $ 7,748

1940s $ 100,000.00 $755,000 1949 Joe DiMaggio New York Yankees $ 11,197

1950s $ 125,000.00 $772,500 1959 Ted Williams Boston Red Sox $ 12,340

1960s $ 111,000.00 $572,164.95 1968 Curt Flood St. Louis Cardinals $ 18,568
1970s $ 561,500.00 $1,656,215.28 1977 Mike Schmidt Philadelphia Phillies $ 55,802
Orel Hershiser, Frank
1980s $ 2,766,666.00 $4,006,895.59 1989 Dodgers, Twins $ 333,686
Viola
1990s $11,949,794.00 $ 12,905,777.52 1999 Albert Belle Baltimore Orioles $1,160,548
2000s $22,000,000.00 $22,322,742.55 2001 Alex Rodriguez Texas Rangers $2,165,627

Real values based on 2002 Consumer Price Index.

Over the long haul, the changes have been even more dramatic. The average salary
increased from $45,000 in 1975 to $2.4 million in 2002, while the minimum salary
increased from $6000 to $200,000 and the highest paid player increased from $240,000
to $22 million. This is a 5200% increase in the average salary. Of course, not all of that
increase is due to free agency. Revenues increased during this period by nearly 1800%
from an average of $6.4 million to $119 million, primarily due to the 2800% increase in
television revenue over the same period. Ticket prices increased by 439% while
attendance doubled (the number of MLB teams increased from 24 to 30).
Strikes and Lockouts

Miller organized the players and unified them as no one had done before. The first test
of their resolve came in 1972, when the owners refused to bargain on pension and salary
issues. The players responded by going out on the first league-wide strike in American
professional sports history. The strike began during spring training, and carried on into
the season. The owners finally conceded in early April after nearly 100 games were lost
to the strike. The labor stoppage became the favorite weapon of the players, who would
employ it again in 1981, 1985, and 1994. The latter strike cancelled the World Series for
the first time since 1904, and carried on into the 1995 season. The owners preempted
strikes in two other labor disputes, locking out the players in 1976 and 1989. After each
work stoppage, the players won the concessions they demanded and fended off attempts
by owners to reverse previous player gains, particularly in the areas of free agency and
arbitration. From the first strike in 1972 through 1994, every time the labor agreement
between the two sides expired, a work stoppage ensued. In August of 2002 that pattern
was broken when the two sides agreed to a new labor contract for the first time without
a work stoppage.

Catfish Hunter

The first player to become a free agent did so due to a technicality. In 1974 Catfish
Hunter, a pitcher for the Oakland Athletics, negotiated a contract with the owner,
Charles Finley, which required Finley to make a payment into a trust fund for Hunter on
a certain date. When Finley missed the date, and then tried to pay Hunter directly
instead of honoring the clause, Hunter and Miller filed a complaint charging the contract
should be null and void because Finley had broken it. The case went to an arbitrator who
sided with Hunter and voided the contract, making Hunter a free agent. In a bidding
frenzy, Hunter ultimately signed what was then a record contract with the New York
Yankees. It set precedents for both its length five years guaranteed, and its annual
salary of $750,000. Prior to the dawning of free agency, it was a rare circumstance for a
player to get anything more than a one-year contract, and a guaranteed contract was
virtually unheard of. If a player was injured or fell off in performance, an owner would
slash his salary or release him and vacate the remainder of his contract.
The End of the Reserve Clause Messersmith and McNally

The first real test of the reserve clause came in 1975, when, on the advice of Miller,
Andy Messersmith played the season without signing a contract. Dave McNally also
refused to sign a contract, though he had unofficially retired at the time. Up to this
time, the reserve clause meant that a team could renew a players contract at their
discretion. The only changes in this clause that occurred since 1879 were the maximum
amount by which the owner could reduce the players salary. In order to test the clause,
which allowed teams to maintain contractual rights to players in perpetuity, Messersmith
and McNally refused to sign contracts. Their teams automatically renewed their
contracts from the previous season, per the reserve clause. The argument the players
put forth was that if no contract was signed, then there was no reserve clause. They
argued that Messersmith and McNally would be free to negotiate with any team at the
end of the season. The reserve clause was struck down by arbitrator Peter Seitz on Dec.
23, 1975, clearing the way for players to become free agents and sell their services to
the highest bidder. Messersmith and McNally became the first players to challenge and
successfully escape the reserve clause. The baseball labor market changed permanently
and dramatically in favor of the players, and has never turned back.

Current Labor Arrangements

The baseball labor market as it exists today is a result of bargaining between owners and
players. Owners ultimately conceded the reserve clause and negotiated a short period of
exclusivity for a team with a player. The argument they put forward was that the cost of
developing players was so high, they needed a window of time when they could recoup
those investments. The existing situation allows them six years. A player is bound to his
original team for the first six years of his MLB contract, after which he can become a
free agent though some players bargain away that right by signing long-term contracts
before the end of their sixth year.

