Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 36

Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia: The Mesopotamian Advantage

Author(s): GuillermoAlgaze
Source: Current Anthropology, Vol. 42, No. 2 (April 2001), pp. 199-233
Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of Wenner-Gren Foundation for
Anthropological Research
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/320005 .
Accessed: 04/12/2015 17:04

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

The University of Chicago Press and Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research are collaborating
with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Current Anthropology.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
C u r r e n t A n t h r o p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001
2001 by The Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research. All rights reserved 0011-3204-2001/4202-0002$3.00

In a recent review of Gary Feinman and Joyce Marcuss


edited book Archaic States (1998), Robert McCormick
Initial Social Adams (2000) expresses surprise that contributors gen-
erally neglected issues pertaining to the social evolu-
Complexity in tionary impact of interrelationships between human so-
cieties and their natural ecosystems. It is a sign of our
times, he argues, that questions like these, so seriously
Southwestern Asia regarded a generation ago, are presently as widely dis-
regarded as they appear to be in this otherwise state-of-
the-art collection. The absence of such questions partly
obscures our understanding of the very processes that
The Mesopotamian Advantage1 the various contributors to Archaic States seek to clarify.
Social process viewed in a vacuum is tantamount to so-
cial determinism, which ultimately is as incorrect as the
by Guillermo Algaze geographical determinism that often tainted the work of
an earlier generation of anthropologists and geographers
(Livingstone 1992). Socioeconomic systems invariably
operate within geographical and ecological constraints
on the social actions that are possible (given existing
The emergence of early Mesopotamian (Sumerian) civilization technologies) and probable (given earlier developmental
must be understood within the framework of the unique ecology trends [path dependency] and cultural perceptions of op-
and geography of the alluvial lowlands of the Tigris and Euphra-
tes Rivers during the late 5th and 4th millennia b.c. The former portunities and threats) at any one time. For this reason,
gave Mesopotamian societies important advantages in agricul- history displays a wide range of results of the interaction
tural productivity and subsistence resource resilience not pos- of societies and their environment. At the same time,
sessed by contemporary polities on their periphery, while the lat- however, evolving environmental factors can also extend
ter gave them enduring transportational advantages. This
the boundaries of both the possible and the probable by
material imbalance created opportunities and incentives that
made it both possible and probable that early Mesopotamian acting, in the words of Joel Mokyr (1990), as focusing
elites would use trade as one of their earliest and most impor- devices that powerfully influence the direction that so-
tant tools to legitimize and expand their unequal access to re- cieties take in their search for technological innovations.
sources and power. Given this, a still hypothetical (but testable) New technologies, in turn, to quote Robert Heilbroner
model is presented that accounts for the precocious socioeco-
nomic differentiation and urban growth of southern Mesopota- (1994[1967]:59), cannot but impose certain social and
mia in the 4th millennium as social multiplier effects inadver- political characteristics upon the societies in which they
tently set in motion by evolving trade patterns. This trade was are found.
first largely internal, between individual southern polities ex- To be sure, neither Mokyr nor Heilbroner advocates a
ploiting rich but localized ecological niches within the Mesopo-
return to Marxian technological reductionism. Both well
tamian alluvium during the Late Ubaid and Early Uruk periods.
By the Middle and Late Uruk periods, however, inherently asym- understand that the present is shaped from the past by
metrical external trade between growing southern cities and so- a combination of selective pressures that impose a mea-
cieties at their periphery in control of coveted resources gained sure of directionality on human history, random acci-
more prominence. In due course, import-substitution processes dents, and unpredictable innovations that add an ele-
further amplified the one-sided socio-evolutionary impact on
southern societies of these shifting trade patterns. Unequal de- ment of indeterminacy to any attempt at historical
velopmental rates resulting from the operation of these processes explanation. Moreover, both are well aware that tech-
over time explain why the earliest complex societies of south- nological innovation not only acts on society but is itself
western Asia appeared in southern Mesopotamia and not often contingent on socioeconomic forces (Scranton
elsewhere.
1994). However, their admonitions as to the social con-
sequences of technological innovation and the existence
g u i l l e r m o a l g a z e is Chair of the Department of Anthro-
pology at the University of California, San Diego (La Jolla, Calif. of an often close relationship between ecological context
92093-0532, U.S.A. [galgaze@ucsd.edu]). Born in 1954, he was ed- and technological change do raise important issues for
ucated at the University of Puerto Rico (B.A., 1976) and the Uni- archaeologists attempting to explain the evolution of
versity of Chicago (Ph.D., 1986). His publications include The
Uruk Expansion: Cross-cultural Exchange in Early Mesopotamian
Civilization (current anthropology 30:571608), The Uruk
World System (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993), and
The Prehistory of Imperialism: The Case of Uruk Period Meso- Rosenberg (University of Delaware), Eric Rupley (University of
potamia, in Uruk Mesopotamia and Its Neighbors, edited by M. Michigan), Gil Stein (Northwestern University), Donald Tuzin
Rothman (Santa Fe: School of American Research Press, 2001). (UCSD), Tony Wilkinson (University of Chicago), and several anon-
The present paper was submitted 11 v 00 and accepted 7 ix 00. ymous CA referees. Each offered substantive criticism, important
editorial comments, and crucial missing references. Their invalu-
able contributions are acknowledged with gratitude, even though
1. Earlier drafts of this article were read and criticized by Elise occasionally I chose to disregard their advice. Remaining errors of
Auerbach (University of Chicago), Claudio Cioffi-Revilla (Univer- omission and interpretation are entirely my own. The manuscript
sity of Colorado), Alex Joffe (Penn State University), Joyce Marcus also owes much to the editorial comments and grammatical cor-
(University of Michigan), Robert McC. Adams (UCSD), Jennifer rections of my wife, Susan Becker Algaze. The accompanying map
Pournelle (UCSD), Steve Rosen (Ben Gurion University), Michael (fig. 1) was ably drafted by Valerie Batt.

