Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 16

Lan Xia, Kent B. Monroe, & Jennifer L.

Cox

The Price Is Unfair! A Conceptual


Framework of Price Fairness
Perceptions
Recent news coverage on pricing portrays the importance of price fairness. This article conceptually integrates the
theoretical foundations of fairness perceptions and summarizes empirical findings on price fairness. The authors
identify research issues and gaps in existing knowledge on buyers perceptions of price fairness. The article con-
cludes with guidelines for managerial practice.

he issue of price fairness has become newsworthy as 1975). In this article, we present a conceptual framework

T concerns about gasoline prices, prescription drug


prices, physicians retainer fees, smart vending
machines, hidden fees and charges, or Amazon.coms
for price fairness that integrates the conceptualizations and
organizes existing price fairness research. We then use the
framework to identify gaps in existing research and to offer
dynamic pricing test have become public knowledge. The guidance for further research. As we proceed, we develop a
uproar that occurred when an Amazon.com customer dis- set of propositions for new research. We conclude with
covered that the price of same-title DVDs differed across some practical prescriptions for pricing managers.
purchase occasions was a public relations nightmare for the
firm (Adamy 2000). This example shows that both the price
offered and the rationale for offering a certain price may Perceived Price Fairness: The
lead to perceptions of price unfairness. Perceptions of price Conceptual Framework
unfairness may lead to negative consequences for the seller, Over the years, researchers have developed and adapted
including buyers leaving the exchange relationship, spread- various theories to obtain an understanding of when and
ing negative information, or engaging in other behaviors how buyers form price fairness judgments (see the Appen-
that damage the seller (e.g., Campbell 1999). dix). Figure 1 illustrates our conceptual framework, the
Why do consumers at times believe that they are being rationale for which we develop next. We begin by dis-
treated unfairly? Given increasing public concern, it seems cussing the concept of price fairness. Then, we discuss var-
appropriate to explore further the theoretical bases and ious factors that influence price fairness perceptions at the
empirical findings to clarify what is known about the causes transaction level. Finally, we discuss buyers behavioral
of perceived price unfairness and how the perceptions influ- reactions to sellers when unfair price perceptions occur.
ence customers behaviors. Various conceptualizations have
been developed and adapted to explain the phenomenon of The Concept of Price Fairness
fairness. However, each approach tends to address a specific Previously, fairness has been defined as a judgment of
reason for price fairness. For example, the dual entitlement whether an outcome and/or the process to reach an outcome
principle emphasizes the influence of supply and demand are reasonable, acceptable, or just (e.g., Bolton, Warlop, and
changes and the sellers profit orientation (Kahneman, Alba 2003). The cognitive aspect of this definition indicates
Knetsch, and Thaler 1986b). Equity theory and distributive that price fairness judgments involve a comparison of a
justice emphasize the importance of equality of outcomes price or procedure with a pertinent standard, reference, or
between two parties in an exchange (Adams 1965; Homans norm. Nevertheless, to develop the conceptual meaning of
1961). In contrast, procedural justice focuses on the influ- fairness, we need to make several clarifications about this
ence of the underlying procedures used to determine the construct. First, fairness and unfairness may be conceptu-
outcomes on fairness perceptions (Thibaut and Walker ally different constructs. It is possible to be clear about one
without having clarity about the other (Finkel 2001).
Notions of unfairness are typically clearer, sharper, and
Lan Xia is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Bentley College (e-mail: more concrete than notions of fairness. People know what is
lxia@bentley.edu). Kent B. Monroe is J.M. Jones Professor of Marketing, unfair when they see or experience it, but it is difficult to
Department of Business Administration, University of Illinois, Champaign articulate what is fair.
(e-mail: kbmonroe@uiuc.edu). Jennifer L. Cox is Associate Brand Man- Second, all price evaluations, including fairness assess-
ager, John Deere Worldwide Commercial & Consumer Equipment ments, are comparative. Both equity theory and the theory
(e-mail: CoxJenniferL@JohnDeere.com). The authors gratefully acknowl-
of distributive justice suggest that perceptions of fairness
edge the support of the anonymous JM reviewers for their helpful sugges-
tions and for their support during the development of this article. are induced when a person compares an outcome (e.g.,
input and output ratio) with a comparative others outcome.

Journal of Marketing
Vol. 68 (October 2004), 115 Price Fairness Perceptions / 1
FIGURE 1
A Conceptual Framework of Price Fairness

Actions
No action/influence
Perceived price Perceived value Self-protection (e.g.,
Price fairness Negative emotions withdraw from a purchase,
comparison Cognitive get a refund, complain)
Affective P5P6 Revenge (e.g., word of
mouth, legal actions)
P7P9

Transaction similarity
and choice of
comparison party Perceived cost of
Knowledge, beliefs, and social action and relative
P1P2 norms power

Distribution of cost and profit


Attributions of responsibility

Buyerseller relationship stage (trust) P3P4

The principle of distributive justice maintains that people, inequality may lead to a judgment either that the price is
in an exchange relationship with others, are entitled to less fair than the equal prices situation or that it is unfair.
receive a reward that is proportional to what they have Third, a price fairness judgment is subjective and usu-
invested in the relationship (Homans 1961). Equity theory ally is studied from the buyers perspective. Therefore, the
broadens this perspective to include various comparative judgment tends to be biased by the buyers self-interest; that
others that may influence the perceived fairness of an is, the buyer tries to maximize his or her own outcome (i.e.,
exchange relationship (Adams 1965). A reference other tries to pay a lower price) compared with that of the other
may be another person, a class of people, an organization, party (Oliver and Swan 1989a). Thus, the judgment and
or the individual himself relative to his experiences from an feelings associated with advantaged and disadvantaged
earlier point in time (Jacoby 1976, p. 1053). Indeed, social price inequality are different. Consequently, perceived
comparison processes are central to most theories of justice unfairness is less severe when the inequality is to the
and outcome satisfaction (Major and Testa 1989). In the buyers advantage than when it is to the buyers disadvan-
context of price fairness, the outcomes to be compared are tage. That is, for an equivalent magnitude of price inequal-
prices. When the price being judged differs from the price ity, we expect to observe a smaller degree of perceived
in the reference transaction, the price difference may induce unfairness when the inequality is to the buyers advantage
an unfairness perception. Such a price comparison is a nec- than when it is to the buyers disadvantage (Ordez, Con-
essary but not sufficient condition for price unfairness per- nolly, and Coughlan 2000). Indeed, Martins (1995) finds
ceptions to occur. that the perceived fairness effect of a comparable other
It should be noted that price comparisons can be explicit buyer paying less is stronger than when the comparable
as well as implicit. In explicit comparisons, people compare other pays more.
one price with another price or with a range of prices. For Fourth, previous research has concentrated on the cog-
example, a consumer may claim, I paid more than another nitive aspect of unfairness perceptions. We propose that
customer did, which is a comparison between two price affect is an important element that accompanies the cogni-
points, or I paid more than I used to, which is a compari- tion of price equality or inequality. A buyer may have feel-
son between a price point and a price range. However, the ings of unease or guilt when the inequality is to his or her
comparison may not necessarily be explicitly stated. For advantage but feelings of anger or outrage when the
example, senior citizens may claim that a price is unfair. inequality is to his or her disadvantage. These emotions
Although this judgment seems to be based on a single price, may occur concurrently with the unfair cognitions, or
it nevertheless is an implicit comparison to an unspecified arguably they may even precede such cognitions (Campbell
but expected lower price that they believe they are entitled 2004). Severe unfairness perceptions typically come with
to because of their limited fixed income. heat and passion, anger, and outrage; and they insistently
Price comparisons lead consumers to one of three types press for action or redress (Finkel 2001, p. 57). This strong
of judgments: equality, advantaged inequality, or disadvan- negative emotion is an element that distinguishes unfairness
taged inequality. A perception of price equality normally either from fairness or from less fairness. In this article, we
does not trigger a fairness perception, or if one is triggered, add affect as an important element of price fairness
it may lead to perceived fairness. A perception of price perceptions.

