Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 4

Insights Finance Regulation World Americas Africa Asia/China Europe Middle East

The Privatization of Regulation in Global Markets:


Winners and Losers in the Private Governance of Financial and Product Markets

By Tim Bthe and Walter Mattli

Over the past two decades, governments have


delegated extensive regulatory authority to in-
ternational private-sector organizations. In
this article, based on their new book, The New
Global Rulers, Tim Bthe and Walter Mattli
examine this internationalization and privati-
zation of rule-making for global financial and
product markets. They analyze who writes the
rules in international private organizations
and explain why some win, and others lose in
the process of setting standards in such bodies.
The focus is on three powerful global private
regulators: the IASB, which develops interna-
tional financial reporting rules (IFRS) used by
corporations in more than a hundred countries,
and ISO and IEC, which account for 85 percent
of all international product standards.

O
n 28 August 2008, the world finan-
cial community awoke to stunning
headline news: The Securities and Financial reporting affects all sectors of the economy.
Exchange Commission (SEC), the powerful The shift of rule-making from the domestic to the inter-
U.S. financial market regulator, had put forth national level therefore is bound to affect a wide range
a "roadmap" for to the adoption of Interna- of interests, and bring deep, costly changes.
tional Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS),
produced by the International Accounting
Standards Board (IASB)a private-sector jurisdictions where stock market regulators particular types of transactions and events
regulator based in London. SEC-regulated permit or even require the use of IFRS has to disclosein a firm's financial statements.
U.S. corporations would have to switch from exploded since 2001. In the member states The common use of IFRS is likely to increase
using Generally Accepted Accounting Prin- of the European Union (EU) and about sixty the cross-national comparability of corporate
ciples (U.S. GAAP) to using IFRS, possibly as other countries across all continents, the information and improve the transparency
soon as 2014. Only a decade earlier, the sug- use of IFRS is already mandatory for compa- of financial statements for shareholders, in-
gestion that the United States might adopt nies with publicly traded financial securities vestors, and creditors. Consequently, it may
IFRS "would have been laughable," as many (stocks and bonds). And the trend is continu- bring greater efficiency and stability of global
experts expected U.S. standards to become ing: Government regulators of several addi- capital markets.
the de facto global rules for financial report- tional countries, including Japan, Canada, At the same time, much more is at stake
ing.1 Brazil and India, have committed themselves than disclosures in corporate financial re-
The SEC's proposal to require U.S. corpo- to requiring IFRS in the near future. ports. Through the incentives they create,
rations to follow international private rules The shift to common reporting rules financial reporting standards shape research
for financial reporting is part of a broader promises important gains for many par- and development, executive compensation,
and highly significant trend that is the focus ticipants in increasingly internationally inte- corporate governance, etc. Financial report-
of our new book, The New Global Rulers: grated financial markets. Financial reporting ing affects all sectors of the economy and is
The Privatization of Regulation in the World standards specify how to calculate assets, central to the stability of a country's finan-
Economy. As Figure 1 shows, the number of liabilities, profits, and lossesand which cial system. The shift of rule-making from

22 The World Financial Review


growing steadily over the last twenty-five years while the production
Use of IFRS as Allowed or Required by Stock Market Regulators
of national standards has dwindledas illustrated by the declining
number of new German (DIN) standards in Figure 2 (see next page).
120
Number of Jurisdictions/Countries

Little known until the mid-1980s, ISO and IEC have become promi-
100

nent, in part due to the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade, ne-