199

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
200 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

complex societies. In addition to taking into account the which the organizational structure of Ebla (and presum-
dynamics of social and economic interactions within and ably that of other comparable Syro-Mesopotamian cities)
between societies, such attempts must also explore what paralleled earlier and contemporary southern Mesopo-
technological innovations the groups under investiga- tamian prototypes. Economic texts, for instance, reveal
tion developed in order to adapt to or, alternatively, to patterns of palatial control of animal herds and of various
circumvent or transform their evolving environmental strategic industrial activities (e.g., metals and textiles)
and geographic context.
that are immediately comparable to contemporary prac-
This latter perspective is adopted here to explore the
tices in southern Mesopotamian city-states (Archi 1988).
emergence of early Mesopotamian (Sumerian) civiliza-
tion in the alluvial lowlands of the Tigris and Euphrates If the potential to support regionally organized and
Rivers of southern Iraq during the so-called Uruk period, urbanized state-level societies existed in a variety of
roughly dated to 38003100 b.c. This emergence entailed regions of southwestern Asia, how does one account for
a veritable revolution in human social and spatial or- the temporal primacy of social complexity in southern
ganization, culminating in new conceptualizations of Mesopotamia? I believe that this primacy was the result
the nature of the social order (Baines and Yoffee 1998) of social and technological innovations that were se-
and the rise of the worlds earliest cities and states (Ad- lected for and promoted by the unique geographic and
ams 1966, 1981; Adams and Nissen 1972; Nissen 1988; environmental framework of the Tigris-Euphrates allu-
Stone 1997). Of the myriad aspects of this phenomenon, vial lowlands. This is a point already made by Adams
this paper focuses on explaining why the earliest urban- (1978, 1981) but one that bears being revisited because
ized state societies in southwestern Asia emerged in the new analytical methodologies allow for more precise in-
alluvial lowlands of the Tigris and Euphrates fluvial sys- terpretations of the available survey data from southern
tem and not elsewhere. This question is now relevant
Mesopotamia than were heretofore possible. At the same
because recent work across portions of southwestern
time, new paleoenvironmental data and computer sim-
Iran, northern Iraq, northern Syria, and southeastern Tur-
key shows that in those areas societies comparable in ulations of ancient climates allow for more precise re-
their scale and level of organizational complexity to constructions of the ecology of the alluvial lowlands of
those of 4th-millennium southern Mesopotamia arose the Tigris and Euphrates Rivers at the time Mesopota-
only after the Sumerian emergence and, to a great degree, mian civilization first crystallized than have been prac-
as a reaction to it (Algaze 1993). ticable until now.
By the beginning of the 3d millennium, for instance, More specifically, I argue that the primacy of southern
we witness the emergence of a Proto-Elamite state that Mesopotamia was in part due to the fact that southern
extended over parts of Fars and Khuzestan provinces of societies had several important material advantages over
southwestern Iran and exerted considerable influence polities in neighboring areas. These included (1) a denser
over remote areas of the Iranian Plateau (Alden 1982, and more varied concentration of exploitable subsistence
Lamberg-Karlovsky 1996). Equally pertinent and better resources, (2) higher and more reliable agricultural yields,
documented are the numerous competing Early Bronze and (3) an exponentially more efficient distribution sys-
Age city-states, each centered at a fortified capital of
tem based on water transport. These advantages pro-
substantial proportions, that coalesced across the well-
moted the creation of inherently asymmetrical exchange
watered plains of northern Syria, northern Iraq, and
southeastern Turkey (hereafter Syro-Mesopotamia) patterns among independent polities in the Mesopota-
sometime during the middle of the 3d millennium (Weiss mian alluvium and between those polities and societies
1983, 1986, 1990; Wilkinson 1994). Recent reviews of in neighboring regions which, over time, produced im-
pertinent evidence by both Weiss (1983, 1986) and Wil- portant organizational asymmetries between southern
kinson (1994, 1997) show that these urban societies had societies and contemporary polities. In particular, by the
associated settlement networks that were as complex, second half of the 4th millennium the various advan-
differentiated, and extensive as those that had existed in tages listed had promoted the emergence and rapid dif-
southern Mesopotamia prior to the Sargonic period. They fusion of innovative mechanisms of commodity produc-
also show that for most of the Early Bronze Age the tion, labor control, and information processing within
agricultural potential of the high plains of Syro-Meso- the myriad competitive but mutually communicative
potamia (based on extensive rain-fed cultivation of grain) polities occupying the southern Mesopotamian alluvium
was sufficient to sustain the urban systems that devel- and immediately associated areas (Susiana). These in-
oped there.
novations can be classed as ideational technologies,
Best-known among the Early Bronze Age city-states of
and more than anything else they help explain why the
Syro-Mesopotamia is ancient Ebla (Tell Mardikh), near
Aleppo, where the chance find of palace archives helps initial locus of early state development in southwestern
us better understand the internal social and economic Asia was the alluvial lowlands of the Tigris and Eu-
structure of the city and the extent of the regional ec- phrates Rivers.
onomic and political control that it was able to exercise In the sections that follow, I discuss the various ma-
(Arcari 1988, Archi 1990, Astour 1988, Bonechi 1993, terial and ideational advantages underpinning the rise of
Matthiae 1988). These archives also reveal the degree to early Mesopotamian civilization in the Uruk period.