2 / Journal of Marketing, October 2004


Fifth, an unfairness perception and potential negative transactions. Costprofit distributions and consumer attribu-
emotions usually are directed toward the party that is per- tions are specific to a transaction (i.e., reasons for a specific
ceived as having caused the unfair situation. For price price). Then, such a transaction can be considered in a
unfairness, the target of the perception and the emotions is broader context of buyerseller relationships that are based
usually the seller. Thus, the actions that buyers take when on repeated transactions. Trust is the major concept in
they perceive that prices are unfair are usually directed buyerseller relationships, and we propose that it influences
toward the seller rather than toward a comparative other fairness perceptions. Finally, we place price fairness judg-
buyer or the product involved in the transaction. Finally, ments in a still broader social context and suggest that
fairness is different from satisfaction, though research has social norms and consumers metaknowledge of the market-
shown that the two concepts are highly correlated and are place also influence price fairness judgments. Most previ-
sometimes used interchangeably (Ordez, Connolly, and ous research has concentrated on costprofit distributions or
Couglan 2000). In this article, we define price fairness as a attributions, and we summarize previous research in that
consumers assessment and associated emotions of whether area. We further offer new propositions in the other areas.
the difference (or lack of difference) between a sellers Transaction similarity and choice of comparative other
price and the price of a comparative other party is reason- parties. Although social comparison research has focused
able, acceptable, or justifiable. on the similarity between comparative parties (Major 1994),
we extend the concept to include all aspects of the two
Factors That Influence Unfairness Price transactions. An economic transaction involves the
Perceptions exchange of a given product at a certain location for an
Various factors may influence unfairness price perceptions. agreed-on amount of money with specified terms between
In this section, we summarize the potential factors into four at least two parties. That is, transactions may vary in several
groups. The factors vary in terms of relevancy and immedi- ways. Transactions may occur at different times. Products
acy to a specific comparative transaction. The first group of may be the same type but with different brand names or
factors includes the variables that specify the context of the with the same brand name but different models. The same
comparative transactions. We have indicated that price com- product may be sold in a department store rather than a dis-
parisons, whether explicit or implicit, are a necessary but count store or in two different department stores. Different
not sufficient condition for price fairness perceptions to terms might accompany the transactions, such as a sellers
occur. Although both distributive justice and equity theory price promotion or a buyers coupon redemption. Finally,
use buyer and seller input and output ratios as comparatives, characteristics of the parties involved also contribute to the
consumers usually do not know either the sellers cost struc- degree of similarity between the two transactions. When
ture or other pertinent information to determine the sellers another customer is the other party involved in the compar-
input accurately (Bolton, Warlop, and Alba 2003). Thus, a ison, a person similar in age to the buyer is more compara-
price fairness judgment most likely is based on comparative ble than a person who belongs to a different age group (e.g.,
transactions that involve different parties. When perceived child, student, senior citizen), which might be entitled to
price discrepancies occur, the degree of similarity between different prices (Martins 1995). Such characteristics are an
the transactions is an important element of price fairness integral part of the comparison, and differences in the char-
judgments. Moreover, a fairness judgment also depends on acteristics decrease transaction similarity.
the comparative parties involved in the transactions. Social comparison research has reported a similarity
Second, in addition to information that establishes the bias, demonstrating that people tend to pay attention to the
relevant context for price fairness judgments, procedure jus- similarity between the two parties or entities being com-
tice theory, equity theory, and the principle of dual entitle- pared. Observable similarities between the two comparison
ment all indicate that information that provides reasons why entities induce people to access information that supports
a certain price is set may influence perceptions of price fair- the similarities selectively, which leads to an assimilation
ness. Previous research has shown that such information effect (Mussweiler 2003). Such an assimilation effect with
may include procedures or processes that lead to the respect to the involved comparative parties enhances the
observed prices. For example, a price increase may be saliency of the outcome differences that lead to a strong
caused by an increase in costs. In addition, the type of cost feeling of entitlement (Major 1994; Major and Testa 1989).
and whether sellers have control over the costs may influ- However, when the dissimilarity between the two entities is
ence the degree of perceived unfairness. Third, consumers obvious, people selectively access information that supports
may consider more than a particular transaction and make the dissimilarities, which leads to a contrast effect (Muss-
inferences based on their previous experiences. For exam- weiler 2003). Such a contrast effect leads to judgments that
ple, a consumer who has had a good experience with a the comparative transactions or parties are not similar,
seller during repeated transactions may assume that a price which offers a natural explanation for the perceived price
increase occurs for legitimate reasons when the reason for differences.
the price increase is actually unknown. Fourth, consumers Although this similarity bias has been discovered in
may also rely on their general knowledge or beliefs about person-to-person comparisons, we argue that the same prin-
sellers practices to adjust their judgments of price fairness. ciple applies to comparisons between two transactions. For
These four groups of influencing factors vary in their price comparisons, when the degree of similarity between
relative scope. Transaction similarity and choice of compar- the comparative transactions is relatively high, buyers have
ative party set an immediate context for the comparative little differential information to explain a price discrepancy.

Price Fairness Perceptions / 3


Thus, the assimilation effect leads consumers to expect or outcomes (Major and Testa 1989). Moreover, only social
believe that they are entitled to equal prices, and they are comparisons have a significant relationship with fairness
likely to judge the price discrepancy as unfair. However, judgments (Austin, McGinn, and Susmilch 1980).
when the degree of similarity between the transactions is For price comparisons, we propose that given the same
low, the contrast between the two transactions explains the transaction characteristics, the other-customer comparison
price difference. As a result, consumers will judge the price has the greatest effect on perceived price unfairness because
discrepancy as fair or less unfair. Indeed, a fairness judg- of the salience of such a comparison (Major and Testa
ment may not even occur if consumers consider the two 1989). Our early research shows that given a price discrep-
transactions incomparable. ancy, a comparison with a similar other customer leads to
P1: Given a perceived price discrepancy between two transac- higher unfair perceptions. Moreover, when there is no price
tions, a high degree of transaction similarity leads to a discrepancy, a comparison with a similar other customer
high perception of price unfairness. leads to higher fair perceptions than does the self/self com-
parison (Xia and Monroe 2004).
Many aspects of a transaction influence the similarity However, similar others are not always available as
between two transactions and consumers consequent price comparative references, and self/self comparisons are also
fairness perceptions. Whether and how one element (e.g., common. In self/self comparisons, people typically believe
product differences) has a greater effect than another ele- that they deserve the same treatment or outcomes that they
ment (e.g., store differences) is an empirical issue that have previously received. Overall, the choice of a compara-
needs research. It has been shown that observable product tive other party depends on both immediate availability and
differences naturally lead to quality inferences and cost salience (Major 1994).
attributions (Bolton, Warlop, and Alba 2003). Such infer-
ences are likely to decrease the degree of similarity. P2: Given a perceived price discrepancy and two transactions
with similar characteristics, the other- (similar) customer
Because the product or service is the focus of a transaction
comparison, when available, has a greater effect on price
and has a direct effect on consumers perceived value, we unfairness judgments than does the buyers self-reference.
expect that product differences have the greatest effect on
the degree of similarity and thus on price fairness Furthermore, little research has examined the effect of
perceptions. multiple comparative parties. Ordez, Connolly, and
In an application of equity theory to price comparisons, Coughlan (2000) examine the effect of multiple external
there are three types of comparative reference parties that references and suggest that instead of integrating all the ref-
consumers may use: self, other customers, or different orga- erences, people tend to compare with each reference inde-
nizations (e.g., stores). Indeed, each type of references has pendently. Consistent with prospect theory, Ordez, Con-
been shown to influence price fairness perceptions (Bolton, nolly, and Coughlan find that the pain of a disadvantaged
Warlop, and Alba 2003). Here, we single out the difference inequality relative to one reference is greater than the plea-
between self/self and self/other-customer comparisons and sure of an advantaged inequality relative to another refer-
suggest that price fairness judgments also depend on the ence. Thus, we suggest that when both self and other cus-
source of comparison as well as transaction similarity. tomers are available as references, the reference that
Although self is more similar to the individual customer produces a disadvantaged inequality for the buyer has a
than is another customer, a self/self comparison may not greater impact as a result of the loss-looms-larger effect.
necessarily have a greater effect on price fairness judgments However, when the two references both are advantaged or
than a comparison with another customer. Therefore, we disadvantaged, the similar other-customer comparative ref-
focus on the relative effects of a self-comparison compared erence has a greater effect on price unfairness perceptions
with those of other-customer comparison on perceptions of than do consumers self-comparisons.
price fairness. Which reference has a greater effect on price The costprofit distribution and attributions for the
fairness perceptions? If multiple references are available, inequality. A perception that a price is unfair results not
how do customers choose one reference over another, or only from a perceived higher price but also from con-
what is the combined effect? sumers understanding of why the higher price was set. The
Social comparison theory has identified similar others sellers cost plays an important role in buyers assessing of
as the most important comparison target because of its whether a price or a price increase is acceptable or fair
salience (Major 1994; Wood 1989). When people estimate (Bolton, Warlop, and Alba 2003). When buyers believe that
their own entitlement, they are most likely to choose others sellers have increased prices to take advantage of an
who are similar to themselves as the comparative other increase in demand or a scarcity of supply, without a corre-
party (Wood 1989). Only when external comparison others sponding increase in costs, they will perceive the new
are unavailable or not salient in the environment, or when higher prices as unfair (Frey and Pommerehne 1993; Kah-
people regard them as too dissimilar, will they make esti- neman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1986a, b; Urbany, Madden, and
mates of entitlement on the basis of intrapersonal (self/self) Dickson 1989). However, an unavoidable increase in a
comparisons (Major 1994). In addition, comparisons with firms costs may make the price increase acceptable (Kah-
others produce a greater effect on feelings of entitlement neman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1986a). Buyers will perceive a
than do self-comparisons. Research shows that social com- disadvantaged price inequality as more unfair if they per-
parisons (i.e., comparisons with others) explain more vari- ceive that the seller profits from the buyers loss. For exam-
ance in satisfaction than do peoples individual expected ple, consumers consider a price increase for snow shovels

