Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 16

Journal of Economic Literature 2016, 54(1), 224239

http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.54.1.224

Did Science Cause


the Industrial Revolution?
Cormac Grda*

The role of science and technology in the First Industrial Revolution is still contested.
Some scholars, focusing on the textiles sector, argue that skilled and talented artisans
with no scientific training were mainly responsible for the key inventions; others, with
steam power in mind, hold that the links between science and the crucial inventions
of the period were fundamental. Margaret Jacob has been a leading contributor to the
debate for nearly four decades. The publication of her The First Knowledge Economy
offers an opportunity to review the issues. (JEL J24, L26, N13, N73, O31, O33)

We are not anxious about the honour of acquiring gold medals nor of making an eclat
in philosophical societies.
Matthew Boulton to James Watt, 1783

M argaret Jacob believes that economists


and economic historians have gotten
some key elements of the British Industrial
quantitative impact. She wants to lure them
away from their stubborn belief that skilled
artisans, who seldom cracked a book, held
Revolution wrong. In The First Knowledge the key to British industrial prowess (p.
Economy (FKE), she pleads with them to 85).1 And she berates them for their overem-
focus more on James Watts improved steam phasis on relative factor prices and resource
engine and less on Richard Arkwrights water endowments and for their failure to give the
frame (the water-powered device that revo- culture of applied science its due.
lutionized cotton spinning); more on the Economic models of the Industrial
complexities of science-based technologi- Revolution increasingly emphasize the role
cal change and less on its determinants and of human capital (e.g., Becker, Hornung,
and Woessmann 2011; Galor and Moav
*University College Dublin. Review of Margaret C. 2004; and Kelly, Mokyr, and Grda
Jacob, The First Knowledge Economy: Human Capital and 2014). But what did that capital consist
the European Economy, 17501850. Cambridge: Cam- of? Was it literacy, numeracy, and affec-
bridge University Press. The comments of John Kanef-
sky, Morgan Kelly, Liam Kennedy, Deirdre McCloskey, tive traits learned at school? Or was it skills
Joel Mokyr, Peter Solar, and Eric Vanhaute are gratefully and discipline learned on the job? Or did it
acknowledged. The standard disclaimer applies.

Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.54.1.224 to visit the
article page and view author disclosure statement(s).
1All
Cited in Cookson 1994, p. 154. unattributed page references are to FKE.

224
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 225

consist in better n utrition and health, with ments of what she long ago (1981) dubbed
perhaps associated gains in cognitive abil- the moderate Enlightenment, is in line
ity? It could well have been an amalgam of with recent work by Joel Mokyr (2002, 2009),
these. But Jacobs focus is much narrower, though he takes a much broader view of the
for she concentrates only on science-based Enlightenments effects on economic develop-
knowledge acquired by entrepreneurs and ment. Also, and again unlike both Mokyr and
mechanics. participants in the earlier debate, Jacob wants
FKE is a combative contribution by a to argue that Englands precocious industrial-
distinguished historian of science to an ization was chiefly the result of its being more
old debate about the role of science-based enlightened in its attitude to science than
technology at the dawn of modern eco- countries on the continent. This reading of
nomic growth. That debate flourished in the scientific and industrial history is informed
1960s and 1970s and centred around the by Jacobs (1981, 1987, 1997) own extensive
argument by Musson and Robinson (1969, research on science during the Enlightenment.
p. vii) that the technology underpinning the She does not bring to the problem any major
Industrial Revolution required something or systematic collection of data in the sense
more than the unlettered empiricism of known to economists. Instead, she offers vivid
traditional historiography. Work by histo- storytelling based on wide reading and rich
rians of science such as Cardwell (1972) qualitative archival material.
and Hall (1974) and economic historians This review essay pays tribute to Jacobs
such as Mathias (1972) and Harris (1997) feisty case for the role of science, but takes
called into question Musson and Robinsons issue with her characterization of the human
emphasis on science in the development capital that made the Industrial Revolution
of the new industrial technology and reaf- and defends the role of more modest forms
firmed the primacy of artisanal knowledge. of learning and of artisanal genius.
Subsequent work, notably by Cookson
(1994), has tended to reinforce this posi-
1. Lunaticks and Mechanicks
tion. As a result, for the period before the
mid-nineteenth century, the history of sci- Europe, on the eve of industrialization,
ence and the history of technology have saw economist Franois Quesnay wowing
become increasingly independent of each the court in Versailles with his physiocratic
other (Wengenroth 2000; compare Berg et zig-zags, Benjamin Franklin hobnobbing
al. 2007). with the Birmingham industrialist Matthew
What new does Jacob bring to this old Boulton, and George Washington exchang-
debate? In FKE her focus is less on the ing notes with agronomist Arthur Young.
development of science from the sixteenth In FKE, Jacob populates her England with
century onthe so-called scientific revo- similarly urbane cosmopolitans (p. 35),
lutionthan on the culture that forged the spindle makers versed in theoretical and
link between science and industry in the eigh- applied mathematics (p. 16), ubiquitous
teenth and early nineteenth centuries. Her engineers learning from Newtonian text-
depiction of that culture through a series of books (p.114), noblemen familiar with the
microcosms (p. 221), or case studies encap- mechanical knowledge necessary to inter-
sulating the values and the informational rogate surveyors and engineers (p. 133;
transmission mechanisms that she champions, also pp.8, 222, 224), traveling lecturers and
is done with skill and conviction. Her empha- mathematics teachers who criss-crossed
sis on innovative entrepreneurs, embodi- the country, and study groups organized
226 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LIV (March 2016)

