Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 6

Contracting in Agriculture, Design, and Welfare Considerations

(Tom Vukina, North Carolina State University, presiding)

QUALITY INCENTIVES AND SUPPLY CHAINS:


MANAGING SALMONELLA IN PORK PRODUCTION
PETER BOGETOFT AND HENRIK BALLEBYE OLESEN

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Mahidol University / Library & Information Center on March 17, 2015
Food safety is an important concern in mod- controlled by different producers, and the
ern food production. The transmission of setup involves moral hazard (as actions cannot
Salmonella from animals to humans via pork be precisely monitored), and adverse selection
meat exemplifies this (Hald and Wong). (as the costs of the actions are private informa-
Managing Salmonella in pork production in- tion). In this article we analyze how the struc-
volves quality management in supply chains ture of the supply chain (i.e., who trades with
with multiple players. The Salmonella preva- whom) affects the possibility to motivate in-
lence in pork meat can be reduced through vestments in quality improvement. Pig produc-
measures taken both before slaughtering and tion is predominantly organized in one of the
during the slaughtering process. We focus on two ways (see figure 1). In integrated produc-
the farm-level control measures. Actions can tion, a single producer handles both the mul-
be taken both in the production of piglets (the tiplying and the finishing stages. In separate
multiplying stage) and in the fattening of the production, two producers handle the multi-
pigs (the finishing stage) (Hald and Wong). plying and the finishing stages, respectively. In
Salmonella control measures in the finishing Denmark, separate production is typically gov-
stage have the highest effect if there are severe erned by three-month contracts between the
Salmonella problems in the multiplying stage, multiplier and the finisher (Graversen). With
and vice versa (Dahl). Hence, the control mea- the time lag between contracting and the test-
sures are substitutes. Salmonella rarely causes ing, the relationship among producers shall be
noticeable health problems to pigs and has no analyzed as a priori trading, where prices, pos-
direct effect on productivity (Dahl). Hence, the sibly conditional on subsequent test results, are
incentives to implement control measures at settled before testing (Bogetoft and Olesen
farm level must come from economic incen- 2003a).
tive schemes. Technically, this article is an extension of
One can test for Salmonella prevalence us- Bogetoft and Olesen (2003a), where we ana-
ing an inexpensive serological test (approxi- lyzed the investment incentives in a two-stage
mately $1.00 per test) at the slaughterhouse. supply chain (standard principal-agent rela-
Also, bacteriological testing of the piglets is tionship) with imperfect grading. We showed
possible, but expensive (approximately $1,000 that the possibilities to motive investments
per test) and, therefore, rarely used (Wegener depend crucially on the competitive environ-
et al.; Dahl). In Denmark, testing is done reg- ment. Consider the case of risk-neutral play-
ularly only at slaughtering. Based on these ers. When a buyer (processor or finisher) faces
tests, the producers are penalized for supply no competition (monopsonist), he can (a) han-
of Salmonella infected pigs (Nielsen et al.). dle the moral hazard problem by using a suf-
Often, multiplying and finishing stages are ficiently high powered incentive scheme and
(b) handle the informational asymmetry con-
Peter Bogetoft and Henrik Ballebye Olesen are professor and as-
cerning costs by rationing the investments to
sistant professor, respectively, Department of Economics and Nat- save information rent. Competition among
ural Resources, The Royal Veterinary and Agricultural University buyers prevents this. In this case the expected
Copenhagen, Denmark.
This article was presented at the ASSA winter meetings payments in an ex ante settled contract will
(San Diego, CA, January 2004). Articles in these sessions are not equal the expected value of the good that re-
subjected to the journals standard refereeing process. sults from the induced investment policy. In

Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 86(3) (August 2004): 829834


Copyright 2004 American Agricultural Economics Association
830 August 2004 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Integrated ownership Salmonella preva-


lence measured
Possible investment in Possible investment in
Salmonella Control Salmonella Control

