Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 18

Portents of Pluralism: How Hybrid Regimes Affect

Democratic Transitions
Jason Brownlee The University of Texas at Austin

The original studies of competitive authoritarianism and hegemonic authoritarianism inspected the occurrence of
hybrid regimes during the 1990s but stopped short of testing their propensity for democratic change. This article assesses
the causal effects of hybrid regimes, and the postcold war period itself, on regime breakdown and democratization. Using
a dataset of 158 regimes from 1975 to 2004, and a discrete measure for transitions to electoral democracy, I find that
competitive authoritarian regimes are not especially prone to losing power but are significantly more likely to be followed
by electoral democracy: vigorous electoral contestation does not independently subvert authoritarianism, yet it bodes well
for democratic prospects once incumbents are overthrown.

I
n the wake of the cold war authoritarian rulers in- and competitive authoritarian (Diamond 2002, 2932;
creasingly adopted the forms of democracy even as Levitsky and Way 2002, 53). These subtypes enabled stu-
they resisted substantive democratization. By 2001 dents to reconsider authoritarianism as a repertoire of
electoral authoritarianism had become the modal form political practices much broader than simple repression.
of nondemocracy; autocrats allowing some form of mul- Pioneering works explored how hybrid regimes
tiparty elections outnumbered those who did not by more emerged and functioned, refraining from long-term prog-
than two to one (Schedler 2002, 47). As Larry Diamond noses except to observe that a variety of trajectories were
observed, these hybrid regimes were not completely likely.1 Martha Brill Olcott and Marina Ottaway noted
new. Much earlier authoritarian regimes in Mexico, that what they dubbed semi-authoritarianism could de-
Senegal, and Taiwan had permitted the opposition cay into fully closed authoritarianism, advance into full-
to contest elections, although many more regimes blown democracy, or persist in its present form (1999).
had excluded their challengers from such competition Steven Levitsky and Lucan Way likewise observed that
(Diamond 2002, 2324). In the 1990s rulers were fusing competitive authoritarian regimes confounded the telos
plebiscitarianism and authoritarianism at an astound- of earlier democratization studies:
ing rate, in the process defying expectations that they
would soon adopt genuine democracy. To apprehend this Although some hybrid regimes (Mexico, Senegal,
trend, comparativists developed a new conceptual ap- Taiwan) underwent democratic transitions in
paratus of authoritarian typologies. Fully closed au- the 1990s, others (Azerbaijan, Belarus) moved
thoritarian regimes were distinguished from their elec- in a distinctly authoritarian direction. Still oth-
toral counterparts, while the latter group was further ers either remained stable or moved in multiple
disaggregated into hegemonic electoral authoritarian directions (Malaysia, Russia, Ukraine, Zambia,

Jason Brownlee is Assistant Professor of Government, The University of Texas at Austin, 1 University Station A1800, Austin, TX 78712-0119
(brownlee@austin.utexas.edu).
I am grateful to Catherine Boone, Valerie Bunce, Terrence Chapman, Larry Diamond, Thad Dunning, Marc Morje Howard, Stathis Kalyvas,
Steven Levitsky, Staffan Lindberg, Matthew Longo, Eric McDaniel, Patrick McDonald, Philip Roessler, Andreas Schedler, Benjamin Smith,
Elisabeth Jean Wood, and three anonymous reviewers for their comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this article. I also thank
Rachel Sternfeld, for research assistance, Barbara Geddes, for sharing her original dataset on authoritarian breakdown, and the staff of
Freedom House, for providing early lists of electoral democracies. Previous versions of this article were presented at the annual meeting of
the American Political Science Association Annual Meeting, the Junior Faculty Workshop at the University of Texas, and the Comparative
Politics Workshop at Yale University.
1
This initial focus on regime origins was reflected in the title of one leading work, The Rise of Competitive Authoritarianism (Levitsky
and Way 2002), and the subtitle of a peer monograph, The Rise of Semi-Authoritarianism (Ottaway 2003).
American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 53, No. 3, July 2009, Pp. 515532

C 2009, Midwest Political Science Association ISSN 0092-5853

515
516 JASON BROWNLEE

Zimbabwe), making the unidirectional impli- 19752004 (for a total of 2,132 regime-years). The regres-
cations of the word transitional misleading. sion analyses thereby cumulate upon published large-n
(2002, 52) and small-n research, matching the numerical analysis
with the theoretical insights of the qualitative literature.
As these researchers began examining variations in The results show hybrid regimes have better prospects
regime outcomes over time, their studies probed among for democratization than fully closed regimes. None of the
hybrid regimes, rather than contrasting them with new authoritarian types significantly raised the chance of
nonelectoral authoritarian cases (Levitsky and Way the regime losing power. However, competitive author-
2006, forthcoming; Ottaway 2003; Schedler 2006). A itarian regimes, where the opposition had fared at least
fresh cohort of social scientists soon began writ- moderately well in presidential or parliamentary polls,
ing on the dynamics of hybrid regimes, including were more likely than other regimes to be succeeded by
the question of whether electoral contestation in- electoral democracies. The data also indicate that both
creased the likelihood of democratization (Hadenius and hybrid and closed regimes have been less durable and
Teorell 2006, 2007; Howard and Roessler 2006; Lindberg more prone to democratization during the postcold
2006, 2007). After illumining the political gray zone, war era than in prior years. Predicted probability esti-
comparative studies could consider what todays regimes mates show the magnitude of these effects has been sub-
portended for the millions of people living under them stantial, with competitive authoritarian regimes of the
(Carothers 2002). post-1989 period emerging as the strongest candidates
The present study joins research on contemporary for democratization.
authoritarianism and its implications for long-standing Before presenting the findings and their implications,
questions of regime change and democratization. I at- I first relate this study to existing literature and discuss
tempt to discern broad trends. Accordingly, this article how I operationalized the main explanatory and depen-
encompasses a wider swath of nondemocracies and a dent variables. My treatment of the cross-national statis-
larger time period than initially pursued in the hybrid tical research on authoritarian subtypes begins with the
regimes literature. Rather than combing through the sub- seminal studies of hybrid regimes and then addresses the
set of competitive and hegemonic electoral authoritarian influential work of Barbara Geddes (1991a, 1991b, 2003).
regimes I compare cases from these categories with ex- Geddess tripartite typology predates the categories of
clusionary, nonelectoral regimes. I also look at patterns electoral and competitive authoritarianism and provides
of regime politics from 1989 and earlier, in addition to an alternative taxonomy of the nondemocratic spectrum.
cases from the postcold war era. This panorama of elec- Subsequent scholars have evaluated the effect of elec-
toral and nonelectoral authoritarianism, during and af- tions and legislatures on authoritarian regimes, an area
ter the cold war, enables me to test claims that are of- Geddes did not initially address. Based on these works
ten treated as givennamely that the new authoritarian I propose four hypotheses regarding electoral, compet-
regimes are distinct from their fully closed counterparts itive, and hegemonic authoritarianism and their effects
and that the end of the cold war exerted a profound in- on the major outcomes of regime breakdown and demo-
fluence on regimes worldwide (Huntington 1991; Shin cratic transition. In the subsequent logistic regression
1994). tests, Geddess main regime types retain their explana-
My approach differs from recent works in the field tory weight for authoritarian breakdown, but they do
by operationalizing the primary explanatory variables not account for variations in democratic transitions. By
and outcomes in discrete categories that comport with contrast, the newer regime types are salient only in the
the prevailing concepts of comparative democratization second batch of results, where competitive authoritarian-
scholarship. For example, rather than assessing regime ism evinces a significant positive effect on the likelihood
change as a shift in Polity or Freedom House scores, I the successor regime will be an electoral democracy.
measure changes from authoritarianism to democracy
based on Freedom Houses underutilized listing of elec-
toral democracies. Similarly, for authoritarian types, I
code regimes based on their electoral competitiveness and Authoritarianism in the 1990s: New
whether they exhibit the basic characteristics of electoral Regimes and Old Debates
authoritarianism and its two subcategories (competitive
authoritarianism and hegemonic electoral authoritarian- When political change swept through Eastern Europe
ism, henceforth hegemonic authoritarianism). I then in 198990, the nascent postcommunist democracies
deploy a dataset covering 158 regimes during the period capped a 15-year wave of democratization that had circled
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 517

