Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 7

European Business Review

The continuing importance of economies of scale in the automotive industry


Rumy Husan
Article information:
To cite this document:
Rumy Husan, (1997),"The continuing importance of economies of scale in the automotive industry", European Business
Review, Vol. 97 Iss 1 pp. 38 - 42
Permanent link to this document:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/09555349710156046
Downloaded on: 16 November 2016, At: 18:22 (PT)
References: this document contains references to 20 other documents.
To copy this document: permissions@emeraldinsight.com
The fulltext of this document has been downloaded 5721 times since 2006*
Users who downloaded this article also downloaded:
Downloaded by Management and Science University At 18:22 16 November 2016 (PT)

(2001),"Economies of scale", Property Management, Vol. 19 Iss 2 pp. - http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/pm.2001.11319bab.012


(1998),"Economies of scale", Facilities, Vol. 16 Iss 7/8 pp. - http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/f.1998.06916gad.001

Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by emerald-srm:546288 []
For Authors
If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service
information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please
visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information.
About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com
Emerald is a global publisher linking research and practice to the benefit of society. The company manages a portfolio of
more than 290 journals and over 2,350 books and book series volumes, as well as providing an extensive range of online
products and additional customer resources and services.
Emerald is both COUNTER 4 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee on Publication
Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive preservation.

*Related content and download information correct at time of download.


The considerable attention given to flexible
The continuing methods of production and work organization
as a fundamental determinant of achieving
importance of international levels of competitiveness in the
economies of scale in manufacturing industry (and of late, in ser-
vice industries also) in the wake of Japanese
the automotive dominance over the past two decades has, as a
industry corollary, seen a tendency to neglect the
importance of economies of scale (EOS).
Indeed, in regard to the automotive industry
Rumy Husan
(the first to introduce rapidly various methods
of increasing flexibility), it has been suggested
that the importance of EOS has been reduced
as a result of the introduction of increased
flexibility in motor manufacturing . This
indeed was the conclusion of the first major
report on the automotive industry conducted
Downloaded by Management and Science University At 18:22 16 November 2016 (PT)

The author by the International Motor Vehicle Program


Rumy Husan is Research Fellow in the School of Business (IMVP) under the auspices of the Massachu-
and Economic Studies, University of Leeds, Leeds, UK. setts Institute of Technology (Altshuler et al.,
1984), while the second IMVP report
Abstract (Womack et al., 1990 the largest survey of
The considerable attention given to flexible methods of any industry) and the survey on manufactur-
production and work organization as a fundamental ing productivity by the McKinsey Global
determinant of achieving international levels of competi- Institute (1993), in their respective analyses of
tiveness in the manufacturing industry (and of late, in the various determinants of competitiveness
service industries also) in the wake of Japanese dominance in the motor industry, did not cite economies
over the past two decades has, as a corollary, seen a of scale.
tendency to neglect the importance of economies of scale Despite the indubitable importance of
(EOS). Despite the indubitable importance of flexibility, flexibility, it is argued here that EOS remain
argues that EOS remain an essential determinant for cost- an essential determinant for cost-efficient
efficient production, and that without sufficient EOS, high production, and that, without sufficient EOS,
levels of flexibility cannot alone translate into world high levels of flexibility cannot alone translate
competitive production. Summarizes the reasons for the into world competitive production. This
continued importance of EOS, and provides a discussion on paper summarizes the reasons for the contin-
the levels of EOS (in particular, minimum efficient scale) ued importance of EOS, and provides a dis-
that are necessary for efficient automotive manufacturing. cussion on the levels of EOS (in particular,
It is assumed that EOS are optimal only when a plant is minimum efficient scale) that are necessary
operating at high capacity utilization levels, and that for efficient automotive manufacturing. It is
where this is not the case penalties are severe. assumed that EOS are only optimal when a
plant is operating at high capacity utilization
levels, and that where this is not the case
penalties are severe.
As a rule, EOS arise from the fact that an
increase in output (of one or more products)
does not give rise to a proportional increase in
cost hence the longer the production run
over a period of time, the lower the unit costs
will be, until the minimum efficient scale of
production (MES) for the product(s) in
question has been reached. Most economies
are internal to the manufacturer, although
external economies also exist. Internal
European Business Review
Volume 97 Number 1 1997 pp. 3842 This paper draws on Husan (1996). My thanks are
MCB University Press ISSN 0955-534X due to Sanjaya Lall for helpful comments.
38
Importance of economies of scale in the automotive industry European Business Review
Rumy Husan Volume 97 Number 1 1997 3842