Pigs
Multiplying Finishing
payment

Separate ownership
Slaughterhouse
Possible investment in Possible investment in

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Mahidol University / Library & Information Center on March 17, 2015
Salmonella Control Salmonella Control

piglets Pigs
Multiplying Finishing
payment payment

Figure 1. Supply chain structures

this article, we extend this model to a three- gets a signal about the quality of the good.
stage supply chain. At delivery, the pigs can be graded as either
In Denmark, the Salmonella control plan in- H (high quality = no Salmonella) or L (low
volves a nationwide incentive scheme adopted quality = Salmonella). The probability of re-
by all slaughterhouses (Nielsen et al.). Hence, ceiving these grades depends on the invest-
there is no competition after grading, and a pri- ment behavior (table 1).
ori trading is again the appropriate regime to Here, ,  0 and  +  1. Hence, the
consider. More than 95% of the pigs in Den- probability of getting a high signal is  if there
mark are delivered to cooperatives owned and is no investment. The  and V values are the
controlled by the producers. Cooperatives will extra chances of a high signal and the extra
not exercise market power against the produc- value generated by investment. The base value
ers (the owners). Thus, the trading between the (V 0 ) of a pig and the base costs (c0M and c0F ) of
finishers and the cooperatives should be con- multiplying and finishing a pig are normalized
sidered as a priori competition (Bogetoft and to 0 to simplify the exposition.
Olesen 2003a). For simplicity, we assume that the invest-
The article is organized as follows. First, we ment costs in the multiplying and in the fin-
develop a simple model. We then analyze the ishing stages are independent. Also, to sim-
outcome of different, but given (exogenous) plify notation, we assume that the costs are
supply chain structures, i.e., we assume that identically distributed across producers and
the trading partners are fixed. Next, we ana- stages. The investment costs are known only to
lyze the outcome with variable (endogenous) the individual producer. However, the cumu-
supply chain structure, i.e., when the produc- lative distribution of the costs, F(c), is common
ers choose with whom to trade. Finally, we give knowledge and satisfies F(c) > 0 and F  (c) >
numerical examples and conclude the article. 0 for all c > 0.

Exogenous Matching
The Model
We first consider a (static) situation where
We consider a three-stage supply chain, where
the producers cannot decide with whom to
a multiplier delivers piglets to a finisher who
fattens the pigs and ships them to the proces-
sor. Both the processor and the producers are Table 1. Investment Behavior, Signals, and
risk neutral. Each producer produces one unit. Expected Value
The expected value of a pig to the proces- Expected
sor depends on the investments made by the H L Value
producers. The producers investments are per-
fect substitutes. Hence, investing in both stages No investment  1 0
does not give higher expected value than in- Investment in + 1 V
vesting in just one stage. one stage
Investment in + 1 V
The processor cannot directly monitor the both stages
producers behavior. However, the processor
Bogetoft and Olesen Quality Incentives and Supply Chains 831

 
trade. Hence, the supply chain structure is (6) F = F cM [V ( + ) ph
exogenous. Since the processor does not exer-   
cise market power, he chooses prices such that (1  ) pl ] + 1 F cA
the expected payment is V if there has been in- [0 ph (1 ) pl ]
vestment in the chain and 0 otherwise. Hence,    
following Bogetoft and Olesen (2003a), the = F cM V F cM cM .
processor offers prices given by
Solving the first-order condition gives the
(1 )  following cost threshold in the multiplying
(1) PH = V and PL = V. stage
 

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Mahidol University / Library & Information Center on March 17, 2015
 
Integrated Ownership F cM
(7) cM = V   .
An integrated producer makes the investment F cM
in the stage with the lowest cost and invests if
The cost threshold, V minus the hazard rate,
(2) min{c M , c F } V. shows that the finisher uses his market power
to ration investments in the multiplying stage
The probability of the producer investing is to save information rent.
1 (1 F(V))2 = 2F(V) F(V)2 , i.e., one We can now derive the cost threshold for the
minus the probability of the investments costs finisher, who will invest [using (7)] if
exceeding V in both stages.    
(8) V c F F cM V F cM cM
Separate Ownership  