to brush up on Newtonian mechanics other collateral and kindred manufactures


(pp.5556). (cited in Cardwell 1972: p. 23), its mem-
In this land of science-based innovation, bership was highly selective. Birminghams
Matthew Boultons paradigmatic partnership Lunaticks excluded even the most gifted
with James Watt is so resonant of the mar- of Boulton and Watts employees. Such soci-
riage between manufacturing and science eties operated more like private clubs than
that Birmingham, where the dandy and open forums for the spread of ideas, and
the Scot (p. 27) made their steam engines, were more interested in the scientific topics
becomes the epicenter of the nascent of the day than in their links with industry.
Industrial Revolution (pp. 12, 21, 49). This Industrialists who joined them saw them
is the land of the Lunar Society, where sci- as a stairway to social mobility and gentility
entists and businessmen brushed shoulders (Cardwell 1970; Cookson 1994, pp. 15455;
and talked science, and of the Literary and Uglow 2002, p.353; Jones 2009, pp. 8294).3
Philosophical Society of Manchester (1781), Agronomist Arthur Young was a member
which joined the intellectual curiosity and of the Society for the Encouragement of the
useful knowledge (Mokyr 2002) at the heart Arts, Manufactures and Commerce and was
of Jacobs story (pp. 10406). Thirteen of the elected Fellow of the Royal Society in 1774,
Lit and Phils original membership of fifty but those links postdated his famous tours
were textile manufacturers, and its honorary of English agricultural districts. His role was
members included Josiah Wedgwood and recognized by the Enlightenment, but not
Antoine Lavoisier. James Watt Junior would inspired by it, because the gradual improve-
become its secretary in 1790 at the age of ment in agricultural productivity that he
twenty-one and atomic scientist John Dalton documented preceded the Enlightenment,
the Societys leading light. Manufacturers and the information that he gathered on his
mingled with surgeons, lawyers, clergymen, early tours owed little to book learning or
and merchants and discussed topics ranging science. Ironically, Boulton and Watt were
from a clergymans Attempt to Shew that quite paranoid about protecting their own
a Taste for the Beauties of Nature has no useful knowledge,4 so much so that Young
Influence Favourable to Morals to Daltons
Extraordinary Facts Relating to the Vision
of Colours.2 3To add to the irony, before Boulton and Watt began
Yet while such societies lent scientific steam engine production in Soho in 1795, they relied heav-
ily on outsourcing to other manufacturers and consultant
knowledge respectability, their role in erectors who in turn were heavily dependent on skilled
spreading it was limited. The Lunar Society artisans unversed in science and mathematics.
4Jacob (p. 12) notes the prevalence of industrial
had no more than about a dozen members,
espionage, against which patents offered little protec-
met rarely, and some of its meetings were tion. Probably more useful knowledge was transmit-
poorly attended (Jones 2009, pp. 8694). ted through espionage than through learned societies.
And although one of the reasons given for Lieven Bauwens (17691822) and Samuel Slater (1768
1835) spread the new spinning technology to Belgium
the foundation of the Manchester Phil and and Rhode Island, respectively, with ideas or machinery
Lit was the perception that few of our smuggled out of England in the late 1790s. Slater had
mechanics understand the principles of worked in Belper for Jedediah Strutt; soon New England
blacksmiths and wheelwrights were duplicating Slaters
their own arts and the discoveries made in designs (compare Jeremy 1973; Ben-Atar 1995; Harris
1997; Mokyr 1976: pp.2728). And while the legend that
Benjamin Huntsmans steel-making process was pirated by
2These presentations may be found in Memoirs of the a Sheffield rival who gained access by seeking a warm place
Literary and Philosophical Society of Manchester (1789) 1: to sleep sounds apocryphal, Huntsman was indeed prey to
pp. 22340; (1798) 5(1): pp. 2845. continental pirates (Hey 2004).
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 227

was no where more disappointed than in Wilkinson, who attended a school for aspi-
Birmingham where he could not gain rant churchmen (Uglow 2002, p. 56; Jacob
any intelligence even of the most common 2014, p. 25; Fitton and Wadsworth 1958, p.
nature, including data on wages (Young 3; Chaloner 1960, p. 33)? Jacob devotes dis-
1771: III, p. 279). proportionate attentionthree chapters of
FKE also makes much of the mechanics FKEto Boulton and Watt in Birmingham,
institutes that sprouted up all over Britain in James McConnel and John Kennedy in
the 1820s and taught workmen the knowl- Manchester, and John Marshall in Leeds.
edge of scientific principles (pp. 99, 104, The first two were associated with the
10609, 115). Products of a campaign to improved steam engine; the others were tex-
educate and reform the working classes, they tile producers who employed such engines.
represented a mass movement in the sense Jacobs pen pictures of them are well done
that every large town and many a small one and compelling. All five fit an identikit inno-
had its own institute (Inkster 1975). The big- vator wedded to scientific and technological
gest of them, offering courses in mechanics, culture and to steam. But how typical were
drawing, and the like, attracted member- they?
ships of a thousand or more. The institutes Describing what was typical is not
won support from the stratum that also easy,5 but Allen (2009) and Meisenzahl and
supported the savings banks movement Mokyr (2012) have produced databases
including David Ricardo and James Mill. But directed at this question. About half of the
like the savings banks, the mechanics insti- eighty high-profile inventors in Allens data-
tutes ultimately failed to retain the interest base had enlightenment connections (2009,
of the people they were supposed to benefit pp. 24849), although a few, such as the
(Tylecote 1957, pp. 25960; Fishlow 1961; agronomist Arthur Young, the textile baron
Cookson 1994, p. 151). Soon, attendances John Kennedy, and the clock- and instru-
began to fall off; attempts were made to lure ment-maker Henry Hindley, made the con-
people back with classes on mesmerism, nection late in the day. But those were the
phrenology, and literature (Cardwell 1972, p. Whos Who: Meisenzahl and Mokyr focus
71). In any event, the institutes came much instead on 759 more modest tweakers and
too late to have had an impact on that crucial implementers who merely improved on
period of the Industrial Revolution c. 1785 existing inventions. Less than one-fourth
1820, when the economic and geographic of those had any schooling other than an
landscape of Britain was transformed. apprenticeship, while only one in seven was a
member of a society such as the Manchester
Lit and Phil (Meisenzahl and Mokyr 2012,
2. The Identikit Entrepreneur?
tables 2 and 6).
How reliant were the inventors and entre- In reality, most of the foremost
preneurs of the Industrial Revolution on inventor-entrepreneurs of the Industrial

the rocket science of their day? Who was Revolution were of rather modest, artisanal
the more typical: potter Josiah Wedgewood, origins. The list includes Arkwright, Strutt,
who could hold forth on Acids & Alcalies, ironmaster John Wilkinson (inventor of the
Precipitation, Saturation, &c, or Jedediah precision boring machine used in the con-
Strutt, whose education was narrow and struction of steam engines), Henry Maudslay
contracted; Matthew Boulton, who was
more at home in courtly society than on 5Compare Honeyman 1982; Crouzet 1985; MacLeod
the workshop floor, or ironfounder Isaac and Nuvolari 2006; Cantrell and Cookson 2002.
228 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LIV (March 2016)