80

gotiated during the Uruguay Round trade negotiations from 1987 to


1994. This Agreement obliges all member states of the World Trade
60

Organization (WTO) to use international standards as the technical


40

basis of domestic laws and regulations unless international standards


20

are "ineffective or inappropriate" for achieving the specified public


policy objectives.3 Regulations requiring the use of a standard that
0

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010


Year
differs from the pertinent international standard may be challenged
Jurisdictions permitting use of IAS/IFRS2 through the WTO dispute mechanism as unnecessary non-tariff barri-
Figure 1 Jurisdictions requiring use of IAS/IFRS for some/all firms
ers to trade and thus a violation of international trade law.
The commitment by governments to use international rather
the domestic to the international level therefore is bound to affect than domestic standards has enormous economic significance, since
a wide range of interests, and bring deep, costly changes, especially governments adopt hundreds of new or revised regulatory measures
for countries or regions with large, sophisticated capital markets and each year. These regulations affect trade through the product stan-
long-standing domestic accounting traditions, such as the United dards embedded or referenced in them. And government regula-
States and many European countries. The greater the difference be- tions are just the tip of the iceberg, since consumer demand and con-
tween IFRS and long-established domestic rules and practices, the cerns about legal liability create strong incentives for firms to comply
larger these costs will be. International standards that end up being with a wealth of product standards that may not be legally mandated
identical or very similar to a country's domestic standards will maxi- but define best practice.
mize that country's net benefits of switching to "international" rules.
And in highly competitive international markets, differential switch-
This simultaneous privatization and inter-
ing costs may jeopardize even the survival of disadvantaged firms.
nationalization of governance is driven, in
Given the enormous stakes involved, distributional conflicts are very
likely, and the battle over global rules is likely to be intensely fought, part, by governments' lack of requisite tech-
especially between Americans and Europeans. nical expertise, financial resources, or flex-
The shift of financial rule-making to the IASB is part of a striking and ibility to deal expeditiously with ever more
much wideryet little understoodtrend: the delegation of regu- complex and urgent regulatory tasks.
latory authority from governments to a single international private-
sector body which, for its area of expertise, is viewed by both public
and private actors as the obvious forum for global rule-making. This The shift from domestic regulation to global private rule-making
simultaneous privatization and internationalization of governance is brings substantial gains, particularly to multinational and internation-
driven, in part, by governments' lack of requisite technical expertise, ally competitive firms, for which it opens up commercial opportuni-
financial resources, or flexibility to deal expeditiously with ever more ties previously foreclosed by cross-national differences in standards
complex and urgent regulatory tasks. Firms and other private actors and related measures. The share of U.S. exports affected by foreign
also often push for private governance, which they see as leading to product standards, for instance, had risen from 10% in 1970 to 65%
more cost-effective rules more efficiently than government regula- in 1993, and by the time the WTO's TBT-Agreement came into force,
tion. cross-national differences in product standards were estimated to
Besides the IASB, two such international private regulators stand result in a loss of $20-$40 billion per year in U.S. exports alone. U.S.
out: the International Organization for Standardization (ISO) and the imports and consumers were also affected. For some manufacturing
International Electrotechnical Commission (IEC). They jointly account industries, U.S. non-tariff barriers in the late 1980s created losses due to
for about 85 percent of all international product standards, i.e., the increased costs and reduced trade equivalent to a tariff of 49%. Even
technical rules that specify design and performance characteristics of today, about one third of global trade in goodsvalued at $15.8 tril-
manufactured goods. Cross-national differences in these standards lion for 2008is affected by standards that often differ across coun-
mattered little when product markets were predominantly domes- tries, and the boost in trade from a complete international harmoni-
tic. The global integration of product markets, however, has greatly zation of product standards would be equivalent to a reduction in
and lastingly increased international interdependence and thus cre- tariffs by several percentage points.4 A shift to common international
ated strong incentives to coordinate on common technical solutions. standards thus benefits internationally competitive firms by increas-
International standards offer such a solution. ISO and IEC product ing their export opportunities. It also benefits consumers who, as a
standards, in particular, play a critical role in facilitating international result of increased trade and competition, have access to a broader
trade and boosting economic growth. Their numbers have been range of goods and services and can buy them more cheaply.

September - October 2011 www.worldfinancialreview.com 23


areas of the global economy. The book is based on two compre-
New Domestic and International Standards per Year, 1980-2008
hensive multi-country, multi-industry business surveysone about
international financial reporting standards and IASB standardization,
Number of Standards

1800
1600
1400 the other about international product standards and ISO/IEC stan-
1200
1000 dardizationwhich we conducted among hundreds of companies
800
600
400
in the United States, as well as France, Germany, Spain, Sweden, and
200
0 the UK. We supplement the analysis of the survey data with insights
gained from more than two hundred interviews with senior and

20 6
20 7
08
19 5
19 6
19 7
19 8
20 9
20 0
20 1
20 2
20 3
20 4
20 5
19 0
19 1
19 2
19 3
19 4
19 5
19 6
19 7
19 8
19 9
19 0
19 1
19 2
19 3
19 4
9
9
9
9
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
8
8
8
8
8
8
8
8
8
8
9
9
9
9
9
9
19