FIGURE 1 Global Count of Electoral Democracies (19872008)

the globe (Huntington 1991). The Soviet Unions demise 3. regularly contested elections under a secure and
soon yielded more new democracies, as well as over a secret ballot and the absence of massive, outcome-
dozen other regimes with noticeable autocratic counter- changing fraud;
currents (McFaul 2002, 227). Hence a surge of democra- 4. significant public access of major political par-
tization at the turn of the decade imparted an ambiguous ties to the electorate through the media and open
legacy, with states from Central Asia to sub-Saharan Africa campaigning (Puddington 2007, 3).
seemingly more pluralistic than their predecessors but far
short of electoral democracy. During the second half of the 1990s the count of electoral
From 1990 to 1994 the global number of electoral democracies nearly leveled off, with the number hovering
democracies as tallied by Freedom House rose 50% (from around 120 for the past decade (Figure 1).
76 to 114; Freedom House 2008). These democracies were As democratization hit a plateau new authoritarian
identified by Freedom House for meeting the minimalist regimes arose. The third wave subsided, electoral author-
standard adopted by political scientists.2 The criteria for itarianism spread, and hybrid regimes became the modal
being counted as an electoral democracy are form of government in the developing world. By the end
of the 1990s political scientists were beginning to consider
1. a competitive multiparty political system; these governments in their own terms, not as incomplete
2. universal adult suffrage for all citizens; democratization but as new and resilient forms of au-
thoritarianism. Right as earlier approaches to democratic
2
transitions were accused of obsolescence, comparativists
The standard measure originated with the work of Joseph Schum-
peter, who defined democracy in procedural terms: the democratic
seized upon hybrid regimes as a pressing empirical and
method is that institutional arrangement for arriving at political analytic problem for postcold war politics (Carothers
decisions in which individuals acquire the power to decide by means 2002; Diamond 2002; Levitsky and Way 2002; Schedler
of a competitive struggle for the peoples vote (1950, 269). Scholars 2002).
subsequently added basic protection of civil liberties as a further
criterion for the exercise of democracy (Dahl 1971, 3; Diamond Levitsky and Way coined the term competitive au-
2002, 21). thoritarianism for cases in which elections were the
518 JASON BROWNLEE

principal means for acquiring power but where incum- In sum, the electoralist bent of hybrid regimes merited at-
bents routinely abuse state resources, deny the opposition tention because it departed from the traditional means by
adequate media coverage, harass opposition candidates which autocrats had held power. The foundational stud-
and their supporters, and in some cases manipulate elec- ies of hybrid regimes thus outlined a scholarly agenda
toral results (2002, 53). They linked their regime type that recognized the particular nature of electoral author-
to the conditions of the postcold war period: West- itarianism and that suggested postcold war politics had
ern liberalisms triumph and the Soviet collapse under- generated these regimes at a pace and in ways distinct
mined the legitimacy of alternative regime models and from earlier periods.
created strong incentives for peripheral states to adopt Scholars of the new authoritarian subtypes sought to
formal democratic institutions (2002, 61). Indeed many map out the universe of nondemocratic cases while re-
of the former Soviet states that did not become competi- serving judgment on the future trajectory these regimes
tive democracies epitomized the problem of competitive might take. The primary aim was identifying and classify-
authoritarianism: ing authoritarian regimes, rather than assessing their like-
lihood for democratization. Toward this end Diamond in-
cluded a comprehensive table placing nearly all regimes
The post-Cold War world has been marked by of the world under one of six mutually exclusive and col-
the proliferation of hybrid political regimes. In lectively exhaustive headings: liberal democracy, electoral
different ways, and to varying degrees, poli- democracy, ambiguous regimes, competitive authoritar-
ties across much of Africa (Ghana, Kenya, ian, hegemonic electoral authoritarian, and politically
Mozambique, Zambia, Zimbabwe), postcom- closed authoritarian (2002, 3031). The competitive and
munist Eurasia (Albania, Croatia, Russia, Serbia, hegemonic electoral authoritarian categories clarified the
Ukraine), Asia (Malaysia, Taiwan), and Latin distinction between cases in Levitsky and Ways type and
America (Haiti, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru) com- those regimes that would fit Schedlers broader category
bined democratic rules with authoritarian gov- but fell short of the competitive standard (2002, 25).
ernance during the 1990s. . . . (2002, 51) Competitive and hegemonic authoritarianism could be
distinguished by the strength of the oppositions chal-
For Larry Diamond, it was the proliferation of hybrid lenge to incumbents:
regimes, not their simple emergence, which made these
cases novel. Hybrid regimes (combining democratic and One defining feature of competitive authoritar-
authoritarian elements) are not new, he remarked. Even ian regimes is significant parliamentary opposi-
in the 1960s and 1970s, there existed multiparty, electoral, tion. In regimes where elections are largely an au-
but undemocratic regimes (2002, 2324). The contem- thoritarian facade, the ruling or dominant party
porary period differed, though, because nondemocratic wins almost all the seats: repeatedly over 95 per-
regimes tended not to ban their opponents outright but cent in Singapore, about 80 percent in Egypt
instead corral them through other methods. in 2000 and Mauritania in 2001, 89 percent in
Similarly, Andreas Schedler observed that the prac- Tanzania in 2000, and repeatedly over 80 percent
tice of combining elections and non-democratic rule had in Tunisia during the 1990s. (Diamond 2002, 29,
a long history, but noted that electoral authoritarianism 32)
(identified by the presence of multiparty elections, re-
gardless of competitiveness) had grown more common Hence a salient feature of competitive authoritarian
during the late twentieth century: regimes was that the rulers faced stiff electoral chal-
lengers, despite the opposition contesting a lopsided po-
litical arena.
Since the early days of the third wave of global Even as the new studies of authoritarianism refrained
democratization, it has been clear that transi- from speculating about the dynamic properties of their
tions from authoritarian rule can lead anywhere. regimes, work by Diamond, Schedler, Levitsky and Way,
Over the past quarter-century, many have led to and others implicitly spoke to an older debate about the
the establishment of some form of democracy. effects of elections and other pseudo-democratic insti-
But many others have not. They have given birth tutions on regime change. After regime-initiated elec-
to new forms of authoritarianism that do not fit tions in the Philippines (1986), Chile (1989), Poland
into our classic categories of one-party, military, (1989), and Nicaragua (1990) produced opposition vic-
or personal dictatorship. (2002, 36) tories, Samuel Huntington remarked that liberalized
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 519

authoritarianism is not a stable equilibrium; the halfway reflected the contrasts among different regimes: Because
house does not stand (1991, 17475). On this score, I consider the most important differences among author-
comparativists found conflicting evidence. Guillermo itarian regimes to be qualitative, I create a typology for
ODonnell and Philippe Schmitter had contended that measuring regimes rather than a scale or index. Typolo-
postWorld War II autocrats can justify themselves in gies are theoretical constructs used when variables can
political terms only as transitional powers (1986,15) and only be measured nominally. . . . To be useful, they have
envisioned a slippery slope from liberalization to democ- to capture differences that are essential to the argument
ratization. Other scholars observed that elections and par- being made (2003, 5051). Those differences primarily
liaments helped rulers manage their opponents (Chehabi concerned the interests and power bases of regime rulers,
and Linz 1998, 18; Gandhi and Przeworski 2007, 1280; whether they originated in the countrys military (whence
Joseph 1997, 375; Remmer 1999, 349). they could return after the regime ended), a party (upon
The hybrid regimes of the 1990s and early twenty- which they depended for influence), or a personal clique.
first centuryholdouts from the third wave of democ- Geddes thus developed a tripartite typology of military,
ratization, as well as newcomersblended liberalization personalist, and single-party regimes, with various mixed
with further authoritarianism. A bevy of dictators tout- types for regimes that spanned more than one category.
ing their electoral bona fides in Africa, the Middle East, A set of coding rules enabled Geddes and her research
and Central Asia suggested that elections could be tightly team to classify 167 regimes from 92 countries in these
bridled by those in power. Hybrid regimes implied that categories (for discussion of these coding decisions, see
elections were not the lid of Pandoras box, unleashing Geddes 1999a, 1722).
a torrent of political change, and were perhaps a safety The outcome of interest was the breakdown of an
valve for regulating societal discontent and confining the authoritarian regime, identified by the replacement of
opposition. incumbent rulers by an alternative set of elites.3 Consis-
On balance, one can invoke cases in favor of either tent with Geddess game theoretic elaboration of elites
perspective, the notion of liberalization as regime con- interests, military regimes tended to have the shortest du-
trol and the concept of liberalization as regime change ration (average lifespan: 8.5 years), single-party leaders
catalyst. Scholars are thus charged with examining this were least likely to relinquish power (22.7 years), and per-
question broadly, through quantitative data on recent au- sonalistic leaders lasted longer than military ones but not
thoritarian regimes. Popular assumptions about elections as long as single-party rulers (15.0 years; Geddes 1999b,
are largely driven by iconic cases, like the Philippines 37).4 In logit regressions and survival analysis that con-
and Nicaragua. Rather than spotlighting these familiar trolled for levels of economic development, region, and
episodes, this article widens the lens of analysis to see how age, military regimes were the most likely to lose power in
well the competing arguments of elections under author- a given year, personal regimes the second most likely, and
itarianism comport with general trends. A recent expan- party regimes the least likely (Geddes 1999a, 38; Geddes
sion of statistical research on authoritarian rule promises 2003, 78). The approach developed by Geddes has been
to build on initial research about the origins of electoral widely employed in subsequent studies of regime change
regimes with studies of their impact on major outcomes (Kinne 2005; Peceny, Beer, and Sanchez-Terry 2002; Smith
of change and democratization. 2005; cf. Lai and Slater 2006).
One of the most ambitious successors to Geddess
project has been Axel Hadenius and Jan Teorells cross-
national study of regime change. In a working paper
Recent Findings and Remaining and subsequent article, Hadenius and Teorell report on a
Questions
3
Geddes described the dependent variable as follows: I counted
Barbara Geddess study of authoritarian breakdown, in- an authoritarian regime as defunct if either the dictator and his
supporters had been ousted from office or a negotiated transition
troduced as a conference paper and subsequently ex- resulted in reasonably fair, competitive elections and a change in
panded in a monograph on research methods, distilled the party or individual occupying executive office. Where ousters
decades of scholarship on nondemocratic regimes and occurred, I used that date as the endpoint. Where elections oc-
set a new baseline for cross-national studies of regime curred, I used the date of the election but did not include the case
unless the winner of the election was allowed to take office (1999a,
change (Geddes 1999a, 1999b, 2003). Intentionally de- 19).
veloping a set of regime subtypes that matched the ex- 4
Geddes placed a few especially resilient regimes (Egypt,
tant literature, Geddes eschewed a numerical range of au- Suhartos Indonesia, Stroessners Paraguay) in a doubly hybrid
thoritarianism in favor of categories that more accurately Personal/Military/Single-Party category (1999b, 22).
520 JASON BROWNLEE

