Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 20

2

Punishment and Political


Economy
Alessandro De Giorgi

Since its origins in the first decades of the objective causes that social scientists could
19th century, and for most of the 20th cen- discover through adequate methodologies,
tury, criminology has been the study of and its ambition to unveil objective truths
crime rather than the study of punishment: about criminal behavior. Most importantly,
punishments, criminal policies, and strate- the emerging new criminology (Taylor
gies of social control were not the objects et al., 1973) would question the political
of criminological analysis, but rather tools implications of the positivist approach in
to govern the criminal question. The main particular, its emphasis on the elaboration of
objective of criminology, particularly in its strategies that could effectively address the
positivist currents, was the scientific produc- causes of deviance, correct criminals, and
tion of effective strategies for the govern- ideally eradicate crime itself.
ment of deviance and criminality (Pasquino, The political context of the 1960s, with
1980). its radical critique of all repressive institu-
Between the late 1960s and the early tions (family, university, asylum, prison), and
1970s, however, these epistemological bound- the irruption of Marxism into the academic
aries were challenged by the emergence of field, laid a fertile ground for the emergence
radical perspectives on punishment and social of critical perspectives on social and penal
control. The main target of this new critical control.1 The forms of punishment, rather
approach was exactly the positivist paradigm than the causes of crime, became the focus of
that had dominated the field of criminologi- the new criminological agenda. In particular
cal research since its very birth. The rejection the prison, the technology of punishment
of what David Matza famously defined as peculiar to modernity, became the object
the correctional perspective (1969: 1540) of critical inquiry. Several studies began to
concerned in the first place the theoretical investigate the historical trajectory through
and methodological tenets of positivist crim- which imprisonment had come to replace
inology its presumed scientific neutrality, earlier forms of punishment and the reasons
its assumption that social problems had for its persistence in contemporary societies.

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 40 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 41

Looking beyond the rhetorical legitimation Taken together, these two perspectives
of the prison the defense of society from contend that penal politics plays a very
crime in the name of public safety critical different role than defending society from
scholars began to reveal its latent functions. crime: both the historical emergence of
A first direction of analysis focused on specific penal practices and their persistence
the role of penal systems in the history of in contemporary societies, are structurally
capitalist societies. The new revisionist his- linked to the dominant relations of produc-
tories of punishment that appeared between tion and to the hegemonic forms of work
the late 1960s and the early 1980s decon- organization. In a society divided into classes,
structed mainstream penal historiography, criminal law cannot reflect any general
criticizing in particular its teleological bias interest:
that is to say, its tendency to represent the
history of punishment as an ongoing process The would-be theories of criminal law that derive
the principles of penal policy from the interests of
of reform and as a linear advancement toward society as a whole are conscious or unconscious
more humane sanctions. Against this reform- distortions of reality. Society as a whole does not
ist historiography (Ignatieff, 1983: 76), char- exist, except in the fantasy of the jurists. In reality
acterized by a narrative of progress that we are faced only with classes, with contradic-
obscured the role played by penal technolo- tory, conflicting interests. Every historically given
system of penal policy bears the imprint of the
gies in the consolidation of class power, revi- class interests of that class which instigated it.
sionist historians attempted to re-politicize the (Pashukanis, 1978: 174)
history of punishment, reconstructing it from
the point of view of the privileged targets of Whether in the context of a structural cri-
social control: the working classes, the poor, tique of bourgeois legal ideologies (as in the
the dispossessed (Platt, 1969; Foucault, 1977; work of Evgeny Pashukanis just quoted), of
Ignatieff, 1978; Melossi and Pavarini, 1981). a cultural analysis of the role of moral panics
A second body of research emerged toward in policing the crisis of late-capitalist socie-
the end of the 1970s and focused on the ties (Hall et al., 1978), or of a deconstruction
transformations of penality in contemporary of penal discourses as ideological state
late-capitalist social formations (Quinney, apparatuses (Althusser, 1971), the ground
1980). In this context, changes in penal had been set for a materialist critique of pun-
practices and specifically variations in the ishment as a tool of class control.
severity of punishment, as measured by rates
of imprisonment were analyzed against the
background of the transformation of class
relations in advanced capitalist societies THE FOUNDATIONS OF THE
(Spitzer, 1975; Quinney, 1980; Adamson, POLITICAL ECONOMY OF
1984). Thus, while revisionist historians of PUNISHMENT
punishment unveiled the historical connec-
tions between the invention of the peniten- The sociological foundations of what would
tiary and the birth of a capitalist system of later become the political economy of punish-
production based on the extensive exploita- ment had already been laid down in the late
tion of wage labor, neo-Marxist critics of 1930s by Georg Rusche and Otto Kirchheimer
contemporary penal politics examined the in the early pages of their classic Punishment
persistence of that same connection in late- and Social Structure:
capitalist societies, analyzing the relationship
Every system of production tends to discover
between current penal forms and capitalist
punishments which correspond to its productive
labor markets (for a review of this literature, relationships. It is thus necessary to investigate the
see Chiricos and DeLone, 1992; Melossi, origin and fate of penal systems, the use or avoid-
1998; De Giorgi, 2006: 1939). ance of specific punishments, and the intensity of

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 41 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


42 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

penal practices as they are determined by social confinement of beggars, criminals, prosti-
forces, above all by economic and then fiscal tutes and the idle poor in workhouses, poor-
forces. (1939 [2003]: 5)2
houses and houses of correction throughout
Rusche and Kirchheimer argued that a socio- Europe (Foucault, 1965: 3864) contributed
logical understanding of the historical and to transform the free and rightless proletar-
contemporary transformations of penal sys- iat (Marx, 1867 [1976]: 896) created by the
tems should be informed by a structural crisis of the feudal economy into a docile,
analysis of the connections between penal obedient and disciplined labor force ready
technologies and transformations of the to be incorporated in the emerging sites of
economy in particular, the transition of capitalist production. The historical emer-
modern societies from a pre-capitalist to a gence, consolidation, and ongoing transfor-
capitalist mode of production. mation of modern penal practices would
The birth of what Michel Foucault would thus reflect capitals need to carve a docile
later define as disciplinary practices and and laborious workforce out of the unruly,
institutions of confinement in place of the undisciplined and sometimes riotous dan-
torturous spectacles of suffering staged in gerous classes constantly generated by capi-
the main squares of European cities until tal itself as a by-product of its movement
the 18th century (see Spierenburg, 1984), of accumulation by dispossession (Harvey,
should thus be interpreted as a constitutive 2003: 13782).
part of the broader shift toward a new system According to this materialist framework,
of production based on the complete separa- the specific configurations of the relation-
tion between the workers and the owner- ship between penal technologies and eco-
ship of the conditions for the realization of nomic structures would be shaped by the
their labor (Marx, 1867 [1976]: 874). Against logic of less eligibility. This concept, first
the background of a new emerging class developed in England in the early 19th cen-
structure shaped by the relation between tury, had provided the main rationale for
capital and wage labor, the political economy the English Poor Laws of 1834. In its early
of proto-capitalist societies started to con- formulation, the principle held that:
ceive the human body as a resource to be The first and most essential of all conditions,
exploited in the process of production, rather a principle which we find universally admitted,
than wasted in the symbolic rituals of corpo- even by those whose practice is at variance with it,
ral punishment: is, that his [the relief recipients] situation on the
whole shall not be made really or apparently
In fact the two processes the accumulation so eligible [i.e., desirable] as the situation of the
of men and the accumulation of capital independent laborer of the lowest class. (Quoted
cannot be separated; it would not have been in Piven and Cloward, 1993: 35)
possible to solve the problem of the accumulation
of men without the growth of an apparatus According to this logic, public assistance
of production capable of both sustaining them should never raise the living conditions of
and using them; conversely, the techniques that
the destitute above the standards of life avail-
made the cumulative multiplicity of men useful
accelerated the accumulation of capital. (Foucault, able to the poorest among the working poor;
1991: 221) otherwise, public relief would become more
eligible (more desirable) than waged work.
Modern penal institutions played a decisive Georg Rusches intuition was to apply the
role in the consolidation of a process of capi- principle of less eligibility to the analysis
talist production based on the factory and of penal change: since the aim of any penal
grounded in the commodification of human system is to deter the most marginalized
labor (Marx, 1867 [1976]: 896926). At the classes of society from committing crimes
outset of the bourgeois revolution, the great of desperation (Rusche, 1933 [1978]: 4)