(machine-tool inventor), James Hargreaves Its development owed most to the Royal
(inventor of the spinning jenny), Charles Navys willingness and ability to finance
Tennant (who discovered bleaching pow- experimental voyages (Solar 2013).
der), and Matthew Murray (machinist, rival Captivated by Boulton and Watts strug-
to Boulton and Watt). Watt described Henry gles with their patents, Jacob asserts that in
Cort, inventor of the puddling process, as a Britain, innovations meant patents (pp. 22,
simple good-natured man but not very know- 24, 4042, 159). But this is to embrace a very
ing (MacLeod 2007, p. 40), while Samuel narrow view of technological change during
Crompton possessed only such tools as he the Industrial Revolution. It is also to ignore
purchased with his little earnings acquired by an extensive literature that deems Britains
labour at the loom or jenny (Kennedy 1831, patent system cumbersome and unreliable
pp. 31920). The history of smallpox inocu- and expensive, with the result that most
lation, a technique developed in the 1750s by inventors shunned it (Dutton 1984; MacLeod
a group of provincial surgeons/apothecaries 1988, 2009; MacLeod and Nuvolari 2011;
without formal medical training, is another Moser 2012). Several high-profile inventions
example.6 These artisans-made-good were were never patented; more importantly, the
the most talented and ambitious products incremental changes that were occurring
of a system that combined basic schooling in throughout the economy were impossible to
literacy and arithmetic with apprenticeships patent. Significantly, most British goods and
based mainly on learning by doing. That sys- processes on show at the Great Exhibition
tem yielded workers so valuable that it was of 1851 had been developed without a pat-
a crime for them to emigrate before the ent. Perhaps a system closer to the American
mid-1820s (Cookson 1994, p. 145; Bensimon model would have spurred more inventive
2011). activity; as matters stood, Britain achieved
Yet even focusing on the likes of those and maintained technological leadership
named above ignores the incremental, low- until mid-century with little resort to patents.
tech, and anonymous nature of much tech-
nological change in this era. During the
3. Textiles, Coal, and Steam
eighteenth century, for example, watchmak-
ing benefited from no major technologi- Whoever says industrial revolution says
cal breakthroughs apart from the deadbeat cotton (Hobsbawm 1999, p. 34). This
escapement (c. 1715) and the invention of enduring clich remains a useful exagger-
cast steel (c. 1740). Yet productivity growth ation, since estimates of the textile sec-
was continuous and significantthough tors contribution to measured productivity
not quite as fast as implied by Adam Smith growth between the 1780s and the 1860s
(Smith 1976, pp. 26061; Kelly and Grda range from a quarter to between a half and
2015). Ship design in Britain was mainly arti- three quarters when agriculture is added on
sanal in this period. The major breakthrough (McCloskey 1981, p. 114; Harley 1993; Clark
was copper sheathing, an idea that was never 2014, table2). Productivity growth in textiles
patented and whose inventor is unknown.7 (cotton, woolens, worsteds, linens) mattered
because the sector accounted for about half
of British industrial output throughout the
6Indeed, many academically trained physicians opposed eighteenth century (Harley and Crafts 1995,
their methods. I owe this example to Peter Razzell.
7True, in 1779 the Navy experimented with bolts made
of the copper alloy patented by James Keir, an associate copper alloy bolts held more promise for ships fastenings
of Matthew Boulton, but by 1781 it was held that other (Staniforth 1985, p. 24).
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 229

p. 729). By c.1830 cotton goods accounted on waterpower for a few more decades (von
for half of all British exports. Tunzelmann 1978: pp. 183, 224). Nor did
Yet because Jacob dislikes the old ortho- waterpower technology stand still: Cardwell
doxy that the industrialization of cloth (1965) and Kanefsky (1979a) have high-
production required not steam, but jennies lighted advances in waterpower technology
8
and water power, she is not interested in well into in the nineteenth century. And
textiles except insofar as they were linked Jacob is silent on the widely cited finding
to steam engine technology (Jacob 2007, by von Tunzelmann (1978; compare Crafts
p.200). She is aware (p. 90) of people like 2004) that before the early nineteenth
the two Journeymen Clock-Makers, or oth- century the contribution of steam power
ers that understands Tooth and Pinion well, to economic growth was minimal. Jacobs
the Smith that can forge and file, and the undue focus on McConnel and Kennedy
two Wood Turners that have been accus- refuses to acknowledge the stubborn facts
tomed to Wheel-making, Spole-turning, that all the major technical breakthroughs
&c. sought by Arkwright and Strutt for in cotton-spinning predated steam power
their revolutionary water-powered spin- and that in the early years, the use of
ning mill in Cromford in 1771 (Fitton and steam power was confined to carding and
Wadsworth 1958, p. 65), but in FKE neither mule spinning (von Tunzelmann 1978, pp.
Crompton nor Strutt represent the first 18283). These examples also highlight the
generation of cotton manufacturers (p. 85). tendency of FKE to treat the entire period
Fine cotton spinners James McConnel between c. 1750 and c. 1850 as timeless and
and John Kennedy, who installed a sixteen homogenous.
horsepower steam engine in 1797, are allo- Data on professional prizes and other
cated that role. But there was nothing spe- rewards to tweakers across a range of sec-
cial about their steam engine. Kanefskys tors, as a measure of the link between sci-
database of eighteenth-century steam ence and commerce, point to a stark contrast
engines (Kanefsky 1979a and personal com- between textiles and the rest of the econ-
munication to the author) records around omy (Meisenzahl and Mokyr 2012). Before
200 steam engines, including over fifty by 1800, only 16 percent of the 124 tweak-
Boulton and Watt, as having been installed ers in textiles won awards, compared to 67
in British cotton mills before 1797; over half percent of the remainder. Post-1800, the
of these engines were in Lancashire. Nearly percentages were 20 and 81, respectively.
one hundred are known to have driven Pre-1800, only 2 of 124 tweakers in tex-
textile machinery directly (at least forty tiles became members of the Royal Society,
recirculated water to water wheels and the compared to 31 of 73 instrument makers
use of the remainder is not known), and of (derived from Meisenzahl and Mokyr 2012,
these direct drive engines, over forty had table 6). And the proportions whose educa-
again been installed in Lancashire, includ- tion was minimal or unknown were higher
ing seventeen by Boulton and Watt, start- than in any other sector.
ing over a decade earlier. So, whatever their
scientific leanings, McConnel and Kennedy
were followers rather than leaders in their
use of steam power. 8The most important (described in detail by Kanefsky
The water wheel may have lacked the 1979a, pp. 4862) include Fairbairns rim drive, lighter and
stronger steel wheel frames, Jean-Victor Poncelets curved
steam engines versatility but most English buckets and, from the 1840s, water turbines (the invention
textile manufacturers would continue to rely of French engineer Benot Fourneyron).
230 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LIV (March 2016)

Table 1.
Sources of Energy 17601870 (1,000 horsepower)

Year Steam Water Wind Total


1760 5 70 10 85
1800 35 120 15 170
1830 165 165 20 350
1870 2,060 230 10 2,300

Source: Crafts 2004, p. 342, after Kanefsky 1979a.