economies also known as technical reduce total average unit costs by less than 5%
economies relate to production costs and and above which any possible subsequent
emanate from a variety of sources. Pratten doubling in scale would reduce value added per
unit (total costs less the cost of bought out
and Dean (1965, pp. 17-20) list the following:
materials, services, and components) by less
The existence of indivisibilities (for exam- than 10%.
ple of capital equipment), which results in
economies accruing from the attainment of Scherer and Ross (1990, p. 103) , authors of a
full plant capacity. major work that deals substantively with EOS,
Economies of increased dimension where provide a rather imprecise, circular definition:
cost increases less rapidly than capacity, the smallest scale at which minimum unit
a phenomenon known to engineers as the costs [are] attained. They in their work list
0.6 rule (Hay and Morris, 1986, p. 42) three types of EOS: product-specific, plant-
or two-thirds rule (Scherer and Ross, specific and firm-specific. Conventional
1990, p. 98). Economies arise from the fact thinking on the motor industry has limited
that, generally speaking, costs increase with EOS to only the product-specific type in
surface area, while output increases with other words, output of various processes for
Downloaded by Management and Science University At 18:22 16 November 2016 (PT)

volume (or capacity) of additional units of either a single product or related products, is
plant and equipment hence, for example, considered the most important factor in
a 100 per cent increase in output will determining EOS and MES. But plant size is
necessitate only a 60 per cent (or 66 per also an important determinant of product
cent, depending on the rule adopted) cost.
increase in costs. However, in practice, this need not alter
Economies of specialization whereby the conventional view of EOS. Firms choos-
higher output provides opportunities for ing to expand output (of one or more of their
greater division of labour into specialist products at one or more of their plants) are
tasks, together with increasingly more obliged to consider the nature and method of
sophisticated equipment which further expanding capacity in tandem: product-
specialize (hence quicken) and improve scale is therefore inextricably linked to
quality of tasks. plant-scale.
Economies of massed resources where What are the levels of volume needed to
higher levels of production yield propor- attain MES in the volume car industry? These
tional savings in stocks, spare parts, and, as vary according to the process under consider-
Silberston (1972, p. 374) argues, larger ation. Estimates tend to be notional, so have
output per unit of time allows flow produc- to be treated with caution, and vary according
tion to replace batch production. to year and assumptions made. A clear exam-
Superior organization of production here ple of the magnitude of economies possible
economies emanate from the possibility of comes from Fords production of the model T
planning more efficient forms of organiza- before and after the use of the assembly line in
tion. 1914 when a cost reduction of 50 per cent
The learning effect in other words, accrued over the following five years, in line
economies from learning by doing. with a rapid increase in scale (Maxcy and
Clearly such economies exist for all levels Silberston, 1959, p. 78). Table I gives various
of output, and it is by no means certain that estimates for MES levels for the major manu-
long, sustained output of an unchanged facturing processes for volume cars.
product yields significantly more Notwithstanding the fact that the data are
economies from the learning effect in rather dated (more recent figures being
comparison with shorter runs of output unavailable)[1], the most striking aspect of
where the full learning effect has taken Table I is the large variance in figures for all
place. processes except for final assembly, which is
The existence of EOS implies that those remarkably uniform. Thus generalizations
manufacturers not operating at the MES will cannot be made with a high degree of validity.
incur a cost-penalty vis--vis competitors who But having made these cautionary remarks,
are. Pratten (1971, p. 26) defines the MES as: the figures do reveal two loose trends worth
the minimum efficient scale above which any commenting on: first, there appears to be a
possible subsequent doubling in scale would gradual increase in MES levels over time;
39
Importance of economies of scale in the automotive industry European Business Review
Rumy Husan Volume 97 Number 1 1997 3842