new dataset that includes cases, variables, and outcomes mental identification of regimes by Geddes.5 Two other
not addressed by Geddes. Notably, their data encompass recent works have approached the impact of regime com-
monarchies and democracies, as well as autocracies. In petitiveness for both breakdown and democratization.
all, they have five main regime types: monarchy, military, Using an original dataset on elections in sub-Saharan
no-party, one-party, and multiparty, as well as hybrids Africa, Staffan Lindberg argues that elections do not
that fall between categories (2006, 8). Combining these merely ratify preceding democratic development but ac-
five subtypes with their coding of democracies, Hadenius tually facilitate democratization independently (2006, 3).
and Teorell track both intra-authoritarian regime shifts Over time, Lindberg contends, elections have a self-
for example, a change from no-party to multiparty reinforcing effect that embeds and consolidates demo-
authoritarianismand extra-authoritarian transitions, cratic practices in previously authoritarian settings: My
from authoritarianism to democracy. The approach of- analysis of more than two hundred third-wave elections
fers a substantial advance in our understanding of transi- in Africa shows that an uninterrupted series of compet-
tions not only from authoritarian regimes, but also within itive elections imbues society with certain democratic
them. But its application in the accompanying statisti- qualities. Repeated electionsregardless of their rela-
cal analysis elides the distinction between these kinds of tive freeness or fairnessappear to have a positive im-
change. pact on human freedom and democratic values (2007,
Hadenius and Teorell code intraregime periods of 139). He reaches this conclusion by tracking improve-
varying authoritarianism as distinct regimes and in some ment in democratic qualities as measured by changes
cases this has the effect of fragmenting one regime into in Freedom House civil liberties scores for the relevant
several. For example, whereas Geddes accords with most countries (2006, 1819). Yet Lindberg leaves unexplored
area specialists in coding Mexico under the PRI as one the relationship of these shifts in democratic quality for
regime from 1929 to 2000, Hadenius and Teorell identify the arguably more monumental change from an electoral
two different cases: a dominant party regime (196087) authoritarian regime to an electoral democracy. The re-
and a multiparty regime (198898) (2006, 2728). Like- sulting implications are unclear; repeated elections may
wise, most comparativists consider the dictatorial rule be accompanied by a flourishing of civil society, but we
of Ferdinand Marcos in the Philippines one regime that cannot be confident they spur regime change.
lasted from Marcoss declaration of martial law in 1972 Finally, in a cross-national analysis of competitive au-
until his ouster following the snap election of 1986. For thoritarianism, Marc Morje Howard and Philip Roessler
Hadenius and Teorell, the Marcos regime is counted three found that what they termed liberalizing electoral out-
ways before its collapse: as a residual other (197277), as comes were most likely when the opposition coordinated
a dominant party regime (197883), and as a multiparty around a single candidate and challenged a nonincum-
regime (198486) (2006, 28, 3031). bent in the elections (2006, 37576). The authors thus
This coding decision departs from the conventional capture the importance of strategy for contesting compet-
concepts of the comparative politics literature and under- itive authoritarian regimes, illustrating their quantitative
mines the reliability of Hadenius and Teorells measures. findings with the example of Kenyas break from single-
The PRI in Mexico and Marcos in the Philippines did not party rule in 2002 (Howard and Roessler 2006, 37879).
lose power multiple times; they each lost power once. Yet Howard and Roesslers study marks one of the first
Hadenius and Teorell include these subperiods as separate attempts to carefully apply Levitsky and Ways compet-
regimes in their survival analysis and test of democratiza- itive authoritarian subtype to the dynamic question of
tion (2006, 16, 21). By counting intra-authoritarian mod- how regimes become more politically open and plural-
ulations as distinct instances of breakdown, Hadenius and ist. Like Hadenius and Teorell, they combine Polity and
Teorell risk biasing their results and overstating the poten- Freedom House data to measure their dependent vari-
tial for change. Mexicos democratization was not the con- able. An electoral outcome counts as liberalizing the
clusion of a 10-year-old multiparty authoritarianism, but regime if in that year the Polity score increased by three
the climax of a decades-old ruling party that had become
5
more competitive in its final years. It is thus premature A secondary problem involves their measure of democracy based
on a regimes average numerical score from the Freedom House and
to conclude: all other possible determinants of democ- Polity data (Hadenius and Teorell 2006). That measurement may
ratization being equallimited multiparty systems are miss the discrete shift from authoritarianism to democracy that
more likely to democratize (Hadenius and Teorell 2007, accompanies many transitions. To give two illustrative examples,
154). In order to recognize intra-authoritarian regime Hadenius and Teorells Polity/Freedom House threshold records
Nicaragua and Romania becoming democracies in 1995, whereas
variations, comparative analysis must account for shifts observers conventionally date Nicaraguas transition to 1990 and
within authoritarianism without obscuring the funda- Romanias to 1992.
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 521

or more points and the Freedom House political rights more likely than their exclusionary counterparts to
score decreased by one point or more (Howard and experience a democratic transition.
Roessler 2006, 370). This approach measures the signifi-
H 4 : Following the prior hypothesis, the relatively higher
cant shift from competitive authoritarianism toward elec-
levels of contestation enjoyed by opposition parties
toral democracy while leaving open the issue of how such
in competitive authoritarian regimes further increase
a regime change fits in the full spectrum of democrati-
the likelihood that the regimes successor will be an
zation: An important question that will have to be left
electoral democracy.
for future research is what explains transitions from more
closed regimes to competitive authoritarian regimes, such Before presenting logistic regression results on these hy-
that elections become competitive and the opposition has potheses, I next discuss how I measured and operational-
a greater opportunity to contribute to political liberaliza- ized the relevant variables.
tion through strategic electoral coalitions (2006, 375, fn.
26). In tandem with that question, one should also con-
sider the prospect that some regimes may transition from
closed authoritarianism to electoral democracy without Measuring Hybrid Regimes and
lingering in the zone of competitive authoritarianism. In Transitions from Authoritarianism
order to pursue such analysis, comparativists must set
competitive authoritarian regimes alongside their hege- The foregoing studies produced valuable findings for our
monic electoral and fully closed counterparts. understanding of what variables undermine authoritar-
ianism and generate democracy. Geddes distinguished
among different forms of authoritarianism, showing a
rulers base of power affected the likelihood of regime
Deriving Hypotheses for the Newest collapse. However, she did not address the dependent
Authoritarian Subtypes variable of democratization, an outcome approached
directly by the study of Hadenius and Teorell. Those
Based on the preceding overview, the latest quantitative authors suggested that authoritarian regimes with multi-
studies of elections and regime tend to support Hunting- party elections were more prone to breakdown and de-
tons idea that liberalized authoritarian regimes are more mocratization. In a similar vein, Lindberg argued that
likely than closed regimes to experience democratization. repeated elections improved the quality of democracy in
These arguments can be translated into testable propo- a given regime, as shown by an increase in the exercise
sitions. We should expect that electoral and competitive of civil liberties. These projects had limitations too. On
authoritarianism increase the likelihood of regime break- the one hand, Hadenius and Teorells measures of in-
down and democratic transition. Therefore, based on the traregime change may underestimate the durability of
prior works I derive four hypotheses regarding the likely multiparty authoritarian regimes. On the other, Lind-
impact of hybrid regimes on the collapse of authoritari- bergs work does not assess the discrete shift from author-
anism and its replacement by electoral democracy. They itarianism to democracy, instead placing the quality of
are follows: democracy on a continuum. At that point, Howard and
Roessler capture the transition from competitive authori-
H 1 : The holding of multiparty elections under authoritar- tarianism to electoral democracy, showing that contested
ian circumstances provides an additional venue for elections tended to facilitate such shifts.
mobilizing opposition and challenging incumbents, I integrate these gains in knowledge, compensate for
thereby making electoral authoritarian regimes more some of the limitations in prior works, and submit their
prone to regime breakdown than their nonelectoral implications to additional observation. Toward this end
counterparts. I have taken advantage of available measurements rather
than constructing new ones (Snyder 2006, 227). Specif-
H 2 : When the opposition is better able to compete against
ically, I update and expand the regime data of Geddes,
incumbents and electoral contestation risesa situ-
provide a measure for a dependent variable of transitions
ation of competitive authoritarianismthe regime
to electoral democracy, and introduce categorical vari-
will be more likely to break down.
ables for electoral, competitive, and hegemonic author-
H 3 : Because the holding of elections under authoritarian itarianism. I also add new control variables for political
circumstances primes opposition parties for electoral liberalization and the postcold war period. The dataset
participation, electoral authoritarian regimes will be covers a total of 158 regimes and 2,132 regime-years. With
522 JASON BROWNLEE

