Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 18

Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

www.elsevier.com/locate/aos

Budget negotiations in multi-period settings


a,*
Joseph G. Fisher , James R. Frederickson b, Sean A. Peer c

a
Department of Accounting, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405, USA
b
Melbourne Business School, The University of Melbourne, Carlton, VIC 3053, Australia
c
Von Allmen School of Accountancy, Gatton College of Business and Economics, University of Kentucky, Lexington,
KY 40506-0034, USA

Abstract

Budgets are typically set through a negotiation process that is repeated in successive periods, often between the same
superior and subordinate. Despite this, little is known about budget negotiations in multi-period settings. Temporal
interdependence is a fundamental aspect of budget negotiations in multi-period settings, and it refers to the fact that
in multi-period budget settings, superiors (subordinates) decisions and actions in one period can be inuenced by sub-
ordinates (superiors) decisions and actions in earlier periods and, in turn, can inuence subordinates (superiors) deci-
sions and actions in later periods. We report the results of an experiment that addresses two issues related to temporal
interdependence.
The rst issue we examine is the eect of an expectation of future budget negotiations with the same individual on
current period negotiation strategies and outcomes. Consistent with our expectations, our results indicate that superiors
and subordinates who expect future budget negotiations act more cooperatively. For example, when superiors and sub-
ordinates expect future budget negotiations, they are more likely to reach agreement on a budget and subordinate per-
formance is higher. The second issue focuses on a multi-period setting with repeated budget negotiations between the
same individuals. We examine the pattern of negotiation outcomes across periods to assess the eect of prior budget
outcomes on current period negotiation strategies and outcomes. Our results indicate that in this setting, superiors
and subordinates react to negotiation strategies and outcomes from prior periods in predictable ways. For example,
once a particular superior and subordinate reached agreement, they were more likely to continue to reach agreement
in future periods. In addition, superiors initial negotiation positions across periods and the budget levels across periods
were consistent with superiors using subordinate performance in the prior period to update their beliefs about subor-
dinate performance capability. One implication of our results is that some issues identied in prior, single-period bud-
geting research do not generalize to the multi-period setting where there is temporal interdependence.
2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

*
Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 812 855 3705; fax: +1 812 855 4985.
E-mail address: josher@indiana.edu (J.G. Fisher).

0361-3682/$ - see front matter 2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.aos.2005.12.008
512 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

Introduction individual, which is a necessary condition for tem-


poral interdependence to exist. We examine
Almost all rms engage in budgeting, and bud- whether this aspect of temporal interdependence
gets typically are set through a negotiation process aects budget negotiation strategies and outcomes.
(Anthony & Govindarajan, 2001; Umapathy, Specically, we examine the eect of the presence
1987). Despite this, only a few studies have exam- versus absence of an expectation of future budget
ined budget negotiations (e.g., Fisher, Frederick- negotiations with the same individual on negotia-
son, & Peer, 2000, 2002), and these studies have tion strategies and outcomes. We compare two set-
focused on single-period settings. Budget negotia- tings where the only dierence between the settings
tions in practice typically are not a one-time event, is the knowledge of future or no future budget
but, rather, a process that is repeated in successive interactions. We view this issue as an important
periods, often between the same superior and sub- rst step in moving the budget negotiation litera-
ordinate. As Mannix, Tinsley, and Bazerman ture from a single-period setting to a multi-period
(1995) suggest, individuals engaged in a series of setting. The results from our experiment indicate
similar tasks are likely to behave dierently than that superiors and subordinates who expect future
individuals performing a task only once. Thus, budget negotiations have smaller dierences in
given that budget negotiations between the same their initial negotiation positions and are more
individuals in multi-period settings are common, likely to reach agreement on budgets. In addition,
it is important to understand negotiation strategies subordinates who expect future budget negotia-
and outcomes in such settings. In addition, given tions have higher performances, both in absolute
that prior research has focused on one-shot (i.e., terms and relative to their budgets, than do subor-
single period) negotiations, it is important to dinates who do not expect future budget negotia-
understand how fundamental factors that distin- tions. This performance eect is due primarily to
guish repeated negotiations with the same individ- subordinates in dyads that fail to reach budget
ual from one-shot negotiations aect budget agreement. For these subordinates, those who do
negotiation strategies and outcomes. not expect future budget negotiations perform sig-
Budget negotiations in single-period settings nicantly below their budgets, whereas those who
create intra-period interdependence between supe- expect future budget negotiations do not.
riors and subordinates because their respective The second aspect of temporal interdependence
payos for the period depend on each others deci- we consider is that individuals can learn from and
sions and actions in that period (Lewicki, Litterer, react to negotiation strategies and outcomes from
Minton, & Saunders, 1994). In multi-period set- prior periods, which is the dening aspect of tem-
tings, not only is there intra-period interdepen- poral interdependence. Specically, we focus on a
dence but also temporal interdependence. That multi-period setting with repeated budget negotia-
is, superiors (subordinates) decisions and actions tions between the same individuals and provide
in one period can be inuenced by subordinates evidence about the eect of prior budget negotia-
(superiors) decisions and actions in earlier periods tions and outcomes on current period negotiation
and, in turn, can inuence subordinates (superi- strategies and outcomes by examining the pattern
ors) decisions and actions in later periods. Tempo- of negotiation strategies and outcomes across peri-
ral interdependence is a fundamental feature of ods. Our results indicate that superiors and subor-
budget negotiations in multi-period settings. The dinates in a repeated multi-period setting react to
existence of temporal interdependence suggests prior budget negotiations and outcomes in predict-
that negotiations in a multi-period setting may able ways. The dierence between superiors and
have dierent outcomes than a one-shot subordinates initial negotiation positions
negotiation. decreases across periods, and the likelihood of
In this study, we examine two aspects of tempo- negotiation agreement increases. Further, the like-
ral interdependence. The rst aspect is an expecta- lihood of budget agreement in a subsequent period
tion of future interactions with the same also depends on the prior period. Once a particular
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 513

superior and subordinate reach agreement, they Finally, our results indicate that temporal inter-
are more likely to continue to reach agreement in dependence has performance benets. Firms might
future periods. Finally, superiors initial negotia- be able to increase the benets induced by tempo-
tion positions across periods and the budget levels ral interdependence by making interdependence
across periods each reect subordinate perfor- more salient to its employees. Firms, therefore,
mance in the prior period, consistent with superi- may want to emphasize to employees the repeated
ors using subordinate performance in the prior nature of budgeting, as well as ongoing relations in
period to update their beliefs about subordinate the rm, particularly when superiors impose a
performance capability. Specically, superiors budget following a failed negotiation.
pursue higher (lower) budgets when subordinate The remainder of the paper is organized as fol-
performance in the preceding period exceeded lows: The setting and background are described in
(lagged) the budget. Setting section, and hypotheses are developed
Our results have several implications for in Hypotheses section. We explain the method in
research and practice. First, we extend the budget Method section and present the results in Results
negotiation literature (e.g., Fisher et al. 2000, section. The paper concludes with a discussion of
2002) from a single-period setting to a multi-per- the results in Discussion section.
iod setting, which is a very common setting found
in practice. Moreover, because temporal interde-
pendence is a fundamental dierence between sin- Setting
gle-period budget negotiations and multi-period
budget negotiations, our results suggest that Consider the following setting. There are supe-
results from studies that used single-period bud- rior and subordinate dyads where subordinates
geting settings may not easily generalize to multi- provide a productive input, and it is common
period settings. knowledge that there are multiple production peri-
Second, our results for superiors initial negoti- ods. Superiors and subordinates are compensated
ation positions across periods and the budget lev- in each period according to the following
els across periods are consistent with superiors contracts:1
engaging in ratcheting. Ratcheting refers to a bud- 
F if X 6 B
geting process where the current periods budget P subordinate 1
equals the preceding periods budget plus an F AX  B if X > B
adjustment (i.e., ratchet) based on actual output 
RDX  F if X 6 B
relative to the budget in the preceding period P superior
(Chow, Cooper, & Haddad, 1991; Leone & Rock, RfDX  F AX  Bg if X > B
2002; Weitzman, 1976, 1980). In addition, our 2
experiment provides insights on two aspects of
where P: compensation; F: subordinate xed com-
superior ratcheting behavior. The rst is that the
pensation; A: subordinate compensation per unit
degree of adjustment in both the superiors initial of production over budget, X: actual production;
negotiation positions and the budget levels
B: budget; D: protability, exclusive of subordi-
reected only a relatively small portion of the dif-
nate compensation, per unit produced; R: supe-
ference in the preceding period between the subor-
riors percentage of rm protability.
dinates performance and the budget, regardless of
whether subordinate performance in the preceding
period exceeded or lagged the budget. The second 1
We selected the subordinates contract because of its
item is that the magnitudes of the upward and theoretical importance (e.g., Demski & Feltham, 1978; Holm-
downward ratchets generally were equal (i.e., sym- strom, 1982; Weitzman, 1980) and its common use in practice
and research (Atkinson, Banker, Kaplan, & Young, 2001;
metrical ratcheting), which contrasts with Leone Crystal, 1993; Dillard & Fisher, 1990; Henderson, 2000;
and Rocks (2002) nding, based on budgeting at Milgrom & Roberts, 1992; Murphy, 2000). The superiors
one rm, of asymmetrical ratcheting. contract is simply a residual contract.
514 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