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 42 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 43

thus violating the capitalist injunction to What Rusche is criticizing here is the repre-
rely only on their work to survive it follows sentation of the history of punishment as a
that the conditions of life generally available sequence of humanitarian reforms toward
in the lowest regions of the class structure civility. This progressive description of penal
will invariably set the standards of living for transformation is unrealistic, Rusche argues,
those who are caught in the net of the penal because the principle of less eligibility
system. In Rusches words: to which any penal system must ultimately
conform sets a structural limit to any
Although experience shows the rich to occasion- reform effort or civilization process. The
ally break the law too, the fact remains that a
substantial majority of those who fill the prisons
pace and direction of penal change are
come from the lower strata of the proletariat. dictated by the overall situation of the work-
Therefore, if it is not to contradict its goals, ing class, and in a capitalist economy that
the penal system must be such that the most situation is determined in the first place by
criminally predisposed groups will prefer a minimal the labor market. The dynamics of the market
existence in freedom, even under the most
miserable conditions, to a life under the pressure
will establish the fair price of labor as
of the penal system. (1930 [1980]: 42) of any other commodity: an increase in the
supply of workers that are superfluous to
In Rusches view, however, the rationality of capitals average requirements for its own
penal practices is not limited to the negative valorization (Marx, 1867 [1976]: 782), will
logic of deterrence. Indeed, the function of lessen the value of human labor, worsening
less eligibility is not only to deter the most the conditions of the working class. The
disadvantaged classes from resorting to crime consequence, according to the principle of
(or public assistance) to survive, but also less eligibility, is that any increase in the
and even more importantly to force the size of the surplus population will prompt
poor to prefer any available working condi- harsher penal policies:
tions to the sanctions attached to criminal
behavior and refusal to work. By setting the Unemployed masses, who tend to commit crimes
standards of living for those punished below of desperation because of hunger and deprivation,
will only be stopped from doing so through cruel
the situation of the lowest socially signifi- penalties. The most effective penal policy seems
cant proletarian class (Rusche, 1933 [1978]: to be severe corporal punishment, if not ruthless
4), the principle of less eligibility ensures extermination In a society in which workers
that the most marginalized fractions of the are scarce, penal sanctions have a completely
working class will accept any level of exploi- different function. They do not have to stop
hungry people from satisfying elementary needs.
tation in the capitalist labor market, as this If everybody who wants to work can find work,
will be in most cases preferable to being pun- if the lowest social class consists of unskilled
ished for refusing to work at the given condi- workers and not of wretched unemployed work-
tions. In a capitalist economy, this means that ers, then punishment is required to make the
the situation of the marginal proletarian class unwilling work, and to teach other criminals that
they have to content themselves with the income
will shape criminal policies, and therefore of a honest worker. (Rusche, 1933 [1978]: 4)
the conditions of those who are punished:

One can also formulate this proposition as Consequently, the emergence or the demise
follows: all efforts to reform the punishment of of different penal practices cannot be ascribed
criminals are inevitably limited by the situation to the ideas of the reformers: penal change
of the lowest socially significant proletarian class is ultimately determined by the conditions
which society wants to deter from criminal acts. of labor and, more specifically, of the labor
All reform efforts, however humanitarian and
well meaning, which go beyond this restriction, market. This implies that no penal reform is
are condemned to utopianism. (Rusche, 1933 irreversible, and that humane punishments
[1978]: 4) will be quickly replaced by penal cruelty

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 43 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


44 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

whenever new socioeconomic conditions In Europe, by contrast, the significant


will prompt this shift; and penal institutions size of the industrial reserve army of labor
will turn again into places of pure torture, throughout much of the 19th century led to
suitable to deter even the most wretched an increase in penal severity and prompted
(Rusche, 1933 [1978]: 6)3. the demise of the idea of a productive prison
Rusche and Kirchheimer reinterpret the in favor of a purely punitive model of solitary
whole history of punishment institutions, confinement (Rusche and Kirchheimer,
from the late Middle Ages to the 1930s, 1939 [2003]: 1337). Toward the end of the
according to this basic principle. Thus, when 19th century, when the rise of an organized
in the 16th century Europe was affected by working class and changes in the labor
a huge demographic crisis (in part as a market led to an improvement of the living
consequence of the Thirty Years War), the standards of the poor, penal policies changed
labor force became scarce and wages started again: social policies were implemented in
to grow. These circumstances prompted sev- order to deal with a working class in turmoil,
eral European states to revise their policies and a new climate of penal tolerance spread
toward the poor: those who were able-bodied throughout European prisons.
had to be put to work. The imposition of At the end of their historical analysis,
work would deal with two crucial issues at Rusche and Kirchheimer hypothesized a fur-
once: on the one hand, the social problems ther shift toward the replacement of incar-
created by the visible presence of beggars, ceration by monetary sanctions. This section,
and on the other hand, the decline of capital- less convincing than the first part of the book,
ist profits caused by rising wages. Inspired is the result of Kirchheimers later reworking
by this new philosophy of poverty, the first of Rusches original manuscript.4
institutions for the confinement of the poor
spread throughout Europe: the Bridewell
in England, the Hpital General in France,
the Zuchtaus and the Spinnhaus in the THE PRISON AND THE FACTORY:
Netherlands. Confinement emerged as an PUNISHMENT AS CLASS CONTROL
alternative to corporal punishments for the
control of the marginal classes: its utility After its publication in 1939, Punishment
went beyond the segregation of socially and Social Structure was almost ignored
undesirable populations (poor, beggars, pros- for a long time, both by penal historians
titutes or criminals) from the rest of society, and criminologists. Its politico-economic
to include the possibility to transform critique of punishment virtually disappeared
through discipline the unruly criminal into from the purview of criminological theory
a productive worker. until a second edition of the book appeared
The future transformations of the peniten- in 1969, prompting a revival of Rusche and
tiary would also be influenced by changes in Kirchheimers structural perspective within
the labor markets. According to Rusche and the emerging field of critical criminology.
Kirchheimer, labor market dynamics explain Both the initial oblivion and the subsequent
the emergence of the Philadelphian model interest in the political economy of punish-
(based on solitary confinement), its later ment have a historical explanation: the first
crisis, and the ultimate prevalence of the edition of Rusche and Kirchheimers work
Auburn model (based on work in common appeared in a period characterized by a
during daytime and solitary confinement strong adversity to Marxism in the USA and
at night) in the USA a country whose capi- to the social sciences in Europe. The emer-
talist economy was suffering an acute short- gence of totalitarian regimes, the Second
age of labor in a period of rapid industrial World War, and later the postwar reconstruc-
development. tion with its technocratic approach to social

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 44 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 45