Steamand therefore coal (pp. 5782) sector remained largely untouched. Even in
are at the heart of Jacobs case for sci- coal mining, the expansion of output con-
ence. In the long run, certainly, coal and sisted of hiring more men with picks and
James Wattand Richard Trevithick, who shovels to extract the coal (Kanefsky 1979b;
pioneered the railway locomotive9were
Samuel 1977; Crafts 2004, pp. 34142).
more important than cotton and Richard Jacob devotes a chapter to Leeds, a city
Arkwright. The part played by coal in transformed by woolen and linen mills
freeing humanity from dependence on
and major engineering firms during the
vegetal energy sources was as important in Industrial Revolution.10 Leeds textile
its day as the role of nonfossil fuels in pro- manufacturers did take up steam power

tecting this and future generations against quite rapidly, but by the 1820s and 1830s
global warming (Wrigley 2010). However, this was no longer good evidence of reli-
steams role at the height of the Industrial ance on the scientifically informed, fac-
Revolution, both as a source of energy rela- tory based experimentation (p. 110) that
tive to waterpower and in terms of its con- she champions. Ironically, Leeds provides
tribution to overall economic growth, was the best witnesses against the centrality of
distinctly secondary (table 1). scientific knowledge of a mechanical sort,
For all their novelty, the average horse- and chemistry (p. 114). Jacobs depiction of
power of Boulton and Watt rotative engines Leeds industrialist Matthew Murray (1765
was only fifteen horsepower around 1800 1828) as a mechanically literate entrepre-
(von Tunzelmann 1978, pp. 2829), and sixty neur (p. 125) is not easily squared with the
horsepower was still considered large in the artisan-genius who continued to make his
1820s. Moreover, Kanefksys review of the calculations with a carpenter sliding rule,
evidence around 1870 suggests that while and had nothing to do with scientists during
steam was of fundamental importance in his most productive and innovative years
mining, textiles, transport, and metallurgy, (Cookson 1994, pp. 150, 15455; Cookson
across large swathes of industrial Britain, 2004). Another famous Leeds engineer and
the diffusion of steam power was still far inventor, Peter Fairbairn, began work in a
from complete. Agriculture and the service colliery at the age of eleven; he set up busi-

10Leeds population grew from about 30,000 in 1770 to


9My thanks to John Kanefsky for insisting on this. 222,189 in 1841.
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 231

ness in a small room in Lady Lane in 1826, makers who married in Prescot between
where a stalwart Irishman powered the 1773 and 1845, more than two-thirds (131)
lathe (Cookson 1994: p. 219). signed the marriage register. Their wives
were nearly all illiterate, which suggests that
watchmakers saw literacy as an investment,
4. Artisan Human Capital whereas for the white-collar elite it was
consumption. In sum, artisans tended to
Today, the key role of education and lit- invest in literacy, if factory hands and miners
eracy in promoting economic growth is did not.11
admitted on all sides, but economic histori- Jacob repeatedly states that how sci-
ans disagree about the role of education in entific knowledge was acquiredand
the Industrial Revolution. It is often noted therefore how widespread it wasremains
that because Britains record on literacy was a black box (pp. 8, 133, 223). But she fails
mediocre (Schofield 1973), mass literacy to note that even some of the discoveries of
was not a prerequisite for early industri- better-educated inventors such as George

alization. Jacobs focus is not on mass lit- Stephenson and Richard Roberts were
eracy, but on the sort of scientific training based, not on scientific knowledge but on
she deems necessary for a career in indus- tinkering (compare McCloskey 2010, pp.
try during the Industrial Revolution: that 4344). Even Tennants discovery of bleach-
required, besides literacy and numeracy, an ing powder in 1799 was the product of trial
education in geometry, algebra, and basic and error and could have been made by
mechanics of a Newtonian sort (p. 157). any observant artisan (Coley 2000, p. 37).
One local case study may be instructive And although Jacob concedes the ubiquity
in this respect. Prescot in southwestern of trained artisans, she underrates their cen-
Lancashire had been epicenter of Englands tral role in the Industrial Revolution (pp. 12,
watch-making industry since the early eigh- 157; compare Tann 1974). Apprenticeship in
teenth century (Bailey and Barker 1969). England was far removed from the carica-
Its Anglican parish registers reveal that the ture painted by Adam Smith in the Wealth
overall literacy rate in Prescot, located within of Nations. Resilient and adaptable, it was
eight miles of Liverpool, was very low, and a far more effective means of transmitting
showed little sign of any increase before the useful knowledge than the learned societ-
mid-nineteenth century. But there was con- ies, secondary schools, or mechanics insti-
siderable variation in literacy across occu- tutes given pride of place by Jacob. So open
pations. Colliers were nearly all illiterate was access to apprenticeships that in 1700,
throughout the period, as were shoemakers over one young adult male in four had com-
and laborers. Farmers were much less likely to pleted one (Mokyr 2009, p. 118). This was a
be illiterateand Thirsk (1985, pp. 57174) productivity-augmenting, market-driven, and
has highlighted the role of print in hastening self-regulated institution, in which masters
the diffusion of agricultural techniquesbut and servants cooperated in a well-recognized
they were not reluctant to marry illiterate way (Humphries 2003; Minns and Wallis
women. White-collar workers, invariably lit- 2012; van der Beek 2014). Less distanced
erate themselves, married literate women. from the traditional textbook stereotype, the
But what is surely significant is that Prescots French apprenticeship system was much
watchmakers and artisans generally were
much more likely to be literate than the 11This pattern is broadly replicated in the neighboring
average. Of the 183 watch- and watch-tool parish of Warrington.
232 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LIV (March 2016)

more restrictive than the English (Kaplan France had been generating science-based
1993; Crowston 2005). knowledge in spades long before the
Industrial Revolution. It was still ahead of
Britain in applied science c. 1800, and the
5. French and Dutch Retardation French Revolution arguably accentuated
its lead for a time (Cardwell 1972, pp. 22,
Jacob attributes Britains lead over France 2627; Mathias 1972; Hobsbawm 1996, pp.
to an elite that was at least a generation 2930).12 Nor were English scientists and
ahead in terms of scientific knowledge and mathematicians that adept at spreading their
education of a mechanical sort (pp. 132, gospel: Cardwell describes English math-
138). Britains other continental rivals, the ematics textbooks of the early Industrial
Dutch, were highly literate but failed to con- Revolution era as belonging to an earlier
centrate on technological learning (p. 205 century and far removed from practice;
08). But there is an alternative explanation moreover they were incomprehensible to
of her evidence: the private supply of such mechanics and expensive as well (Cardwell
training was usually ample where there was a 1972, p. 124; Cookson 1994, p. 146).
demand for it. And so it is hardly surprising What France lacked was not an enlight-
that the University of Durham, sitting in the ened elite, but the mechanics and
midst of Britains largest coalfields, would artisan-entrepreneurs so plentiful in Britain.
offer courses in mining engineering in the On the eve of the Industrial Revolution
1830s, while there was little enthusiasm for British workers were taller, healthier, sav-
mechanics in institutions of higher learning vier, and more productive than their French
in Harderwijk, Deventer, and Gelderland counterparts. Wages in Britain were higher
(pp. 74, 193, 207). than elsewhere, not because labor was cost-
Economic historians have long debated lier, but because British workers were more
why France and the Netherlands failed productive (Kelly, Mokyr, and Grda
to industrialize when Britain did (e.g., 2014). French retardation depended less on
Kindleberger 1964; OBrien and Keydar what Jacob calls the expansion of human
1978; Mokyr 2000; Crouzet 2003). For Jacob, knowledge (p. 15) than on the relatively
the main reason for French economic retar- poor quality of its labor force.
dation is that scientific education occurred
in fits and starts (p. 188), while the con-
6. Timing
trasting fortunes of industrializing Belgium
and the laggard Netherlands stemmed from Nobody doubts the centrality of techno-
their respective stance on education with logical change to the Industrial Revolution,
an industrial focus. Maastricht is the Dutch but the timing of its impact is still debated.
exception that proves the rule: the only rea- Macroeconomic data imply that rapid,
son Jacob gives for its relative success is its self-sustaining economic progress did not
relative strength in science-based education
(pp. 20711). She might have also noted the
12Diderot and dAlemberts Encyclopdie (175172),
additional effect of the events of 17891815
which highlighted such knowledge, had sold 25,000 cop-
in both the Netherlands and France, which ies by 1789, half of them in France (Darnton 1979: p. 37).
clearly diverted resources and ingenuity And whereas Newton wrote the Principia in Latin, Voltaire
from productive to other ends. and Emilie du Chatelet popularized its findings through
their Elments de la philosophie de Newton in 1738 and
But French precocity in this sphere sug- Chatelets full French translation of the Principia followed
gests that science was not the key, because in 1756.
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 233