4 / Journal of Marketing, October 2004


the morning after a snowstorm unfair, but they consider an Trust can be conceptualized as consisting of three dimen-
increase in grocery prices after an equivalent increase in sions: ability (i.e., skills and competencies of the trustee),
wholesale prices not unfair (Frey and Pommerehne 1993; benevolence (i.e., the extent to which a trustee is believed to
Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1986b). want to do good to the truster), and integrity (i.e., the
Making the sellers costs salient reduces peoples esti- trusters perception that the trustee is honest and fulfills its
mate of a firms profit margin, thereby decreasing their per- promises) (Mayer, Davis, and Schoorman 1995). These
ceptions of price unfairness (Bolton, Warlop, and Alba dimensions are closely related and are necessary for the for-
2003). However, not all costs are equally legitimate mation of overall trust.
(Bolton, Warlop, and Alba 2003). Price increases that result We suggest that buyers perceptions of price fairness are
from managerially influenced cost increases are perceived influenced by different dimensions of trust associated with
as less fair than are externally caused cost increases the relationship. In the context of buyerseller relationships,
(Vaidyanathan and Aggarwal 2003). Therefore, in addition it is possible that buyers emphasize different dimensions of
to considering the sellers costprice (profits) relationship, trust at different relationship stages. Lewicki and Bunker
consumers may make attributions as to who is responsible (1995) suggest that at an early stage of a buyerseller rela-
for such an outcome, especially when there is no clear tionship, the two parties are regulated by the potential bene-
information on the sellers actual costs and profits. fits of their promises and/or by the costs of cheating (i.e.,
Although attribution theory is not a theory of fairness calculus-based trust). Over repeated interactions, the rela-
per se, it provides a basis for how people rationalize an tionship develops, and the two parties begin to know each
ambiguous situation (Weiner 1985). When it is ambiguous other (i.e., knowledge-based trust). At this stage, pre-
as to why an unexpected price occurred and who is respon- dictability is key to the relationship, and each party antici-
sible for it, an explanation provides people with feelings of pates the actions of the other party. When the relationship is
control over their environment and serves as an adaptive fully developed, trust is based on a full internalization of the
function (Folkes 1990). In general, people are less moti- other partys desires and intentions (i.e., identification-
vated to seek attributions when they perceive the inequality based trust). At this stage, the two parties effectively
as to their advantage than when they perceive it as to their understand, agree with, and endorse each others wants
disadvantage (Weiner 1985). (Lewicki and Bunker 1995, p. 151). A party can be confi-
As we discussed previously, a perception of price dent that its interests are fully protected by the other party.
unfairness, especially the emotional aspect of it, typically is We propose that trust has a different meaning (i.e., empha-
targeted toward the seller. Therefore, buyers seek informa- sis on different dimensions) at different stages of a buyer
tion to determine whether the seller is responsible for the seller relationship. Thus, the nature of the influence of trust
situation of inequality. It has been shown that consumers on price fairness perceptions may depend on the specific
respond more unfavorably if a perceived price inequality is stage of a buyerseller relationship.
due to a firms volitional intentions or actions (internal On initial contact with the seller, buyers have no previ-
locus of causality and controllability) (Bolton, Warlop, and ous transaction experience with the seller. As a result, they
Alba 2003; Vaidyanathan and Aggarwal 2003). Thus, we may base their trust on the sellers reputation and contextual
argue that when buyers seek attributions to determine cues, such as store display and product assortment, or the
whether the seller is responsible for the price inequality, sellers publicized goodwill to assess the costbenefit of
they are strict with the seller out of their self-interest. That transacting with this seller (i.e., calculus-based). The initial
is, the seller is responsible for the perceived inequitable trust may not necessarily be low because a buyer may
price unless there is evidence that shows otherwise. There- choose to trust a seller until something goes wrong (McK-
fore, if buyers perceive the seller as having control over the night, Cummings, and Chervany 1998). At this initial stage
situation, or if the cause of the price differential is internal of the relationship, the important dimension of trust may be
to the seller, then the seller is responsible. However, buyers competence, because buyers may be more concerned about
may accept a firms goodwill motive even when the higher various aspects of a transaction, such as product quality,
price is not due to cost-related factors and is controlled by delivery, and return policy. For example, the sellers reputa-
the company (Campbell 1999). tion may serve as a cue for the buyer to form initial trust. A
good reputation signals competence of the seller or the
Buyerseller relationship and trust. Moving beyond sellers goodwill and serves as a buffer to buyers potential
transaction-specific information of costprofit distributions negative attributions for a price discrepancy (Campbell
and attributions, we now examine whether a buyerseller 1999). A sellers good reputation may make an equal or
relationship that is built on repeated transactions over time advantaged unequal price situation seem more fair and
influences fairness perceptions. A construct that is impor- decrease buyers price unfairness perceptions when a disad-
tant for understanding the status of a buyerseller relation- vantaged price inequality occurs.
ship is trust (Morgan and Hunt 1994; Sirdeshmukh, Singh, As repeated transactions between buyers and the seller
and Sabol 2002). Trust is a multidimensional construct, occur, buyers gain more information about the sellers trust-
defined as the willingness of a party to be vulnerable to the worthiness. Previous transaction experiences play an impor-
actions of another party based on the expectation that the tant role in determining trust. Thus, trust becomes more
other will perform a particular action important to the interpersonal and is more knowledge-based. Moreover,
trustor, irrespective of the ability to monitor or control that buyers begin to consider themselves loyal customers, and
other party (Mayer, Davis, and Schoorman 1995, p. 712). the relationship becomes an important basis for continued