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 201

Is Geography Destiny? ville 1989) (fig. 1).3 Not only were these resources par-
ticularly accessible but they were especially dense and
varied at this time. Sedimentological evidence from
deep-sea cores in the Persian Gulf indicates that summer
While geography is certainly not destiny, southern Me- monsoonal rains of Indian Ocean origin had a more
sopotamian societies, at their outset, did enjoy a variety northerly track during the late 5th and early 4th millen-
of environmental and geographical advantages over their nia than at present, bringing intense monsoonal rains to
neighbors that increased the likelihood that self-aggran- large parts of the Mesopotamian alluvial plain and the
dizing individuals and factions in the south would be entire length of the Persian Gulf (Sirocko et al. 1993,
more successful in maintaining, expanding, and legiti- Petit-Maire, Sanlaville, and Yan 1995). The consequences
mizing unequal access to resources and power than their of this climatic phenomenon for littoral resources are
peers in surrounding areas. This made it probable that well understood: the resulting upwelling of nutrient-rich
complex societies would emerge earlier in southern Mes- waters and increased water oxygenation would have
opotamia than in other regions of southwestern Asia. caused across-the-board biomass productivity increases
The first advantage of the southern societies over pol- (Reichart et al. 1997) both throughout the gulf and its
ities in immediately adjoining areas was the greater re- estuaries and within the mosaic of canals, marshes, and
silience with regard to subsistence failure of the Tigris- lagoons surrounding many Uruk population centers.
Euphrates lowlands resulting from a greater variety and The second advantage of southern Mesopotamia over
denser concentration of exploitable subsistence re- its neighbors was provided by the higher yields and re-
sources. As Adams (1978; 1981:1114) has noted, south- liability of the southern agricultural base. While this
ern Mesopotamian societies could easily exploit several edge was to taper off somewhat after the Uruk period, it
complementary ecosystems at the same time, including never totally disappeared, and it naturally increased the
(1) the irrigable alluvial plain, which provided high once- aforementioned beneficial impact of greater resource va-
a-year yields of subsistence crops, principally barley, (2) riety and density. Modern agricultural data from a variety
smaller irrigable areas near the rivers, providing for in- of locales in southeastern Turkey, northern Syria, north-
tensively cultivated gardens and orchards where multi- ern Iraq, and southern Iraq show that, under conditions
ple high-value crops could be produced throughout the of controlled irrigation, the alluvial landscape of south-
year, (3) fallow fields within and outside the irrigated ern Mesopotamia is, on average, about twice as produc-
areas that provided extensive pasture lands for millions tive per unit of land than the rain-fed agricultural re-
of sheep and goats and some cattle, and (4) rivers, arti- gimes characteristic of northern societies (Weiss 1986:
figs. 1 and 2; Wilkinson 1990a:4246). Although there
ficial canals, freshwater marshes, and brackish lagoons
are no exactly comparable ancient data regarding pro-
and estuaries that provided plentiful protein in the form