During that six-year period however, players are not bound to the salary whims of the
owners. The minimum salary will rise to $300,000 in 2003, there is a 10% maximum
salary cut from one year to the next, and after two seasons players are eligible to have
their contract decided by an independent arbitrator if they cannot come to an
agreement with the team.

Arbitration

After their successful strike in 1972, the players had increased their bargaining position
substantially. The next year they claimed a major victory when the owners agreed to a
system of salary arbitration for players who did not yet qualify for free agency.
Arbitration was won by the players at in 1973, and has since proved to be one of the
costliest concessions the owners ever made. Arbitration requires each side to submit a
final offer to an arbitrator, who must then choose one or the other offer. The arbitrator
may not compromise on the offers, but must choose one. Once chosen, both sides are
then obligated to accept that contract.

Once eligible for arbitration, a player, while not a free agent, does stand to reap a
financial windfall. If a player and owner (realistically, a players agent and the owners
agent the general manager) cannot agree on a contract, either side may file for
arbitration. If the other does not agree to go to arbitration, then the player becomes a
free agent, and may bargain with any team. If arbitration is accepted, then both sides
are bound to accept the contract awarded by the arbitrator. In practice, most of the
contracts are settled before they reach the arbitrator. A player will file for arbitration,
both sides will submit their final contract offers to the arbitrator, and then will usually
settle somewhere in between the final offers. If they do not settle, then the arbitrator
must hear the case and make a decision. Both sides will argue their point, which
essentially boils down to comparing the player to other players in the league and their
salaries. The arbitrator then decides which of the two final offers is closer to the market
value for that player, and picks that one.

Collusion under Ueberroth

The owners, used to nearly a century of one-sided labor negotiations, quickly grew tired
of the new economics of the player labor markets. They went through a series of labor
negotiators, each one faring as poorly as the next, until they hit upon a different
solution. Beginning in 1986, under the guidance of commissioner Peter Ueberroth, they
tried collusion to stem the increase in player salaries. Teams agreed not to bid on one
anothers free agents. The strategy worked, for awhile. During the next two seasons,
player salaries grew at lower rates and high profile free agents routinely had difficulty
finding anybody interested in their services. The players filed a complaint, charging the
owners with a violation of the labor agreement signed by owners and players in 1981,
which prohibited collusive action. They filed separate collusion charges for each of the
three seasons from 1985-87, and won each time. The ruling resulted in the voiding of the
final years of some players contracts, thus awarding them second look free agency
status, and levied fines in excess of $280 million dollars on the owners. The result was a
return to unfettered free agency for the players, a massive financial windfall for the
impacted players, a black eye for the owners, and the end of the line for Commissioner
Ueberroth.

Table 5:Average MLB Payroll as a Percentage of Total Team Revenues for Selected
Years

Year Percentage
1929 35.3
1933 35.9
1939 32.4
1943 24.8
1946 22.1
1950 17.6
1974 20.5
1977 25.1
1980 39.1
1985 39.7
1988 34.2
1989 31.6
1990 33.4
1991 42.9
1992 50.7
1994 60.5
1997 53.6
2001 54.1

Exploitation Patterns

Economist Andrew Zimbalist calculated the degree of market exploitation for baseball
players for the years 1986-89, a decade after free agency began, and during the years of
collusion, using a measure of the marginal revenue product of players. The marginal
revenue product of a player is a measure of the additional revenue a team receives due
to the addition of that player to the team. This is done by calculating the impact of the
player on the performance of the team, and the subsequent impact of team
performance on total revenue. He found that on average, the degree of exploitation, as
measured by the ratio of marginal revenue product to salary, declined each year, from
1.32 in 1986 to 1.01 in 1989. The degree of exploitation, however, was not uniform
across players. Not surprisingly, it decreased as players obtained the leverage to bargain.
The degree of exploitation was highest for players in their first two years, before they
were arbitration eligible, fell for players in the 2-5 year category, between arbitration
and free agency, and disappeared altogether for players with six or more years of
experience. In fact, for all four years, Zimbalist found that this group of players was
overpaid with an average MRP of less than 75% of salary in 1989. No similar study has
been done for players before free agency, in part due to the paucity of salary data
before this time.

Negotiations under the Reserve Clause

Player contracts have changed dramatically since free agency. Players used to be subject
to whatever salary the owner offered. The only recourse for a player was to hold out for
a better salary. This strategy seldom worked, because the owner had great influence on
the media, and usually was able to turn the public against the player, adding another
source of pressure on the player to sign for the terms offered by the team. The pressure
of no payday a payday that, while less than the players MRP, still exceeded his
opportunity cost by a fair amount, was usually sufficient to minimize the length of most
holdouts. The owner influenced the media because the sports reporters were actually
paid by the teams in cash or in kind, traveled with them, and enjoyed a relatively
luxurious lifestyle for their chosen occupation. A lifestyle that could be halted by edict
of the team at any time. The team controlled media passes and access and therefore
had nearly total control of who covered the team. It was a comfortable lifestyle for a
reporter, and spreading owner propaganda on occasion was seldom seen as an
unacceptable price to pay.