Year
mid-level managers, current and former IASB and ISO/IEC staff, and
government regulators. Together, these data allow us to provide the
Figure 2 ISO + IEC Standards DIN German National Standards
first systematic analysis of key private institutions for the regulation of
global markets.
At the same time, the shift to global private-sector regulation
also entails costs. To comply with international product standards,
Global standardization is rarely about
for example, firms may have to re-design their products, retool their
production methods, or pay licensing fees to other firms whose pro- reaching a compromise among different
prietary technology may be needed to implement the international regulatory models and approaches. In-
standard efficiently. These costs can be massive, to the point where stead, it often entails battles for preemi-
some feel forced to discontinue production of certain goods or even nence of one regulatory approach or techni-
go out of business. cal solution over another.
In sum, while the convergence on a single set of international stan-
dards may bring overall gains for all countries, those gains can differ
greatly across countries and firms. Firms therefore have a strong in- International private rule-making as a
centive to seek to influence the process of international rule-making political process
to minimize their switching costs. For those who succeed in push- International standardization is sometimes described as an apolitical,
ing their domestic standards for adoption as international standards, scientific process of identifying or developing the technically optimal
switching costs will be minimal. The stakes thus are also high in the solution to a regulatory or technical problem. But there is seldom a
private regulation of product markets, and severe conflicts of interest single, universally optimal solution, and global standardization is rare-
are likely. ly about reaching a compromise among different regulatory mod-
There is essentially no alternativepublic or privateto ISO, IEC, els and approaches. Instead, it often entails battles for preeminence
and IASB as the global rule-makers in their respective areas. Their of one regulatory approach or technical solution over another. The
prominent position in the regulation of international markets raises language accompanying these processes is technical; the essence
pressing empirical and analytical questions, including: of global rule-making, however, is political, because it has important
Who exactly gets to write the rules in these private organizations? distributional implications and generates winners and losers. To
Who wins and who losesand whywhen standard-setting takes lose may mean higher production costs, steeper costs of switching
place in these private international organizations? What, in other to international standards, lower international competitiveness, loss
words, is the nature of politics in private-sector rule-making? of export markets, and even risk of corporate demise. Under these
Specific answers to these questions are hard to come by, in large conditions, technical expertise (and financial resources) are neces-
part because these global regulators are private. Financed mostly by sary but not sufficient conditions for successful involvement in global
voluntary contributions from private-sector stakeholders, they are not private-sector standardization. It is timely information and effective
subject to public oversight, and writing specific rules is in the hands representation of domestic interest that confer the critical advantage
of groups of experts who are not required to keep records of their in these regulatory processes, determining who wins or loses. Such
proceedings. It is therefore difficult to obtain systematic information representation occurs not through state or government intervention,
about these regulatory processes. Yet, global private regulation has as in traditional intergovernmental organizations, but through do-
in recent years become vastly more important and is now a phenom- mestic private-sector standard-setters.
enon of considerable social and economic consequenceit matters ISO, IEC, and IASB are not operationally self-sufficient. They heavily
to understand it. This makes the lack of reliable information all the rely on private-sector standards bodies at the national level for logisti-
more problematic, since comprehensive data are a crucial prerequi- cal and technical support. The domestic bodies thus are part and par-
site, not only for assessing but also for improving the performance cel of the global institutional structure of standardization; in a sense,
and processes of global private regulators. they form the institutional backbone of the global regulators. Domes-
In our book, The New Global Rulers, we provide not only a gen- tic standards bodies, however, are not disinterested aides to the inter-
eral framework for understanding private regulation but also detailed national bodies. They are accountable to their domestic stakeholders,
empirical answers to the above questions, thanks to seven years of whose regulatory preferences they seek to promote and defend at the
collecting extensive information on private rule-making in central international level to minimize domestic switching costs.