Panel A. GDP and GDP per capita in England, Panel B. GDP per capita,
14001870 16001870
7 5.5

GDP GDPPOP
6
5

GDPPOP
5
4.5
4

3 4
1400 1500 1600 1700 1800 1900 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850
Period Period

Figure 1. Economic Growth Before and During the Industrial Revolution

begin in the 1760s (p. 1); moreover, eco- remarkable increase in literacy; between 1600
nomic growth during the following century and 1750, England moved from being essen-
was very slow by later standards, certainly tially a preliterate society to one where more
no more than 1.5 percent per annum. More than half of all adults could sign a m arriage
interestingly, the latest attempts at estimating register. And although literacy (thus defined)
British output and productivity in the more did not increase much for some decades
distant past reveal an upward trend in GDP thereafter, the number of books published
that began long before the ages of cotton and and the circulation of newspapers did. Other
steam and, indeed, before the Enlighten indicators are the increasing urbanization and
ment could have had any impact (Broadberry openness of the economy, and the integration
et al. 2015; Nuvolari and Ricci 2013). of its regional markets. With increasing com-
Figure 1 describes the movements in GDP mercialization came increases in the vari-
and GDP per head (both measured in logs) ety of goods consumed, and those increases
in twenty-year blocks between 13901409 were not confined to the rich. Adult life
and 185069 implied by Broadberry et al.13 expectancy began to rise too, that of the elite
Over this period, GDP grew about ten times during the seventeenth century and that of
as fast as GDP per head. Note that from the the population at large during the eighteenth
early seventeenth century on, GDP per head (Edwards 2008; Johansson 2010; Razzell
was higher in each period than in the pre- 2014). In sum, the slow takeoff of the British
vious period, growth had somehow become economy antedated the Enlightenment and
built-in. Note too the rather intriguing impli- the steam engine by a century or more.
cation that the growth rate of GDP per head None of this rules out a first knowledge
fell during the eighteenth century before economy. But if one is to feature in the mac-
accelerating again early in the nineteenth. roeconomic landscape described in figure1,
Other indicators point to progress in this its birth must have been a gradual, long,
preIndustrial Revolution era. One is the drawn-out process. This is problematic for
interpretations that emphasize the revolu-
13These numbers are the best available but not defini- tionary role of a few inventions such as Watts
tive: see Kelly and Grda (2013). and Arkwrights, but more congenial to a
234 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LIV (March 2016)

slow-burning but eventually all-embracing archive. This again is invoked repeatedly in


diffusion of ideas and technologies that is FKE (at least nine mentions) to underpin
actually more in line with the older arguments broader points about sciences role in indus-
for the importance of science-based change. try. Clarks letter from his base in Mons,
A process with roots in the p reindustrial era dated 6 Messidor Year XII (25 June 1804,
in sectors other than cotton and coal and in not 1812 as claimed), describes an attempt at
forms of knowledge distinct from applied raising capital to produce an improved mule
science seems most likely. spindle under the trade name of Clarks
In her claims for the centrality of science Mathematical Spindles, for muslin &c. At
and knowledge, the importance of mechan- that point, Clark was manufacturing spindles
ics institutes, and the pivotal role of coal and and carding cylinders; his local partners had
steel, Jacobs chronology of timing of eco- invested a modest seventy guineas in steel,
nomic change in Britain lets her down. Her grinding stones, bellows, and other tools.
claims for science and steam are perfectly Nothing further is revealed in FKE about
plausible for the so-called Second Industrial Clark beyond what is in the letternot
Revolution of the later nineteenth century, even his given name. But a little sleuthing
but they carry far less conviction for the reveals that he was far from being the lone
period before 1830 or 1840. mechanic (p. 133) that Jacob imagines him
to be. Indeed, David Clarks career spanned
England (where he had gone bankrupt
7. Stretching the Evidence
twice), Ireland (where he managed a new
FKEs case for applied science is weakened spinning mill in Malahide outside Dublin in
by a propensity to spread evidence too thin or the early 1780s),14 Paris (c. 18001804), and
else, occasionally, to misread it. Thus it makes Belgium (where in 1804 he began the busi-
much of episodes involving members of the ness mentioned above in Hyon, next to the
House of Lords interrogating canal builders in city walls of Mons, and where he disappears
engineering language in 1769. These episodes, from view in the late 1810s). Clark, a serial
which Jacob has already discussed repeatedly entrepreneur, was involved in various part-
elsewhere (1987, pp.24042; 1997, pp. 203 nerships in the Mons area and was in close
05), are recycled seven times here (pp. 8, 13, contact with other expatriate Englishmen on
23, 56, 133, 222, 224). Nor is the evidence as the make.15 Given his long experience, he
clear-cut as claimed. While some nobles with
a financial interest in the proposed canals
14Minutes of the evidence taken before a committee of
asked very technical questionson which
the House of Commons, . . . to whom the bill for repeal-
presumably they were closely briefedmost ing the duties on tobacco and snuff . . . was committed.
found it hard to concentrate and were reluc- London, 1789, pp. 20810; Aspin 2010.
15The Kennion mentioned in the letter presum-
tant to attend the hearings (Schofield 1982,
ably refers to William Kenyon and Sons, proprietors of a
pp. 27071). More telling is the low quality cable-manufacturing plant in Armentires, northern France.
of some of the expert witnesses brought in to Farrar and Mather (apparently Clarks b rother-in-law), also
criticize a canal project designed by Englands mentioned, are listed in Chassagne (1991). Jacobs prone-
ness to stretch her evidence too far produces a howler:
foremost engineer, and the easy ride given to she misreads Clarks proposal to employ prison labor as
engineers generally by lawyers for whom a source of energy for his determination to pay workers
engineering mechanics was a foreign lan- (offenders) as little as possible (p. 16):
guage (Schofield 1982, pp. 265, 268). I do not well understand the word of Maison de
force (i.e., prison: CG) but if it imploys (= implies)
Another example is Jacobs use of a letter thisto make their offenders to work, and that there
from one Mr. Clark, uncovered in a Belgian will be very little to pay in[?], I then could make a
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 235