Recent Concerns

The major labor issue in the game has shifted from player exploitation, the cry until free
agency was granted, to competitive imbalance. Today, critics of the salary structure
point to its impact on the competitive balance of the league as a way of criticizing the
rising payrolls. Many fans of the game openly pine for a return for the good old days,
when players played for the love of the game. It should be recognized however, that the
game has always been a business. All that has changed has been the amount of money at
stake and how it is divided among the employers and their employees.
Suggested Readings

A Club Owner. The Baseball Trust. Literary Digest, December 7, 1912.


Burk, Robert F. Much More Than a Game: Players, Owners, and American Baseball since 1921. Chapel Hill: University of North
Carolina Press, 2001.
Burk, Robert F. Never Just a Game: Players, Owners, and American Baseball to 1920. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press,
1994.
Dworkin, James B. Owners versus Players: Baseball and Collective Bargaining. Dover, MA: Auburn House, 1981.
Haupert, Michael, baseball financial database.
Haupert, Michael and Ken Winter. Pay Ball: Estimating the Profitability of the New York Yankees 1915-37. Essays in Economic and
Business History 21 (2002).
Helyar, John. Lords of the Realm: The Real History of Baseball. New York: Villard Books, 1994.
Korr, Charles. The End of Baseball as We Knew It: The Players Union, 1960-1981. Champagne: University of Illinois Press, 2002.
Kuhn, Bowie, Hardball: The Education of a Baseball Commissioner. New York: Times Books, 1987.
Lehn, Ken. Property Rights, Risk Sharing, and Player Disability in Major League Baseball. Journal of Law and Economics 25, no. 2
(October1982): 273-79.
Lowe, Stephen. The Kid on the Sandlot: Congress and Professional Sports, 1910-1992. Bowling Green: Bowling Green University
Press, 1995.
Lowenfish, Lee. A Tale of Many Cities: The Westward Expansion of Major League Baseball in the 1950s. Journal of the West 17 (July
1978).
Lowenfish, Lee. What Were They Really Worth? The Baseball Research Journal 20 (1991): 81-2.
Lowenfish, Lee. The Imperfect Diamond: A History of Baseballs Labor Wars. New York: Da Capo Press, 1980.
Miller, Marvin. A Whole Different Ball Game: The Sport and Business of Baseball. New York: Birch Lane Press, 1991.
Noll, Roger G. and Andrew S. Zimbalist, editors. Sports Jobs and Taxes: Economic Impact of Sports Teams and Facilities. Washington,
D.C.: Brookings Institute, 1997.
Noll, Roger, editor. Government and the Sports Business. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1974.
Okkonen, Mark. The Federal League of 1914-1915: Baseballs Third Major League. Cleveland: Society of American Baseball Research,
1989.
Orenstein, Joshua B. The Union Association of 1884: A Glorious Failure. The Baseball Research Journal 19 (1990): 3-6.
Pearson, Daniel M. Baseball in 1889: Players v Owners. Bowling Green, OH: Bowling Green State University Popular Press, 1993.
Quirk, James. An Economic Analysis of Team Movements in Professional Sports. Law and Contemporary Problems 38 (Winter-Spring
1973): 42-66.
Rottenberg, Simon. The Baseball Players Labor Market. Journal of Political Economy 64, no. 3 (December 1956) 242-60.
Scully, Gerald. The Business of Major League Baseball. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989.
Sherony, Keith, Michael Haupert and Glenn Knowles. Competitive Balance in Major League Baseball: Back to the Future. Nine: A
Journal of Baseball History & Culture 9, no. 2 (Spring 2001): 225-36.
Sommers, Paul M., editor. Diamonds Are Forever: The Business of Baseball. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1992.
Sullivan, Neil J. The Diamond in the Bronx: Yankee Stadium and the Politics of New York. New York: Oxford University Press, 2001.
Sullivan, Neil J. The Diamond Revolution. New York: St. Martins Press, 1992.
Sullivan, Neil J. The Dodgers Move West. New York: Oxford University Press, 1987.
Thorn, John and Peter Palmer, editors. Total Baseball. New York: HarperPerennial, 1993.
Voigt, David Q. The League That Failed, Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press, 1998.
White, G. Edward. Creating the National Pastime: Baseball Transforms Itself, 1903-1953. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996.
Wood, Allan. 1918: Babe Ruth and the World Champion Boston Red Sox. New York: Writers Club Press, 2000.
Zimbalist, Andrew. Baseball and Billions. New York: Basic Books, 1992.
Zingg, Paul, Bitter Victory: The World Series of 1918: A Case Study in Major League Labor-Management Relations. Nine: A Journal
of Baseball History and Social Policy Perspectives 1, no. 2 (Spring 1993): 121-41.
Zweig, Jason, Wild Pitch: How American Investors Financed the Growth of Baseball. Friends of Financial History 43 (Summer 1991).
Citation: Haupert, Michael. The Economic History of Major League Baseball. EH.Net Encyclopedia, edited by Robert Whaples.
December 3, 2007. URL: http://eh.net/encyclopedia/the-economic-history-of-major-league-baseball/

Вам также может понравиться