Price Fairness Perceptions / 5


transactions with the seller. At this stage, the buyer knows their beliefs about the exchange norms to refine their price
the competence of the seller, so there is more emphasis on fairness judgments.
the benevolence dimension than on the competence dimen- In addition, because information is more readily avail-
sion. The buyer is more likely to take the sellers actions able in publications such as Consumer Reports and con-
personally. Thus, for customers who believe that they sumers are able to gain more information from their buying
have a close relationship with the seller, when the price is as experiences, they develop knowledge of marketers pricing
expected or lower, they may perceive it as a benefit of the tactics and of the relative costprofit composition of a prod-
relationship. However, when loyal buyers pay a price that is ucts price. This metaknowledge, whether accurate or not,
higher than their comparative standard, they may judge the guides consumers fairness judgments (Bolton, Warlop, and
seller as having betrayed their good relationship (Sirdesh- Alba 2003). However, the beliefs and metaknowledge may
mukh, Singh, and Sabol 2002), leading to a more unfair evolve over time (Wright 2002). A norm develops when
price perception. To illustrate, Huppertz, Arenson, and many people engage in the same behavior regardless of the
Evans (1978) find that when perceived price and service reason for the initial action (Opp 1982). Similarly, as the
inequity are high, buyers judge the situation as less fair dual entitlement principle suggests, stability is the norm. A
when they have a close and frequent exchange relationship practice that is initially perceived as unfair may slowly
with the seller than when the exchanges are infrequent. In spread and evolve into a new norm that is accepted by most
the context of online dynamic pricing, Garbarino and Lee people and is less likely to be perceived as unfair (Kahne-
(2003) find that a comparatively higher price decreases the man, Knetsch, and Thaler 1986b). For example, as the air-
benevolence dimension of trust but has no significant effect lines practice of dynamic pricing with yield management
on the competence dimension. technology becomes accepted by most consumers, the prac-
Finally, when buyers and sellers enjoy a close relation- tice is more likely to be perceived as fair (Kimes 1994).
ship that is truly based on identification, they share each Therefore, perceived unfairness of a price or procedure may
others values, desires, and intentions. In this case, level of decline over time (Kachelmeier, Limberg, and Schadewald
trust may be high on all dimensions, and faith is an 1991). Overall, when and how social norms and consumers
important element in such a relationship (Rempel, Holmes, general knowledge influence price fairness should be inves-
and Zanna 1985). Because of the strong attachment tigated in further research.
between the two parties, the relationship may sustain rather
strong challenges (Lewicki and Bunker 1995). Therefore, Effects of Buyers Unfairness Perceptions
the buyers overall trust in the seller serves as a buffer to Previous research has shown that unfair price perceptions
decrease the negative effect of a comparatively disadvan- influence customer satisfaction, purchase intentions, and
taged price on price unfairness perceptions. However, most complaints (Campbell 1999; Huppertz, Arenson, and Evans
business relationships remain at the calculus- or knowledge- 1978; Martins 1995). We suggest that price fairness percep-
based level without developing into an identification-based tions influence assessments of product value and customer
relationship (Lewicki and Bunker 1995). In summary, the satisfaction. In addition, the perceptions generate negative
influence of trust on price fairness perceptions depends on discrete emotions that may vary in intensity and type. These
the direction of the inequality and the nature of the trust, value assessments and negative emotions are mediating
which varies depending on the stages of the buyerseller variables that influence different behavioral actions, includ-
relationship. ing purchase intentions, complaints, and negative word-of-
P3: When the comparative outcome is positive or neutral (i.e., mouth communications.
advantaged inequitable or equitable prices), trust in the Perceived value. An important mediating variable of
seller has a positive effect on price fairness perceptions. buyers purchase intentions is their perceptions of the value
P4: When the comparative outcome is negative (i.e., disadvan- of the sellers offering. Buyers perceptions of value are
taged inequitable price), trust in the seller has a U-shaped
mental trade-offs of what they believe they gain from a pur-
effect on price fairness perceptions.
chase with what they sacrifice by paying the price (Monroe
Social norms and metaknowledge of the marketplace. 2003). Research has shown that buyers believe that a per-
Beyond the buyerseller relationship, consumers may draw ceived unfair price represents a lower value than a finan-
on their general knowledge about the marketplace. As cially equivalent fair price (Martins and Monroe 1994).
Bolton, Warlop, and Alba (2003) suggest, buyers may judge Assuming that there is no perceived difference in quality or
fairness at an aggregate level across a transaction space that benefits received from the product or service, this reduction
consists of multiple dimensions. In addition, buyers per- in perceived value must result from an increase in percep-
ceptions of price fairness stem both from economic compar- tions of monetary sacrifice (Monroe 2003). Similarly, Sinha
isons and from social norm comparisons. Social norms of and Batra (1999) find that perceived price unfairness
economic exchange are the understood rules of behavior for increases buyers price consciousness. Because price-
both buyers and sellers, and they serve as guides to behav- conscious buyers tend to focus on the monetary sacrifice of
iors of parties in exchanges (Maxwell 1999). Maxwell a price, higher perceived price unfairness increases percep-
(1995) demonstrates that, indeed, many price fairness judg- tions of monetary sacrifice. However, it should be recog-
ments stem from buyers considerations of how the seller nized that the same asymmetry between advantaged and
determines price and whether the price is affordable to disadvantaged inequality exists here. Although a disadvan-
everyone, particularly in reference to necessities such as taged price inequality may lower the perceived value of an
pharmaceuticals. Therefore, consumers may also rely on offer, an advantaged inequality may have no effect or may

6 / Journal of Marketing, October 2004


even decrease perceptions of monetary sacrifice (Martins pensation. Another objective is to cope with the negative
1995). emotions that may have occurred. A perceived large price
P5: A perceived disadvantaged price inequality increases per- inequality motivates consumers to seek monetary compen-
ceptions of monetary sacrifice, thereby lowering perceived sation. In addition, the different types of emotions that arise
value of an offer compared with situations of equal prices with perceptions of unfairness induce different actions
or advantaged price inequality. (Bougie, Pieters, and Zeelenberg 2003; Raghunathan and
Pham 1999; Zeelenberg and Pieters 2004). Such responses
Negative emotions. Research shows that unfair price
to perceived unfairness may be viewed as coping mecha-
perceptions lead to dissatisfaction (Oliver and Swan 1989a,
nisms to restore the desired equitable situation both finan-
b). Dissatisfaction is a negative experience that is correlated
cially and psychologically. We now outline a set of actions
with anger (Folkes, Koletsky, and Graham 1987; Storm and
that buyers may take when they perceive prices as fair or
Storm 1987). Research also suggests that specific emotions
unfair. Some actions are taken mainly to address the finan-
that arise from purchase situations may be more relevant to
cial issue, whereas others address the psychological issue.
buyers complaint behaviors, word-of-mouth communica-
It is not costless when buyers take actions to cope with
tion, switching, and repurchase than are satisfaction or dis-
a perceived inequitable situation. If they decide to leave the
satisfaction (Bagozzi, Gopinath, and Nyer 1999). Thus, to
relationship, they may incur switching costs that include
examine the affect dimension of price unfairness percep-
time, effort, and even money (Urbany, Madden, and Dick-
tions, we use a discrete emotions approach rather than dis-
son 1989). In addition, when considering the actions to
satisfaction, and we suggest that perceived price unfairness
take, buyers may also estimate their relative power and the
is accompanied by various negative emotions.
likelihood that they will succeed in executing the potential
An advantaged inequality may lead to feelings of
actions. Thus, the cost of action and relative powers
uneasiness or guilt, whereas a disadvantaged inequality may
between the buyer and seller moderate buyers potential
induce disappointment, anger, or outrage (Austin, McGinn,
actions when they face a perceived unfair situation.
and Susmilch 1980). We suggest that similar feelings occur
in the context of price fairness. Emotions that accompany No action. In a no-action situation, perceived unfair-
unfairness perceptions may vary in intensity as well as type. ness has no significant influence on buyers planned trans-
Although some emotions, such as uneasiness, may not lead actions with the seller. When buyers are advantaged, the sit-
to specific actions, some strong negative emotions, such as uation does not lead either to lower perceptions of value or
anger, may require a person to use coping mechanisms to strong negative emotions, though buyers may have feel-
(Bougie, Pieters, and Zeelenberg 2003). ings of unease or guilt. Research has shown that feelings of
guilt may promote a desire to redistribute or a giving
P6: An advantaged price inequality is associated with feelings behavior (Walster, Walster, and Berscheid 1978). For exam-
of uneasiness or guilt, whereas a disadvantaged price
inequality is associated with feelings of disappointment or
ple, in the context of price (un)fairness, the target for the
anger. potential giving activity, if there is any, may be a charity
rather than the seller, because the seller is not the disadvan-
These emotions may occur concurrently with or after taged party that suffers. Because the giving action is
the cognition of a price inequality, which leads to immedi- directed outside the buyerseller transactions, feelings of
ate reactions, or they may occur (or be modified) during guilt lead to no particular action in the buyerseller
value assessments, which lead to more deliberate actions. relationship.
Aiming to reinstate a price equality condition and coping When buyers are slightly disadvantaged, there may be
with the psychological discomfort of perceived unfairness, some decrease in perceived value and feelings of disap-
buyers may initiate actions to compensate themselves for pointment. If so, buyers either are not motivated to take
the monetary sacrifices and/or to vent their emotions in action or believe it is not worthwhile to take action because
ways that help them return to a normal emotional state. In of the cost of complaining or switching to another seller
the next section, we discuss buyers reactions when per- (Urbany, Madden, and Dickson 1989). However, although
ceived price unfairness occurs. Because the target of buy- consumers may take no action to change the current or
ers perceptions and emotions is the seller, buyers reactions future transaction relationships with the seller, they may
have consequences for the seller. still spread negative word of mouth to vent their discomfort
or disappointment with the seller (Zeelenberg and Pieters
Buyers Behavioral Reactions 2004).
Early price fairness research was motivated by the belief Self-protection. When buyers believe that an inequality
that perceived price unfairness constrains firms attempts to in an exchange is unacceptable and are upset, disappointed,
maximize profitability (Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler or regretful (if they believe that there is a better option),
1986b). That is, buyers react in ways that produce negative they may choose to complain, ask for a refund, spread neg-
consequences for firms, including lower purchase inten- ative word of mouth, and/or leave the relationship, depend-
tions, complaints, and negative word of mouth (Campbell ing on their assessment of which action is most likely to
1999; Huppertz, Arenson, and Evans 1978; Martins 1995). restore equity with the least cost. In addition, they may
We believe that when perceptions of unfair prices occur, search for additional information to assess the potential
buyers act to address the two elements of the outcome of switching costs or to assess their power to renegotiate with
their assessments. Therefore, an objective of buyers is to the seller. For example, Bougie, Pieters, and Zeelenberg
protect themselves financially and to seek monetary com- (2003) find that the experience of dissatisfaction usually