must have been a competent mechanic, but the Industrial Revolutionreflected not
there are no grounds whatever for inferring just in book publishing and newspaper cir-
from his mathematical spindles that he culation, but in increased familiarity with
was familiar with mathematics . . . and the counting, classifying, cataloguing (Mokyr
applied science of mechanics (p. 16). 2009, p. 43)was an important ingredient of
Several other readings of the literature the Baconian program that she champions.
are questionable. Jacob refers to London But between the 1760s and the 1830sthe
porters who were proficient in algebra (p. period of the Industrial Revolutionthat
154), and to clockmakers being key players human capital resided mainly in the skills,
in machine making (pp. 15, 90). But Gillian dexterity, and occasional genius of Britains
Cookson, whose authoritative research on the craftsmen and artisans-made-good, not in
West Riding machine-making industry Jacob sophisticated mechanics in the Newtonian
mentions but otherwise ignores, is at pains to tradition (pp. 221, 222).17 It accounted for
deemphasize the role of clockmakers (1994, the relatively high wages of such workers,
51ff), and Cooksons overall assessment, that and it rested mainly on their mechanical
most significant technological progress was ingenuity and what they learned by doing.
achieved in a workshop rather than in a lab- In the meantime, Englands endowment of
oratory, by machine-makers who apparently science-based knowledge was growing, but
had little or no exposure to scientific books only during the so-called second Industrial
or any education in science flies directly in Revolution, when steam and coal occupied
the face of FKE. Finally, few economic histo- center-stage, would the sort of human capi-
rians will take seriously Jacobs assertion that tal championed by Jacob come into its own.
by European standards most English hand The supreme self-confidence (p. 106) that
workers and their families lived at best at a Jacob attributes to Manchester manufactur-
subsistence level precisely in the period when ers refers to the 1850s, not the 1780s.
industrialization began in earnest (p. 65, A key feature of the Enlightenment was its
emphasis added). On the contrary, most will faith in progress. Ironically, its optimism was
be convinced by Allens demonstration that on not shared by a majority of economists during
the eve of the Industrial Revolution, unskilled the Industrial Revolution. The dismal scien-
male workers in Britain earned three to four tists emphasized instead the limited pros-
times a barebones subsistence wage.16 pects for technological change, particularly
in agriculture, and the power of the princi-
ple of population to keep down wages. The
8. Conclusion
utopian optimism of William Godwin and
Human capital indeed mattered, as the Marquis de Condorcet famously fueled
Margaret Jacob claims. The big increase in Malthuss Essay on Population. And, indeed,
the quality of English literacy and numer- as noted earlier, growth rates during the
acy during the century or so leading up to Industrial Revolution were modest.
Yet Mokyr has persuasively empha-
sized another important aspect of the
simple machine, so that 12 or 18 men may go slowly
round, and they being relieved each hour, so by this Enlightenment that classical economics
means the stones will be turnedbut their price of embraced, but on which Jacob says little:
wages must determine that, as soon as I know it. its role as a force against rent seeking and
That is a far cry from mathematical spindles.
16Allen 2001, 2009: pp. 3342. And Kelly and Grda
(2013) have argued that the nutritional value of their diet 17McCloskey (2010, pp. 35565; 2014, p. 439) has
was commensurate. repeatedly articulated this point.
236 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LIV (March 2016)

monopoly. When Mokyr (2010) claims that The Gifts of Athena. History of Science 45 (2):
enlightenment ideas . . . created the pros- 123221.
Broadberry, Stephen, Bruce M. S. Campbell, Alexan-
perity that we enjoy today, he is referring not der Klein, Mark Overton, and Bas van Leeuwen.
just to the spread of useful knowledge, but 2015. British Economic Growth 12701870. Cam-
also to a political philosophy that stood for bridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Cantrell, John, and Gillian Cookson, eds. 2002. Henry
freedom of expression and an end to mercan- Maudslay and the Pioneers of the Machine Age.
tilist restrictions on trade. Stroud, UK: Tempus.
While the likes of Adam Smith and David Cardwell, D. S. L. 1965. Power Technologies and the
Advance of Science, 17001825. Technology and
Hume favored competition and free trade, Culture 6 (2): 188207.
Matthew Boulton lobbied against the free Cardwell, D. S. L. 1970. Review of The Lunar Society
export of buckle-chapes and brass in the of Birmingham. English Historical Review 85 (334):
185.
1760s and against the emigration of skilled Cardwell, D. S. L. 1972. The Organization of Science in
workmen in the 1780s. And while in 1786 England, Second edition. London: Heinemann.
Wedgewood was a vociferous opponent of Chaloner, W. H. 1960. Isaac Wilkinson, Pot Founder.
In Studies in the Industrial Revolution: Essays Pre-
Pitts Commercial Propositions, which sented to T. S. Ashton, edited by L. S. Pressnell,
would have gained Irish manufacturers freer 2351. London: Athlone Press.
access to the British market (Uglow 2002, Chassagne, Serge. 1991. Le coton et ses patrons:
France, 17601840. Paris: Editions de lEcole des
pp. 62, 39192), Jacobs hero Boulton was Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales.
all in favor of bartering our buttons . . . for Clark, Gregory. 2007. The Long March of History:
pipes of champagne when it came to trade Farm Wages, Population, and Economic Growth,
England 12091869. Economic History Review 60
with France (Roll 1930, p. 139). Boultons (1): 97135.
and Wedgewoods commercial interests Clark, Gregory. 2014. The Industrial Revolution. In
always trumped broader Enlightenment Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 2A, edited
by Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf, 21762.
principles. Amsterdam and Boston: Elsevier, North-Holland.
Coley, N. G. 2000. The Shape of the British Chemical
References Industry. In A New History of the British Chemical
Industry, edited by Colin A. Russell, 1342. Cam-
Allen, Robert C. 2001. The Great Divergence in Euro- bridge: Royal Society of Chemistry.
pean Wages and Prices from the Middle Ages to the Cookson, Gillian. 1994. The West Yorkshire Textile
First World War. Explorations in Economic History Engineering Industry 17801850. Unpublished.
38 (4): 41147. Cookson, Gillian. 1996. Millwrights, Clockmakers and
Allen, Robert C. 2009. The British Industrial Revo- the Origins of Textile Machine-Making in Yorkshire.
lution in Global Perspective. Cambridge and New Textile History 27 (1): 4357.
York: Cambridge University Press. Cookson, Gillian. 2004. Murray, Matthew (1765
Ashton, T. S. 1948. The Industrial Revolution 1760 1826). Oxford Dictionary of National Biography.
1830. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. http://www.oxforddnb.com/index/19/101019641/.
Aspin, Chris. 2010. The Unfortunate Philanthropists. Crafts, Nicholas. 2004. Steam as a General Purpose
Helmshore: Helmshore Local Historical Society. Technology: A Growth Accounting Perspective.
Bailey, F., and T. C. Barker. 1969. The Seventeenth- Economic Journal 114 (495): 33851.
Century Origins of Watch-Making in South-West Lan Crouzet, Franois. 1985. The First Industrialists: The
cashire: Essays in the Economic and Social History of Problem of Origins. Cambridge and New York: Cam-
the Port and Its Hinterland. In Liverpool and Mer- bridge University Press.
seyside, edited by J. R. Harris, 115. London: Cass. Crouzet, Franois. 2003. The Historiography of
Becker, Sascha O., Erik Hornung, and Ludger Woess- French Economic Growth in the Nineteenth Cen-
mann. 2011. Education and Catch-Up in the Indus- tury. Economic History Review 56 (2): 21542.
trial Revolution. American Economic Journal: Crowston, Clare Haru. 2005. Lapprentissage hors
Macroeconomics 3 (3): 92126. des corporations: Les formations professionnelles
Ben-Atar, Doron. 1995. Alexander Hamiltons Alterna- alternatives a Paris sous lAncien Regime/Appren-
tive: Technology Piracy and the Report on Manufac- ticeship Outside the Guilds: Alternative Systems of
tures. William and Mary Quarterly 52 (3): 389414. Vocational Training in Old Regime Paris. Annales:
Bensimon, Fabrice. 2011. British Workers in France, Histoire Sciences Sociales 60 (2): 40941.
18151848. Past and Present 213 (1): 14789. Crowston, Clare Haru. 2007. From School to Work-
Berg, Maxine, et al. 2007. Reflections on Joel Mokyrs shop: Pre-training and Apprenticeship in Old
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 237