problems (including crime), all conjured side alone exists for our bourgeois historians. But,
against the success of Punishment and Social on the other hand, these new freedmen became
sellers of themselves only after they had been
Structure and its materialist perspective. It robbed of all their own means of production, and
was only in the transformed cultural atmos- of the guarantees of existence afforded by the old
phere of the 1960s and 1970s that the struc- feudal arrangements. (Marx, 1867 [1976]: 875)
tural critique elaborated by Rusche and
Kirchheimer could be rediscovered. Although The consolidation of the factory system gave
not always inspired by the neo-Marxist birth to the process Marx defined as real
framework, the revisionist histories of pun- subsumption of labor under capital (1867
ishment that appeared between the late 1960s [1976]: 10348). In the wake of capitalisms
and the early 1980s signaled the broad influ- struggle to establish itself as a new mode of
ence (whether acknowledged or not) of production, the various typologies of pre-
Punishment and Social Structure (Platt, 1969; capitalist work are subsumed under the gen-
Foucault, 1977; Ignatieff, 1978; Melossi and eral form of abstract wage labor. Independent
Pavarini, 1981).5 producers are transformed into a social labor
Elsewhere I have analyzed the relation- force, and the collective worker replaces the
ship between Marxist theory and the emer- individual worker:
gence of radical histories of punishment
(De Giorgi, 2006: 919). Here I will concen- [W]ith the development of the real subsumption
of labor under capital, or the specifically capitalist
trate specifically on Melossi and Pavarinis mode of production, the real lever of the overall
The Prison and the Factory, since this is labor process is not the individual worker. Instead,
the most systematic attempt to develop a labor-power socially combined and the various
politico-economic critique of the history of competing labor powers, which together form
the prison. This work situates the birth of the the entire production machine, participate in very
different ways in the immediate process of
penitentiary in the specific phase of capitalist making commodities, or, more accurately in this
development that Marx describes as primi- context, creating the product. (Marx, 1867 [1976]:
tive accumulation (Marx, 1867 [1976]: 873 103940)
940). In its early stages, capitalism had to
create the conditions for its own develop- Penal institutions played a crucial role in the
ment, and this required first of all the crea- historical process of subsumption of labor
tion of a capitalist labor force. In order to under capital. The penitentiary emerged as
establish a new system of production based an institution ancillary to the factory, as a
on wage labor, capital had first to separate penal technology whose power effects were
the producers from the means of production, consistent with the requirements of an emerg-
unraveling the economic structure of feudal ing industrial system of production. The
society; then, it had to transform the dis- unfolding of a disciplinary penal regime con-
possessed populations generated by that nects the internal dynamics of the prison
dissolution into a unified and disciplined (both in its material and ideological forms)
working class. to the transformations taking place in the
Capitalism liberated labor from feudal sphere of production. The logic of penal dis-
exploitation only to subject it to a purely cipline characterizes all the institutions of
economic form of subordination. Thus, the confinement that emerged since the end of
liberation of work took the form of an the 17th century:
expropriation of producers, replacing one
kind of enslavement with another: Over and above their specific functions, one over-
all aim united them: control over a rising prole-
Hence, the historical movement which changes tariat. The bourgeois state assigns to all of them
the producers into wage-workers, appears, on a directing role in the various moments of the
the one hand, as their emancipation from serf- formation, production and reproduction of the
dom and from the fetters of the guilds, and this factory proletariat: for society they are essential

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 45 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


46 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

instruments of social control, the aim of which is it represents the unconditional acceptance of
to secure for capital a workforce which by virtue that subordination as the only way to break
of its moral attitude, physical health, intellectual
capacity, orderliness, obedience, etc. will readily
free one day from this condition. Thus,
adapt to the whole regime of factory life and pro- the prison creates, on the one hand, the con-
duce the maximum amount of surplus labor. dition of prisoner, and it imposes, on the
(Melossi and Pavarini, 1981: 42) other, the prisoners subjection to a regime of
labor, obedience and discipline (elements
A new class of individuals is shaped by that constitute that very condition) as the
the penitentiary institution. The mission of only path to freedom. In this way, the suffer-
the prison is to inculcate new habits into the ing generated by the prison is ideologically
minds and bodies of the expropriated masses, represented as the consequence of the pris-
turning these unruly subjects into a disci- oners own refusal to submit to the discipline
plined labor force that, having interiorized of work.
an entirely new concept of time and space, The ideological normalization of the
will be ready to obey, execute orders, and prison is also reinforced by the contractual
comply with the rhythms of production logic of imprisonment as a punishment whose
dictated by the capitalist division of labor severity is measured by time:
(Thompson, 1967). Thus, the penal institu-
tion transforms the poor into a criminal, Deprivation of freedom, for a period stipulated
the criminal into a prisoner and, finally, the in the court sentence, is the specific form in
which modern, that is to say bourgeois-capitalist,
prisoner into a proletarian.
criminal law embodies the principle of equivalent
Outside the prison, in the factory, the recompense. This form is unconsciously yet
disciplined body of the individual proletar- deeply linked with the conception of man in the
ian will be associated with other bodies, abstract and abstract human labor measurable in
and the capitalist organization of labor will time. (Pashukanis, 1978: 1801)
turn this collective worker into a source of
surplus-value: The capitalistic principle of the exchange
of equivalents provides ideological legiti-
This discipline is the basic condition for the macy to the sanction of imprisonment through
extraction of surplus-value, and is the only real the same mystification that makes a work
lesson that bourgeois society has to propose contract fair: in both cases, exploitation,
to the proletariat. If legal ideology rules outside
production, within it reign servitude and inequal-
violence and subordination disappear from
ity. But the place of production is the factory. the smooth logic of the contractual reason.
Thus, the institutional function of the workhouses The legal fiction of punishment as retribu-
and later of the prisons was to teach the prole- tion conceals the disciplinary dimension of
tariat factory discipline. (Melossi and Pavarini, the prison in the same way as the economic
1981: 195)
fiction of the work contract as an exchange
of equivalents conceals the exploitative
Unlike Rusche and Kirchheimer, who had
dimension of wage labor.
focused exclusively on the instrumental role
of penal institutions in the material reproduc-
tion of a capitalist labor force, Melossi and
Pavarini insist on the crucial contribution
provided by disciplinary penal technologies THE LIMITS OF THE OLD
to the ideological reproduction of capitalist POLITICAL ECONOMY OF
relations of production. The prison is surely PUNISHMENT
a repressive institution because it imposes
to its confined populations a regime of depri- In an excoriating review of the 1939 edition
vation and complete subordination to author- of Punishment and Social Structure pub-
ity. But it is also an ideological tool because lished on the March-April 1940 issue of the

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 46 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 47

Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology, Despite having attracted the early attention
American legal theorist Jerome Hall came to of such prestigious scholars, Punishment and
the following conclusions about the signifi- Social Structure would almost disappear
cance of Rusche and Kirchheimers work: from the criminological landscape for almost
thirty years. Once the book reemerged from
[D]espite the importance of the thesis, abundant oblivion, the charge of economic reduction-
descriptive data, and many acute observations, ism and/or determinism would haunt again
the study falls far short of being an important Rusche and Kirchheimers work, along with
contribution to our present knowledge. For it
becomes rather quickly apparent that the authors
the materialist critique of punishment built
social situation, and historical-sociological analy- on it. Thus, in one of the founding texts in
sis of penal methods simmer down to economic the field of punishment and society, David
influence and economic becomes sometimes Garland concluded his chapter on the politi-
the conditions of the labor market, occasionally cal economy of punishment suggesting that:
methods of production, often the bias of domi-
nant economic classes, usually the bourgeoisie.
Punishment and Social Structure seriously overes-
As a consequence it is impossible to determine
timates the effective role of economic forces
just what their thesis is. The most persistent cur-
in shaping penal practice. It grossly understates
rent of their debate suggests, but never explicitly,
the importance of ideological and political forces
Marxist determinism. (1940: 9712)
and has little to say about the internal dynamics
of penal administration and their role in determin-
Jerome Hall was not alone in accusing Pun- ing policy. It gives no account of the symbols
ishment and Social Structure of economic and social messages conveyed by penal measures
to the law-abiding public and hence no sense of
determinism; indeed other early reviewers the ways in which these symbolic concerns help
agreed, although sometimes in a less shape the fabric of penal institutions. (Garland,
acrimonious tone, that this was the books 1990: 1089)
main theoretical flaw. For example, in a
review published in The Economic Journal, It is not surprising that these critiques
renowned British sociologist T.H. Marshall became particularly strong during the 1980s
argued that the authors try to press their and 1990s, when, as Dario Melossi writes
point too far and to make everything fit in in his introduction to the third edition of
too neatly, adding in particular that as soon Rusche and Kirchheimers book, Marxism
as their analysis focused on the 19th century was symbolically burnt at the stake, while
(and on the emergence of modern prisons), honoring the totem pole of cultural insight
the simple correlation between penal meth- (2003: ix). What is slightly more surprising,
ods and economic systems breaks down however, is that the distancing of critical
(Marshall, 1940: 1267). A few months later, sociologies of punishment from the struc-
David Riesman Jr added his voice to the tural approach took place despite the fact
choir, stating that Rusche and Kirchheimers that in those years advanced capitalist socie-
analysis neglected the role of politics, ties were witnessing the most significant
religion and culture in penal transformation, process of structural transformation since the
and concluding that social scientists have Industrial Revolution. In fact, those decades
a right to demand an analysis of the plural- witnessed the crisis of the Fordist-industrial
ity of factors, and an attempt to assign a paradigm, the demise of the Keynesian wel-
proper weight to each (1940: 1299). Finally, fare state, the globalization of production and
Chicago sociologist Ernest W. Burgess reit- consumption, the consolidation of a neolib-
erated in his own review of the book that eral model of socioeconomic (de)regulation6,
the authors overemphasize the relation of and particularly in the USA the unfolding
crime to economic conditions and ignore or of a punitive turn that would lead to a radical
minimize cultural and psychogenic factors reconfiguration of the penal landscape.
(1940: 986). However, with the notable exception of Stuart