Price Fairness Perceptions / 7


evokes thoughts about what buyers missed out on and the driver of their actions. They evaluate the costs of action
need to search for more information to find out who or what and inaction and are likely to respond to the situation by
is responsible for the event. In terms of actions, buyers tend either no action or actions that seek mainly monetary
compensation.
to make a deliberate judgment about how to act, or they try
P9: When buyers perceive a price as unfair, negative emotions
to devote attention to something else. Therefore, when con-
are the major driver of their actions. They are more likely
sumers perceive a price as less fair, they may choose actions to cope with the negative emotion by spreading negative
to enhance their own benefits and to reduce their perceived word of mouth or even by seeking revenge with the goal of
monetary sacrifice. When the actions are less obtainable or harming the seller to get even psychologically.
too costly, they may choose to leave the relationship (Hup-
pertz, Arenson, and Evans 1978). The objective of these Overall, we have examined the various influencers and
actions is essentially for consumers to protect themselves consequences of price fairness perceptions. Our framework
from being taken advantage of in the future. At the same is not completely inclusive; we consider price fairness in a
time, spreading negative word of mouth is a low-cost action buyerseller transaction context and examine it from the
that helps buyers cope with their negative feelings of disap- buyers perspective. This perspective does not mean that
pointment or regret and prevents other customers in their price fairness cannot be studied from the sellers or third
social network from being exploited. partys perspective or at the group or organizational level. In
addition, factors such as buyers individual characteristics
Revenge. When a strong negative emotion, such as may influence whether customers evoke perceptions of
anger or outrage, occurs with a perception of price unfair- price unfairness under certain circumstances and how they
ness, customers leaving the relationship or complaining may react to those perceptions.
may not be sufficient to address the perceived inequity. The
feeling of anger, which is a distinct emotion from dissatis-
faction or disappointment (Bougie, Pieters, and Zeelenberg Implications for Pricing Managers
2003), typically is associated with perceived unfairness and The importance of price unfairness perceptions and their
leads to a tendency toward aggressive behavior. Anger impact on firms profitability has long been recognized
evokes immediate actions with no deliberation of how to (Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler 1986a, b). Although buy-
act. Studying consumers reactions to product failures, ers perceptions of price unfairness are based on perceived
Folkes (1990) suggests that anger mediates the relationship price differences, a goal of fair pricing does not mean a one-
between the attributions regarding the sellers responsibility price policy for everyone, nor does it mean that customers
and the desire to engage in conflict with the seller. Thus, to do not accept price changes or price differences. Indeed, a
cope with anger or outrage, customers may seek revenge. survey of retail businesses found 12 different customer
Angry customers want to get back at the organizations groups to which price discounts can be offered (Martins
(Bougie, Pieters, and Zeelenberg 2003). Such actions can 1995). A key question is how to make price differences
even occur at the customers expense, rather than compen- more acceptable and less likely to evoke unfairness percep-
sating them for their perceived loss. It has been demon- tions. We now offer some guidelines for achieving and
strated that customers seek revenge for a companys wrong- maintaining perceived fair prices in the context of differen-
doing by switching to the companys direct competitor, tial pricing.
even when switching is a less-than-optimal choice (Bech-
wati and Morrin 2003). Although the choice itself seems to Decrease Transaction Similarity
be irrational, the psychological benefit of switching helps As we conceptualize, when customers perceive two transac-
customers cope with the situation. In addition, when cus- tions as similar, the effect of observed price differences on
tomers become more angry, they are more likely to com- perceptions of price unfairness is greater than for other situ-
plain and engage in negative word of mouth and less likely ations. Therefore, perceptions of price unfairness can be
to repatronize the seller (Folkes, Koletsky, and Graham mitigated by a decrease in the similarity of the transactions.
1987). Although negative word of mouth in no action and The practice of yield management sets different prices for
self-protection is a mechanism for customers to comfort seemingly similar products or services, such as a hotel room
themselves psychologically, negative word of mouth driven or an airplane seat, but additional benefits or restrictions are
by anger transcends customers social network and has the attached to each offer, which makes the products or services
objective of damaging the seller. Therefore, additional less comparable. These restrictions decrease the similarity
actions such as reports to the media or legal and regulatory of the transactions and the attention that customers place on
agencies are possible. In summary, we argue that the sever- perceived price differences, thereby reducing the likelihood
ity of the perceived inequality and the differences in emo- of price unfairness perceptions. Contrary to this principle,
tions experienced further induce different actions that cus- Amazon.com charged the same customer a higher price for
tomers may take, the objectives of these actions, and the the same product on the basis of his purchasing history.
degree of damage inflicted on the seller. There was no differentiation between the products or ser-
P7: When buyers perceive a price as less fair as a result of an vice in the two transactions. As a result, Amazon.com
advantaged inequality, they take no particular actions to received negative customer and media response when the
change the transactions or relationships with the seller. practice was discovered (Adamy 2000).
P8: When buyers perceive a price as less fair as a result of a We suggest that product differentiation is a dominant
disadvantaged inequality, the value for money is the major factor in decreasing transaction similarity. Consumers infer

8 / Journal of Marketing, October 2004


quality differences when products differ, which helps them discrepancies occur. For example, as demand increases for
attribute the price differences to sellers cost, thereby reduc- products such as building materials after the occurrence of a
ing perceptions of price unfairness (Bolton, Warlop, and natural disaster, local retailers often maintain prices for
Alba 2003). Therefore, product customization and differen- necessity items (Haddock and McChesney 1994). Second,
tiation help decrease transaction similarity and the likeli- repeat transactions with a seller help build benevolence
hood of price unfairness perceptions. Information technol- trust. Therefore, loyal customers focus more on whether
ogy offers firms opportunities to customize their price and sellers care about them. When customers perceive an unfair
products. Price differentiation without corresponding prod- price, they are likely to perceive it as exploitation and are
uct customization may evoke price unfairness perceptions more likely to punish the seller. To show appreciation to
among consumers. loyal customers, sellers offer various reward mechanisms,
such as loyalty programs. Finally, the benefit to sellers of
Anticipate Reactions to Price Differences and continuously building such good relationships is higher
Provide Relevant Information overall trust, which can survive a strong challenge.
Our review indicates that additional information is helpful Although it is important for marketers to attract new cus-
for buyers to sort out whether the seller is responsible for tomers while maintaining existing profitable customers, we
the price differences and whether the seller benefits from recommend that marketers focus on different needs in trust
such differences. Anticipating that buyers will find price building and use different communication programs or offer
discrepancies based on the sellers pricing strategies and differentiated products to different segments to minimize
tactics, marketers should proactively provide relevant infor- potential unfavorable price comparisons across groups of
mation to influence buyers attributions for the price customers.
discrepancies.
When buyers are uncertain about product quality, price, Damage Control When Perceptions of Unfairness
and the sellers costs in an exchange relationship, sellers Arise
can communicate their costs or inputs to the exchange rela- It is important not only to prevent unfair price perceptions
tionship in several ways. Buyers perceive cost-based pricing but also to control the damage when perceptions of unfair-
rules as fairer than market-based ones (Maxwell 1999); ness occur. Our framework suggests that buyers believe that
however, consumers have little knowledge of a sellers they have made monetary sacrifices and/or have negative
actual costs and profit margins (Bolton, Warlop, and Alba emotions when they perceive a price as unfair. Although
2003). Therefore, sellers making the relevant cost and qual- increased perceived monetary sacrifice induces switching or
ity information transparent helps. Considerable amounts of complaint behaviors, the effect of negative emotions due to
such information are available on various Web sites. For price unfairness perceptions has not been studied. We argue
example, marketing communications campaigns that that negative emotions accompany a perceived unfair price
explain the firms commitment to using top-of-the-line raw and that buyers use different repair mechanisms to cope
materials for its products signal to consumers that the with the increased perceived monetary sacrifice and their
sellers quality and costs are relatively high (Kirmani and negative emotions.
Rao 2000). When buyers major concern is the actual price differ-
In addition, although sellers may be unwilling to make ence, the seller may control the potential damage by offer-
their cost structures and margins known to customers, they ing a refund, an additional reward (monetary or gift), or
can switch buyers attention away from prices to focus on another form of compensation. However, when unfairness
the value that they provide. For example, sellers emphasis perceptions are accompanied with strong negative emo-
on flexible travel dates, the ability to seek a refund, and tions, financial compensation may not be sufficient. The
friendly cancellation policies communicate the relative seller needs to offer a venue that allows buyers to vent
value of a comparatively higher airfare. Furthermore, such their negative emotions. Negative word of mouth is a com-
benefits help reduce the tension of a comparatively higher mon behavior that consumers use to release their disap-
price when the buyers value the benefits. Buyers are more pointment with a transaction. Instead of having consumers
likely to seek information when price discrepancies occur. spread such negative word of mouth to their social network
Thus, sellers offering relevant information in advance may or beyond, marketers can set up a forum, such as an online
decrease the likelihood of severe perceptions of price discussion board monitored by the firm, to redirect such
unfairness (Collie, Bradley, and Sparks 2002). feelings and to give the firm an opportunity to explain and
offer compensation.
Manage Customer Relationships In addition, the interaction between the buyers and the
We have conceptualized price fairness in the context of sellers representatives is the key to managing angry cus-
buyerseller transactions, and we have argued that trust is tomers. The desire for vengeance after a dissatisfying expe-
an important factor that influences perceptions of price fair- rience is influenced by how well consumers are treated dur-
ness. As we argue, trust may have different meanings in dif- ing the redress process (Bechwati and Morrin 2003). When
ferent stages of the buyerseller relationship. First, a sellers treated appropriately (e.g., politely, respectfully), buyers
building of a good reputation may help build initial trust may reinstate their normal emotional state (Bowman and
and attract new customers, and this trust may serve as a Narayandas 2001; Smith, Bolton, and Wagner 1999).
buffer that helps decrease negative attributions when price Although buyers may still choose to leave the relationship,