nominal variables for authoritarian subtypes and democ- ally by Freedom House since 1989, from which observers
ratization, the subsequent tests can comprehensively and track global trends in democratization.7
reliably assess the effect of hybrid regimes on breakdown In this study the dependent variable for successor
and democratization. Addressing the main variables em- regime type takes the value of 1 if three out of four
ployed, I begin with the two outcomes of interest. years after regime breakdown (as coded by Geddes) are
coded as electoral democracy, as identified by Freedom
House. The available list of electoral democracies be-
gins in 1989. To measure the dependent variable in the
Dependent Variables: Regime prior period, 197588, I consulted the relevant country
Breakdown and Democratic reports in Freedom Houses Freedom in the World. (There
Transition were 12 such cases: Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Spain,
Peru, Honduras, Argentina, Turkey, El Salvador, Uruguay,
Following Geddes, the dependent variable of regime Brazil, Guatemala, and the Philippines.) This measure
breakdown is a dummy variable that takes the value of distinguishes between regimes that lost power only to
one in a year in which the incumbent rulers are ousted be followed by further authoritarianism (e.g., Nicaragua
from power, whether through revolution, coup, electoral 1979, Haiti 1986) from those that lost power and were
defeat, or other means. Significant positive coefficients succeeded by a sustained period of, at least minimally,
mean the variable in question is associated with an in- democratic rule (Nicaragua 1990, Haiti 1994).
creased likelihood of regime breakdown. The coding of democratic successor regimes aims to
Regime-years of breakdown signal the end of the cur- identify the bulk of cases driving the global trend depicted
rent regime but do not provide information on what kind earlier (in Figure 1).8 Regime-years coded as democratic
of regime was established next. For example, Nicaragua transitions constitute a pool of cases that approximate the
1979, when the Somoza dictatorship was followed by the conventional set of democratization during the period
Sandinista regime, is coded as a year of breakdown. So is 19752004. (As with breakdown, positive coefficients in-
Mexico 2000, when opposition victory at the polls ended dicate an increased likelihood of democratic transition.)
the PRIs rule. As Geddes noted in her original study, Table 1 lists the countries in which authoritarian regimes
authoritarian regimes are often replaced by new authori- that lost power during 19752004 were succeeded by elec-
tarian regimes (1999a, 19). The breakdown variable does toral democracies.
not distinguish between the establishment of democracy
and the start of another authoritarian regime. A second
dependent variable, introduced for this study, accounts Regime Variables: Hybrid Regimes
for the nature of the successor regime.
Whereas Geddes treated authoritarian breakdown
Diamond, Schedler, Levitsky, and Way specified the fea-
with a dichotomous coding of regime maintenance and
tures of hybrid regimes, but did not establish the full
collapse, she refrained from creating a dependent vari-
universe of such cases over the time period in question.
able for democratization. The prevailing method for do-
In the spirit of not throwing the baby out with the bath
ing so typically involves using Freedom House or Polity
water, I introduced measures for these subtypes while
data and then identifying a numerical threshold or cut-
off point at which a regime is said to have democratized.
7
This is the tact of Hadenius and Teorell, and the codings Observers have noted diminutions of democracy in the form of
illiberal democracies, delegative democracies, and other vari-
they reach largely comport with general understandings ants (Collier and Levitsky 1997; ODonnell 1994; Zakaria 1997).
in the field about which regimes have democratized.6 Yet Yet the field has retained the categorical distinction between
there is another source of data and another approach democracies and nondemocracies. The procedural definition of
democracymanifest through the rotation of top elites from com-
comparativists could adopt. Rather than trying to infer peting groupsremains standard for judging whether or not a
a dichotomous distinction from ordinal data, one may government is democratic (Schmitter and Karl 1991, 51).
instead turn to the qualitative codings of electoral democ- 8
One omission from the set is newly independent democratic states
racies that are available. Specifically, comparativists may that were not previously coded as authoritarian regimes. The main
utilize the list of electoral democracies, composed annu- instance of this phenomenon was the Baltic states that emerged
from the USSR: Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania. For purposes of
the democratic transition variable, I treated Russia as the relevant
successor polity of the Soviet Union. In addition, microstates, with
6
Lindberg (2006) and Howard and Roessler (2006) also use numer- populations of less than one million, are not included in the regimes
ical measures for their dependent variables. dataset and not classified in this study.
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 523

TABLE 1 Authoritarian Regimes Succeeded by Electoral Democracy (19752004)


Regime Electoral Regime Electoral
End Democracy End Democracy
Year Country Years Year Country Years
1978 Dominican 19891993, 1991 Benin 19912008
Republic 19962008
1979 Ecuador 19892008 1991 Mali 19922008
1979 Spain 19892008 1991 USSR/Russia 19932003
1980 Peru 19891991 1991 Zambia 19911995,
20062008
1981 Honduras 19892008 1992 Congo-Brazaville 19921997
1983 Argentina 19892008 1993 Madagascar 19932008
1983 Turkey 19892008 1993 Paraguay 19932008
1984 El Salvador 19892008 1994 Central African Republic 19942000
1984 Uruguay 19892008 1994 Haiti 19941999,
20062008
1985 Brazil 19892008 1994 Malawi 19942008
1985 Guatemala 19892008 1994 South Africa 19942008
1986 The Philippines 19892006 1996 Sierra-Leone 19982008
1987 South Korea 19892008 1998 Armenia 19992002
1988 Pakistan 19891998 1998 Indonesia 19992008
1988 Thailand 19891990, 1999 Guinea-Bissau 19942002,
19922005 20052008
1989 Chile 19892008 1999 Niger 19992008
1989 Panama 19902008 1999 Nigeria 19992005
1989 Poland 19902008 2000 Ghana 20002008
1990 Bangladesh 19912006, 2000 Mexico 20002008
2008
1990 Bulgaria 19912008 2000 Peru 20012008
1990 Czechoslovakia 19902008 2000 Senegal 20002008
1990 East Germany 19902008 2000 Taiwan 20002008
1990 Hungary 19902008 2002 Kenya 20022006
1990 Nepal 19912001 2003 Burundi 20052008
1990 Nicaragua 19902008 2003 Georgia 20042007
1990 Romania 19922008 2003 Liberia 20052008
1991 Albania 19912008 2004 Ukraine 20042008
Notes: Freedom Houses published list of electoral democracies was used for years from 1989 to 2008. Earlier transitions to democracy
(denoted by an ) were coded based on country reports in the annual Freedom in the World, and the following secondary sources:
ODonnell and Schmitter (1986b); Huntington (1991); Linz and Stepan (1996); and Nohlen (2005). Microstates, with a population of less
than one million, were not included. The full listing of regimes is available from the author.

retaining the data from Geddess work. The most direct only a single party to field candidates). In order to code
way of doing so was to create a separate set of dummy vari- all regimes in the dataset one must apply some measure
able categories based on Diamonds distinctions between that sorts the regimes into the appropriate categories. Al-
electoral authoritarianism and fully closed authoritarian- though comparativists frequently use the numerical mea-
ism, as well as his division of electoral authoritarianism sures of Freedom House and Polity, those datasets are in-
into competitive and hegemonic subcategories. tended to measure political contestation, and they match
These categories may be seen as stacked tiers of au- poorly with the particular institutional characteristics of
thoritarianism above and beyond closed authoritarianism Schedler, Levitsky, and Ways subtypes (see Mainwar-
(in which rulers do not permit elections at all or allow ing and Perez-Lina n 2003; Munck and Verkuilen 2002).
524 JASON BROWNLEE