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 47 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


48 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

Halls (1978) analysis of the role of penal points to the tendency of the political economy
discourses in the reproduction class (and of punishment to favor global accounts of penal
racial) hegemony in late capitalism (see also transformation over comparative analysis.
Laclau and Mouffe, 1985), the cultural turn
in the sociology of punishment coincided In some cases, these theoretical concerns
with (and to some extent encouraged) a have emerged from works directly or indi-
rejection of the Marxist political economy at rectly engaged with the neo-Marxist pers-
a time when this was most needed in order pective (Cavadino and Dignan, 2006; Lacey,
to elaborate a grounded critique of penal 2008; Wacquant, 2009), while in others they
change7. emerged from critical analyses of penality
This is not to suggest that the traditional the background of which is rather distant
politico-economic analysis, with its reduc- from the materialist paradigm (Simon, 2007;
tive focus on the relationship between unem- Barker, 2009). I suggest that we engage with
ployment and imprisonment (Jankovic, 1977; each of these themes, since they shed light on
Greenberg, 1980; Wallace, 1980; Galster relevant dimensions of the penal question
and Scaturo, 1985; Inverarity and McCarthy, that have been left underexplored by the old
1988), had been able to elaborate a persua- political economy of punishment.
sive structural critique of contemporary The first theme points to one of the most
punishment; nor to argue that an exclusive persistent critiques addressed to neo-Marxist
emphasis on punishment as an instrument criminology: its apparent lack of interest
of class control would provide an exhaustive for the cultural, expressive, and discursive
explanation of the transformations of penal dimensions of penality. While this critique
politics in contemporary societies. Indeed, is clearly well grounded, it is worth noting
from the standpoint of what I would define here that the emphasis on the symbolic dimen-
as a post-reductionist political economy sions of punishment has often come at the
of punishment, the challenge is to envision cost of deemphasizing (if not ignoring) the
a non-orthodox critique of penal strategies historically determined structural dimensions
that is able to overcome the false alterna- of penality, almost in a kind of zero-sum logic
tive between structure and culture while where more culture seems to imply less
addressing the important theoretical concerns structure (see for example Garland, 1990,
raised by other critical perspectives in the 2001). Recently, the issue of the culture/
field of punishment and society. structure schism has resurfaced in Loic
In this respect, I would suggest that at least Wacquants (2009) analysis of neoliberal
three main themes addressed by recent narra- penality and of the emergence of an American
tives of penal change (particularly in the penal state. This work aims explicitly at
USA) deserve the attention of neo-Marxist bridging the gap between instrumental and
criminologists: symbolic dimensions of punishment. In the
very first pages of his Punishing the Poor,
1 the already mentioned issue of the symbolic in fact, Wacquant states that his work does
dimension of punishment, which points to the not belong to the genre of the political
materialist frameworks excessive focus on the economy of imprisonment inaugurated by
instrumental side of penal practices; the classic work of Georg Rusche and
2 the issue of the broader governmental effects Otto Kirchheimer, Punishment and Social
generated by penal strategies, which points Structure, since its ambition is:
to the neo-Marxist paradigms narrow focus
on socioeconomic marginality as the exclusive [t]o hold together the material and symbolic
target of penal technologies; dimensions of the contemporary restructuring of
3 the issue of the specific politico-institutional the economy of punishment that this tradition
contexts that define the background against of research has precisely been unable to wed,
which specific forms of penality unfold, which owing to its congenital incapacity to recognize the

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 48 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 49

specific efficacy and the materiality of symbolic consolidation of a repressive machine whose
power. (2009: xvii) operations are functional to the reproduction
of current capitalist relations, but also to
Wacquant argues that the unfolding of the the configuration of new categories and dis-
American penal experiment over the last courses, novel administrative bodies and
three decades should not be interpreted government policies, fresh social types and
as the leitmotiv of the old political economy associated forms of knowledge (2009: 295).
of punishment would suggest as a simple Wacquants attempt to assign proper
reflection of the transition from a Fordist- weight to the discursive and symbolic
industrial model of production based on effects of penal politics provides important
stable labor markets, extensive networks of insights towards a post-reductionist revision
social protection, and inclusive welfare of the materialist critique of punishment.
policies, to a post-Fordist economic system Yet, the image that emerges most often from
based on deregulated labor markets, flexible the pages of Punishing the Poor is that of a
working conditions, and weak social pro- penal state involved in a struggle to regulate
tections. Indeed, an exclusive focus on the (by repressive means) the most precarious
instrumental dimension of the new punitive- sectors of the post-industrial labor force,
ness would prevent a deeper understanding while less emphasis is given to its symbolic
of the significance of the American penal reach across other regions of American
state as a broader political project. society. Thus, despite Wacquants insistence
According to Wacquant, the emerging on the necessity to escape the narrowly
penal state would pursue three distinct strate- materialist vision of the political economy
gies with both instrumental and symbolic of punishment (2009: xviii), his approach
outcomes. At the instrumental level, the risks to reproduce the much contested
American penal experiment would entail a material/symbolic divide. Not unlike other
massive warehousing of the surplus popula- materialist critiques of penality, indeed,
tions generated by the restructuring of Wacquants work seems to come to the
the Fordist-industrial economy. In turn, by conclusion that the neoliberal penal state
increasing the cost of any attempt to escape reveals its instrumental side against the new
from the lowest regions of the labor market poor, while projecting its purely symbolic
(according to the well known principle of hold on the rest of society specifically, on
less eligibility) this new great confinement the middle classes it struggles to reassure by
would contribute to impart a new discipline allowing them to witness the punitive excess
of labor on the marginal sectors of the post- unleashed against the new dangerous classes.
industrial workforce. Finally, at the symbolic In other words, Punishing the Poor might be
level, the new penal discourse would appease less distant from the traditional politico-eco-
the growing insecurities experienced by the nomic critique of punishment than its author
middle class, by staging a ritual reassertion acknowledges, since once again the symbolic
of the states power to neutralize the unwor- and discursive dimensions of penal politics
thy and dangerous classes. appear mostly as ideological outgrowths
In other words, the tentacles of the penal of a penal state whose main role is to puni-
state would extend deeply into the fabric of tively regulate the poor in order to force them
American society, reshaping both at the into the post-Fordist labor market. Finally,
instrumental and symbolic level its public we are left with our unsolved dilemma:
sphere, its political institutions and its cul- how can the symbolic and instrumental
tural orientations. Distancing himself from dimensions of punishment be reconnected
the reductionist tendency of the political under a comprehensive structural critique of
economy of punishment, Wacquant suggests penal change? How do penal discourses and
that the punitive turn leads not only to the practices consolidate themselves as powerful

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 49 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