Price Fairness Perceptions / 9


they may be less likely to seek revenge, an action that is compared (other than price) and how customers choose a
most damaging to the seller. Thus, sellers need to reach comparison source among various available references have
their customers proactively when severe unfair price per- not been studied. Empirical identification of the characteris-
ceptions arise and to minimize the damages by redressing tics of the comparative transactions that lead to greater sim-
the situation appropriately. Honest and fair prices and prac- ilarity and thus greater unfairness perceptions will provide
tices can prevent detrimental buyer behavior and harm to ideas on how to control or reduce such perceptions.
the buyerseller relationship. Third, we suggest that researchers examine factors that
influence price fairness judgments across the spectrum:
transaction contextual information, procedure information
Directions for Further Research (e.g., specific attributions), buyerseller relationships (e.g.,
Research in the area of price fairness has been sparse until different types and dimensions of trust along relationship
recently. Our framework integrates existing theories of fair- development), and more generic influences (e.g., social
ness and provides potential directions for further research. norms, consumer knowledge, individual characteristics).
First, existing research has used the concept of price fair- Recent research has focused on the influence of costprofit
ness without explicitly defining it. We argue that price fair- distributions and buyers attributions of the causes of price
ness is a different concept from that of price unfairness. discrepancies (e.g., Bolton, Warlop, and Alba 2003; Camp-
Consumers are clearer and more articulate about what they bell 1999; Vaidyanathan and Aggarwal 2003). We suggest
perceive as unfair prices than they are about fair prices. that the influence of the buyerseller relationship and the
Indeed, price fairness may not even be an issue until con- different types and dimensions of trust in the different stages
sumers perceive a price as unfair. We have added affect as of the relationship are worthy and testable factors. In addi-
an important element of the price fairness concept, and we tion, consumers may have different degrees of sensitivity to
suggest that there are different types of negative emotions fairness or equity issues, which provides a potentially inter-
associated with price unfairness perceptions. A truly unfair esting covariate for further empirical research (Oliver 1997).
perception is accompanied by strong negative emotions, Finally, we have identified potential consequences of
such as anger and outrage, which may lead to severe actions perceived fairness or unfairness on both buyers and sellers.
toward the seller. Using qualitatively different emotions as For buyers, a perceived less fair or unfair price may lead to
anchors and the cognition of price inequality, we argue that lower perceived value and/or negative emotions. These two
much of existing empirical research on price unfairness can consequences may require different coping actions, thus
be labeled less fairness. Although consumers may believe leading to different behaviors. It would be informative to
that it is less fair that a department store sells a similar prod- test whether and how perceptions of value and negative
uct at a higher price than a discount store, this less price emotions mediate the relationship between perceived
fairness perception may not prevent them from shopping at unfairness and the various types of actions that consumers
the department store. Conceptually distinguishing between may take. In addition, recent research has pointed out that
less fair and unfair and different types of emotions associ- different types of emotions can be qualitatively different
ated with price inequality helps us focus on the real unfair and associated with different thoughts and behavioral reac-
price situations, which have not received much research tions. An examination of different emotions that accompany
attention in marketing. different degrees of perceived price unfairness may enhance
Second, we use similarity and the source of comparison the understanding of consumers potential responses and
(parties involved in the transactions being compared) as the consequences to the sellers. These consequences and
key concepts of the price comparison process. Although responses provide a basis for broadening the previous
previous price fairness research has recognized that fairness research focus beyond buyers purchase intentions and make
judgments are comparative, both the specifics of what is important substantive contributions to marketing knowledge.

APPENDIX
Summary of Research Relevant to Price Fairness

Author(s) Proposed Theory Study Variables Tested Key Results

Bolton, Warlop, and Fairness judgments Tests reactions to Historical prices; People do not have
Alba (2003) may be based on perceived differences store-price image; accurate mental cost
previous prices, of historical prices, store strategies, risks, or profit models for
competitor prices, and relation between and costs; and firms.
profits; attributions store-price levels, perceived price Increases in some
depend on the expected profits, fairness. firm (fair) costs lead
difference between perceived firm costs, to increased
reference point and and profit sources. perceived fairness;
price. some costs are unfair
for price increases.
Price differences are
fairest when
attributed to quality
differences.

10 / Journal of Marketing, October 2004


APPENDIX
Continued

Author(s) Proposed Theory Study Variables Tested Key Results

Campbell (1999) Inferred motive and a Tests consumer Firms reputation, Relative profit and
firms reputation affect reactions to retail inferred motive, inferred motive
perceptions of price purchasing scenarios; inferred profit, influence fairness
fairness and future presents variations in perceived fairness, perceptions, which in
shopping intentions. the sellers intent and and shopping turn affect shopping
reputation. intentions. intentions.
A firms reputation
moderates inferences
of motive.

Collie, Bradley, and When outcomes of Tests scenarios in Knowledge of others Subjects who did not
Sparks (2002) others are unknown, which subjects paid outcomes, outcome know others
judgments vary with more, less, or equal to fairness, and outcomes rated their
procedural fairness, comparable others satisfaction with outcomes as more
but not when others and did or did not interaction. fair.
outcomes are known. know others prices. It is difficult to judge
distributive fairness
because of ambiguity
of why the outcomes
occurred.

Darke and Dahl Greater satisfaction Tests scenarios in Bargain size, loyalty Perceived fairness
(2003) occurs when the which subjects status of comparative mediates the bargain
outcome/input ratio of received smaller or other, satisfaction, and sizesatisfaction
a comparative other is equal discounts perceived fairness. relationship.
equivalent. Perceptions of
fairness enhance the
value of a bargain.

Dickson and Perceived fairness of Surveys traders of Frequency of rule use, Rules that treat cost
Kalapurakal (1994) a price depends on bulk electricity to fairness of rules, and increases and
the rule used to set determine use of and response to perceived decreases
price. perceived fairness of unfair prices. symmetrically are fair.
four cost-based Price increases due
pricing rules and four to demand increases
market-based rules. are unfair. The more
frequently a rule
occurs, the fairer the
rule is perceived.

Frey and Consumers evaluate Surveys consumers to Fairness judgments Perceived price
Pommerehne (1993) fairness by starting determine and acceptability of fairness for a price
from a fair or just acceptability of allocation alternatives. increase with excess
price. rationing excess demand is higher
demand. when supply may
expand.
Increasing price to
profit from demand is
unfair.

Huppertz, Arenson, When consumers Tests consumer Price inequity, service Price inequity may
and Evans (1978) perceive certain judgments of fairness inequity, shopping dominate service
factors in a of hypothetical retail frequency, item cost, inequity in consumer
relationship as exchange situations. and behavioral buying situations.
inequitable, they seek response. Buyers are more apt
inequity reduction. to complain when
price inequity is high.
Frequent buyers are
more likely to
perceive inequity in a
relationship.