Superiors do not know the performance capa- actual output relative to the budget in the current
bility of their particular subordinate at the begin- period (Chow et al., 1991; Leone & Rock, 2002;
ning of the rst period, whereas subordinates Weitzman, 1976, 1980).3 Subordinates who believe
know their own performance capability. The two that superiors will engage in ratcheting may have
parties are aware of both incentive contracts. incentives to curtail performance in the current
The superiors and subordinates determine the period to avoid a higher budget in the next period
budget via a negotiation process. In the negotia- (Weitzman, 1980).4
tion, subordinates make the initial budget pro- Given their contract in Eq. (2), superiors prefer
posal, consistent with bottom-up processes high subordinate eort and, for revenue sharing
(Anthony & Govindarajan, 2001; Chandra, purposes, high budgets. Therefore, the static and
1993), and superiors have the right to set the bud- dynamic incentive problems imply conicts
get in the event of a negotiation impasse, consis- between superiors and subordinates. Specically,
tent with most budgeting processes in practice the static incentive problem implies conict
(Umapathy, 1987). Once dyads set a budget for between superiors and subordinates about the
the period, subordinates exert eort in the work desired budget level for a given level of subordi-
period, which in turn determines their perfor- nate performance while the dynamic incentive
mance and rm revenues for the period. At the problem may result in conict between them about
end of the period, the dyad is informed of the sub- the desired subordinate performance level for a
ordinates performance. given budget level.
Weitzman (1976, 1980) notes that in multi-per- Budget negotiations allow superiors and subor-
iod budgeting settings where subordinates are dinates to explicitly address their conict about the
compensated via budget-based contracts that budget level. In addition, budget negotiations also
reward over performing the budget, such as the allow them to indirectly address the second conict
contract in Eq. (1), two incentive problems exist: because the negotiation process, as well as the
a static incentive problem and a dynamic incentive resulting budget, may inuence subordinate per-
problem. The former refers to the incentives subor- formance. The contracts in Eqs. (1) and (2) create
dinates have in any given period to misrepresent intra-period interdependence between superiors
their private information in order to get a low bud- and subordinates because their respective payos
get for that period, making it easier to earn a lar- in a particular period are inuenced by the others
ger bonus in that period.2 The dynamic incentive decisions and actions in that period (Lewicki et al.,
problem, which is a manifestation of temporal 1994). There also is temporal interdependence
interdependence, arises as a reaction to the poten- because superiors (subordinates) decisions and
tial for superiors to engage in ratcheting. Ratchet- actions in one period can be inuenced by subordi-
ing refers to the natural tendency of superiors who nates (superiors) decisions and actions in earlier
are not fully informed about subordinates perfor- periods and, in turn, can inuence subordinates
mance capabilities to use current performance as a (superiors) decisions and actions in later periods.
basis for the budget in the next period (Weitzman,
1980). With ratcheting, next periods budget
3
equals the current periods budget plus an adjust- Weitzman (1980, p. 303) refers to the adjustment as a
ment (i.e., ratchet), with the adjustment based on ratchet because current performance acts like a notched wheel
in xing the point of departure for next periods target. With
full ratcheting, prior period performance is the lower limit for
subsequent budget targets (Leone & Rock, 2002). Holthausen,
2
The static incentive problem is present in both single-period Larcker, and Sloan (1995) provide an example of a full
budgeting settings and multi-period budgeting settings. ratcheting process at H. J. Heinz Company. At this company,
Research on budgetary slack (see, e.g., Chow, Cooper, & budgets were set at the greater of 115% of prior period
Waller, 1988; Frederickson & Cloyd, 1998; Waller, 1988; performance or 115% of the prior period budget.
4
Young, 1985; Young, Fisher, & Lindquist, 1993) generally The subordinates motivation to curtail performance
has focused on the static incentive problem in single-period depends on several factors, most importantly on the magnitude
settings. of the ratchet adjustment factor.
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 515

In the next section we discuss the eect of temporal guish cooperative from competitive behavior. For
interdependence on negotiation strategies and example, in the standard Prisoners Dilemma
outcomes. game, the joint payo is public information, and
varies from low in the competitive solution to
moderate in the mixed solution to high in the
Hypotheses cooperative solution.
Dening cooperative outcomes in budget
As indicated previously, we examine two negotiations is more dicult because the link
aspects of temporal interdependence. The rst is between the negotiation and the joint payo is
the eect of knowledge of future interactions with less clear. Unlike negotiation settings typically
the same individual or the knowledge of no future used in the negotiation literature, superiors and
interactions. The second aspect is the pattern of subordinates in budget negotiations do not
negotiation strategies and outcomes in a multi-per- explicitly negotiate the factor that determines
iod setting with repeated negotiations between the the total joint payo. That is, superiors and sub-
same individuals. As discussed in more detail ordinates do not directly negotiate the subordi-
below, prior research suggests that interaction nates performance level, which is the factor
length can aect cooperation between individuals. that determines rm revenues. Instead, superiors
Therefore, we rst dene a cooperative outcome in and subordinates negotiate the budget level,
our budget negotiation setting prior to formally which in turn may aect subordinate perfor-
developing our hypotheses. mance and thus rm revenues.6
We use the two sources of conict between
Cooperation in budget negotiations superiors and subordinates in multi-period budget
settings that we identied earlier (i.e., subordinate
In integrative situations, a cooperative solution performance level and the budget level) to dene a
generates a higher joint payo than a competitive cooperative solution in budget negotiation set-
solution (Bazerman, 1998; Pruitt, 1981; Rubin, tings. Specically, we dene a cooperative solution
Pruitt, & Kim, 1994).5 Prior studies that have by two factors: high subordinate performance and
addressed cooperative versus competitive behav- negotiation agreement. High subordinate perfor-
ior generally have used integrative settings where mance maximizes the joint payo available to the
the link between the negotiation and the joint superior and subordinate, consistent with the con-
payos is clear, making it relatively easy to distin- cept of an integrative solution. Negotiation agree-
ment implies that the superior and subordinate
resolved their conict about the budget level and
5
Negotiations can be either distributive or integrative. In a indicates an implicit agreement about the division
distributive negotiation, the parties are negotiating over a xed of rm revenues between them.
sum, resulting in a zero-sum game where a gain for one party
causes an equal loss for the other (Kersten, 2001; Pruitt, 1981).
Compromise could be considered a cooperative solution for
such negotiations. In contrast, in an integrative negotiation,
6
there exists the possibility to increase the magnitude of the An additional complication is that budget negotiations
payo that will be split between the parties. An integrative (i.e., contain aspects of both integrative and distributive negotia-
cooperative) solution reconciles the interests of both parties and tions. Budget negotiations are integrative in that the negotia-
results in a higher joint prot than provided by either party tions and/or resulting budget have the potential to aect the
getting their respective preferred solution (Bazerman, 1998; amount of rm revenues, which is the joint payo to the
Pruitt, 1981; Thompson, 1990). Because integrative solutions superior and subordinate. Budget negotiations are distributive
focus on the joint payo, they often result in the parties being in that for a xed subordinate performance level, the budget
individually worse o, compared to their respective preferred determines how rm revenues are divided between the superior
solutions (Pruitt, 1981; Rubin et al., 1994). Integrative solutions and subordinate. For performance above the budget, a higher
that make both parties strictly better o compared to non- budget results in a larger portion of rm revenues being
cooperative solutions are called fully integrative (Rubin et al., allocated to the superior while decreasing the portion allocated
1994). to the subordinate.
516 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