Further, Freedom House and Polity scores fail to capture testation. Levitsky and Way explicitly excluded regimes
the discrete changes that taxonomically partition the hy- like Egypt and Uzbekistan, where rulers enjoyed hege-
brid regimes. Accordingly, I instead drew on the World monic electoral dominance (2002, 5354).
Banks Database of Political Institutions and constructed Regime-years coded as electoral authoritarianism
dummy variables for the presence of limited multiparty were further disaggregated based on the level of competi-
elections and the competitiveness of those polls (Beck tion reported in the DPI. Electoral authoritarian regime-
et al. 2001). years that scored a 7 on one of the indices of legislative
The latest version of DPI covers the years 1975 and executive electoral competitiveness were identified
to 2006 and includes 7-point indices of legislative and as competitive authoritarian. The remainder of electoral
executive electoral competitiveness: 1 = no legislature, authoritarian regimes, with scores no greater than 5 or
2 = unelected legislature/executive, 3 = elected legisla- 6 on the same measures, were considered hegemonic au-
ture/executive, one candidate/post, 4 = one party, mul- thoritarian regimes.9
tiple candidates, 5 = multiple parties are legal but only The two sets of categoriesfully closed authoritar-
one party won seats, 6 = multiple parties did win seats ian versus electoral authoritarian and fully closed author-
but the largest party received more than 75% of the seats, itarian versus competitive authoritarian and hegemonic
7 = largest party got less than 75% (Keefer 2002). Because authoritarianoffer a distinct and complementary ty-
they measure the legislatures and offices filled by election pology to the prior regime divisions of Geddes. The hy-
these scores are typically assigned the year subsequent to brid regime variables function as independent and cu-
voting. Thus they have a built-in one-year lag. The DPI mulative variables beyond the types based on military,
data on multipartyism cut across Geddess regime types personal, and single-party rule.10
and are not endogenous to the outcomes of breakdown
or continuity. They provided the operational tools for
testing the hybrid regime types.
Regime Variables: Geddess Subtypes
The dataset on authoritarian breakdown developed by
Electoral Authoritarianism Geddes originally covered the years 194696. It omitted
authoritarian Soviet successor states (e.g., Kazakhstan,
Electoral authoritarianism is the foil of electoral democ- Turkmenistan) and other regimes emerging after 1990 be-
racy: a system in which elections are held but incumbents cause their inclusion, as relatively new regimes, could have
systematically manipulate the voting (Schedler 2002, 37 biased the conclusions (Geddes 1999a, 17). With nearly
38). For a nondemocratic regime to be considered elec- a decade of additional economic and political data now
toral authoritarian, some form of multiparty or multi- available, I updated Geddess data and included regimes
factional polling must be allowed. Otherwise it belongs that began in the 1990s. I also added monarchies.
in the category of fully closed authoritarianism. Regime- For each regime-year, a regime is coded as one of Ged-
years that measured 14 in the DPI index were coded dess regime types (or as a monarchy). The seven regime
as fully closed authoritarian; regime-years with a score types (military, military-personalist, personalist, single-
of 57 were coded as electoral authoritarian (the com- party hybrid, single-party, military/personalist/single-
bined category encompassing competitive and hegemonic party, monarchy) are mutually exclusive and collectively
regimes). exhaustive. (Personalist regimes are omitted from the re-
gression analysis. Coefficients for the other six regime
type variables should be interpreted as the likelihood of
breakdown relative to personalist regimes.) Regimes are
Competitive and Hegemonic
Authoritarianism 9
Monarchies in which the chief executive does not contest elections
were coded as hegemonic authoritarian, including those cases in
The standard for competitive authoritarianism is higher which regime-years received a score of 57. On elections under
than for simple electoral authoritarianism: Although in- monarchies, see Lust-Okar and Jamal (2002).
10
cumbents in competitive authoritarian regimes may rou- Accordingly the study addresses two institutional dimensions of
tinely manipulate formal democratic rules, they are un- authoritarianism: variations in the profile of the ruling elite as
operationalized by Geddes and differences in the occurrence and
able to eliminate them or reduce them to a mere facade. competitiveness of elections as highlighted in the hybrid regimes
These regimes must exhibit a meaningful level of con- literature.
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 525

classified in one of the categories based on a series of cod- the regimes existence they are not endogenous to regime
ing questions, most of which relate to the background and change, nor do they reflect decisions by Freedom House
operations of the ruling elite.11 The following list provides analysts in the wake of a regimes collapse.
illustrative examples of these classifications:

Military regimeThailand, 197688


Military-personalChile, 197389 Time Variables: PostCold War
Personalist regimeThe Philippines, 197286 Period and Regime Duration
Single-party hybridNorth Korea, 1948
Single-partyMalaysia, 1957 As addressed above, the initial theories of hybrid regimes
Personal/Military/Single-partyIndonesia, tied their emergence and proliferation to the particular
196798 geopolitical and ideological context of the postcold war
MonarchyIran, 195379 era. These claims are well accepted in the case study lit-
erature on democratization, but comparativists seldom
test them in a systematic manner (Bratton and van de
Walle 1997; Huntington 1991). To evaluate whether the
Regime Variables: Prior end of the cold war exerted a causal impact on the stability
Liberalization of authoritarian regimes and the likelihood of democratic
transition, I include a post-1989 dummy variable: regime-
A final political variable addresses the question of liber- years from 1975 to 1989 receive a score of zero; subsequent
alization in authoritarian regimes. Comparativists have years are scored as one.
argued that the relaxing of restrictions on civil liberties Regarding the potential effects of age on regime
presages the end of authoritarian rule and bodes well for change (during and after the cold war), I reproduced
future democracy (Linz and Stepan 1996, 7; ODonnell Geddess variablesage, age squared, and age cubed
and Schmitter 1986, 15). Because an expansion in op- that enable the logistic regression to test for curvilinear
portunities for political expression is not captured by the effects of time, including theories that the hazard rate de-
DPI measures of electoral competition, this factor merits clines after a rulers initial years in power (Bienen and van
distinct treatment. de Walle 1991; Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2003).
I incorporated a lagged variable to assess whether lib-
eralization affected the likelihood of regime breakdown
and democratization. For each regime-year a dummy
variable, prior liberalization, reflected the prior years Additional Control Variables:
civil liberties score (as reported by Freedom House on a Economic Development and Region
17 scale). Regime-years that had received a score of 57
(basic parameters of Freedom Houses not free cate- Consistent with Geddess approach and conventions in
gory) were coded as un-liberalized. Those regime-years the field, I include control variables for wealth and eco-
with a lower, better rating on civil liberties (14) were nomic growth. The first is measured as the natural log of
coded as liberalized.12 In the current data, 411 regime- GDP per capita, while the second records the change in
years (19.3%) fell in the set showing liberalization, i.e., GDP per capita over the prior two years. These variables
a score of 4 or better on civil liberties one year prior. address a countrys development level and the govern-
Because these codings come from the previous year of ments economic performance (Boix and Stokes 2003;
Haggard and Kaufman 1995; Lipset 1959; Przeworski
11
The full dataset, including Geddes, hybrid regime, and electoral et al. 2000).
democracy codings, is available from the author. I began collecting this data from the latest Penn World
12
The choice of a categorical dichotomous variable over a simple Tables 6.2 (2006). However, a number of regimes rele-
ordinal measure was based on the nonlinear nature of improve- vant for this study lack economic data and would thus
ments in regime politics along the civil liberties scale. Whereas
opposition groups may not enjoy meaningful expansions in orga-
be dropped from the regression tests. Governments not
nizational space when a regime shifts from 7 to 6 or 6 to 5, further reporting economic data are not randomly distributed.
gains in civil liberties may yield a qualitative improvement in public In this dataset they tended to fall at the fully closed
expression and mobilization. For example, in 2008 the difference end of the authoritarian spectrum: the Penn World
between Egypts 5 in civil liberties and Indias 3 would carry
more analytic significance than the numerically equal (two-point) Tables lacked economic data for such regimes as Al-
gap between India and Iceland (with a civil liberties score of 1). bania, Angola, Bulgaria, Cambodia, Libya, Myanmar,
526 JASON BROWNLEE

and the Soviet Union. This gap among some of the communism (Bunce 2003; Linz and Stepan 1996; McFaul
most relevant regimes for the questions of this article 2002).14
reinforces the missing data problem Kristian Gleditsch
identified:

The processes or mechanisms that induce miss- Effects of Hybrid Regimes


ing data often make certain types of cases on Breakdown
more likely not to be observed than oth-
ers. . . . Researchers often ignore missing data To test the first pair of hypotheses I ran logistic re-
problems and proceed by . . . working with the gressions on the full set of 158 regimes (2,132 regime-
sample that remains after omitting each case years). In these tests the dependent variable is coded as
or row of the data matrix with missing ob- 1 when the regime experienced breakdown in a given
servations. . . . However, when the attrition due year. For interpreting the results, negative coefficients in-
to missing data is not random, simply going dicate durability and positive coefficients signal a greater
with the available data when faced with missing likelihood of regime collapse. After first running a pared-
data can lead researchers astray. (Gleditsch 2002, down model with only the control variables, I introduced
713) Geddess regime types and the prior liberalization variable
(Model 2), followed by the broad electoral authoritarian
To ameliorate the potential biases of this problem, Gled- category (Model 3), and separate hegemonic and compet-
itsch used relevant regional data, the existing Penn data, itive authoritarianism categories (Model 4). Sample size
and information from alternative sources to provide GDP refers to regime-years. As noted above, standard errors
and population figures for all the countries listed.13 are robust and clustered around regime.
In the present study economic control variables con- In the results of Table 2 (below), Geddess regime
stitute a small portion of the battery of explanatory fac- subtypes retain their salience: single-party regimes and,
tors, yet closed regimes like the Soviet Union, Myanmar, to a lesser extent, monarchies appear to be significantly
and Libya make up an important segment of the universe more durable than other types. Military regimes are con-
of cases. The problem of dropping fully closed regimes sistently more likely to lose power. Also significant are
was substantial and Gleditschs treatment has gained wide variables for the postcold war period and prior liberal-
currency in the field (Chiozza and Goemans 2004, 617 ization. Both variables are significant throughout all the
18; Mansfield and Snyder 2002, 545; Oneal, Russett, and models in which they are included. Prior liberalization
Berbaum 2003, 377). I used Gleditschs Expanded Trade is strongly linked to an increased likelihood of regime
and GDP Data to fill in missing data. breakdown. A Freedom House civil liberties score of 4 or
The final control variables are regional dummies. better proves to be as strong a bellwether of regime change
To capture more precisely whether particular countries as the institutional profiles of Geddess subtypes. By con-
or regimes had unusual properties, I utilized the clus- trast, the newer hybrid regime categories show small neg-
ter function in Stata to produce robust standard errors ative coefficients, suggesting a decreased chance of regime
based around regime. Thus, the logistic regression re- breakdown, but the robust standard errors are too high to
laxes the assumption that, for example, the events of reject the null hypothesis. Electoral authoritarianism and
regime maintenance in Egypt in 1980 and 2000 are com- competitive authoritarianism show no significant impact
pletely independent. This technique reduced the need for on the outcome; Hypotheses 1 and 2 are not supported.
regional control variables. Although Geddes originally The significance of control variables for per capita
placed all countries in one of eight regional categories, GDP, economic growth, and Central and Eastern Europe
I included two regional dummies, for theoretical rea- remains consistent across the four models, strengthen-
sons. The first was for Middle East and North African ing the overall impression that nonelectoral variables are
cases, based on the fields renewed consideration of Mid- exerting the greatest influence on the maintenance or col-
dle East exceptionalism (Herb 2005; Posusney 2004; Ross lapse of the regimes in question. To further interpret these
2001; Stepan and Robertson 2003). I also tested the re- findings, one might consider the empirical source of these
gional significance of Central and Eastern Europe, be- data patterns. The essential reason that competitive and
cause of those cases common experience emerging from
14
I also tested for interactions effects about the Central and Eastern
13
For full discussion of his methodology, see Gleditsch (2002) and European cases, the postcold war period, and the hybrid regime
his web site, http://privatewww.essex.ac.uk/ksg/exptradegdp.html. types. None of the interaction variables emerged as significant.
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 527

TABLE 2 Tests of Hybrid Regimes on Breakdown

Dependent Variable = End of Regime Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4


Electoral authoritarian .261
(.293)
Hegemonic authoritarian .431
(.404)
Competitive authoritarian .163
(.310)
Military regime 1.209 1.147 1.141
(.373) (.376) (.375)
Military-personalist .475 .458 .502
(.380) (.372) (.373)
Party hybrid .036 .069 .070
(.407) (.405) (.410)
Single-party .832 .837 .811
(.380) (.378) (.387)
Personal/military/single-party .467 .370 .332
(.647) (.654) (.626)
Monarchy 1.051 1.136 1.111
(.669) (.651) (.646)
Prior liberalization 1.101 1.196 1.177
(.242) (.272) (.274)
Per capita GDP ln .209 .382 .345 .350
(.119) (.131) (.135) (.135)
Lagged GDP/capita growth .035 .037 .037 .037
(.011) (.012) (.012) (.012)
Middle East .512 .005 .007 .060
(.368) (.420) (.416) (.432)
Central and Eastern Europe .684 1.081 1.047 1.039
(.211) (.285) (.280) (.283)
Age of regime .009 .042 .049 .050
(.059) (.063) (.064) (.064)
Age2 .0007 .008 .001 .001
(.002) (.002) (.002) (.002)
Age3 .00001 .00009 .00001 .00001
(.00002) (.00002) (.00002) (.00002)
Postcold war .565 .423 .521 .514
(.229) (.247) (.289) (.291)
Constant 1.367 .968 1.232 1.208
(1.046) (1.156) (1.208) (1.206)
N 2132 2132 2132 2132
Pseudo R2 .040 .098 .099 .100
Log pseudolikelihood 407.565 382.749 382.261 381.982

p .001; p .05; p .10. Two-tailed tests. Robust standard errors in parentheses.

electoral authoritarian regimes are not strongly associated endured the third wave; others, like the Dominican Re-
with breakdown (or prolonged regime maintenance) is public and the Philippines, were overthrown during the
their diversity in terms of longevity. Many of these hybrid same period. By contrast, repeated tests have shown a
regimes, such as Malaysia and Zimbabwe, have resiliently strong trend of durability among single-party regimes
528 JASON BROWNLEE

and an equally strong tendency toward breakdown in democracies. Although the coefficients for these variables
military dictatorships. mainly went in the same direction as they had in the pre-
Based on these results, if one were interested in fore- ceding tests of regime breakdown, their standard errors
casting the durability of todays dictatorships, the most were sufficiently large that the null hypothesis could not
important regime distinctions would be the variance be rejected.
among military, single-party, and personalist regimes (the A different relationship emerged in the hybrid regime
omitted category), as well as between liberalized regimes categories. Whereas neither electoral nor competitive au-
and those with much tighter controls on free expres- thoritarianism carried a significant impact on the col-
sion and association. By contrast, electoral authoritar- lapse of authoritarian rule, these categories performed
ian regimes, whether competitive or hegemonic, exhibit more strongly at predicting the emergence of electoral
no substantial differences in their propensity for regime democracy after regimes had fallen. In Model 3 the broad
breakdown. These characteristics shift when we turn to category of electoral authoritarianism (without regard
the question of what type of government will emerge after to competitiveness) fell just short of significance at the
a regime falls. .10 level. The underlying dynamics come into focus in
Model 4. Once the hegemonic and competitive variants
of electoral authoritarianism were disaggregated, com-
Tests of Hybrid Regimes petitive authoritarianism emerged as a strong predictor
on Democratic Transitions of democratic transitions. Although the data did not sup-
port Hypothesis 3, they strongly affirmed Hypothesis 4.
Predicted probabilities show that the effect of com-
Table 3 presents results from four tests using the same petitive authoritarianism on subsequent democracy is not
explanatory variables from Table 2 but changing the de- only statistically significant, but it also carries substan-
pendent variable to transitions to electoral democracy. tial magnitude. During the 197589 period the predicted
For these tests I restricted the sample to those regime- probability of a typical personalist authoritarian regime
years in which breakdown occurred. There were 107 in- being succeeded by electoral democracy was 26.1% for
stances of regime breakdown, 54 of which were followed fully closed regimes and 62.5% for competitive author-
by electoral democracies. To recall the dependent vari- itarian regimes. The starting likelihood becomes much
able, a 1 in a given year means that the regime experienced higher after the cold war, but it too increases among
breakdown and was followed by three years of electoral competitive authoritarian regimes. For 19902004 the
democracy, as identified by Freedom House, within the predicted probability of democratization in fully closed
next four years. (Refer back to Table 1 for the resulting set regimes was 78.2%, rising to 94.4% in cases of competitive
of transitions.) authoritarianism.
Among the controls, per capita GDP, the Middle
East dummy variable, and the postcold war period were
highly significant. Regimes with higher GDP per capita
and regimes operating after 1989 were much likelier to be Theoretical Interpretation
succeeded by democracy than their counterparts. Loca-
tion in the Middle East significantly reduced the chance The statistical results on breakdown seemed to track with
of democratic transition, relative to those of regimes in the heterogeneity of durable and fragile electoral author-
other regions. These results accord with what scholars of itarian regimes. What are the empirics beneath the pat-
democratization and Middle Eastern politics have previ- terns in democratic transitions? To begin with Geddess
ously explored in great depth (Boix 2003; Haggard and regime types, the sources of rulers authority and the na-
Kaufman 1995; Herb 2005; Lipset 1959; Posusney 2004). ture of their coalitions are poor predictors of what kind
The significance of certain regime variables charts new of government will follow their withdrawal from power.
terrain. Military leaders may pass power to elected presidents:
Turning first to the regime variables from Geddess Argentina, Brazil, and Turkey. They may also be suc-
original project, only the single-party type evinced any ceeded by elites no less authoritarian than themselves,
significant effect on the likelihood of democratic transi- as occurred in the late 1970s in Chad and Ghana. It ap-
tions, and even that correlation weakened in the expanded pears that the same diversity characterizes personalist and
models. Otherwise, there were no significant differences single-party regimes. Against that backdrop, the distinct
among the military, personalist, and mixed regimes in posttransition legacy of competitive authoritarianism is
their tendency to be followed by non-democracies or striking.
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 529