  F cM
If a finisher in a supply chain with separate cF = V F cM   .
production does not invest, he will offer the F cM
multiplier prices depending on the signal of
the final good, i.e., the finisher will pay ph to Observe that cF < V because the finisher in-
the multiplier if the signal is H and pl if the vests only if the profit from investing exceeds
signal is L. However, if the finisher decides to the expected profit that he can obtain by mo-
invest, he will not motivate the multiplier to tivating the multiplier to invest. Note also that
invest and offer prices ph = pl = 0. Below, we cF > cM , i.e., investments will be higher in the
define the cost thresholds for the finisher and last stage of the production chain, because of
the multiplier, respectively. The cost thresh- the rationing effect.
olds are the cost levels below which the pro- The probability of investment in the sup-
ducers will invest and above which they will not ply chain is the probability of the finisher in-
invest. vesting plus the probability of the multiplier
We first analyze the investment behavior of investing
the multiplier when the finisher does not in-  2    
vest. The multiplier will invest if (9) F(V F cM F cM
   2    
(3) ( + ) ph + (1  ) pl c M + 1 F V F cM F cM
     
ph + (1 ) pl . F V F cM F cM .

This means that the cost threshold for the Comparing this to the outcome with inte-
multiplier is grated producers gives the following result.

(4) cM = ( ph pl ). PROPOSITION 1. With exogenous trading


structure, integrated ownership yields more in-
The individual rationality constraint for vestments and thus better quality than separate
a noninvesting multiplier will be binding ownership.
(Bogetoft and Olesen 2003a). Hence, Proof : From F(V F(cM )2 /F  (cM )) <
(5) ph + (1 ) p1 = 0. F(V) and 1 F(V F(cM )2 /F  (cM )) < 2
F(V), we get F(V F(cM )2 /F  (cM )) 1 F(V
The profit to the finisher when he does not F(cM )/F  (cM )) < F(V)[2 F(V)] = 2F(V)
invest [using (4) and (5)] is F(V)2 . 
832 August 2004 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

This is a standard result for a model tain an expected net payment of 0 and an
with two-sided moral hazard (Holmstrom). investing finisher will obtain V due to the sym-
Bogetoft and Olesen (2003b) analyze this sit- metry. This follows from a Bertrand-like ar-
uation in further detail. gument. Suppose that a noninvesting finisher
matched up with an investing multiplier re-
Endogenous Matching quired a positive expected net payment, he
would then be undercut by another noninvest-
ing finisher trading with a noninvesting multi-
We now consider a dynamic world where the plier and, therefore, earn 0. The equilibrium1
trading structure is endogenous. We assume gives cost thresholds of cIM = cIF = V and re-
that the integrated producers will not change quires F(V) 1/2 to be feasible.