Expectation of future budget negotiations tions (Greenhalgh, 1999; Mannix et al., 1995;
Rubin et al., 1994). The latter creates a rational
In our setting, an expectation of future negotia- expectation of temporal interdependence (Mannix
tions with the same individual is a necessary condi- et al., 1995), creating incentives to develop a work-
tion for temporal interdependence. In this section, ing relationship with the other by acting coopera-
we address the eect of the presence versus absence tively (Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993; Rubin et al.,
of such expectations. We argue below that an 1994). For example, individuals who expect future
expectation of future negotiations will cause indi- interactions with the same individual may be will-
viduals to act more cooperatively, resulting in ing to forgo current benets and receive a smaller
more cooperative outcomes. current payo in an eort to create sustainable
A model of conict resolution, the dual concern cooperative solutions across future periods, even
model (Pruitt & Rubin, 1986; Rubin et al., 1994) though such solutions are not enforceable ex-post
argues that the degree to which an individual pur- in any given period. Such joint cooperative behav-
sues a cooperative solution depends on the relative ior maximizes the present value of the individuals
strength of two factors: (1) the individuals con- respective payos relative to a series of non-cooper-
cern about his/her own outcomes in the current ative solutions. Results from buyer-seller negotia-
conict (i.e., self-interest) and (2) the individuals tions (e.g., Ben-Yoav & Pruitt, 1984a, 1984b;
concern about the others outcomes in the current Mannix et al., 1995), repeated Prisoner Dilemma
conict (i.e., other-interest). Although concern for games (e.g., Axelrod, 1990; Murnighan & Roth,
the other can be genuine, implying an intrinsic 1983), and public goods games (Ledyard, 1995)
interest in the welfare of the other, it is more com- are consistent with individuals who expect future
monly instrumental (Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993; interactions acting more cooperatively.
Pruitt & Rubin, 1986; Rubin et al., 1994). That Recall that in our budget negotiation setting,
is, in resolving the current conict, individuals there is intra-period interdependence between
act as if they are concerned about the other superiors and subordinates, and it exists regardless
because doing so has strategic benets. of the expectation of future budget negotiations.
Regardless of whether it is genuine or instru- This suggests that regardless of whether they
mental, concern for the other is what distinguishes expect future negotiations, superiors and subordi-
cooperative behavior from competitive behavior nates may have some degree of concern for each
(Janssen & van de Vliert, 1996; Larrick & Blount, other. However, consistent with the discussion
1995; Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993). Competitive above, superiors and subordinates who expect
behavior occurs when concern for the other is future negotiations have an additional reason to
weak. In contrast, when concern for the other is exhibit concern for the other in the current period:
strong, individuals are motivated to pursue coop- to inuence the others decisions and actions in
erative strategies to resolve the conict, either by future periods. Thus, superiors and subordinates
yielding to the other party (if self-interest is weak) who expect future budget negotiations have
or by collaborating with the other (if self-interest is greater incentive to act cooperatively in the current
strong). If both parties employ collaboration, the period than do those who do not expect future
result is a cooperative solution to the conict. budget negotiations. Below we discuss how greater
Thus, any increase in concern for the other should cooperation aects specic negotiation strategies
cause the individual to act more cooperatively, and outcomes.
regardless of whether the increased concern is gen-
uine or instrumental. Initial negotiation positions
Contextual factors can aect the strength of con- The static incentive problem (Weitzman, 1976,
cern for the other, and thus aect the degree to 1980) creates a conict between superiors and sub-
which individuals act cooperatively. Two contex- ordinates about the desired budget level, regardless
tual factors posited to create instrumental concern of the expectation of future budget negotiations,
are interdependence and expected future interac- implying a dierence in superiors and subordi-
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 517

nates initial negotiation positions. However, con- own expense (Pillutla & Murnighan, 1995). Fisher
sistent with an expectation of future interactions et al.s (2002) ndings are consistent with subordi-
increasing concern for the other and thus inducing nates in single-period budget negotiation settings
cooperation, the dierence should be smaller for acting spiteful in response to superiors imposing
dyads that expect future budget negotiations a budget following failed negotiations, even when
because less extreme initial negotiation positions the imposed budgets were achievable. Specically,
typically are considered to signal more cooperative subordinates in this situation signicantly under-
behavior than do more extreme initial negotiation performed their budgets, thereby generating less
positions (Benton, Kelley, & Liebling, 1972; Fisher revenue for the superiors while foregoing a bonus
et al., 2000; Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993). for themselves.
When superiors impose a budget following a
H1: The dierence between superiors and subor- failed negotiation, we expect subordinates who
dinates initial negotiation positions is smal- do not expect future budget negotiations to act
ler for dyads that expect future budget spiteful and signicantly under perform their bud-
negotiations than for dyads that do not gets. In contrast, subordinates who expect future
expect future budget negotiations. budget negotiations should have greater concern
for the other (even if only instrumental), which
in turn should motivate them to act more cooper-
Negotiation agreement atively. Given our denition of a cooperative solu-
Negotiation agreement is an important aspect tion in budgeting negotiation settings, acting more
of budget negotiations because it aects subordi- cooperatively should cause subordinates to per-
nate performance (Fisher et al., 2000, Fisher, form closer to the budget. We expect, therefore,
Frederickson, & Peer, 2002). Given our denition that when superiors impose a budget following a
of a cooperative solution in budget negotiation set- failed negotiation, subordinates who expect future
tings, superiors and subordinates who expect budget negotiations will, at least partially, sup-
future budget negotiations are more likely to reach press their desire to act spiteful, resulting in a
budget agreement. smaller underperformance of the budget.