50 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

technologies for governing not just social in a distinct governmental rationality that
marginality, but late-capitalist/neoliberal Simon calls governing through crime:
societies at large?
This question points to the issue of the When we govern through crime, we make
crime and the forms of knowledge historically
broader governmental effects generated by
associated with it available outside their limited
penal discourses and practices in contempo- original subject domains as powerful tools with
rary societies. In its basic formulation, this which to interpret and frame all forms of social
theme draws on the Foucauldian insight that action as a problem for governance. (2007: 17)
penal practices, as historically determined
technologies of power, are always inscribed Simon offers a rigorous genealogy of this
within broader rationalities of government. new governmental rationality, whose origins
Thus, according to Foucaults genealogy, can be situated in the legimation crisis
the emergence of modern penality (with the affecting the liberal-welfarist forms of gov-
transition from the spectacle of suffering to ernance that had been hegemonic in the
the consolidation of disciplinary technolo- USA for most of the 20th century. Simon
gies) would mirror a broader shift from a reconstructs the concatenation of discur-
destructive sovereign power that struggles to sive events that provided the symbolic back-
neutralize its enemies to a productive govern- ground for the unfolding of the American
mental rationality engaged in the efficient punitive turn from Goldwaters incendiary
regulation of whole populations (Foucault, 1964 electoral campaign, to the wars on
2009: 117). It is worth emphasizing the con- crime and drugs launched by Nixon, Reagan
nection, often overlooked, between Foucaults and Bush Sr, to the war on terror declared
theorization of the power to punish and the by George W. Bush in the aftermath of 9/11.
neo-Marxist analysis of capitalist reproduc- All these transformations have converged
tion, particularly in light of the French phi- toward a new paradigm of social governance
losophers own emphasis on the role played based on the prevention and neutralization
by the emergence of a capitalist political of criminal risks as a constitutive element of
economy in the unfolding of modern governmental action at all levels of American
governmental rationalities (Foucault, 2009: society.
1067). What matters the most here, how- This Foucauldian perspective eschews a
ever, is Foucaults insistence that penal top-down concept of penal power common
strategies (and governmental technologies in to much neo-Marxist criminology, and
general) should not be seen simply as repres- describes the punitive turn from the point
sive tools for the control of the poor, but of view of both its politico-institutional con-
rather as elements of broader rationalities for sequences and the diffusion of lifestyles,
the governing of entire social formations. cultures of work, and patterns of consump-
Following this perspective, in a recent tion revolving around the crime-punishment
work Jonathan Simon (2007) situates his nexus. Simon deconstructs, on the one,hand
critique of the American penal experiment the peculiar governmental technologies that
within a theoretical framework that is rather emerged around this punitive shift, and on
distant from the one advanced by Rusche and the other, the discursive chains that allowed
Kirchheimer. The level privileged by Simon these rationalities to resonate with punitive
is that of a socio-legal and political analy- and neo-authoritarian declinations of fear
sis of the governmental rationalities that and insecurity in a neoliberal society. If ana-
emerged as a consequence of the increasing lyzed under this particular lens, the punitive
centrality of the penal question in the USA. turn appears as a broad social dynamic whose
In the last 30 years, the ongoing proliferation power effects are constantly reproduced
of discourses, practices and knowledge on through the daily interactions between
crime and punishment would have resulted citizens (not only the poor) and a power to

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 50 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 51

punish that is part of a broader strategy for The issue of the lack of comparative insti-
regulating the social. tutional analysis in neo-Marxist accounts of
However, I would suggest, this reconfigu- penal change has been recently raised in par-
ration of governmental technologies is ticular by theoretical perspectives directly
not disconnected from the deep structural engaged with (if not internal to) the politico-
inequalities affecting the social and urban economic framework (Sutton, 2004; Cavadino
landscape of American society. The molecu- and Dignan, 2006; Lacey, 2008). In The
lar diffusion of the power effects associated Prisoners Dilemma, for example, Nicola
with this new model of governing through Lacey clearly situates her analysis in the
crime does not mean that such effects materialist field, broadly accepting the
spread evenly. Although we can agree with politico-economic argument that current
Simon that we should focus on both the penal trends must be linked to the socioeco-
criminal justice system that is concen- nomic transformations affecting late capital-
trated on poor communities and the pri- ist societies. However, rather than assuming
vate sector of middle-class securitized a global spread of the neoliberal ideology
environments as class-specific modes of gov- sustained by a uniform shift toward penal
erning through crime that interact with each severity, Lacey offers a detailed comparative
other (Simon, 2007: 7), we also need to analysis of the different varieties of capital-
emphasize that these rationalities of govern- ism existing in the Western world (Hall
ment do not generate similar (or even compa- and Soskice, 2001), and suggests that their
rable) effects at different latitudes of the specific features must be given proper weight
American socioeconomic hierarchy. The in the analysis of punishment and social
neo-Foucauldian argument that crime does structure:
not govern only those on one end of struc-
tures of inequality (Simon, 2007: 18) needs My analysis builds on structural theories inspired
by Marxism, but it argues that political-economic
to be qualified by the Marxist insight that forces at the macro level are mediated not only
penal strategies contribute to the overall by cultural filters, but also by economic, political,
reproduction of those very structures of and social institutions It is this institutional
socioeconomic inequality, in directions that stabilization of and mediation of cultural and
resonate with current dynamics of capitalist structural forces, and the impact which this has
on the perceived interests of relevant groups of
accumulation. social actors, which produce the significant and
Furthermore, the actual configuration of persistent variation across systems at similar stages
this symbiotic relationship between penal of capitalist development. (Lacey, 2008: 57)
technologies and socioeconomic processes
cannot be taken for granted, nor can it be According to Lacey, the American shift
presumed to unfold along the same coordi- toward a punitive governance of social mar-
nates across all late-capitalist societies. This ginality has not spread to all advanced
question sheds light on the third theme I capitalist democracies, and the specific con-
would like to discuss here: the specific figurations of the punitive turn (where it has
politico-institutional arrangements through indeed taken place) cannot be automatically
which the relations between punishment and derived from the emergence of a post-indus-
social structure are mediated. Such issue trial, neoliberal economy. Instead, different
also points to what recently John Sutton has capitalist social formations show diverging
identified as a serious theoretical flaw in trends. If some neoliberal market economies
the political economy of punishment: its ten- such as the USA (and to a much more limited
dency to assume that all capitalist econo- extent, the UK) have witnessed a significant
mies are the same and that business cycles transition from social to penal means for
are wholly exogenous to other kinds of social governing the poor, this has not been the
processes (Sutton, 2004: 171). case in the social-democratic or corporatist

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 51 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


52 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

economies of continental Europe, where in explanations of penal change, these themes


the last few decades welfare protections have are not incompatible with a politico-
not been drastically reduced and indicators of economic critique of penality. Instead, as I
penal severity have remained relatively will argue more extensively in the final sec-
stable. In this sense, social-democratic and tion of this chapter, they can help us envision
corporatist economies would seem to be a conceptual roadmap for the construction
better positioned than their neoliberal coun- of a post-reductionist, culturally sensitive
terparts to resist the punitive turn (despite political economy of punishment.
their own problems of rising unemployment
and growing social inequality), thanks to
their politico-economic and institutional
structures based on stable labor markets, NEW DIRECTIONS IN THE POLITICAL
long-term public investments in the work- ECONOMY OF PUNISHMENT
force, coalition-oriented electoral politics,
and greater insulation of the judiciary from In the 1933 article which outlined the thesis
the ebbs and flows of public opinion (see to be later developed in Punishment and
also Cavadino and Dignan, 2006: 339). Social Structure, Georg Rusche had already
Conversely, in neoliberal economic forma- been careful to emphasize the complexity of
tions characterized by flexible labor mar- the relationship between economic structure
kets, low levels of investment in public and penal forms:
services, two-party political systems, a single-
issue orientation in political debate, and The dependency of crime and crime control
a hegemonic orientation favoring individual on economic and historical conditions does
not, however, provide a total explanation. These
competitiveness over social equality the
forces do not alone determine the object of our
most disruptive consequences of the crisis investigation and by themselves are limited and
of the industrial economy (namely, the pro- incomplete in several ways. (1933 [1978]: 3)
duction of a large surplus of labor) would
unfold in a politico-institutional context that This early warning against oversimplified
facilitates the shift toward a more punitive interpretations of the economy/punishment
model of social regulation. Lacey suggests nexus would not inoculate the political econ-
that in order to be able to explain both omy of punishment against the dangers of
the punitive shift of neoliberal societies and economic determinism. It must also be said
the relative penal moderation of other late- that the reductionist drift would indeed become
capitalist social formations, the materialist particularly evident in the neo-Marxist
approach needs to be grounded in a compara- criminological literature of the 1970s and
tive analysis of the institutional, political and 1980s, whose attempts to apply Rusche and
cultural arrangements which, in each variety Kirchheimers paradigm to late-capitalist
of capitalism, mediate (and sometimes societies focused on narrow statistical analy-
mitigate) the effect of economic forces on ses of the relationship between changes
penal politics. in the labor market and variations in impris-
Taken together, the three themes dis- onment rates (for a review see Chiricos and
cussed the symbolic dimension of penality, DeLone, 1992; Melossi, 1998; De Giorgi,
the governmental effects of penal politics 2006: 1939). This literature was for the
and the different politico-institutional con- most part able to provide empirical support
texts in which penal practices unfold can to the hypothesis of a positive and direct
assist neo-Marxist criminology in its effort correlation between unemployment and
to overcome some of the old conundrums of incarceration and to show how, in accordance
materialist criminology. Indeed, as far as with Rusche and Kirchheimers insights,
they are not seen as alternatives to structural penal severity tended to increase in times of