Table I MES estimates (in thousand units p.a.) for major manufacturing operations

Foundry/ Final
Source Year forging Pressing Powertrain assembly
Maxcy and Silberston 1958 1,000 500a 100
Toyota 1960 180-360b 480-600 120-240c 96-180
Pratten 1971 1,000 500 250 300
White 1971 Variable 400 260 200-250
Rhys 1972 200 2,000 1,000 200
McGee 1973 2,000
Ford UK 1974/5 2,000 300
CPRS 1975 100 500 250
Euroeconomics 1975 2,000 2,000 1,000 250
Notes:
a This is for machining only; b Forging only; c Machine fabricating

Sources:
Adapted from Central Policy Review Staff (1975, p. 16); Euro-Economics (1975); Ford UK (1975); McGee
Downloaded by Management and Science University At 18:22 16 November 2016 (PT)

(1973); Marsden et al. (1985, Table 4, p. 43); Maxcy and Silverston (1959, pp. 84-6); Odaka et al. (1988, p. 63
(cite Toyota figures)); Pratten (1971, p. 243); Rhys (1972); White (1971)

second, MES levels decline, the further possible, related, factors giving rise to disec-
downstream a process is. onomies: first, imperfect expansibility of the
The first trend can be attributed to the fact management factor, i.e. management is less
that the constant revolutionizing of technolo- efficient in larger firms, and second, diminish-
gy and methods of work organization yield ing returns of management (Bain, 1956,
significant economies beyond the prevailing p. 61).
MES levels: so applying Prattens definition, The second trend arises from upstream
total average unit costs would be reduced by processes being more capital and material-
more than 5 per cent if production were to be intensive[2]. Thus they require higher levels
doubled: thus, there is a shift in the MES. of output to ensure economic unit-contribu-
Figure 1 demonstrates this. tion to plant costs both fixed and variable.
Herein lies a great advantage for the large
Long-run cost-curve A for a motor manu-
manufacturers and a major barrier to entry to
facturer gives MES1 the point at which the
newcomers. Those manufacturers able to
scale curve A becomes horizontal (Silberston,
fulfil MES levels for upstream operations, i.e.
1972, p. 376). Improvements in technology
2 million plus for foundry, forging and press-
and methods of work organization, ceteris
ing, in conjunction with multiple plants for
paribus, yield cost-curve B, with a shift in
assembly operations the least common
MES from MES1 to MES2. DOS1 and principle incur decisive unit-cost savings
DOS2 are respective diseconomies of scale, over smaller manufacturers who are able to
arising from managerial or bureaucratic achieve MES levels for final assembly opera-
drag. To this can be added two other tions but not for others. The least common
principle is simply the least common denomi-
Figure 1 Illustrative MES Cost Curves nator for each operation. Thus if MES for
assembly is 250,000, for engine and transmis-
Unit
costs sion 1m, and for forgings/foundry and press-
ings 2m, the least common principle suggests
that the optimum configuration for a manu-
A facturer would be to have eight assembly
plants and two powertrain plants for each
pressings and forging/foundry plant.
B It is clear that only the largest manufactur-
ers will have resources for this. Such manufac-
turers are few in the motor industry just two
Scale MES1 MES2 DOS1 DOS2 in the USA (GM and Ford); two in Japan
(Toyota and Nissan); and possibly three in
40
Importance of economies of scale in the automotive industry European Business Review
Rumy Husan Volume 97 Number 1 1997 3842