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Mahidol University / Library & Information Center on March 17, 2015
trading partners. This assumption seems plau- In Case II, we assume that the number of
sible. An integrated producer will expose his investing finishers exceeds the number of non-
herd to new diseases and loose coordination investing multipliers, i.e., F(cIIF ) > 1 F(cM ).
II
advantages if he buys piglets from an out- An investing finisher matched up with an in-
side source (Dahl and Graversen). On the vesting multiplier gets 1/2 V. If an investing fin-
other hand, we allow the separate producers isher trading with a noninvesting multiplier
to match up with the most attractive trad- requires more than 1/2 V, he will be undercut
ing partner. In practice, separate producers by an investing finisher, who trades with an
actually change trading partners frequently investing multiplier. Thus, investing finishers
(Graversen). and investing multipliers cannot obtain more
than 1/2 V. This means that, noninvesting finish-
Separate Ownership ers will obtain at least 1/2 V since a supply chain
generates a payment of V. It follows that an
The substitution between investments makes
investing finisher has incentives to save his in-
it attractive for an investing producer to be
vestment costs because this can happen with-
paired with a noninvesting producer. Figure 2
out loosing expected payment. Thus, Case II
illustrates the possible trading structures when
cannot be an equilibrium.
investing multipliers trade with noninvesting
In Case III, where F(cIII M ) = F(cF ) = 1/2,
III
finishers and vice versa. The producers will use
all pigs delivered to the processor come from
separating contracts (e.g., contracts that are
a supply chain with investment in one stage.
only attractive to investing multipliers) to re-
The equilibrium must satisfy two sets of con-
veal the investment behavior of their trading
straints: (a) the producers should not gain by
partner (Bogetoft and Olesen 2003a).
changing trading partner and (b) the producers
The incentives to invest depend on the equi-
should not gain by changing their status (e.g.,
librium prices for the piglets. We analyze the
from noninvesting to investing producer). If
three cases from the finishers perspective.
an investing finisher obtains expected payment
However, the results also hold for multipliers
(EPI ) between 1/2 V and V, V/2 EPI V,
because the problem is symmetric.
neither he nor his trading partner, a nonin-
In Case I, we assume that the number of
vesting multiplier, have incentives to change
noninvesting finishers exceeds the number of
trading partner. An investing finisher, how-
investing multipliers, i.e., 1 F(cIF ) > F(cIM ).
ever, will stop investing and thereby change
In this case, the investing multipliers hold the
the equilibrium to Case I if his costs exceeds
market power. A noninvesting finisher will ob-
EPI . Thus, in Case III, we must have EPI
c, where c is given by F(c) = 1/2. A nonin-
vesting finisher obtains V/2 c by investing
Case I Case II Case III and changing the equilibrium to Case II. This
means that the expected net payment to an in-
M F M F M F
vesting finisher2 in Case III must also satisfy
Inv. N.Inv. Inv. N.Inv. Inv. N.Inv.
V EP I V /2 c. In total, we have c
N.Inv. N.Inv. Inv. Inv. Inv. N.Inv.

N.Inv. N.Inv. Inv. Inv. N.Inv. Inv. 1


This can be achieved if investing finishers offer prices ph =
pl = 0 to multipliers, and noninvesting finishers offer prices ph =

V 1 + + and pl = V  1 , where > 0.
N.Inv. Inv. N.Inv. Inv. N.Inv. Inv. 1 1
2
The equilibrium can be achieved if investing finishers of-
fer ph = pl = V EPI , and noninvesting finishers offer ph =
Figure 2. Matching multipliers and finishers: EPI 1 1 
 + + and pl = E PI  1 , where > 0 and
1

three cases where max(c, V /2) EPI min(V /2 + c, V ).


Bogetoft and Olesen Quality Incentives and Supply Chains 833

EPI V /2 + c and V /2 EP I V. Note 1,2

that these constraints are not incompat-


ible since 0 c V. If c > V , Case I 1

Probability of investment
applies. 0,8
The analysis shows that only Cases I and III
are relevant. Case I applies if F(V) < 1/2 and, 0,6

otherwise, Case III applies. The probability of 0,4


Separate producers, endogeneous
investment in a supply chain with separate pro- Integrated producer
ducers is 2F(V) in Case I and 1 in Case III. 0,2 Separate producers, exogenoeus