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 52 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 53

economic crisis and rising unemployment. dominant form of production and the corre-
However, the narrowly quantitative approach sponding composition of the workforce (e.g.
to socioeconomic change privileged by most mass production, the industrial working
of these analyses (perhaps in an attempt to class); (2) a specific strategy of macroeco-
give scientific validation to the materialist nomic growth, which identifies the leading
approach through the use of ever more com- sectors of an economic formation (e.g. indus-
plex statistical models), has prevented a trial production, manufacturing); (3) a par-
deeper understanding of the extra-economic ticular system of economic regulation, which
and extra-penal factors that contribute to describes the prevailing regulatory frame-
structure this relationship (for notable excep- work (e.g. collective bargaining, market reg-
tions see Box, 1987; Melossi, 1993, 2000). ulation, monetary policies); and (4) a coherent
The reductionist tendency of the political mode of societalization, which identifies the
economy of punishment has resulted in an hegemonic forms of cultural, institutional,
unnecessary oversimplification of Rusche and social organization (e.g. cultures of wel-
and Kirchheimers perspective, which in fare, fiscal policies, patterns of consumption,
turn has deprived the materialist framework etc.).
of the theoretical tools it needs in order to According to this perspective, the Fordist-
elaborate a comprehensive critique of the Keynesian regime of capitalist accumulation
capitalist restructuring that has unfolded in was based on a system of mass-industrial
Western societies since the early 1970s. This production centered on the assembly line,
broad process of socioeconomic transforma- stable labor markets regulated by compre-
tion has certainly involved (particularly in hensive industrial policies, high levels of
the early stage of the transition) a massive labor unionization favored by an extended
expulsion of the labor force from the indus- system of collective bargaining, significant
trial sectors of the economy, as shown by public interventions in the economy, cultural
the vertical growth of unemployment rates orientations favoring mass consumption, and
between the late 1970s and the early 1980s. a tacit social pact between labor and capital
More importantly, however, it has resulted (often mediated by an interventionist state)
in a deep restructuring of the specific regime according to which high wages and generous
of capitalist accumulation that had been social protections would reward high levels
hegemonic in Europe and (to a lesser extent) of labor productivity and work discipline.
in the USA between the 1930s and the Bob Jessop summarizes the internal consist-
1960s. ency between the economic, institutional,
The concept of regime of accumulation and cultural dimensions of this specific
has been elaborated by neo-Marxist political regime of accumulation as follows:
economists belonging to the so called regu-
If the Keynesian welfare national state helped
lation school (see Aglietta, 1979; Jessop,
secure the conditions for Fordist economic expan-
1990). This perspective reconstructs the his- sion, Fordist economic expansion helped secure
torical trajectory of capitalist development in the conditions for the Keynesian welfare national
light of the contradictory tendency of capital- state. Welfare rights based on national citizenship
ism to generate crises and instabilities, on the helped to generalize norms of mass consump-
tion and thereby contributed to full employ-
one hand, and to consolidate new institu-
ment levels of demand; and they were sustained
tions, new norms, and new cultural orienta- in turn by an institutionalized compromise
tions in response to those crises, on the other involving Fordist unions and Fordist firms. (Jessop,
hand.8 According to this perspective (Jessop, 2002: 79)
2002: 568), each different regime of capital-
ist accumulation can be described accord- The gradual demise in Western economies
ing to four main elements: (1) a distinctive of this model of capitalist development
type of labor process, which identifies the during the 1970s was prompted by several

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 53 4/24/2012 3:02:27 PM


54 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

crisis-generating features of the Fordist- the balance of power from labor to capital.
Keynesian paradigm, such as the steady As Melossi puts it, sometimes in the mid-
decline in capitalist profits produced by the 1970s the social system started squeezing
radicalization of class struggles, the fiscal the working class for the juice of production,
crisis of the welfare state precipitated by not with only one hand, but with two hands
increasing demands for social provisions at the same time (2003: XXV).
(coupled, particularly in the USA, with the It is in the context of this broader realign-
rise of anti-tax movements), the inflationary ment of social power throughout the structure
tendencies generated by high wages and of late capitalist societies that a materialist
high welfare expenditures, the saturation of analysis of contemporary penal change must
domestic markets for durable goods, and the situate its critique. And such a critique must
loss of competitive advantage suffered by be able to take into account not only the
Western economies in the wake of economic measurable dynamics of the labor market,
globalization. but also the political, institutional, and cul-
In liberal societies such as the USA, whose tural transformations that have contributed to
economic history has traditionally leaned redefine existing structures of socioeconomic
toward a laissez-faire model of capitalist inequality in the wake of a new emerging
development based on deregulated markets, regime of capitalist accumulation.
minimal public interventions in the economy, In order to illustrate some of the theore-
and a system of social protections resem- tical implications of this qualitative shift,
bling a charitable state (Wacquant, 2009: I will return once again to Rusches original
48), the dismantling of the Fordist-Keynesian formulation of the concept of less eligibility
regime has unfolded in a neoliberal variant as the logic governing the relation between
characterized by extreme labor market flexi- punishment and social structure:
bility, a vertical decline in labor unionization,
a drastic curtailment of welfare provisions All efforts to reform the punishment of criminals
and soaring levels of socioeconomic inequal- are inevitably limited by the situation of the lowest
socially significant proletarian class which society
ity (Sennett, 1998; Shipler, 2004; Katz and
wants to deter for criminal acts. All reform efforts,
Stern, 2006). In this respect, the crisis of however humanitarian and well-meaning, which
the Fordist-Keynesian paradigm and the go beyond this restriction, are condemned to uto-
concurring process of capitalist restructur- pianism. (Rusche, 1933 [1978]: 4, emphasis
ing have involved much more than the expul- added)
sion of a significant fraction of the industrial
labor force from the system of production Here I would argue that Rusches concept
the only aspect captured by a narrow focus of the situation of the lowest socially sig-
on unemployment and imprisonment. nificant proletarian class (1933: 4) lends
Indeed, the transition to a post-Fordist/post- itself to a much broader conceptualization
Keynesian regime of accumulation has taken than the narrowly economistic approach
the form of a broad capitalist offensive privileged by most of the literature on unem-
against the workforce, in a successful attempt ployment and imprisonment: one that encour-
to break the Fordist-Keynesian compromise ages a productive integration between the
and to reestablish suitable conditions for traditional materialist critique of punishment
profitable capitalist accumulation in a global and some of the theoretical issues raised by
economy: a stricter work discipline, higher the recent sociologies of the punitive turn.
levels of labor flexibility, more insecure Indeed, if the relative power of the work-
working conditions, lower social protec- force in a capitalist economy is ultimately
tions, and an increased competition for work determined by the economic value of its
among the poor. This process of capitalist labor,9 the overall situation of that workforce
restructuring resulted in a significant shift in its contingent position inside existing