ductivity per standardized land unit, inferences derived
of fish and fowl, as well as reeds and other useful prod-
from cuneiform records of late-3d-millennium date bear-
ucts.2 In contrast, save for a once-a-year crop of dry-
ing on seed-to-yield ratios suggest that irrigated lands in
farmed grain and ample pasture lands, the high plains
the south had an advantage in terms of productivity over
and intermontane valleys on the periphery of the Mes-
nonirrigated lands elsewhere that was roughly in the 3:
opotamian lowlands offered no comparably varied, re-
1 range.4 Finally, provided that labor existed to maintain,
silient, or dense concentrations of subsistence resources.
repair, and deepen canals, drain excess water from fields,
If anything, the natural advantages of the south over
and build levees, the reliability of irrigated agriculture
the north in resource variety and density would have
been particularly pronounced through much of the Late 3. Some of these early centers, in fact, may owe their location
Ubaid and Uruk periods. Central to this advantage was precisely to their proximity to littoral resources at the time of their
the array of littoral resources that would have been avail- foundation. In reviewing factors that affect urban location, the
able to Mesopotamian societies at that time (Pournelle economist Paul Bairoch (1988) argues that cities preferentially form
at the end of transport routes or at the juncture of two different
2000). Recent geomorphological work shows that a mid-
types of transport routes. The southernmost Uruk centers (Uruk,
Holocene maritime transgression dating to the late 5th Eridu, Ur, Umma, and Girsu) were thus at the same time at the
and 4th millenia raised the level of the Persian Gulf to end of the vast north-south transport route created by the rivers
some 2 m above its present elevation. This resulted in and within reach of the lateral routes created by extensive marshes
an intrusion northwards of the head of the Persian Gulf and lagoons at the encroaching head of the Persian Gulf in the 4th
millennium. This privileged position naturally lessened their trans-
of up to 200 km in places (depending on local variations portation costs and maximized their access to resources from var-
of elevation and differential subsidence rates), thus plac- ious areas.
ing the resource-rich marshes and estuaries of the gulfs 4. Cuneiform records dating to the Ur III period (last century of the
littoral zone in close proximity to Uruk population cen- 3d millennium), for instance, suggest that yield-to-seed ratios of
30:1 were normal for irrigated fields in southern Mesopotamia and
ters such as Eridu, Ur, Uruk, Girsu, and Umma (Sanla- that higher ratios (up to 50:1) were possible (Jacobsen 1982, but see
the reservations of Powell 1985). While comparable data are not
2. Dried fish used as rations were essential to the economy of Me- available from dry-farmed areas in Syro-Mesopotamia in antiquity,
sopotamian city-states in the historical periods (Englund 1990), and ratios for modern grain from a variety of Near Eastern locales cul-
they also figure prominently in some of the Archaic Texts dating tivated under traditional dry-farmed agricultural practices suggest
to the very end of the Uruk period and the immediately following that yield-to-seed ratios in the 7:1 to 9:1 range appear normal for
Jemdet Nasr phase (Englund 1998:12843). wheat and barley (Russell 1988:tables 3, 15, 18).