TABLE 3 Tests of Hybrid Regimes on Democratic Transitions


Dependent Variable = Shift
to Electoral Democracy Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Electoral authoritarian 1.129
(.689)
Hegemonic authoritarian .163
(.916)
Competitive authoritarian 2.024
(.869)
Military regime .629 1.067 1.083
(.901) (.982) (1.063)
Military-personalist .643 1.076 1.236
(.929) (.994) (1.021)
Party hybrid 1.641 1.797 1.508
(1.089) (1.112) (1.145)
Single-party 1.723 1.465 1.440
(1.042) (1.081) (1.145)
Personal/military/single-party .121 .133 .257
(3.233) (3.437) (5.175)
Monarchy 1.785 .597 .658
(1.827) (1.953) (1.998)
Prior liberalization .307 .178 .061
(.634) (.659) (.697)
Per capita GDP ln 1.765 1.839 1.710 1.882
(.422) (.517) (.527) (.588)
Lagged GDP/capita growth .006 .022 .012 .009
(.034) (.037) (.038) (.040)
Middle East 5.840 5.400 5.535 6.230
(1.647) (1.846) (1.902) (2.187)
Central and Eastern Europe .281 .992 1.630 1.227
(1.371) (1.408) (1.511) (1.645)
Age of regime .072 .107 .051 .013
(.164) (.184) (.192) (.200)
Age2 .001 .004 .002 .0006
(.006) (.006) (.007) (.007)
Age3 .000008 .00004 .00002 .00001
(.00006) (.00006) (.00007) (.00006)
Postcold war 2.410 2.763 2.469 2.566
(.666) (.770) (.800) (.849)
Constant 13.333 14.234 14.194 16.024
(3.314) (3.908) (4.056) (4.659)
N 107 107 107 107
Pseudo R2 .383 .437 .456 .492
Log likelihood 45.792 41.777 40.358 37.692

p .001; p .05; p .10. Two-tailed tests. Robust standard errors in parentheses.

Among regimes that have lost power, competitive occurred in regimes classified as competitive authori-
authoritarian regimes are significantly linked to the re- tarian.15 These results illuminate Hadenius and Teorells
placement of authoritarianism with electoral democracy. 15
Transitions from fully closed regimes to democracy constituted
In fact, half of the 54 transitions to electoral democracy 41% of the transition cases and were clustered under two regime
530 JASON BROWNLEE

problematic interpretation of relatively short-lived mul- data also call for closer examination of the causal processes
tiparty autocracies. Such regimes are likely to be followed that propel these trends: why is competitive authoritari-
by electoral democracy. Yet, as demonstrated in the prior anism propitious for the instauration of electoral democ-
battery of tests on regime breakdown, although that elec- racy? A full answer to this must await further study, but a
toralist stage may precede democratization, it does not provisional interpretation may be ventured.
propel that shift. Rather, the internal cohesion of the rul- I derived the foregoing hypotheses from literature
ing elitevarying, as it does, on the institutional profile that underlined the institutional variations between elec-
of that leadershipremains a stronger determinant of toral and nonelectoral authoritarian regimes. Yet only
whether competitive authoritarianism will be a momen- the fourth hypothesis was supported; in cases where the
tary phase or a lasting practice. opposition posed a reasonable electoral challenge, that
These findings also reinforce the importance of con- situation of competitiveness portended a higher likeli-
textual political and historical factors that are often treated hood of democratization after regime breakdown. The
in qualitative discussions but less often incorporated hybrid regimes literature has often been treated apart
into statistical work. Comparativists have long specu- from its forerunner in the old authoritarianism, but
lated about the propitious effect that improvements in this finding suggests a resonance between Levitsky and
civil liberties have on processes of democratization (Linz Ways category and seminal works on democratic transi-
and Stepan 1996; ODonnell and Schmitter 1986). Prior tions and polyarchy. Years ago Dankwart Rustow posited
liberalization of an authoritarian regime, operationalized that democracy began in nationally unified polities that
at the threshold of a 4 or better score on the Freedom experienced a long and inconclusive struggle, a hot
House civil liberties scale, was strongly tied to the re- family feud (1970, 352, 355). Writing in the same period,
moval of incumbents from power. Although the liberal- Robert Dahl argued that governments were more likely to
ization variable was not significantly correlated with the become democratic as the opposition gained in strength
dependent variable of democratic transitions, its salience and inclusion outweighed repression as a political tactic
in the regime breakdown model suggests it deserves at- (1971, 16). The burgeoning opposition movements of to-
tention in future cross-national research. So too, the vari- days competitive authoritarian regimes may display the
able of postcold war period merits deeper consid- kind of incipient pluralism that Rustow and Dahl deemed
eration than it typically receives in quantitative work. a boon to the establishment of democracy. Seen in this
Regimes of the post-1989 era proved to be both more light, systematic testing of competitive authoritarianism
vulnerable to breakdown and more prone to democratic and regime change carries an implicit confirmation of
transition. These effects extended beyond the cases of earlier scholarship.
the Eastern Bloc and Soviet Union. Considering current
trends in global democratization, it remains to be seen
whether this effect will extend into future years (Diamond
2008). Conclusion
In summary, the above results show how electoralist
regime categories complement the explanatory power of Over a decade ago David Collier and Steven Levitsky cau-
earlier authoritarian subtypes. Geddess regime types re- tioned that if research on democratization degenerates
tained their explanatory power in accounting for regime into a competition to see who can come up with the next
breakdown, but they were not effective at capturing famous concept, the comparative study of regimes will
variance in democratic transitions. Electoral and, more be in serious trouble (1997, 451). The subfield studying
specifically, competitive authoritarianism evinced no sig- hybrid regimes arguably faces the same perils. Research
nificant effect on regime breakdown, yet they substan- on authoritarianism has helped students to understand
tially improved the likelihood an authoritarian regime the spectrum of current regimes based on their institu-
would be followed by electoral democracy. These initial tional profile, rather than their lack of democracy. To
results suggest that the regime type of competitive au- ensure that similar explanatory advances continue, com-
thoritarianism provides both descriptive utility for poli- parativists should judiciously evaluate extant hypotheses
tics within the grey zone of hybrid regimes and analytic before replacing them with new suppositions.
value for understanding the long-term (posttransition) In this spirit, the present article has attempted to
legacies of elections under authoritarian constraints. The match statistical data with the main theoretical concepts
of the new hybrid regimes. The resulting tests on 158
types: military regimes (of Latin America) and single-party com- regimes over 30 years help to evaluate the effects of elec-
munist states (of Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union). toral, hegemonic, and competitive authoritarianism on
PORTENTS OF PLURALISM 531