H2: The likelihood of negotiation agreement is H3: For subordinates in dyads that fail to reach
higher for dyads that expect future budget agreement, subordinates who expect future
negotiations than for dyads that do not budget negotiations under perform the bud-
expect future budget negotiations. get by a smaller amount than do subordi-
nates who do not expect future budget
negotiations.
Subordinate performance
Research shows that the factors that aect sub- Now consider dyads that reach agreement.
ordinate performance in single-period budget Agreeing to a budget implies that subordinates
negotiation settings dier depending on whether believe the budget is attainable (i.e., at or below
the superiors and subordinates reached agreement the subordinates performance capability) and
on a budget (Fisher et al., 2002). We, therefore, are committed to achieving the budget. Subordi-
address subordinate performance separately for nates who do not expect future budget negotia-
dyads that do and do not reach agreement to tions have incentives to maximize their
assess the eect in each situation of an expectation performance and over perform the budget up to
of future budget negotiations. their performance capability in order to maximize
First consider dyads that do not reach agree- compensation. Because this performance level
ment. When faced with negotiation outcomes they maximizes the joint prot, this performance level
believe are unfair, individuals may retaliate and is the cooperative solution in a multi-period set-
act spitefully to harm the other party, even at their ting. An expectation of future budget negotiations,
518 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

therefore, is not expected to aect the degree to for H3 and H4. We rely on our empirical results
which subordinates in dyads that reach agreement to provide insight on this issue.
over perform the budget.
Negotiation strategies and outcomes
H4: For subordinates in dyads that reach agree- across periods
ment, subordinates expectations about
future budget negotiations do not aect the A dening aspect of temporal interdependence
amount by which they over perform the is that individuals can learn from and react to
budget. negotiation strategies and outcomes from prior
periods. In this section, we address whether
Taken together, H2H4 imply that performance repeated negotiations with the same individual
overall should be higher for subordinates who aect negotiation strategies and outcomes across
expect future budget negotiations. Recall, how- periods in predictable ways. Specically, we focus
ever, that the dynamic incentive problem suggests on a multi-period setting with repeated negotia-
that subordinates who expect future budget nego- tions between the same individuals and consider
tiations may have incentives to curtail current per- the pattern of negotiation strategies and outcomes
iod performance if they anticipate that superiors across periods to assess the eect of prior budget
will ratchet (Weitzman, 1976, 1980). The dynamic negotiations and outcomes on current period
incentive problem, therefore, suggests that overall negotiation strategies and outcomes.8 We address
subordinate performance will be lower for subor- two broad areas: (1) the eect of prior negotiation
dinates who expect future budget negotiations. agreement and (2) the eect of subordinate perfor-
This conclusion, however, may not be warranted mance in prior periods.
for at least two reasons. First, whether subordi-
nates do in fact have incentives to curtail perfor- Eect of agreement
mance in the current period depends on several Achieving budget agreement indicates coopera-
factors such as the subordinates beliefs about tive behavior by both the superior and subordinate
the size of the anticipated ratchet adjustment fac- (Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993). Research suggests that
tor and interest rates (Weitzman, 1980). As the for-
mer increases or the latter decreases, subordinates
8
incentives to curtail performance in the current Our focus in this section is on the pattern of negotiation
strategies and outcomes across periods in our multi-period
period increase.7 Second, Weitzmans (1980) anal- setting, not how outcomes dier across dierent multi-period
ysis does not consider potentially important fac- settings. We chose to focus on a multi-period setting with
tors such as negotiation agreement, spite, and repeated negotiations between the same individuals for two
subordinates cognitive abilities to make the neces- reasons. The rst is that this setting is arguably the most
sary calculations. There are numerous experimen- common setting in practice. The second reason is that repeated
negotiations with the same individual (as opposed to, for
tal papers that demonstrate individuals do not example, negotiating with a dierent individual each period)
act consistent with economic predictions (e.g., makes it easier for the parties to learn the others negotiation
Frederickson, 1992; Frederickson & Waller, strategies, and thus provides the most powerful setting for
2005; Luft, 1994; Murnighan & Roth, 1983). Thus, ascertaining whether prior negotiations and outcomes aect
it is not clear whether the dynamic incentive prob- current period negotiation strategies and outcomes. Focusing
on only one setting, however, prevents us from ascertaining the
lem provides a meaningful competing hypothesis relevant importance of various factors inherent in our setting
(e.g., the eect of negotiating with a dierent individual each
period versus the incremental eect of negotiating with the same
7
Subordinates essentially must tradeo the current rewards individual each period). Nonetheless, our setting helps us better
from providing higher performance in the current period understand multi-period budget negotiations and, potentially
against lower future rewards due to higher future budgets that more important, moves the budget negotiation literature from a
result from higher current performance (Weitzman, 1980). See single-period setting to the more common multi-period setting.
Weitzman (1980) for a detailed analysis of the dynamic It is left to future research to consider and compare dierent
incentive problem. formulations of the repeated budget setting.
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 519

once established, positive (i.e., cooperative) rela- H7: In a multi-period setting with repeated nego-
tionships tend to persist (see Pruitt & Carnevale, tiations, the likelihood of budget agreement
1993, for a review). For example, once individuals increases over time.
in multi-period Prisoners Dilemma games estab-
lish mutually cooperative behavior, they tend to Consistent with analytical agency models (e.g.,
continue making cooperative choices (Lewicki Weitzman, 1976, 1980), ratcheting is a logical
et al., 1994). This discussion implies that superiors response by superiors when there is information
and subordinates are more likely to reach agree- asymmetry between superiors and subordinates
ment in the current period if they reached agree- about subordinates performance capabilities.
ment in the preceding period. Superiors can use the subordinates performance
to update their beliefs about the subordinates per-
H5: In a multi-period setting with repeated nego- formance capabilities and then use those updated
tiations, the likelihood of a superior and sub- beliefs in the current periods budget negotiations.
ordinate reaching agreement is higher if they We, therefore, expect superiors to ratchet, imply-
reached agreement in the preceding period. ing that over performance (under performance)
of the budget in the preceding period will result
in a higher (lower) budget in the current period.
Eect of subordinate performance
Recall that there is information asymmetry H8a: The current period budget reects ratcheting
between superiors and subordinates at the begin- based on subordinate performance in the
ning of the rst period about the subordinates per- preceding period.
formance capabilities. Subordinate performance
provides superiors with a signal about the subordi- When subordinates over perform the budget in
nates performance capabilities, potentially reduc- the preceding period, superiors must decide
ing the degree of information asymmetry. whether to act more competitively and pursue a
Repeated observations of subordinate performance budget in the current period that equals the subor-
across time allow superiors to more accurately dinates performance (i.e., a full ratchet) or act
assess subordinates performance capabilities, fur- more cooperatively by allowing a lower budget.
ther reducing the degree of information asymmetry. Superiors dependence on subordinates to generate
Thus, due to the observation of subordinate perfor- rm revenues in the current period, as well as the
mance across time, the degree of information asym- expectation of future budget negotiations with
metry should decrease across time. the subordinates, suggests that superiors should
Fisher et al. (2002) document a positive relation exhibit concern for the subordinates. Superiors
between the degree of information asymmetry and concern for subordinates should motivate them
the magnitude of the dierence in superiors and to act cooperatively, implying that superiors will
subordinates initial negotiation positions. In turn, not engage in full ratcheting.
there is a negative relation between the magnitude
of the dierence in initial negotiation positions and H8b: In a multi-period setting with repeated nego-
the likelihood of budget agreement. This discus- tiations, the current period budget does not
sion suggests that over time, there should be both reect full ratcheting when subordinates
a smaller dierence in superiors and subordinates over performed the budget in the preceding
initial negotiation positions and a greater likeli- period.
hood of budget agreement.
The situation is more complex when subordi-
H6: In a multi-period setting with repeated nego- nates under perform the budget because superiors
tiations, the dierence between superiors cannot distinguish whether the performance
and subordinates initial negotiation posi- reects subordinates performance capabilities or
tions decreases over time. shirking in an eort to game the budget process
520 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