Europe (VW, Fiat and PSA)[3]. Dunnett Table II Total production cost penalties from sub-optimal scale (Whites
provides figures to show that for the pressings estimates)
operation, between 1947-77, no UK manu-
Level of
facturer was anywhere near able to exploit all
production 50,000 100,000 200,000 400,000 800,000
scale economies, and that for example, in
Total cost-
1977, total production of pressings was only
penalty (%) 20 10-15 3-5 0 1
two-thirds of the MES level, while that of the
Source: White (1971)
largest manufacturer was one-third of the 2m
MES level (Dunnett, 1980, Table 2.4, p. 23).
What are the cost penalties associated with Table III Total production cost penalties from sub-optimal scale (Waverman
sub-MES production? Again, estimates vary. and Murphys estimates)
Pratten (1971, p. 271), in a study of various Size of plant
UK industries (on the basis of interviews and (% of MES) 100 80 60 30 10
examination of the technical literature) esti- Cost penalty 0 3 6.8 19.5 34.5
mated that, for the passenger car, the percent- Source: Waverman and Murphy (1990)
age increase in cost at 50 per cent MES level
was approximately 6 per cent per unit.
Downloaded by Management and Science University At 18:22 16 November 2016 (PT)

White provides the following estimates for


vertical integration; capital-raising
total production cost penalties at sub-optimal
economies; economies of large-scale promo-
scale of production (see Table II):
tion; economies of research and development
Waverman and Murphy, in a more recent
which become more important as technolo-
survey, provide the following estimates of cost
gy change increases and so are particularly
penalties (in 1984)[4].
relevant for the motor industry; and
Whites estimates are the least penalty-
economies of scope where economies
incurring, while Prattens (1971) and Waver-
accrue from transfer of knowledge across
man and Murphys (1990), assuming MES of
different, but related, product lines. The
250,000, are similar, at approximately 6 per
principle remains the same for these as for
cent; a significant sum, given the highly com-
EOS, i.e. the larger the manufacturer, the
petitive nature of the international market,
greater the ability and opportunities to
and an explanatory factor in the difficulty of
achieve economies. Indeed, under the prevail-
smaller manufacturers to remain independent
ing situation of rapid technological change,
(see Table III). For manufacturers operating
economies derived from R&D and from
at below 50 per cent MES, cost penalties
promotion have become increasingly
increase exponentially. This corroborates a
important.
commonly observed phenomenon in develop-
One can conclude that reduction in MES
ing countries: that, despite lower labour costs,
levels for a single model through increased
average unit costs tend to be substantially
flexibility assumes the existence indeed
higher for similar vehicles in comparison with
requires it of other models for the attain-
those produced by MES manufacturers.
ment of overall line or plant MES. So, in spite
EOS also accrue in just the same way for
of there existing greater flexibility of manufac-
component manufacturers and other suppli-
turing, EOS and related economies remain
ers. If all these operate at their respective
crucial for competitive production. Hence,
MES levels, then ceteris paribus, costs to
implementation of flexibility in the manufac-
OEMs[5] will be optimal. Whether suppliers
turing system does not constitute a substitute
are able to achieve MES levels will, above all,
for EOS, but rather is incremental to it.
depend on levels of demand from the OEMs.
It is therefore clear that there exist
national/regional economies which emanate Notes
from the existence of high demand, high
output, and large firms which augment the 1 Indeed, one can conjecture that this is a consequence
purely product, plant or firm-specific of the focus of attention so significantly shifting to
flexibility issues over the past decade and a half.
economies. This reinforces the disadvantage
2 Rhys much lower figure for the foundry operation
experienced by relatively small manufacturers
stems from his assertion of this being highly labour-
in low-demand, low-output regions. intensive. However, he later qualified this by stating:
Alongside EOS arise various other related at present, the optimum size of the foundry is quite
economies. These are: economies from small, but the increased use of machinery plus the
41
Importance of economies of scale in the automotive industry European Business Review
Rumy Husan Volume 97 Number 1 1997 3842