Regime France. In Learning on the Shop Floor: I nstitutes, 18201850: The Case of Sheffield. Annals
Historical Perspectives on Apprenticeship, edited by of Science 32 (5): 45174.
Bert De Munck, Steven L. Kaplan, and Hugo Soly, Jacob, Margaret C. 1981. The Radical Enlightenment:
4664. New York and Oxford: Berghahn Books. Pantheists, Freemasons and Republicans. London:
Darnton, Robert. 1979. The Business of Enlighten- Allen and Unwin.
ment: A Publishing History of the Encyclopdie, Jacob, Margaret C. 1987. The Cultural Meaning of the
17751800, Volume 2. Cambridge, MA. and Lon- Scientific Revolution. New York: Alfred Knopf.
don: Harvard University Press. Jacob, Margaret C. 1997. Scientific Culture and the
Dutton, H. I. 1984. The Patent System and Inventive Making of the Industrial West. Oxford and New York:
Activity during the Industrial Revolution, 1750 Oxford University Press.
1852. Manchester: Manchester University Press. Jacob, Margaret C. 2007. Mechanical Science on the
Edwards, Ryan D. 2008. Declining Mortality among Factory Floor: The Early Industrial Revolution in
British Scientists during the Age of Enlightenment. Leeds History of Science 45 (2): 197221.
Population and Development Review 34: 10325. Jacob, Margaret C. 2014. The First Knowledge Econ-
Fishlow, Albert. 1961. The Trustee Savings Banks, 1817 omy: Human Capital and the European Economy,
1861. Journal of Economic History 21 (1): 2640. 17501850. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge
Fitton, R. S., and A. P. Wadsworth. 1958. The Strutts University Press.
and the Arkwrights, 17581830: A Study of the Early Jeremy, David J. 1973. British Textile Technology
Factory System. Manchester: Manchester University Transmission to the United States: The Philadelphia
Press. Region Experience, 17701820. Business History
Galor, Oded, and Omer Moav. 2004. From Physical Review 47 (1): 2452.
to Human Capital Accumulation: Inequality and the Johansson, S. Ryan. 2010. Medics, Monarchs and Mor-
Process of Development. Review of Economic Stud- tality, 16001800: Origins of the Knowledge-Driven
ies 71 (4): 100126. Health Transition in Europe. http://papers.ssrn.
Hall, A. Rupert. 1974. What Did the Industrial Revo- com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1661453.
lution in Britain Owe to Science. In Historical Per- Jones, Peter M. 2009. Industrial Enlightenment: Sci-
spectives: Studies in English Thought and Society in ence, Technology and Culture in Birmingham and
Honour of J. H. Plumb, edited by Neil McKendrick, the West Midlands 17601820. Manchester: Man-
12951. London: Europa Publications. chester University Press.
Hardie, D. W. F. 1966. Review of The Lunar Society of Kanefsky, John. 1979a. The Diffusion of Power Tech-
Birmingham: A Social History of Provincial Science nology in British Industry. Unpublished.
and Industry in Eighteenth-Century England. Busi- Kanefsky, John. 1979b. Motive Power in British Indus-
ness History 8 (1): 7374. try and the Accuracy of the 1870 Factory Return.
Harley, C. K. 1993. Reassessing the Industrial Revolu- Economic History Review 32 (3): 36075.
tion. In The Economics of the Industrial Revolution, Kanefsky, John, and John Robey. 1980. Steam Engines
edited by Joel Mokyr, 171226. Totowa, NJ: Rowan in 18th-Century Britain: A Quantitative Assessment.
and Allenfeld. Technology and Culture 21 (2): 16186.
Harley, C. K., and Nicholas Crafts. 1995. Cotton Tex- Kaplan, Steven L. 1993. Lapprentissage au XVIIIe
tiles and Industrial Output Growth during the Indus- siecle: Le cas de Paris. Revue dhistoire moderne et
trial Revolution. Economic History Review 48 (1): contemporaine 40 (3): 43679.
13444. Kelly, Morgan, and Cormac Grda. 2013. Numerare
Harris, J. R. 1997. Industrial Espionage and Technol- est Errare: Agricultural Output and Food Supply in
ogy Transfer: Britain and France in the Eighteenth England before and during the Industrial Revolu-
Century. Aldershot: Ashgate. tion. Journal of Economic History 73 (4): 113263.
Hey, David. 2004. Huntsman, Benjamin (1704 Kelly, Morgan, and Cormac Grda. 2015. Adam
1776). Oxford Dictionary of National Biography. Smith, Watch Prices, and the Industrial Revolution.
http://www.oxforddnb.com/index/14/101014247/. University College Dublin Working Paper 2015-05.
Hobsbawm, Eric. 1996. The Age of Revolution, 1789 Kelly, Morgan, Joel Mokyr, and Cormac Grda.
1848. New York: Random House, Vintage Books, 2014. Precocious Albion: A New Interpretation of
1962. the British Industrial Revolution. Annual Review of
Hobsbawm, Eric. 1999. Industry and Empire: The Birth Economics 6: 36389.
of the Industrial Revolution. London: Penguin, 1968. Kennedy, John. 1831. A Brief Memoir of Samuel
Honeyman, Katrina. 1982. Origins of Enterprise: Busi- Crompton. Memoirs of the Literary and Philosoph-
ness Leadership in the Industrial Revolution. Man- ical Society of Manchester, Second series. 5: 31845.
chester: Manchester University Press. Kindleberger, Charles P. 1964. Economic Growth in
Humphries, Jane. 2003. English Apprenticeship: A France and Britain, 18511950. Cambridge, MA:
Neglected Factor in the First Industrial Revolution. Harvard University Press.
In The Economic Future in Historical Perspective, MacLeod, Christine. 1988. Inventing the Industrial Rev-
edited by Paul A. David and Mark Thomas, 73102. olution: The English Patent System, 16601800. Cam-
London: British Academy. bridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Inkster, Ian. 1975. Science and the Mechanics MacLeod, Christine. 2007. Heroes of Invention:
238 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LIV (March 2016)