The values in case of integrated ownership was


2F(V) F(V)2 . Hence, we have 0

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Mahidol University / Library & Information Center on March 17, 2015
0 0,5 1 1,5 2
V
PROPOSITION 2. With endogenous trading
structures, integrated ownership yields lower in- Figure 3. Quality investments in different
vestment and thus lower quality than separate supply chain structures
ownership.
This finding contradicts the standard find- Conclusion
ing in models with two-sided moral hazard.
The reason is that separate producers have In this article we analyze the incentives for
an advantage in being able to pair multipli- Salmonella control at farm level in different
ers with high costs with finishers with low supply chain structures.
costs and vice versa. The integrated pro- When the supply chain structures are given,
ducers do not have this opportunity, which separate production, where the production
creates a matching problem. One integrated stages are controlled by different producers,
producer may have low costs in both the multi- will suffer from rationing and coordination
plying stage and in the finishing stage while an- problems. The finisher will ration the invest-
other integrated producer may have high costs ments made by the multiplier to reduce the
in both stages. These integrated producers will information rent, and investment will not nec-
not pair up and utilize the differences in cost essarily be undertaken in the stage with the
levels. lowest costs. Integrated production, where one
producer handles both stages of the produc-
tion, does not suffer from these problems.
Example: Uniform Distribution Thus, separate production results in lower
quality than integrated production when the
We assume that cM and cF are uniformly dis- structure of the supply chains is given.
tributed in the interval [0, 1], i.e., F(c) = c. We find the opposite result in a dynamic
Table 2 illustrates the cost thresholds and the world with endogenous trading partners, i.e.,
probability of investment in each of the supply where the producers can choose with whom
chain structures. to trade: Separate production results in higher
Figure 3 illustrates the probability of invest- quality than integrated production. The rea-
ment in each of the supply chain types as a son is two fold. First, competition among the
function of V. The figure shows that a supply producers removes the rationing problem. Sec-
chain with separate producers and endogenous ond, separate producers will match up so that
matching dominates a supply chain with an low-cost producers trade with high-cost pro-
integrated producer that dominates a supply ducers. This gives the separate producers a
chain with separate producers and exogenous matching advantage since integrated produc-
matching. ers are locked in their own supply chains.

Table 2. Cost Thresholds and Probability of Investment in Different Supply Chain Structures
Supply Chain Cost Thresholds Probability of Investment
Integrated producer min{cF , cM } V 2V
3V 2
Separate producer, exogenous cM = V2 , cF = 12 + 12 1 + 4V 4
+ 12 1 + 4V (1 V2 )
Separate producer, endogenous c = min(V, 1/2) 2V for V 1/2 and 1 for V > 1/2
834 August 2004 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

These findings can be made subject to em- tations (Danish). SJFI Working paper, Food
pirical testing. Our model predicts a trend to- Economic Institute, Copenhagen, Denmark,
ward a structure where high-cost producers 1999.
pair up with low-cost producers. Finally, our Hald, T., and D. Wong, eds. Salmonella in
model indicates that Salmonella management Pork (SALINPORK): Pre-Harvest and Har-
increases the gains from specialization in pork vest Control Options Based on Epidemio-
production. logic, Diagnostic and Economic Research.
Final report to European Commission of
project FAIR1 CT950400, 2000, pp. 1249.
References Holmstrom, B. Moral Hazard in Teams. Bell Jour-

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Mahidol University / Library & Information Center on March 17, 2015
nal of Economics 13(1982):32440.
Bogetoft, P., and H.B. Olesen. Incentives, Infor- Nielsen, B., L. Alban, H. Stege, L. Srensen,
mation Systems, and Competition. American V. Mgelmose, J. Bagger, J. Dahl, and D.L.
Journal of Agricultural Economics 85(2003a): Baggesen. A New Salmonella Surveillance
23447. and Control Programme in Danish Pig Herds
. Incentive Schemes and Salmonella in Pork. and Slaughterhouses. Paper presented at Sal-
Paper presented at Third Annual Conference inpork 2001, The 4th International Symposium
on Economics of Contracts in Agriculture, on Epidemiology and Control of Salmonella
Copenhagen, Denmark, 2003b. and other Foodborne Pathogens in Pork,
Dahl, J. Personal Communication, The Danish Meat Leipzig Germany, 2001.
and Bacon Council, Copenhagen, Denmark, Wegener, H.C., T. Hald, D.L.F. Wong, M.
2002. Madsen, H. Korsgaard, F. Bager, P. Gerner-
Graversen, J. Implementing the Multi-Site Con- Smidt, and K. Mlbak. Salmonella Control
cept: An Organizational Economic Assess- Programs in Denmark. Emerging Infectious
ment of Incentives, Opportunities, and Limi- Diseases 9(2003):77480.

Вам также может понравиться