regime breakdown and transitions to electoral democ- Inefficient? American Journal of Political Science 48(3): 604
racy. As it happened, the main markers of electoral au- 19.
thoritarianism showed no substantial effect on the break- Collier, David, and Steven Levitsky. 1997. Democracy with Ad-
down or maintenance of those regimes. Yet, in an in- jectives: Conceptual Innovation in Comparative Research.
World Politics 49(3): 43051.
triguing turn for politics beyond the grey zone, com-
Dahl, Robert Alan. 1971. Polyarchy; Participation and Opposi-
petitive authoritarianism significantly increased the like- tion. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
lihood a successor government would be an electoral Diamond, Larry. 2002. Thinking about Hybrid Regimes. Jour-
democracy. Elections have not provided oppositionists nal of Democracy 13(2): 2135.
an independent mechanism for ousting incumbents, but Diamond, Larry. 2008. The Democratic Rollback: The Resur-
where the opposition is able to perform strongly, com- gence of the Predatory State. Foreign Affairs 87(2): 3648.
petitive elections augur well for chances the successor Freedom House. 1990. Freedom in the World: Political Rights
regime will meet the minimum standard for democratic and Civil Liberties 19891990. New York: Freedom House.
governance. Freedom House. 1991. Freedom in the World: Political Rights
These findings signal fresh opportunities for em- and Civil Liberties 19901991. New York: Freedom House.
bedding hybrid regimes in older theories of democ- Freedom House. 1992. Freedom in the World: Political Rights
and Civil Liberties 19911992. New York: Freedom House.
ratization and its portents. The relationship between
Freedom House. 2008. Freedom in the World: Political Rights
competitive authoritarianism and transitions to electoral and Civil Liberties 2008. New York: Freedom House.
democracy carries echoes from the works of Rustow and
Freedom House. 2009. Freedom in the World 2009: Setbacks and
Dahl, which emphasized diminishing power disparities Resilience. Washington, DC: Freedom House.
between incumbents and their challengers. In that re- Gandhi, Jennifer, and Adam Przeworski. 2007. Authoritarian
gard, the strongest contribution of scholars studying hy- Institutions and the Survival of Autocrats. Comparative Po-
brid regimes may lie in cross-national research that re- litical Studies 40(11): 12791301.
calls and systematically tests the propositions of an earlier Geddes, Barbara. 1999a. Authoritarian Breakdown: Empirical
generation. Test of a Game Theoretic Argument. Presented at the an-
nual meeting of the American Political Science Association,
Atlanta, September 25.
References Geddes, Barbara. 1999b. What Do We Know about Democ-
ratization after Twenty Years? Annual Review of Political
Beck, Thorsten, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer, Science 2: 11544.
and Patrick Walsh. 2001. New Tools in Comparative Politi- Geddes, Barbara. 2003. Paradigms and Sand Castles: Theory
cal Economy: The Database of Political Institutions. World Building and Research Design in Comparative Politics. Ann
Bank Economic Review 15(1): 16576. Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Bienen, Henry, and Nicolas van de Walle. 1991. Of Time and Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede. 2002. Expanded Trade and GDP
Power: Leadership Duration in the Modern World. Stanford, Data. The Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(5): 712
CA: Stanford University Press. 24.
Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. New York: Hadenius, Axel, and Jan Teorell. 2006. Authoritarian Regimes:
Cambridge University Press. Stability, Change and Pathways to Democracy, 19722003.
Boix, Carles, and Susan C. Stokes. 2003. Endogenous Democ- Kellogg Institute Working Paper, Notre Dame University.
ratization. World Politics 55(4): 51749. Hadenius, Axel, and Jan Teorell. 2007. Pathways from Author-
Bratton, Michael, and Nicolas van de Walle. 1997. Democratic itarianism. Journal of Democracy 18(1): 14356.
Experiments in Africa: Regime Transitions in Comparative Haggard, Stephan, and Robert R. Kaufman. 1995. The Political
Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press. Economy of Democratic Transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. University Press.
Siverson, and James D. Morrow. 2003. The Logic of Politi- Herb, Michael. 2005. No Representation without Taxation?
cal Survival. Boston: MIT University Press. Rents, Development and Democracy. Comparative Politics
Bunce, Valerie. 1999. Subversive Institutions: The Design and the 37(3): 297316.
Destruction of Socialism and the State. New York: Cambridge Howard, Marc Morje, and Philip G. Roessler. 2006. Liber-
University Press. alizing Electoral Outcomes in Competitive Authoritarian
Carothers, Thomas. 2002. The End of the Transition Regimes. American Journal of Political Science 50(2): 365
Paradigm. Journal of Democracy 13(1): 521. 81.
Chehabi, H. E., and Juan J. Linz. 1998. A Theory of Sultanism Huntington, Samuel P. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratiza-
1: A Type of Nondemocratic Rule. In Sultanistic Regimes, tion in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: University of
ed. H. E. Chehabi and Juan J. Linz. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Oklahoma Press.
University Press, 325. Joseph, Richard. 1997. Democratization in Africa after 1989:
Chiozza, Giacomo, and H. E. Goemans. 2004. International Comparative and Theoretical Perspectives. Comparative
Conflict and the Tenure of Leaders: Is War Still Ex Post Politics 29(3): 36383.
532 JASON BROWNLEE

Keefer, Philip. 2002. Database of Political Institutions: Changes Olcott, Martha Brill, and Marina Ottaway. 1999. The Chal-
and Variable Definitions. New York: The World Bank. lenge of Semi-Authoritarianism. Carnegie Paper No. 7.
Kinne, Brandon J. 2005. Decision Making in Authoritarian Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International
Regimes: A Poliheuristic Perspective. International Studies Peace.
Perspectives 6(1): 11428. Oneal, John R., Bruce Russett, and Michael L. Berbaum. 2003.
Lai, Brian, and Dan Slater. 2006. Institutions of the Offen- Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and Inter-
sive: Domestic Sources of Dispute Initiation in Authoritarian national Organizations, 18851992. International Studies
Regimes, 19501992. American Journal of Political Science Quarterly 47(3): 37193.
50(1): 11326. Ottaway, Marina. 2003. Democracy Challenged: The Rise of Semi-
Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan A. Way. 2002. The Rise of Com- Authoritarianism. Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment
petitive Authoritarianism. Journal of Democracy 13(2): 51 for International Peace.
65. Peceny, Mark, Caroline C. Beer, and Shannon Sanchez-Terry.
Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan A. Way. 2006. Linkage ver- 2002. Dictatorial Peace? The American Political Science Re-
sus Leverage: Rethinking the International Dimension of view 96(1): 1526.
Regime Change. Comparative Politics 38(4): 379400. Posusney, Marsha Pripstein. 2004. Enduring Authoritarian-
Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan A. Way. Forthcoming. Competi- ism: Middle East Lessons for Comparative Theory. Com-
tive Authoritarianism: The Origins and Evolution of Hybrid parative Politics 36(2): 12738.
Regimes in the Post-Cold War Era. New York: Cambridge Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub,
University Press. and Fernando Limongi. 2000. Democracy and Development:
Lindberg, Staffan I. 2006. Democracy and Elections in Africa. Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 19501990.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lindberg, Staffan I. 2007. The Surprising Significance of Puddington, Arch. 2007. Freedom in the World: Freedom Stag-
African Elections. Journal of Democracy 17(1): 13951. nation amid Pushback against Democracy. Washington, DC:
Freedom House.
Linz, Juan J., and Alfred C. Stepan. 1996. Problems of Democratic
Transition and Consolidation: Southern Europe, South Amer- Remmer, Karen L. 1999. Regime Sustainability in the Latin
ica, and Post-Communist Europe. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Caribbean, 19441994. Journal of Developing Areas 33(3):
University Press. 33154.
Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1959. Some Social Requisites of Ross, Michael L. 2001. Does Oil Hinder Democracy? World
Democracy: Economic-Development and Political Legiti- Politics 53(3): 32561.
macy. American Political Science Review 53(1): 69105. Rustow, Dankwart A. 1970. Transitions to Democracy: Toward
Lust-Okar, Ellen, and Amaney Jamal. 2002. Rulers and Rules: a Dynamic Model. Comparative Politics 2(3): 33763.
Reassessing the Influence of Regime Type on Electoral Schedler, Andreas. 2002. The Menu of Manipulation. Journal
Law Formation. Comparative Political Studies 35(3): 337 of Democracy 13(2): 3650.
66. Schmitter, Philippe, and Terry Lynn Karl. 1991. What Democ-
Mainwaring, Scott, and Anibal Perez-Lina n. 2003. Level of racy Is . . . and Is Not. Journal of Democracy 2(3): 7588.
Development and Democracy: Latin American Exception- Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. 1950. Capitalism, Socialism, and
alism. Comparative Political Studies 11(9): 103167. Democracy. 3rd ed. New York: Harper and Brothers.
Mansfield, Edward D., and Jack Snyder. 2002. Incomplete De- Shin, Doh Chull. 1994. On the Third Wave of Democratization:
mocratization and the Outbreak of Military Disputes. In- A Synthesis and Evaluation of Recent Theory and Research.
ternational Studies Quarterly 46(4): 52949. World Politics 47(1): 13570.
McFaul, Michael. 2002. The Fourth Wave of Democracy and Smith, Benjamin B. 2005. Life of the Party: The Origins
Dictatorship: Noncooperative Transitions in the Postcom- of Regime Breakdown and Persistence under Single-Party
munist World. World Politics 54(2): 21244. Rule. World Politics 57(3): 42151.
Munck, Gerardo L., and Jay Verkuilen. 2002. Conceptualizing Snyder, Richard. 2006. Beyond Electoral Authoritarianism.
and Measuring Democracy: Evaluating Alternative Indices. In Electoral Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree Com-
Comparative Political Studies 35(1): 524. petition, ed. Andreas Schedler. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner,
ODonnell, Guillermo. 1994. Delegative Democracy. Journal 21931.
of Democracy 5(1): 5569. Stepan, Alfred, and Graeme Robertson. 2003. An Arab More
ODonnell, Guillermo A., and Philippe C. Schmitter. 1986. than Muslim Electoral Gap. Journal of Democracy 14(3):
Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions 3044.
about Uncertain Democracies. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Zakaria, Fareed. 1997. The Rise of Illiberal Democracy. For-
University Press. eign Affairs 76(6): 2243.

Вам также может понравиться