echnology, Liberalism and British Identity, 1750


T Mokyr, Joel. 2010. Enlightened and Enriched.
1914. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge Univer- City Journal 20 (3). http://www.city-journal.
sity Press. org/2010/20_3_enlightenment-ideas.html.
MacLeod, Christine. 2009. Patents for Invention: Set- Moser, Petra. 2012. Innovation without Patents: Evi-
ting the Stage for the British Industrial Revolution. dence from Worlds Fairs. Journal of Law and Eco-
Empiria: Revista de metodologia de ciencias sociales nomics 55 (1): 4374.
18: 3758. Musson, Albert E., and Eric Robinson. 1969. Science
MacLeod, Christine, and Alessandro Nuvolari. 2006. and Technology in the Industrial Revolution. Man-
The Pitfalls of Prosopography: Inventors in the chester: Manchester University Press.
Dictionary of National Biography. Technology and Nuvolari, Alessandro, and Mattia Ricci. 2013. Eco-
Culture 47 (4): 75776. nomic Growth in England, 12501850: Some New
MacLeod, Christine, and Alessandro Nuvolari. 2011. Estimates Using a Demand Side Approach. Rivista
Patents and Industrialization: An Historical Over- di Storia Economica 29: 3153.
view of the British Case, 16241907. London: UK Nuvolari, Alessandro, Bart Verspagen, and Nick von
Intellectual Property Office. Tunzelmann. 2011. The Early Diffusion of the
Mathias, Peter. 1972. Who Unbound Prometheus? Steam Engine in Britain, 17001800: A Reappraisal.
Science and Technical Change, 16001800. In Cliometrica 5 (3): 291321.
Science and Society 16001900, edited by Peter Razzell, Peter. 2014. Mortality, Population Growth
Mathias, 5480. Cambridge and New York: Cam- and Economic Development in England, 1600
bridge University Press. 1850. Unpublished.
Mathias, Peter. 1975. Skills and the Diffusion of Innova- Roll, Eric. 1930. An Early Experiment in Industrial
tions from Britain in the Eighteenth Century. Trans- Organisation: Being a History of the Firm of Boul-
actions of the Royal Historical Society 25: 93113. ton & Watt, 17751805. London: Frank Cass and
Mathias, Peter. 1979. The Transformation of England: Company.
Essays in the Economic and Social History of England Samuel, Raphael. 1977. Workshop of the World:
in the Eighteenth Century. London and New York: Steam Power and Hand Technology in Mid-Victorian
Taylor and Francis, Routledge. Britain. History Workshop Journal 3 (1): 672.
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 2010. Bourgeois Dignity: Why Schofield, R. B. 1982. The Promotion of the Cromford
Economics Cant Explain the Modern World. Chi- Canal Act of 1789: A Study in Canal Engineering.
cago and London: University of Chicago Press. Bulletin of the John Rylands Library 64 (2): 24678.
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 2014. The Treasured Bour- Schofield, Roger S. 1973. The Dimensions of Illiteracy
geoisie: How Markets and Innovation Became Vir- in England, 17501850 Explorations in Economic
tuous, 16001848, and Then Suspect. Unpublished. History 10: 43754.
McCloskey, Donald N. 1981. The Industrial Revolu- Smith, Adam. 1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and
tion 17801860: A Survey. In The Economic History Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Chicago and Lon-
of Britain since 1700, Volume 1: 17001860, edited don: University of Chicago Press, 1776.
by Roderick Floud and Donald McCloskey, 10327. Solar, Peter M. 2013. Opening to the East: Shipping
Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University between Europe and Asia, 17701830. Journal of
Press. Economic History 73 (3): 62561.
Meisenzahl, Ralf R., and Joel Mokyr. 2012. The Rate Staniforth, M. 1985. The Introduction and Use of
and Direction of Invention in the British Industrial Copper Sheathing: A History Australian Institute
Revolution: Incentives and Institutions. In The Rate for Maritime Archaeology 9 (1/2): 2148.
and Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited, edited Tann, Jennifer. 1974. The Textile Millwright in the Early
by Josh Lerner and Scott Stern, 44379. Chicago and Industrial Revolution. Textile History 5 (1): 8089.
London: University of Chicago Press. Thirsk, Joan. 1985. Agricultural Innovations and Their
Minns, Chris, and Patrick Wallis. 2012. Rules and Diffusion. In The Agrarian History of England and
Reality: Quantifying the Practice of Apprentice- Wales: Volume V: 16401750: Agrarian Change,
ship in Early Modern England. Economic History edited by Joan Thirsk, 53389. Cambridge and New
Review 65 (2): 55679. York: Cambridge University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 1976. Industrialization in the Low Coun- Tylecote, Mabel Phythian. 1957. The Mechanics Insti-
tries, 17951850. New Haven and London: Yale Uni- tutes of Lancashire and Yorkshire before 1851. Man-
versity Press. chester: Manchester University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 2000. The Industrial Revolution and the Uglow, Jenny. 2002. The Lunar Men: The Friends Who
Netherlands: Why Did It Not Happen? De Econo- Made the Future. London: Faber and Faber.
mist 148 (4): 50320. van der Beek, Karine. 2014. Englands Eighteenth-
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Century Demand for High-Quality Workmanship:
Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton and Evidence from Apprenticeship, 17101770. In Insti-
Oxford: Princeton University Press. tutions, Innovation, and Industrialization: Essays in
Mokyr, Joel. 2009. The Enlightened Economy: An Eco- Economic History and Development, edited by Avner
nomic History of Britain, 17001850. New Haven Greif, Lynne Kiesling, and John V. C. Nye, 22544.
and London: Yale University Press. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Grda: Did Science Cause the Industrial Revolution? 239

Von Tunzelmann, G. N. 1978. Steam Power and Brit- w00bmt/www/Arbeitspapiere/Wengenroth_sci-


ish Industrialization to 1860. Oxford and New York: tech-ind-19c.pdf.
Oxford University Press. Wrigley, E. A. 2010. Energy and the English Industrial
Wengenroth, Ulrich. 2000. Science, Technology, and Revolution. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge
Industry in the 19th Century. Munich Center for University Press.
the History of Science and Technology Working Young, Arthur. 1771. A Six Months Tour through the
Paper. http://www.mzwtg.mwn.tum.de/fileadmin/ North of England. London: Strahan.

Вам также может понравиться