and obtain a lower budget in the current period. If of the expectation condition that there would be
superiors believe the performance reects several periods, and thus future budget negotia-
performance capabilities, the superiors interde- tions with the same individual. The only dierence
pendencies with the subordinates give superiors between the two expectation conditions is that par-
incentives to act cooperatively and seek a budget ticipants in the former expected future budget
below the subordinates performance. If superiors negotiations while participants in the latter did
believe the performance reects shirking, the inter- not; this comparison controls for all other poten-
dependencies with the subordinates still give supe- tially confounding factors.
riors incentives to act cooperatively. However, the
cooperative strategy in this situation is unclear. Procedure
Further, superiors could view subordinate shirking
as a non-cooperative act, which could decrease Participants completed the entire experiment,
their degree of concern for subordinates (Pruitt except for the negotiation process, via computer.
& Carnevale, 1993) and in turn give superiors less The experimental procedure consisted of the fol-
incentive to act cooperatively. Given the ambigu- lowing steps:
ity, we do not provide a prediction for this (1) The computer lab was partitioned into two
situation. halves using a solid room partition. When partici-
pants arrived, they were assigned randomly to a
computer terminal, with half the participants
Method (i.e., superiors) seated on one side of the partition
and half (i.e., subordinates) on the other side.
Participants and design Superiors and subordinates were paired anony-
mously, creating a total of 29 dyads.
The participants were 58 undergraduate stu- (2) The rst few computer screens explained the
dents enrolled in intermediate accounting at a production task, which was adapted from Chow
large Midwestern university.9 Half the participants (1983) and involved decoding numbers into letters.
were assigned to a multi-period condition. We Participants were issued a le folder containing a
used participants responses in each period of this dierent decoding key for each session. All partic-
condition to test the hypotheses about the pattern ipants then completed a 3-min practice session to
of negotiation strategies and outcomes across peri- ensure they understood the basic task.
ods. The remaining participants were assigned to a (3) Subordinates next completed three, 3-min
single period condition (hereafter, no expectation training sessions to learn their performance capa-
condition). We compared negotiation strategies bilities. They earned $0.02 for each item correctly
and outcomes from the no expectation condition decoded and received instant feedback on the total
to the negotiation strategies and outcomes in the number of items correctly and incorrectly decoded.
rst period of the multi-period condition (hereaf- After each session, subordinates received individ-
ter, expectation condition) to test the hypotheses ual summary information on the number of items
about the eects of an expectation of future budget attempted, correctly decoded, and incorrectly
negotiations. As explained below, it was common decoded. After the last training session, subordi-
knowledge at the beginning of the no expectation nates were asked for their best estimate of the
condition that there would be only one period, number of items they could correctly decode in
and thus no future budget negotiations. In con- 3 min.
trast, it was common knowledge at the beginning Superiors also completed three, 3-min practice
sessions to familiarize them with the task. How-
9
ever, they were neither paid nor given feedback
Participants received course credit for participation. Course
requirements called for students to either participate in exper-
to control for the eects of knowledge of their
iments or write a short paper. Almost all students opted for own performance on the subsequent budget-
experiment participation. setting process.
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 521

(4) Participants in the no expectation (expecta- mance capability. Superiors did not receive any
tion) condition were told there would be only one performance information about their own subor-
(several) work session(s), and thus the need to dinate. Thus, subordinates knew both the perfor-
engage in budget negotiations in only one mance capability range of past subordinates and
(several) period(s). Participants in the expectation their own performance capability, whereas superi-
condition also were told that they would ors knew only the performance capability range of
be matched with the same individual for all past subordinates.
periods. (8) Participants began the negotiation process.
(5) The next computer screens rst described To control for interpersonal factors, superiors
the subordinates and superiors respective com- and subordinates were separated by a room parti-
pensation schemes for the work session, and then tion and negotiations were conducted on a negoti-
described the budget-setting process. Their con- ation form (rather than face-to-face). Subordinates
tracts are described in Eqs. (1) and (2), respec- wrote their initial proposal on the negotiation
tively, with F = $1.00, A = $0.05, D = $0.08, and form. The administrator then took the form to
R = 100%.10 Both compensation schemes were the superior, who wrote a counteroer. An oer
illustrated to all participants through several and counteroer constituted one round. An equal
numerical examples. Participants were told that oer and counteroer indicated agreement and
subordinates would make the initial budget pro- ended the negotiation. If a dyad failed to reach
posal, that the budget negotiations would last a agreement within four rounds, the superior set
maximum of four rounds, and that superiors had the budget.
the authority to set the budget if there was not (9) Once the budget was set, subordinates com-
agreement after four rounds. pleted a 3-min work session. Afterwards, both
(6) Participants next answered a series of fac- members of a dyad were told the subordinates
tual questions about the number of periods, sub- performance in the work session. Pay for the per-
ordinate and superior compensation schemes, iod was calculated and communicated to the
and the budget-setting process. An incorrect participants.
answer on a question returned participants to (10) Participants in the no expectation condi-
the explanatory computer screens and then back tion then completed an exit questionnaire, were
to the incorrectly answered question. These forced paid, and exited the study. Participants in the
manipulation checks ensured that participants not expectation condition returned to step 8 (above)
only understood both the compensation schemes and completed steps 8 and 9 twice more before
and budget-setting process before beginning nego- being told time had expired. These participants
tiations, but, more importantly, that their expecta- then completed the exit questionnaire, were paid,
tions regarding future budget negotiations were and exited the study.
correct.
(7) Both superiors and subordinates were told Measures
the performance range for the third training ses-
sion, based on the performance of other partici- FORECAST is the subordinates estimate made
pants drawn from the same student population. at the end of the third training session about their
Participants were told, Prior studies of this same performance capabilities in a 3-min work session.
task have shown that in the third training session BID and COUNTER are the subordinates initial
95% of the subordinates classify between 32 and budget proposals and superiors initial counterof-
54 items correctly. From the third training ses- fers, respectively, made in the negotiations. DIFF
sion, subordinates also knew their own perfor- is the dierence between the superiors and subor-
dinates initial negotiation positions, measured as
COUNTER  BID. BUDGET is the nal budget,
10
The minimum compensation for subordinates was F. All and PERFORM is the number of items subordi-
superiors were endowed with $1.00 per period. nates correctly decoded in a work session.
522 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

Results Hypothesis 2 predicts that superiors and subor-


dinates who expect future negotiations are more
Tests indicate no signicant dierence across likely to reach agreement. In the expectation
the no expectation and expectation conditions condition 47% of the dyads reached agreement,
for any of the following variables for either subor- compared to only 21% in the no expectation con-
dinates or superiors: age, GPA, length of work dition. A test of proportions (Agresti & Finlay,
experience, gender, or performance capability. In 1986) indicates a marginally signicant dierence
addition, there is no signicant dierence between in these percentages (z = 1.54; p < 0.06), providing
subordinate performance in the third training ses- some support for H2.
sion and FORECAST, suggesting that subordi- Hypothesis 3 predicts that when superiors and
nates believed they had mastered the task by the subordinates fail to reach agreement, subordinates
end of the third training session. who expect future negotiations will under perform
Tests of the hypotheses reported below are the budget by a smaller amount. Panel C of Table
based on non-parametric statistical tests.11 We 1 contains descriptive statistics for dyads that
report one-tailed (two-tailed) p-values for direc- failed to reach agreement. For these dyads, the
tional (non-directional) hypotheses. median for PERFORM  BUDGET was 3.00
in the expectation condition versus 40.00 in the
no expectation condition. The results of a
Tests of hypotheses
MannWhitney test indicate the dierence is sig-
nicant (z = 2.14; p < 0.02).12 Additional analysis
Expectation of future budget negotiations
using the Wilcoxon test indicates that subordinates
Descriptive statistics for all dyads in the expec-
in the no expectation condition performed signi-
tation and no expectation conditions are reported
cantly below their budgets (z = 2.05; p < 0.04),
in Panel A of Table 1. Hypothesis 1 predicts that
whereas subordinates in the expectation condition
the dierence in superiors and subordinates ini-
did not (z = 0.56; p < 0.58). These results are con-
tial negotiation positions will be smaller for dyads
sistent with H3.
that expect future budget negotiations. The med-
Hypothesis 4 predicts that when superiors and
ian for DIFF is 10.00 in the expectation condition
subordinates reach agreement, the expectation of
versus 18.50 in the no expectation condition.
future negotiations will not aect the degree by
Results from a MannWhitney test indicate the
which subordinates over perform the budget.
dierence between settings is signicant (z = 2.13;
Panel B of Table 1 contains descriptive statistics
p < 0.02), consistent with H1.
for dyads that reached agreement. For these
Additional analysis indicates that the signicant
dyads, the median for PERFORM  BUDGET
eect is due primarily to subordinates. Subordi-
was 5.00 in the expectation condition versus 6.00
nates who expect future budget negotiations have
in the no expectation setting. The results of a
signicantly less extreme median initial negotia-
MannWhitney test indicate the dierence is not
tion positions (i.e., BID) than do subordinates
signicant (z = 0.69; p < 0.25), consistent with
who do not expect future negotiations (40.00 ver-
H4.13
sus 31.00; z = 2.37; p < 0.01). Although the direc-
Across all dyads, median subordinate perfor-
tion of the dierence in superiors median initial
mance was higher for subordinates who expected
negotiation positions (i.e., COUNTER) is consis-
future budget negotiations (46.00 versus 29.50),
tent with superiors who expect future budget nego-
and the dierence is marginally signicant
tiations taking less extreme initial positions (48.00
(z = 1.42; p < 0.08). Consistent with the results
versus 51.00), the dierence is not signicant
(z = 0.66; p < 0.26).
12
A ranked ANCOVA with FORECAST as the covariate
yields a qualitatively similar result.
11 13
We employed non-parametric tests because of their less A ranked ANCOVA with FORECAST as the covariate
restrictive assumptions (Hollander & Wolfe, 1973). yields a qualitatively similar result.
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 523