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 54 4/24/2012 3:02:28 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 55

hierarchies of social worthiness, or its social outsourcing, etc.) have significantly reduced
value is not simply the product of narrow the economic value of wage labor and con-
economic dynamics. Rather, it results from solidated a tendency toward rising work
the ongoing interaction between structural insecurity, declining wages, longer working
processes of economic transformation (modes hours, and an overall increase in the socially
of production, patterns of economic growth, acceptable levels of exploitability of the
labor market dynamics), governmental tech- American labor force (Schor, 1992; Sennett,
nologies of social regulation (varieties of 1998; Ehrenreich, 2001). At the same time,
welfare/workfare, strategies of public inter- however, a broad reconfiguration of govern-
vention in the economy, politico-institutional mental strategies of social regulation such
arrangements, modes of economic regula- as the transition from welfare to workfare,
tion/deregulation, patterns of wealth redistri- the growing politico-institutional emphasis
bution/concentration), and discursive/ on individual responsibility, and the emer-
symbolic dynamics of cultural reproduction gence of neoliberal forms of governance that
(racialized and gendered taxonomies of social encourage the secession of the successful
worth, mainstream narratives about social in fields like taxation, housing, education,
deservingness and undeservingness). In other etc. (Reich, 1991) has eroded the Fordist-
words, the overall situation of marginalized Keynesian compromise, deepening social
social classes is determined by their place fractures along lines of race and class. Finally,
in the economic structure as much as by their in the field of cultural signification, the pow-
position in the moral economy of capitalist erful neoconservative hold on public debates
social formations (Sayer, 2001). It should on socioeconomic inequality reinforced by
be noted here that this ongoing process of the cyclical emergence of racialized moral
redefinition of the economic and social worth panics about the underclass, welfare depend-
of labor represents a constant feature in the ency, street crime and drugs, illegal immi-
history of capitalism, and that the trajectory gration, etc. has helped to consolidate
of this repositioning of the labor force in hegemonic representations of the poor as
the social structure tends to follow a clear undeserving and potentially dangerous
pattern: the overall situation of the marginal (Handler and Hasenfeld 1991; Gans, 1995;
classes tends to improve when a stable Quadagno, 1995).
dynamic of capitalist valorization guarantees In the field of penal politics, the broad-
extended periods of economic growth and ened materialist framework sketched above
social stability, while it tends to deteriorate would allow the political economy of punish-
when the crisis of a specific mode of devel- ment to overcome its traditional emphasis
opment prompts capitalist social formations on the instrumental side of penality, and to
to revolutionize the system of production and analyze the emergence of the American
spark a new regime of accumulation (Marx, penal state from the point of view of its
1867 [1976]: 896904). impact on each of the different levels at
Following this perspective, a post- which this broad reconfiguration of the
reductionist political economy of the puni- American social structure (and of the situa-
tive turn in the USA should analyze the tion of its marginalized populations) has
changing situation of the marginal classes taken place since the 1970s. In this direction,
in America against the background of the a post-reductionist critique of the punitive
economic and extra-economic processes turn should of course emphasize the struc-
that have redefined the position of the poor tural dimension of recent penal practices,
within the material and moral economy of illustrating their instrumental role in impos-
American society. Over the last three dec- ing the discipline of desocialized wage
ades, structural processes of capitalist trans- work by rising the cost of strategies of
formation (deindustrialization, downsizing, escape or resistance that drive young men

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 55 4/24/2012 3:02:28 PM


56 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

from the lower class into the illegal sectors analyzed prison conditions in the USA during the
of the street economy (Wacquant, 2009: Depression era (Rusche, 1930 [1980]). The second
article, conceived as a research project for the
XVII). But it should also analyze the wide-
Institute for Social Research in Frankfurt, was pub-
spread governmental effects of penal tech- lished in 1933 in the Institutes journal Zeitschrift fr
nologies particularly in conjunction with Sozialforschung, and outlined the main concepts of
other tools of socioeconomic regulation, the materialist critique of punishment (Rusche, 1933
such as fiscal and social policies and illus- [1978]).
3 For an analysis of the return of corporal punish-
trate their tendency to reproduce and rein- ment in the USA during the last quarter of the
force existing structures of socioeconomic 20th century, see Cusac (2009).
inequality. Most importantly, however, it 4 For a broad reconstruction of the complex
should elaborate a culturally sensitive mate- history of Punishment and Social Structure, detailing
rialist critique of the symbolic implications both Rusches biographic vicissitudes and the prob-
lematic reworking of the original manuscript by Otto
of contemporary penal forms, and analyze Kirchheimer, see Melossi (1978, 1980).
how hegemonic representations of deserv- 5 In the first pages of Discipline and Punish,
ingness and undeservingness resonate with Michel Foucault acknowledges that Rusche and
(and provide cultural legitimacy to) an emerg- Kirchheimers great work, Punishment and Social
ing post-Fordist model of capitalist pro- Structure provides a number of essential reference
points, adding that we can surely accept the gen-
duction whose regime of accumulation is eral proposition that, in our societies, the systems
grounded in the material and symbolic deval- of punishment are to be situated in a certain politi-
uation of the poor and their labor. cal economy of the body (1977: 245).
Finally, the epistemological shift proposed 6 Following David Harveys recent work, here
here would enable neo-Marxist criminology I use the term neoliberalism to identify a political
project developed by Western power elites, particu-
to approach penal politics no longer as an larly in the USA and in the UK between the late
outgrowth of capitalist relations of produc- 1970s and the early 2000s, in order to reestablish
tion (a superstructure of the capitalist econ- the conditions for capital accumulation and to
omy, in the language of orthodox Marxism), restore the power of economic elites (Harvey, 2005:
but rather as a set of material and symbolic 19) after the social turbulence of the 1960s and early
1970s. As a politico-economic system, neoliberalism
practices that contribute to the overall repro- emphasizes individual freedom over social responsi-
duction of capitalist social formations and of bility, competition over cooperation, market forces
their specific regimes of accumulation. over state intervention, capital mobility over financial
regulation, and corporate interests over the rights of
organized labor.
7 This statement might seem to overlook the
contributions of those authors most notably David
NOTES Garland (1985, 1990; but see also Howe, 1994)
who during the 1980s and 1990s have engaged in a
1 Several directions of research contributed in this critical conversation with the political economy of
period to the consolidation of critical or radical punishment. The point I would like to make here,
perspectives in criminology (radical feminism, critical however, is that most of these works focused on
race theory, postcolonial studies, etc.), not all of stigmatizing the inability of the neo-Marxist perspec-
which can be ascribed to Marxism. The focus of this tive to grasp the symbolic and cultural dimensions of
chapter, however, is the political economy of punish- punishment, rather than on promoting any signifi-
ment, an approach that owes much to Marxist cant advancement in this approach.
theory. For a broad reconstruction of different 8 Bob Jessop and Ngai-Ling Sum have summa-
currents of thought in critical criminology, see rized the distinctive approach of the regulation
Van Swaaningen (1997), Lynch et al. (2006) and school as follows: The regulation approach is a vari-
DeKeseredy (2010). ant of evolutionary and institutional economics that
2 It is worth noting here that a few years before analyzes the economy in its broadest sense as includ-
the publication of Punishment and Social Structure, ing both economic and extra-economic factors. It
Georg Rusche had already exposed some of his ideas interprets the economy as an ensemble of socially
in two articles. The first article, originally published in embedded, socially regularized and strategically
1930 in the German newspaper Frankfurter Zeitung, selective institutions, organizations, social forces and

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 56 4/24/2012 3:02:28 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 57