September - October 2011 www.worldfinancialreview.com 25


Domestic standards bodies and systems also vary widely in re- indeed due to the greater fit or complementarity between IASB and
sources and organizational structures and consequently in their abil- U.S. domestic institutions.
ity to enable domestic stakeholders to speak with a single voice and ISO and IEC play the corresponding central role in the private reg-
effectively promote domestic preferences. Some countries have one ulation of global markets through international product standards.
domestic institution for standard-setting or a clear organizational hi- Rule-making for product markets constitutes a particularly interesting
erarchy, with long-established procedures for arriving at a single na- counterpart to private rule-making for financial markets, because U.S.-
tional position on any technical rule. In other countries, standard-set- European differences in product standard-setting institutions are the
ting is market-based, and rule-making authority is fragmented among exact opposite of what we observe in accounting standard-setting.
multiple competing standard-setters. Both systems have served their The domestic institutional structure for setting product standards
respective domestic economies well by generally producing (in very in the United States is characterized by institutional fragmentation
different ways) high-quality standards over time. However, they differ and contestation among competing standard-setters, i.e., low insti-
in how well they serve national interests when standardization shifts tutional complementarity. In Europe, by contrast, standard-setting
to the global level. is characterized by a high degree of coordination and organizational
Who then wins or loses and why? We argue that firms operat- hierarchy at both the national and regional levels and thus greater
ing in a domestic system characterized by organizational hierarchy complementarity with the structure of ISO and IEC than in the U.S.
and coordination have a crucial advantage because their system fits And our multi-country, multi-industry business survey provides com-
more naturally with the global structure of private regulation. Such pelling evidence that Europe's usually much greater success in shap-
a domestic system enables a countrys stakeholders to speak with a ing international standards is due to the higher complementarity
single voice and in a timely fashion on the global stage. We call this between standard-setting institutions at the domestic level and the
a case of high "institutional complementarity" between the domestic institutional structure of standardization in Europe compared to the
and global levels. High institutional complementarity implies that United States.
the interaction between domestic and global institutions is smooth
and easy, yielding decisive strategic benefits to the firms in terms of About the authors
effective interest representation in global rule-making and timely Tim Bthe is assistant professor of political science at Duke University
information. By contrast, firms in a fragmented domestic system, and a member of the Rethinking Regulation project. Walter Mattli is
characterized by contestation among rival standard-setters are at professor of international political economy and a fellow of St. Johns
a distinct disadvantage. Their system fits relatively poorly with the College, Oxford University. Bthe and Mattli are co-directors of the In-
global system of private regulation, rendering both effective national ternational Standards Project and co-authors of The New Global Rul-
interest representation and domestic diffusion of information about ers: The Privatization of Regulation in the World Economy, published
new global standards projects more difficult. We call this a case of by Princeton University Press in April 2011.
low institutional complementarity between the domestic and global
levels. Notes
1. The "Roadmap to IFRS adoption" was published on 14 November 2008 in the
Winners and losers in global financial and Federal Register as "proposed rule" # 33-8982/34-58960, File # S7-27-08. The SEC
product markets has not yet committed to a specific timetable for IFRS adoption, but has repeat-
In The New Global Rulers, we show how the focus on institutional edly confirmed its commitment to IFRS in principle, most recently in a round-
complementarity helps explain the very different outcomes in global table held at the SEC on 7 July 2011. The quote is from John House, "Global
private regulation of product and financial markets, based on our in- Standards Here to Stay." Accountancy (August 2005), 72.
ternational business surveys and a wealth of other sources. In the pri- 2. Until 2001, the predecessor of IASB developed International Accounting Stan-
vate regulation of financial reporting, the IASB is unambiguously the dards (IAS). IFRS here refers to both the still-valid IAS and new international stan-
global rule-maker. The United States has in the Financial Accounting dards known since 2001 as International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS).
Standards Board (FASB) a single private organization that is uncon- 3. TBT-Agreement, Article 2.4.
tested as the institutional setting for developing financial reporting 4. These figures are from chapter 1 of our book (Tim Bthe and Walter Mattli,
standards at the domestic level. It provides an efficient and effec- The New Global Rulers: The Privatization of Regulation in the World Economy
tive mechanism for aggregating preferences, with high institutional (Princeton University Press, 2011), which includes the complete references for
complementarity vis--vis the IASB. Accounting standard-setting in them.
Europe, by contrast, is characterized by institutional fragmentation
and competition for authority among multiple institutional centers, The article is based on materials from the book: The
both at the domestic and the European levels. As expected, given New Global Rulers: The Privatization of Regulation in
these differences in domestic institutions, we find that U.S. firms are the World Economy, by Tim Bthe & Walter Mattli,
substantially more successful than European firms when they try to Princeton University Press, April 2011. All Rights Reserved.
influence international financial reporting standards. And responses For more information, please visit:
to a battery of questions about different methods of influencing IASB http://press.princeton.edu/titles/9470.html
standard-setting show that the greater success of American firms is http://www.facebook.com/NewGlobalRulers

26 The World Financial Review

Вам также может понравиться