reported above, this performance eect is due to Hypothesis 7 predicts that the likelihood of
subordinates in dyads that failed to reach agree- agreement will increase over time. Of the 15 dyads,
ment. An expectation of future budget negotia- 67% reached agreement in period 3 versus only
tions not only caused these subordinates to react 47% in period 1. These percentages are in the pre-
to their imposed budgets in a less spiteful manner, dicted direction, and a test of proportions indi-
but this expectation also appears to have com- cates that the dierence in these percentages is
pletely eliminated subordinates spiteful behavior marginally signicant (z = 1.34; p < 0.09). These
as evidenced by the fact that they did not signi- results provide some support for H7.
cantly under perform their budgets.14 Hypothesis 8a predicts that budgets in periods
two and three will reect ratcheting. To test this
Negotiation strategies and outcomes across periods hypothesis, we selected each occurrence in period
Descriptive statistics for each period of the j  1 (j = 2, 3) where subordinate performance
multi-period condition are reported in Table 2. either exceeded or lagged the budget. We then cre-
Hypothesis 5 predicts that superiors and subordi- ated a new variable called RATCHETj, which is
nates are more likely to reach agreement in the the change in the budget from period j  1 to per-
current period if they reached agreement in the iod j, measured as BUDGETj  BUDGET(j1).
preceding period. Of the dyads that reached agree- Ratcheting implies that RATCHETj should be
ment in period i (i = 1, 2), 81% reached agreement positive (negative) when performance was higher
in period i + 1. In contrast, only 43% of the dyads (lower) than the budget in period j  1.
that failed to reach agreement in period i reached There were 15 occurrences in period j  1 where
agreement in period i + 1. These percentages are subordinate performance exceeded the budget, and
in the predicted direction, and a test of propor- 14 occurrences in period j  1 where subordinate
tions indicates that these percentages are signi- performance lagged the budget, for a total of 29
cantly dierent (z = 2.31; p < 0.01), consistent occurrences. RATCHETj was in the predicted
with H5. direction 22 times, in the wrong direction two
Hypothesis 6 predicts that the dierence times, and zero in ve cases. This pattern is consis-
between superiors and subordinates initial nego- tent with the pattern predicted in H8a, and a sign
tiation positions will decrease over time. Of the test indicates that the pattern is signicant
15 dyads in the multi-period condition, DIFF (p < 0.01). These results support H8a, and are con-
was smaller in period 3 than in period 1 for 12 sistent with superiors engaging in ratcheting.
dyads. This pattern is in the predicted direction, We also examined the degree of ratcheting for
and a sign test indicates that the pattern is signi- the 29 occurrences in period j  1 where subordi-
cant (p < 0.02). The results of a Wilcoxon test indi- nate performance either exceeded or lagged the
cate that the magnitude of the decrease is also budget. For each occurrence, we calculated two
signicant (z = 2.02; p < 0.03). The median DIFF new variables. The rst, BASEj, measures the mag-
decreased from 10.00 in period 1 to 4.00 in period nitude of a 100% ratchet in period j as PER-
3. These results are consistent with H6. FORM(j1)  BUDGET(j1). The second,
DEGREEj, measures the degree of ratcheting in
period j as RATCHETj/BASEj.
14
Hypothesis 8b predicts that when subordinates
The performance eects, particularly the fact that perfor-
mance is not signicantly below the budget for subordinates in
overperformed the budget in period j  1, the bud-
dyads that did not reach agreement, are inconsistent with get in period j will not reect full ratcheting. For
subordinates curtailing performance in anticipation of superiors the 15 occurrences in period j  1 where subordi-
ratcheting (Weitzman, 1980). The lack of a dynamic incentive nate performance exceeded the budget, the median
eect indicates that either the conditions were not appropriate RATCHET is 3.00 and the median BASE is 8.00.
for subordinates to curtail their performance (e.g., subordinates
believed the ratchet adjustment factor would be small) or other
The results of a Wilcoxon test indicate a signicant
factors present in the setting (e.g., incentives to act coopera- dierence (z = 2.48; p < 0.01). Further, the median
tively) dominated the dynamic incentive eect. DEGREE is only 0.38, indicating that the budget
524 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

in period j increased by only 38% of the excess in budget negotiations provides incentives for superi-
period j  1 of subordinate performance over the ors and subordinates to act as if they are concerned
budget. These results indicate that the budget does about the others outcomesand thus incentives to
not reect full ratcheting, consistent with H8b. act cooperativelybecause doing so has potential
We did not provide a prediction about the strategic benets (Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993; Pruitt
degree of ratcheting when subordinates underper- & Rubin, 1986; Rubin et al., 1994). Specically, act-
formed the budget in period j  1 due to ambiguity ing cooperatively increases the likelihood of superi-
about the expected eect. For the 14 occurrences ors and subordinates developing sustainable
in period j  1 where subordinate performance cooperative solutions across future periods, even
lagged the budget, the median RATCHET is though such solutions are not enforceable ex-post
6.50 and the median BASE is 14.50. The results in any given period. Our results are consistent with
of a Wilcoxon test indicate a signicant dierence an expectation of future negotiations causing supe-
(z = 2.20; p < 0.02). The median DEGREE is 0.34, riors and subordinates to act more cooperatively.
indicating that the budget in period j decreased by Superiors and subordinates who expect future bud-
only 34% of the excess in period j  1 of the bud- get negotiations have smaller dierences in their ini-
get over subordinate performance. Consistent with tial negotiation positions and are more likely to
the results above, these results indicate that superi- reach agreement on budgets. Further, subordinates
ors did not engage in full ratcheting.15 who expect future budget negotiations have higher
performance, both in absolute terms and relative
to their budgets, than subordinates in a single period
Discussion negotiation.
The second issue we examine is the pattern of
This paper reports the results of an experiment negotiation strategies and outcomes across periods
designed to determine the eects of temporal inter- to assess the eect of prior budget negotiations and
dependencea fundamental aspect of budget nego- outcomes on current period negotiation strategies
tiations in multi-period settingson budget and outcomes. Temporal interdependence implies
negotiation strategies and outcomes. Because an that individuals can learn from and react to nego-
expectation of future interactions is a necessary con- tiation strategies and outcomes from prior periods.
dition for temporal interdependence, one issue we Our results indicate that in a repeated negotiation
examine is the eect of the presence versus absence setting, superiors and subordinates react to negoti-
of an expectation of future budget negotiations with ation strategies and outcomes from prior periods
the same individual on current period negotiation in predictable ways. Superiors initial negotiation
strategies and outcomes. An expectation of future positions and the budget each reect subordinate
performance in the preceding period, consistent
15
with superiors using subordinate performance to
Because the budget is a function of the superiors and
subordinates initial negotiation positions, ratcheting in the
update their beliefs about subordinate perfor-
budget suggests that superiors and/or subordinates ratcheted mance capability. Specically, superiors pursue
their initial negotiation positions. Accordingly, we performed higher (lower) budgets when subordinate perfor-
the ratchet analysis for the superiors initial negotiation mance in the preceding period exceeded (lagged)
position (i.e., COUNTER), now dening RATCHETj as the budget. In addition, the likelihood of agree-
COUNTERj  COUNTER(j1). The results for COUNTER
mirror the results for BUDGET: RATCHET is in the predicted
ment in a particular period depends on the prior
direction 22 times, in the wrong direction two times, and zero in period. Once a particular superior and subordinate
ve cases. For those subordinates whose performance exceeded reach agreement, they are more likely to continue
the budget, the median RATCHET of 3.00 is signicantly to reach agreement in future periods. Further,
smaller than the median BASE of 8.00 (z = 2.68, p < 0.01), and the dierence between superiors and subordinates
the median DEGREE is 0.33. For those subordinates whose
performance lagged the budget, the median RATCHET of
initial negotiation positions decreases across peri-
6.00 is signicantly smaller than median BASE of 14.50 ods, and the likelihood of negotiation agreement
(z = 2.20, p < 0.02), and the median DEGREE is 0.68. increases.
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 525