Price Fairness Perceptions / 11


APPENDIX
Continued

Author(s) Proposed Theory Study Variables Tested Key Results

Kahneman, Knetsch, Dual entitlement: Surveys consumers to Fairness judgments It is fair for a firm to
and Thaler (1986a) Fairness determine standards when presented with raise prices when
considerations of fairness applicable reference transaction, faced with increasing
constrain profit- to price setting and to outcomes of the seller costs.
maximizing firms. understand the effects and buyer and the It is fair for a firm to
of fairness rules on reason behind the maintain prices as
market outcomes. changes. costs decline.
It is unfair for a firm
to benefit from shifts
in demand by raising
prices.
Kalapurakal, Dickson, Fairness of the dual Conducts experiment Perceived fairness of Absorbing cost
and Urbany (1991) entitlement principle is with students using the pricing rule. increases and
subject to context three pricing rules decreases and using
effects and is not as over four context cost-plus pricing is
general as previously scenarios. more fair than the
believed. dual entitlement rule.
Fairness perceptions
are influenced by
information about the
sellers costs,
margins, profits, and
pricing behavior.
Kimes (1994) Yield management Surveys hotel visitors Fairness judgments, Yield management
practices often to gauge their role of information, practices would be
encounter perceptions reactions to and role of restrictions and perceived fair if:
of unfairness. perceptions of fairness benefits, and Information on
when presented with perceived differences. varying pricing
different scenarios. options is available;
Substantial discounts
are given along with
reasonable
restrictions; and
Products perceived
as different have
different prices.
Martins (1995) Buyers may compare Manipulates price paid Perceived monetary Presence of a price
prices with by reference other, sacrifice and discrepancy is
comparable other reference other perceived price perceived as unfair.
buyers; perceptions of income, and product fairness. Perceived monetary
price fairness are type. sacrifice is
affected by significantly less
discrepancies. when reference
others pay more and
significantly more
when reference
others pay less.

Maxwell (1995) Fairness judgments Asks consumers to Price fairness. Both economical and
depend on economic cite cases of fair and social components
and social variables. unfair pricing. affect determinations
of price fairness.

Maxwell (1999) Social norms are Tests consumers Social norms and A classification
important in long- and reactions to questions personal and societal system and proposed
short-term exchange conveying selected approval. method of quantifying
relationships. firms pricing. social norms enables
further study of the
effects of social
norms on consumer
transactions.

12 / Journal of Marketing, October 2004


APPENDIX
Continued

Author(s) Proposed Theory Study Variables Tested Key Results

Maxwell (2002) If price equals Tests fairness Perceived fair price, Adherence to social
reference price, judgments using two attitude toward seller, norms for pricing
buyers infer levels of reference and willingness to procedures forms a
procedural price price, seller power, purchase. basis for fairness
fairness; if not, levels of justification, judgments.
consumers have less and three levels of Judged fairness of
intention to buy. price procedures. pricing practices
influences attitudes
toward the seller and
willingness to buy.
Maxwell, Nye, and Self-interest and Examines the fairness Fair prices, acceptable Priming buyers to
Maxwell (1999) social utility can exist and acceptability of prices, and effects of consider fairness
simultaneously when prices before priming. enables sellers to
buyers have been negotiation by priming increase buyer
primed for fairness fairness in bargaining satisfaction without
considerations. scenarios. sacrificing profit.
Fairness-primed
buyers demonstrate
more cooperative
behavior.
Oliver and Swan Fairness perceptions Surveys automobile Buyers and sellers An exchange is fair if
(1989a) in an exchange result purchasers inputs and outcomes, the buyers outcomes
from not only equity perceptions of fairness fairness, intention, and sellers inputs
dimensions but also and satisfaction in an satisfaction, and are high.
satisfaction. exchange situation. disconfirmation. Intention is influenced
by satisfaction, and
satisfaction is
explained by fairness
perceptions.
Oliver and Swan Consumers compare Surveys automobile Buyers, Consumers
(1989b) inputs and outcomes purchasers, dealers, salespeoples, and perceptions of
of other parties with and salespeoples dealers inputs; fairness are stronger
their own on the basis perceptions of outcomes; fairness; when their
of role expectations. fairness, satisfaction, disconfirmation; and outcomeinput
Fair price is implicit in preference, and satisfaction. scores exceed the
this comparison. disconfirmation. merchants.
Fairness is highly
related to satisfaction.
Ordez, Connolly, When making fairness Tests satisfaction and Satisfaction and Both advantageous
and Coughlan and satisfaction fairness judgments fairness. and disadvantageous
(2000) judgments, consumers when individuals inequity is unfair; the
use multiple reference compared hypothetical latter is judged as
points. salaries offered to more unfair.
MBA graduates. Satisfaction and
fairness are distinct
from each other.

Sinha and Batra Consumers are more Surveys 404 shoppers Perceived risk, price Strong positive effect
(1999) price conscious when about eight grocery versus perceived of perceived price
they perceive price products and uses quality, price unfairness of national
unfairness by national rating scales. consciousness, and brands on price
brands; such price perceived price consciousness.
unfairness leads to unfairness. Perceived price
purchases of private unfairness has
brands. indirect effect on
choice through price
consciousness.
Nonsignificant
relationship between
price quality and
price unfairness.

Price Fairness Perceptions / 13


APPENDIX
Continued

Author(s) Proposed Theory Study Variables Tested Key Results

Urbany, Madden, and ATM fee with cost Surveys 40 adults with Perceived fairness, Confirm dual
Dickson (1989) justification is more scenario that depicts a behavioral intentions, entitlement: Cost-
fair than without bank implementing a and switching costs. justified fee is
justification; switching new ATM fee. perceived as more
costs inhibit intent to fair.
leave bank. Fairness perceptions
may not predict
behavioral intentions.

Vaidyanathan and Inferred causes of Tests fairness Internal versus A price increase
Aggrarwal (2003) price increases affect judgments with external causes of caused by external
perceptions of price scenarios that provide price change, factors and not under
fairness. reasons for price controllability, and the control of the
increases. perceived fairness. seller is perceived as
fair.
A cost-justified price
increase is not
necessarily judged as
fair.

REFERENCES
Adams, J.S. (1965), Inequity in Social Exchange, in Advances in parison Information, Journal of Experimental Social Psychol-
Experimental Social Psychology, Vol. 2, L. Berkowitz, ed. New ogy, 38 (November), 54555.
York: Academic Press, 26799. Darke, Peter R. and Darren W. Dahl (2003), Fairness and Dis-
Adamy, Janet (2000), E-Tailer Price Tailoring May Be Wave of counts: The Subjective Value of a Bargain, Journal of Con-
Future, Chicago Tribune, (September 25), 4. sumer Psychology, 13 (3), 32838.
Austin, W., N. McGinn, and C. Susmilch (1980), Internal Stan- Dickson, Peter R. and Rosemary Kalapurakal (1994), The Use
dards Revisited: Effects of Social Comparisons and Expectan- and Perceived Fairness of Price-Setting Rules in the Bulk Elec-
cies on Judgments of Fairness and Satisfaction, Journal of tricity Market, Journal of Economic Psychology, 15 (3),
Experimental Social Psychology, 16 (5), 42641. 42748.
Bagozzi, Richard P., Mahesh Gopinath, and Prashanth U. Nyer Finkel, Norman J. (2001), Not Fair! The Typology of Common-
(1999), The Role of Emotions in Marketing, Journal of the sense Unfairness. Washington, DC: American Psychological
Academy of Marketing Science, 27 (2), 184206. Association.
Bechwati, Nada Nasr and Maureen Morrin (2003), Outraged Folkes, Valerie S. (1990), Conflict in the Marketplace: Explain-
Consumers: Getting Even at the Expense of Getting a Good ing Why Products Fail, in Attribution Theory: Applications to
Deal, Journal of Consumer Psychology, 13 (4), 44053. Achievement, Mental Health, and Interpersonal Conflict, San-
Bolton, Lisa E., Luk Warlop, and Joseph W. Alba (2003), Con- dra Graham, ed. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates,
sumer Perceptions of Price (Un)Fairness, Journal of Con- 14360.
sumer Research, 29 (March), 47491.
, Susan Koletsky, and John L. Graham (1987), A Field
Bougie, Roger, Rik Pieters, and Marcel Zeelenberg (2003),
Study of Causal Inferences and Consumer Reaction: The View
Angry Customers Dont Come Back, They Get Back: The
from the Airport, Journal of Consumer Research, 13 (March),
Experience and Implications of Anger and Dissatisfaction in
Services, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 31 53439.
(Fall), 37793. Frey, Bruno S. and Werner W. Pommerehne (1993), On the Fair-
Bowman, Douglas and Das Narayandas (2001), Managing ness of PricingAn Empirical Survey Among the General
Customer-Initiated Contacts with Manufacturers: The Impact Population, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,
on Share of Category Requirements and Word-of-Mouth 20 (3), 295307.
Behavior, Journal of Marketing Research, 38 (August), Garbarino, Ellen and Olivia F. Lee (2003), Dynamic Pricing in
28197. Internet Retail: Effects on Consumer Trust, Psychology &
Campbell, Margaret C. (1999), Perceptions of Price Unfairness: Marketing, 20 (6), 495513.
Antecedents and Consequences, Journal of Marketing Haddock, David D. and Fred S. McChesney (1994), Why Do
Research, 36 (May), 18799. Firms Contrive Shortages? The Economics of Intentional Mis-
(2004), Who Says? How the Source of Price Information pricing, Economic Inquiry, 32 (October), 56281.
and the Direction of Price Change Influence Perceptions of Homans, G.C. (1961), Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms.
Price Fairness, working paper, Department of Marketing, Uni- New York: Harcourt, Brace & World.
versity of Colorado, Boulder. Huppertz, John W., Sidney J. Arenson, and Richard H. Evans
Collie, Thrse (Tess), Graham Bradley, and Beverley A. Sparks (1978), An Application of Equity Theory to BuyerSeller
(2002), Fair Process Revisited: Differential Effects of Interac- Exchange Situations, Journal of Marketing Research, 15
tional and Procedural Justice in the Presence of Social Com- (May), 25060.