actions organized around (or at least involved in) Studies in Governmentality. Chicago: University of
capitalist reproduction (2001: 91, original emphasis). Chicago Press. pp. 7104.
9 Which in turn depends on the pressure exer- Foucault, M. (2009) Security, Territory, Population:
cised on the labor market by the unemployed popu- Lectures at the Collge de France, 19771978.
lation that fills the ranks of the Marxian industrial
New York: Picador.
reserve army of labor: The industrial reserve army,
Galster, G. and Scaturo, L. (1985) The US criminal
during the periods of stagnation and average pros-
perity, weighs down the active army of workers; justice system: unemployment and the severity of
during the periods of over-production and feverish punishment, Journal of Research in Crime and
activity, it puts a curb on their pretensions (Marx, Delinquency, 22(2): 163189.
1867 [1976]: 792). Gans, H.J. (1995) The War Against the Poor. New York:
Basic Books.
Garland, D. (1985) Punishment and Welfare: A History
of Penal Strategies. Aldershot: Gower.
REFERENCES Garland, D. (1990) Punishment and Modern Society:
A Study in Social Theory. Chicago: University of
Adamson, C. (1984) Towards a marxian penology: Chicago Press.
captive criminal populations as economic threats Garland, D. (2001) The Culture of Control: Crime
and resources, Social Problems, 41(4): 43558. and Social Order in Contemporary Society. Oxford:
Aglietta, M. (1979) A Theory of Capitalist Regulation. Oxford University Press.
London: New Left Books. Greenberg, D. (1980) Penal sanctions in Poland: a
Althusser, L. (1971) Lenin and Philosophy and Other test of alternative models, Social Problems, 28(2):
Essays. New York: Monthly Review Press. 194204.
Barker, V. (2009) The Politics of Imprisonment: How Hall, J. (1940) Book review: Punishment and social
the Democratic Process Shapes the Way America structure, by G. Rusche and O. Kirchheimer, Journal
Punishes Offenders. New York: Oxford University of Criminal Law and Criminology, 30(6): 971973.
Press. Hall, P.A and Soskice, D. (eds) (2001) Varieties of
Box, S. (1987) Recession, Crime and Punishment. Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
London: Rowman & Littlefield. Hall, S., Critcher, C., Jefferson, T., Clarke, J., Roberts, B.
Burgess, E.W. (1940) Book review: Punishment and (1978) Policing the Crisis. Mugging, the State, and
social structure, by G. Rusche and O. Kirchheimer, Law and Order. London: Palgrave.
The Yale Law Journal, 49(5): 986. Handler, J.F. and Hasenfeld, Y. (1991) The Moral
Cavadino, M. and Dignan, J. (2006) Penal Systems: A Construction of Poverty: Welfare Reform in America.
Comparative Approach. London: SAGE Publications. London: SAGE Publications.
Chiricos, T. and DeLone, M. (1992) Labor surplus Harvey, D. (2003) The New Imperialism. Oxford: Oxford
and punishment: a review and assessment of University Press.
theory and evidence, Social Problems, 39(4): Harvey, D. (2005) A Brief History of Neoliberalism.
421446. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cusac, A. (2009) Cruel and Unusual. The Culture Howe, A. (1994) Punish and Critique. London:
of Punishment in America. New Haven, CT: Yale Routledge.
University Press. Ignatieff, M. (1978) A Just Measure of Pain: The
De Giorgi, A. (2006) Re-Thinking the Political Economy Penitentiary in the Industrial Revolution, 17501850.
of Punishment: Perspectives on Post-Fordism and New York: Pantheon.
Penal Politics. Aldershot: Ashgate. Ignatieff, M. (1983) State, civil society and total
DeKeseredy, W. (2010) Contemporary Critical institutions: a critique of recent social histories of
Criminology. London: Routledge. punishment, in S. Cohen and A. Scull (eds), Social
Ehrenreich, B. (2001) Nickel and Dimed: On (Not) control and the state. Oxford: Martin Robertson.
Getting by in America. New York: Holt. pp. 75106.
Foucault, M. (1965) Madness and Civilization. Inverarity, J. and McCarthy, D. (1988) Punishment
New York: Pantheon. and Social Structure revisited: unemployment and
Foucault, M. (1977) Discipline and Punish: The Birth imprisonment in the United States, 19481984,
of the Prison. London: Penguin. The Sociological Quarterly, 29(2): 26379.
Foucault, M. (1991) Governmentality, in G. Burchell, Jankovic, I. (1977) Labor market and imprisonment,
C. Gordon. and P. Miller (eds), The Foucault Effect: Crime and Social Justice, 8: 1731.

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 57 4/24/2012 3:02:28 PM


58 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF PUNISHMENT AND SOCIETY

Jessop, B. (1990) Regulation theories in retrospect Pasquino, P. (1980) Criminology: the birth of a special
and prospect, Economy & Society, 19(2): 153216. savoir, Ideology & Consciousness, 7: 1733.
Jessop, B. (2002) The Future of the Capitalist State. Piven, F. and Cloward, R. (1993) Regulating the Poor.
Cambridge: Polity Press. The Functions of Public Welfare. New York:
Jessop, B. and Sum, N. (2001) Pre-disciplinary and Vintage.
post-disciplinary perspectives in political economy, Platt, A. (1969) The Child Savers: The Invention of
New Political Economy, 6(1): 89101. Delinquency. Chicago: University of Chicago
Katz, M.B. and Stern, M.J. (2006) One Nation Divisible: Press.
What America Was and What it is Becoming. New Quadagno, J. (1995) The Color of Welfare. New York:
York: Russel Sage Foundation. Oxford University Press.
Lacey, N. (2008) The Prisoners Dilemma: Political Quinney, R. (1980) Class, State and Crime. New York:
Economy and Punishment in Contemporary Longman.
Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Reich, R. (1991) The secession of the successful,
Press. New York Times Magazine 20 January. Accessed
Laclau, E. and Mouffe, C. (1985) Hegemony and March 18, 2012, from http://www-personal.umich.
Socialist Strategy: Towards a Radical Democratic edu/~gmarkus/secession.html
Politics. London: Verso. Riesman Jr, D. (1940) Book review: Punishment and
Lynch, M.J., Michalowski, R.J. and Byron Groves, W. social structure, by G. Rusche and O. Kirchheimer,
(2006) Primer in Radical Criminology: Critical Columbia Law Review, 40(7): 1297301.
Perspectives on Crime, Power & Identity. Monsey, Rusche, G. (1930 [1978]) Labor market and penal
NY: Criminal Justice Press. sanction: thoughts on the sociology of punishment,
Marshall, T.H. (1940) Book review: Punishment and Social Justice, 10: 28.
social structure, by G. Rusche and O. Kirchheimer, Rusche, G. (1933 [1980]) Prison revolts or social
The Economic Journal, 50(197): 1267. policy: lessons from America, Social Justice, 13:
Marx, K. (1867 [1976]) Capital: Volume I. Harmonds- 4144.
worth: Penguin. Rusche, G. and Kirchheimer, O. (1939 [2003])
Matza, D. (1969) Becoming Deviant. Englewood Cliffs, Punishment and Social Structure. New Brunswick,
NJ: Prentice Hall. NJ: Transaction.
Melossi, D. (1978) Georg Rusche and Otto Kirchheimer: Sayer, A. (2001) For a critical cultural political econ-
punishment and social structure, Social Justice, 9: omy, Antipode, 33(4): 687708.
7385. Schor, J. (1992) The Overworked American. New York:
Melossi, D. (1980) Georg Rusche: a biographical Basic Books.
essay, Crime and Social Justice, 14: 5163. Sennett, R. (1998) The Corrosion of Character.
Melossi, D. (1993) Gazette of morality and social whip: The Personal Consequences of Work in the New
punishment, hegemony, and the case of the U.S., Capitalism. New York: Northon.
19701992, Social & Legal Studies, 2: 25979. Shipler, D.K. (2004) The Working Poor. Invisible in
Melossi, D. (2000) Changing representations of America. New York: Vintage.
the criminal, British Journal of Criminology, 40: Simon, J. (2007) Governing Through Crime. How the
296320. War on Crime Transformed American Democracy
Melossi, D. (2003) Introduction to the Transaction and Created a Culture of Fear. New York: Oxford
Transaction edition. The simple heuristic maxim University Press.
of an unusual human being, in G. Rusche and Spierenburg, P. (1984) The Spectacle of Suffering.
O. Kirchheimer (eds), Punishment and Social Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Structure. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers. Spitzer, S. (1975) Toward a Marxist theory of devi-
pp. ixxlv. ance, Social Problems, 22(5): 63851.
Melossi, D. (ed.) (1998) The Sociology of Punishment. Sutton, J. (2004) The political economy of
Aldershot: Dartmouth. imprisonment in affluent western democracies,
Melossi, D. and Pavarini, M. (1981) The Prison and the 19601990, American Sociological Review, 69:
Factory. Origins of the Penitentiary System. London: 1709.
Macmillan. Taylor, I., Walton, P. and Young, J. (1973) The New
Pashukanis, E.B. (1978) Law and Marxism: A general Criminology. For a Social Theory of Deviance.
Theory. London: Ink Links. London: Routledge.

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 58 4/24/2012 3:02:28 PM


PUNISHMENT AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 59

Thompson, E.P. (1967) Time, work-discipline Wallace, D. (1980) The political economy of incarcera-
and industrial capitalism, Past & Present, 38(1): tion trends in late US capitalism: 19711977, The
5697. Insurgent Sociologist, 11(1): 5966.
Van Swaaningen, R. (1997) Critical Criminology: Wacquant, L. (2009) Punishing the Poor. The Neoliberal
Visions from Europe. London: SAGE Government of Social Insecurity. Durham, NC: Duke
Publications. University Press.

5772-Simon-Ch02.indd 59 4/24/2012 3:02:28 PM

Вам также может понравиться