Table 1
Mean, median, and standard deviation for selected negotiation strategies and outcomes by expectation of future budget negotiations
Panel A: all dyads Panel B: dyads Panel C: dyads
that agreed that did not agree
Expect future Expect future Expect future
negotiations negotiations negotiations
Yesa Noa Yes No Yes No
Number of dyads 15 14 7 3 8 11
FORECASTb 47.27 47.36 48.00 44.67 46.63 48.09
47.00 47.00 48.00 45.00 46.00 48.00
6.11 3.03 5.26 1.53 7.07 2.95
BIDc 36.13 31.21 42.29 39.33 30.75 29.00
40.00 31.00 45.00 40.00 37.50 30.00
12.86 5.77 5.34 2.08 15.33 4.15
COUNTERd 50.33 56.21 47.00 44.33 53.25 59.45
48.00 51.00 45.00 41.00 49.00 54.00
15.87 20.49 10.23 6.66 19.83 21.98
DIFFe 15.00 25.00 6.43 5.00 22.50 30.45
10.00 18.50 8.00 3.00 14.50 25.00
16.30 22.44 4.69 6.24 19.36 22.23
BUDGETf 44.67 47.07 44.86 40.33 44.50 48.91
45.00 43.50 45.00 41.00 43.50 45.00
9.85 14.14 8.07 2.08 8.07 15.55
PERFORMg 43.87 26.79 48.14 48.00 40.13 21.00
46.00 29.50 47.00 48.00 45.00 10.00
10.81 22.30 5.70 2.00 13.10 21.77
PERFORM  BUDGET 0.80 20.29 3.29 7.67 4.38 27.91
1.00 16.50 5.00 6.00 3.00 40.00
15.59 32.83 9.10 3.79 19.60 33.16
Percentage of 47 21 N/A N/A N/A N/A
dyads agreeing
a
The data for the expectation of future budget negotiations condition is from the rst period of the multi-period setting while the
data for the expectation of no future budget negotiations condition is from the single-period setting.
b
FORECAST is the subordinates estimate made at the end of the third training session about their performance capabilities in a
work session.
c
BID is the subordinates initial budget proposal in the negotiation.
d
COUNTER is the superiors initial counteroer in the negotiation.
e
DIFF is the dierence between the superiors and subordinates initial negotiation positions, measured as COUNTER  BID.
f
BUDGET is the nal budget.
g
PERFORM is the number of items subordinates correctly decoded in a work session.

These results have several implications for Young, 1985; Young et al., 1993) may not general-
research and practice. First, our results highlight ize to the multi-period setting. For example, we
the importance of temporal interdependence, doc- replicate the nding in Fisher et al. (2002) that
umenting how it aects negotiation strategies and subordinates in single-period settings, where there
outcomes both in the current period and across is no expectation of future negotiations, act spite-
periods. An implication is that results from ful and signicantly under perform the budget
research that examines single-period budgeting set- when superiors impose a budget following a failed
tings (e.g., Fisher et al., 2002; Waller, 1988; negotiation. However, we nd that this result does
526 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

Table 2 ratchets generally are equal. This symmetrical rat-


Mean, median, and standard deviation for selected negotiation cheting contrasts with Leone and Rock (2002),
strategies and outcomes by period for multi-period setting
who found asymmetrical ratcheting based on an
Period examination of budgeting at one rm. They found
1 2 3 that at their sample rm, upward ratchets were
Number of dyads 15 15 15 more than twice as large as the downward ratchets.
BIDa 36.13 35.87 36.47 This dierence merits further research.
40.00 40.00 38.00 Finally, our results indicate that temporal inter-
12.86 10.51 11.01 dependence has performance benets, particularly
COUNTERb 50.33 48.13 43.13 when superiors impose a budget following a failed
48.00 45.00 42.00 negotiation. Firms might be able to increase the
15.87 11.26 7.61 benets induced by temporal interdependence by
DIFFc 15.00 12.27 6.67 making the interdependence more salient to its
10.00 9.00 4.00 employees. Firms, therefore, may want to empha-
16.30 13.58 7.30 size to their employees the repeated nature of
BUDGETd 44.67 43.93 41.53 many budget settings.
45.00 45.00 42.00 This study has several limitations. First, as with
9.85 8.84 7.74 all laboratory experiments, the results depend on
PERFORMe 43.87 36.73 43.00 the specic experimental task, treatments, and
46.00 43.00 49.00 parameter values used. Second, employment con-
10.81 19.21 16.21 tracts in practice are determined endogenously.
Percentage of dyads agreeing 47 60 67 However, although the contracts we used in this
a
BID is the subordinates initial budget proposal in the study are common in practice, they were set exog-
negotiation. enously. Third, superiors used budgets solely as an
b
COUNTER is the superiors initial counteroer in the input into the subordinates contract; superiors did
negotiation.
c not use budgets for making resource allocations.
DIFF is the dierence between the superiors and subordi-
nates initial negotiation positions, measured as Fourth, to control for a variety of factors, partic-
COUNTER  BID. ipants could only communicate budget proposals
d
BUDGET is the nal budget. via a form. In practice, however, negotiation often
e
PERFORM is the number of items subordinates correctly involves personal interaction between the negotia-
decoded in a work session.
tors and greater information exchange. Finally, in
examining the pattern of negotiation strategies and
not hold when subordinates expect future budget outcomes across periods, we chose to focus on just
negotiations with the superiors. one multi-period setting. Although our setting of
Second, our results for superiors initial negotia- repeated negotiations with the same individuals is
tion positions across periods and the budget levels arguably the most common budget negotiation
across periods are consistent with superiors engag- setting in practice, limiting the study to just this
ing in ratcheting. Although it is not surprising that setting prevented us from providing evidence
superiors engage in ratcheting given the presence of about the relative importance of dierent factors
information asymmetry about subordinates per- potentially present in multi-period settings. These
formance capabilities, we nd that the degree of limitations provide opportunities for additional
ratcheting is low, indicating that the budgets reect research.
only a relatively small portion of the dierence
between the subordinates performance in the pre-
ceding period and the budget, regardless of Acknowledgements
whether subordinate performance in the preceding
period exceeded or lagged the budget. In addition, This paper has beneted from the comments of
the magnitudes of the upward and downward Terry Neal, Robert Ramsay, Steve Salterio, Alan
J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528 527