14 / Journal of Marketing, October 2004


Jacoby, Jacob (1976), Consumer and Industrial Psychology: Mussweiler, Thomas (2003), Everything is Relative: Compari-
Prospects for Theory Corroboration and Mutual Contribution, son Processes in Social Judgment, European Journal of Social
in Handbook of Industrial and Organizational Psychology, Psychology, 33 (6), 71933.
Marvin D. Dunnette, ed. Chicago: Rand-McNally, 103161. Oliver, Richard L. (1997), Satisfaction: A Behavioral Perspective
Kachelmeier, Steven, Stephen Limberg, and Michael Schadewald on the Consumer. Burr Ridge, IL: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
(1991), Fairness in Markets: A Laboratory Investigation, and John E. Swan (1989a), Consumer Perceptions of
Journal of Economic Psychology, 12 (September), 44764. Interpersonal Equity and Satisfaction in Transactions: A Field
Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard Thaler (1986a), Survey Approach, Journal of Marketing, 53 (April), 2135.
Fairness and the Assumptions of Economics, Journal of and (1989b), Equity and Disconfirmation Percep-
Business, 59 (4), s285s300. tions as Influences on Merchant and Product Satisfaction,
, , and (1986b), Fairness as a Constraint Journal of Consumer Research, 16 (December), 37283.
on Profit Seeking Entitlements in the Market, The American Opp, Karl-Dieter (1982), The Evolutionary Emergence of
Economic Review, 76 (September), 72841. Norms, British Journal of Social Psychology, 21 (2), 13949.
Kalapurakal, Rosemary, Peter R. Dickson, and Joel Urbany Ordez, Lisa D., Terry Connolly, and Richard Coughlan (2000),
(1991), Perceived Price Fairness and Dual Entitlement, in Multiple Reference Points in Satisfaction and Fairness
Advances in Consumer Research, Vol. 18, Rebecca Holman Assessment, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 13 (3),
and Michael Solomon, eds. Provo, UT: Association for Con- 32944.
sumer Research, 78893. Raghunathan Rajagopal and Michel Tuan Pham (1999), All Neg-
Kimes, Sheryl E. (1994), Perceived Fairness of Yield Manage- ative Moods Are Not Equal: Motivational Influences of Anxi-
ment, The Cornell H.R.A. Quarterly, 35 (February), 2229. ety and Sadness on Decision Making, Organizational Behav-
Kirmani, Amna and Akshay R. Rao (2000), No Pain, No Gain: A ior and Human Decision Process, 79 (1), 5677.
Critical Review of the Literature on Signaling Unobservable Rempel, John K., John G. Holmes, and Mark P. Zanna (1985),
Product Quality, Journal of Marketing, 64 (April), 6679. Trust in Close Relationships, Journal of Personality and
Lewicki, Roy J. and Barbara Benedict Bunker (1995), Trust in Social Psychology, 49 (1), 95112.
Relationships: A Model of Development and Decline, in Con- Sinha, Indrajit and Rajeev Batra (1999), The Effect of Consumer
flict, Cooperation, and Justice: Essays Inspired by the Work of Price Consciousness on Private Label Purchase, International
Morton Deutsch, The Jossey-Bass Management Series and The Journal of Research in Marketing, 16 (3), 23751.
Jossey-Bass Conflict Series, Vol. 33, Barbara Benedict Bunker Sirdeshmukh, Deepak, Jagdip Singh, and Barry Sabol (2002),
and Jeffrey Z. Rubin, eds. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 13373. Consumer Trust, Value, and Loyalty in Relational
Major, Brenda (1994), From Social Inequality to Personal Enti- Exchanges, Journal of Marketing, 66 (January), 1537.
tlement: The Role of Social Comparisons, Legitimacy Smith, Amy K., Ruth N. Bolton, and Janet Wagner (1999), A
Appraisals, and Group Membership, in Advances in Experi- Model of Customer Satisfaction with Service Encounters
mental Social Psychology, Vol. 26, Mark P. Zanna, ed. New Involving Service Failure, Journal of Marketing Research, 36
York: Academic Press, 293355. (August), 35672.
and Maria Testa (1989), Social Comparison Processes Storm, Christine and Tom Storm (1987), A Taxonomic Study of
and Judgments of Entitlement and Satisfaction, Journal of the Vocabulary of Emotions, Journal of Personality and Social
Experimental Social Psychology, 25 (2), 101120. Psychology, 53 (October), 805816.
Martins, Marielza (1995), An Experimental Investigation of the Thibaut, J.W. and L. Walker (1975), Procedural Justice: A Psycho-
Effects of Perceived Price Fairness on Perceptions of Sacrifice logical Analysis. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.
and Value, doctoral dissertation, Department of Business Urbany, Joel E., Thomas J. Madden, and Peter R. Dickson (1989),
Administration, University of Illinois. Alls Not Fair in Pricing: An Initial Look at the Dual Entitle-
and Kent B. Monroe (1994), Perceived Price Fairness: A ment Principle, Marketing Letters, 1 (1), 1725.
New Look at an Old Construct, in Advances in Consumer Vaidyanathan, Rajiv and Praveen Aggarwal (2003), Who Is the
Research, Vol. 21, Chris Allen and Deborah Roedder John, eds. Fairest of Them All? An Attributional Approach to Price Fair-
Provo, UT: Association for Consumer Research, 7578. ness Perceptions, Journal of Business Research, 56 (6),
Maxwell, Sarah (1995), What Makes a Price Increase Seem 45363.
Fair? Pricing Strategy & Practice, 3 (4), 2127. Walster, Elaine H., G. William Walster, and Ellen Berscheid
(1999), The Social Norms of Discrete Consumer (1978), Equity: Theory and Research. Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
Exchange: Classification and Quantification, American Jour- Weiner, Bernard (1985), An Attributional Theory of Achievement
nal of Economics and Sociology, 58 (4), 9991018. Motivation and Emotion, Psychological Review, 92 (4),
(2002), Rule-Based Price Fairness and Its Effect on Will- 54873.
ingness to Purchase, Journal of Economic Psychology, 23 (2), Wood, Joanne V. (1989), Theory and Research Concerning Social
191212. Comparisons of Personal Attributes, Psychological Bulletin,
, Pete Nye, and Nicholas Maxwell (1999), Less Pain, 106 (2), 23148.
Some Gain: The Effects of Priming Fairness in Price Negotia- Wright, Peter (2002), Marketplace Metacognition and Social
tions, Psychology & Marketing, 16 (7), 54562. Intelligence, Journal of Consumer Research, 28 (March),
Mayer, Roger C., James H. Davis, and F. David Schoorman 67782.
(1995), An Integrative Model of Organizational Trust, Acad- Xia, Lan and Kent B. Monroe (2004), Comparative Others, Trust,
emy of Management Review, 20 (3), 709734. and Perceived Price Fairness, paper presented at the Annual
McKnight, D. Harrison, Larry L. Cummings, and Norman L. Conference of Society of Consumer Psychology, San Francisco
Chervany (1998), Initial Trust Formation in New Organiza- (February 20).
tional Relationships, Academy of Management Review, 23 (3), Zeelenberg, Marcel and Rik Pieters (2004), Beyond Valence in
47390. Customer Dissatisfaction: A Review and New Findings on
Monroe, Kent B. (2003), Pricing: Making Profitable Decisions, 3d Behavioral Responses to Regret and Disappointment in Failed
ed. Burr Ridge, IL: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Services, Journal of Business Research, 57 (4), 44555.
Morgan, Robert M. and Shelby D. Hunt (1994), The
CommitmentTrust Theory of Relationship Marketing, Jour-
nal of Marketing, 58 (July), 2038.

Price Fairness Perceptions / 15

Вам также может понравиться