need to work with new sophisticated metals may Husan, R. (1996), An outline of the key determinants of
increase the optimum, especially if more specific competitiveness in the international motor vehicle
equipment is used (Rhys, 1972, Table I, 285-6). industry, Discussion Paper No. 72, Department of
3 Although Fiats production has declined markedly in Economics, University of Portsmouth.
the early 1990s (1990). GM Europe, Ford Europe and Marsden, D., Morris, T., Willman, P. and Wood, S. (1985),
Renault could also be added to the list. The Car Industry: Labour Relations and Industrial
Adjustment, Tavistock, London and New York, NY.
4 It should be noted that Waverman and Murphy
assume assembly plant MES of 400,000. They mistak- McGee, J.S., Economies of size in auto-body manufac-
enly attribute this to White; but Whites (1971) ture, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. XVI (2),
estimate for assembly MES was between 200-250,000 October 1973.
(see Table I) he had, as can be seen from Table II, McKinsey Global Institute (1993), Manufacturing Produc-
estimated total production economies could be tivity, Washington, DC.
utilized at 400,000 units p.a. Maxcy, G. and Silberston, A. (1959), The Motor Industry,
5 OEMs (original equipment manufacturers) manufac- Allen & Unwin, London,
ture and assemble components for new vehicles. They Odaka, K., Ono, K. and Adachi, F. (1988), The Automobile
are also known as final assemblers or simply as Industry in Japan: A Study of Ancillary Firm Develop-
vehicle manufacturers. ment, Kinokuniya, Tokyo, and Oxford University
Press, Oxford
Downloaded by Management and Science University At 18:22 16 November 2016 (PT)

Pratten, C.F. (1971), Economies of scale in manufacturing


References industry, Department of Applied Economics,
Occasional Paper No. 28, University of Cambridge,
Altshuler, A., Anderson, M., Jones, D., Roos, D. and
Cambridge.
Womack, J. (1984), The Future of the Automobile
Industry: Report of Massachusetts Institute of Pratten, C.F. and Dean, R.M. (1965), The economies of
Technologys International Auto Program, Allen & large scale production in British industry, Depart-
Unwin, London. ment of Applied Economics, Occasional Paper No. 3,
University of Cambridge, Cambridge.
Bain, J.S. (1956), Barriers to New Competition, Harvard
University Press, Cambridge, MA. Rhys, D.G. (1972), The Motor Industry, An Economic
Survey, Butterworths, London.
Central Policy Review Staff (1975), The Future of the
Silberston, A. (1972), Economies of scale in theory and
British Car Industry, HMSO, London.
practice, Economic Journal, No. 82, pp. 369-91.
Dunnett, P.J.S. (1980), The Decline of the British Motor
Waverman, L. and Murphy, S. (1990), Total factor produc-
Industry, Croom Helm, London.
tivity in automobile production in Argentina,
The European car industry the problem of structure and Mexico, Korea and Canada: the impacts of protec-
overcapacity, Euro-Economics, March 1975. tion, in Helleiner, G.K., Industrialisation and
Ford UK, Evidence to the House of Commons Expenditure Development, Clarendon, Oxford.
Committee Session 1974/75, Minutes of Evidence White, L.J. (1971), The Automobile Industry Since 1945,
Taken Before the Trade and Industry Sub-committee, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Vol. 1, 1975. Womack, J., Jones, D. and Roos, D. (1990), The Machine
Hay, D.A. and Morris, D.J. (1986), Industrial Economics: that Changed the World, Rawson Associates, New
Theory and Evidence, Oxford University Press, Oxford. York, NY.

42
This article has been cited by:

1. Martin Baumers, Phill Dickens, Chris Tuck, Richard Hague. 2016. The cost of additive manufacturing: machine productivity,
economies of scale and technology-push. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 102, 193-201. [CrossRef]
2. Alejandro Fitzsimons, Sebastin GuevaraTransnational Corporations and the Restructuring of the Argentine Automotive
Industry: Change or Continuity? 183-213. [CrossRef]
3. Eric Dahlgren, Caner Gmen, Klaus Lackner, Garrett van Ryzin. 2013. Small Modular Infrastructure. The Engineering
Economist 58:4, 231-264. [CrossRef]
Downloaded by Management and Science University At 18:22 16 November 2016 (PT)

Вам также может понравиться