Webb, participants of the 2002 ABO Research Fisher, J. G., Frederickson, J. R., & Peer, S. A. (2000). The
Conference and workshop participants at the Uni- budgeting process: An experimental investigation of the
eects of negotiation. The Accounting Review, 75(January),
versity of Kentucky, University of South Florida, 93114.
and University of Waterloo. Indiana University Fisher, J. G., Frederickson, J. R., & Peer, S. A. (2002). The
Kelley School of Business provided nancial eect of information asymmetry on negotiated budgets: An
support. empirical investigation. Accounting, Organizations and Soci-
ety, 27(January), 2744.
Frederickson, J. R. (1992). Relative performance information:
References The eects of common uncertainty and contract type on
agent eort. The Accounting Review, 67(October), 647
Agresti, A., & Finlay, B. (1986). Statistical methods for the 669.
social sciences (2nd ed.). San Francisco: Macmillan. Frederickson, J. R., & Cloyd, C. B. (1998). The eects of
Anthony, R. J., & Govindarajan, V. (2001). Management performance cues, subordinate susceptibility to social inu-
control systems. New York: Irwin. ences, and the nature of the subordinates private informa-
Atkinson, A. A., Banker, R. D., Kaplan, R. S., & Young, S. M. tion on budgetary slack. Advances in Accounting, 14,
(2001). Management accounting. Upper Saddle River NJ: 89115.
Prentice Hall. Frederickson, J. R., & Waller, W. S. (2005). Carrot or stick?
Axelrod, R. M. (1990). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Contract frame and use of decision-inuencing information
Penguin Books. in a principal-agent setting. Journal of Accounting
Bazerman, M. (1998). Judgment in managerial decision making. Research(December), 709733.
New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. Greenhalgh, L. (1999). Managing conict. In R. J. Lewicki, D.
Benton, A. A., Kelley, H. H., & Liebling, B. (1972). Eects of M. Saunders, & J. W. Minton (Eds.), Negotiation: Readings,
extremity of oers and concession rate on the outcomes of exercises, and cases (3rd ed.). New York, NY: Irwin/
bargaining. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, McGraw-Hill.
24, 7383. Henderson, R. I. (2000). Compensation management in a
Ben-Yoav, O., & Pruitt, D. G. (1984a). Resistance to yielding knowledge-based world. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice
and the expectation of cooperative future interaction in Hall.
negotiation. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 20, Hollander, M., & Wolfe, D. (1973). Nonparametric statistical
323353. methods. New York, NY: Wiley.
Ben-Yoav, O., & Pruitt, D. G. (1984b). Accountability to Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. The Bell Journal
constituents: A two-edged sword. Organizational Behavior of Economics, 13, 324340.
and Human Performance, 34, 282295. Holthausen, R., Larcker, D., & Sloan, R. (1995). Annual bonus
Chandra, G. (1993). The behavioral aspects of budgeting. In R. schemes and the manipulation of earnings. Journal of
Rachlin & H. Sweeney (Eds.), Handbook of budgeting (3rd Accounting and Economics, 19, 2974.
ed.). New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. Janssen, O., & van de Vliert, E. (1996). Concern for the others
Chow, C. J. (1983). The eects of job standard tightness and goals: Key to (de-)escalation of conict. International
compensation scheme on performance: An exploration of Journal of Conict Management, 7(2), 99121.
linkages. The Accounting Review, 58(October), 667685. Kersten, G. E. (2001). Modeling distributive and integrative
Chow, C., Cooper, J., & Haddad, K. (1991). The eects of pay negotiations: Reviews and revised characterization. Group
schemes and ratchets on budgetary slack and performance: Decision and Negotiation, 10, 493514.
A multiperiod experiment. Accounting, Organizations and Larrick, R. P., & Blount, S. (1995). Social context in tacit
Society, 4760. bargaining games: Consequences for perceptions of anity
Chow, C., Cooper, J., & Waller, W. (1988). Participative and cooperative behavior. In R. M. Kramer & D. M.
budgeting: Eects of a truth-inducing pay scheme and Messick (Eds.), Negotiation as a social process. Thousand
information asymmetry on slack and performance. The Oaks, CA: Sage Publications, Inc.
Accounting Review(January), 111122. Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods: A survey of experimental
Crystal, G. S. (1993). Budgets and performance compensation. research. In J. H. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), The handbook
In R. Rachlin & H. Sweeney (Eds.), Handbook of Budgeting of experimental economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni-
(3rd ed.). New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. versity Press.
Demski, J. S., & Feltham, G. (1978). Economic incentives in Leone, A. J., & Rock, S. (2002). Empirical tests of budget
budgetary control systems. The Accounting Review, ratcheting and its eect on managers discretionary accrual
53(April), 336359. choices. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33, 43
Dillard, J., & Fisher, J. G. (1990). Compensation schemes, skill 67.
level, and task performance: An experimental examination. Lewicki, J., Litterer, J., Minton, J., & Saunders, M. (1994).
Decision Sciences, 21(Winter), 121137. Negotiation. Homewood, IL: Irwin.
528 J.G. Fisher et al. / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 511528

Luft, J. (1994). Bonus and penalty incentives: Contract choice Rubin, J. A., Pruitt, D., & Kim, S. H. (1994). Social conict:
by employees. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 18, Escalation, stalemate, and settlement. New York, NY:
181206. McGraw-Hill.
Mannix, E. A., Tinsley, C. H., & Bazerman, M. (1995). Thompson, L. (1990). Negotiation behavior and outcomes:
Negotiating over time: Impediments to integrative solutions. Empirical evidence and theoretical issues. Psychological
Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 62, Bulletin, 108(3), 515532.
241251. Umapathy, S. (1987). Current budgeting practices in US
Milgrom, P. R., & Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, organization industry. New York: Quorum Books.
& management. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. Waller, W. S. (1988). Slack in participative budgeting: The joint
Murnighan, J. K., & Roth, A. E. (1983). Expecting continuing eect of a truth-inducing pay scheme and risk preferences.
play in prisoners dilemma games. Journal of Conict Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13, 8798.
Resolution, 27, 279300. Weitzman, M. L. (1976). The new Soviet incentive model. The
Murphy, K. (2000). Performance standards in incentive con- Bell Journal of Economics, 7(Spring), 252257.
tracts. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30, 245278. Weitzman, M. L. (1980). The Ratchet Principle and perfor-
Pillutla, M. M., & Murnighan, J. K. (1995). Being fair or mance incentives. The Bell Journal of Economics, 11(Spring),
appearing fair: Strategic behavior in ultimatum bargaining. 302308.
Academy of Management Journal, 38(5), 14081427. Young, S. M. (1985). Participative budgeting: The eects of risk
Pruitt, D. G. (1981). Negotiation behavior. New York, NY: aversion and asymmetric information on budgetary slack.
Academic Press. Journal of Accounting Research(Autumn), 829842.
Pruitt, D. G., & Carnevale, P. J. (1993). Negotiation in social Young, S. M., Fisher, J., & Lindquist, T. M. (1993). The eects
conict. Pacic Grove, CA: Brooks/Cole Publishing. of intergroup and intragroup cooperation on slack in a
Pruitt, D. G., & Rubin, J. Z. (1986). Social conict. New York, manufacturing setting. The Accounting Review, 68(July),
NY: Mc-Graw-Hill. 468481.

Вам также может понравиться