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
202 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

Fig. 1. The ancient Mesopotamian alluvium during the late 5th and 4th millennia b.c., showing the location
of principal Uruk centers and major watercourses at the time (more precise assessments are the subject of on-
going research by R. McC. Adams and J. R. Pournelle at the Mesopotamian Alluvium Project Laboratory, Uni-
versity of California, San Diego). Location of probable marsh boundaries and Persian Gulf coastline deduced
following Sanlaville (1989). Map by and courtesy of J. R. Pournelle, following Adams (1981, 1999) and Pournelle
(2000).

in the south was greater than that typical of the dry- geomorphological (Hole 1994, 1997; Wilkinson 1999) in-
farmed areas of the north, which are subject to substan- vestigations from various Near Eastern locales can be
tial and unpredictable spatial and temporal variations in combined with recent computer simulations of global
rainfall (Perrin de Brichambaut and Wallen 1963:figs. 2 (de Noblet et al. 1996, Harrison et al. 1998), latitudinal
and 3; Cullen and deMenocal 2000; Turkes 1996). (Hoelzmann et al. 1998), and regional (Bryson and Bryson
The natural advantages in yield, reliability, and pre- 1997, 1999) climatic changes resulting from orbitally in-
dictability of the southern Mesopotamian landscape duced variations in the amount of solar radiation reach-
would also have been particularly pronounced through- ing the earth at about 4000 b.c. to reconstruct mid-Ho-
out much of the 4th millennium. A unique conjuncture locene climatic conditions across the Near East. These
of three related factors helps account for this. The first data suggest that, when compared with that of the his-
factor is climate. The results of new paleoenvironmental torical periods, the climate of the region at the 5th/4th-
(Bar-Matthews, Ayalon, and Kaufman 1997, Blanchet, millennium transition was generally wetter, with
Sanlaville, and Traboulsi 1997, Frumkin et al. 1999) and warmer winters and cooler summers. Further, as much

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 203

as a tenfold expansion (from present levels) in available short distance of each other (ca. 2550 km) during the
surface water appears to have been the norm at the time 4th millennium and that the two rivers actually joined
(Hoelzmann et al. 1998:46). This meant that marginal at several locations within the Mesopotamian alluvial
areas of the Mesopotamian alluvium that are today un- plain of the time, creating a single complexly inter-
productive because of insufficient water or lack of drain- twined fluvial system (fig. 1). The rivers separated to
age would likely have been integrated into fluvial net- their present courses only after the Uruk period, pre-
works draining into the sea (Hoelzmann et al. 1998:47). sumably as a result of the combined effects of environ-
Additionally, the already noted Persian Gulf sediment mental forces and anthropogenic processes that started
cores indicate that parts of the southern Mesopotamian in the 4th millennium.5
alluvium that today receive no summer precipitation Adams and Pournelles conclusions are very relevant
whatsoever would have been affected by summer mon- to the issue of yield differences between alluvial Meso-
soonal rains. Such rains would have been absent from potamia and its neighbors during the Uruk period. It is
the Upper Mesopotamian plains at this time (Blanchet, very likely that throughout much of the 4th millennium
Sanlaville, and Traboulsi 1997:fig. 2). The same cores the waters of the two nearby rivers commingled at flood
(Sirocko et al. 1993, Nutzel 1976) suggest that conditions stage in the northern parts of the alluvium, where their
of increasing aridity and extreme seasonality that more courses came closest. Increasing this possibility is the
closely approach those prevailing at present started to fact that the rivers carried a greater overall amount of
appear by the second half of the 4th millennium and water at that time. The result would have been the cre-
became fully established by the onset of the 3d millen- ation of larger areas than exist at present where various
nium (Butzer 1995). This conclusion is supported by pal- types of high-value vegetables, fruits, and even some ce-
ynological data from lake cores in the Zagros-Taurus reals (e.g., sesame and millet) might have been produced
mountain ranges (van Zeist and Bottema 1991). in late spring and possibly even early summer by means
The implications of these climatic data go well beyond of simple flood-recession irrigation (Sanlaville 1989:24;
the issues already discussed in reference to littoral re- Pournelle 1999).
sources. The data have equally important implications The third factor adding to the advantage in productiv-
for the productivity of the southern Mesopotamian al- ity of the southern alluvial lowlands over neighboring
luvial plain through much of the Uruk period. Increased areas was the effect of the Persian Gulf transgression on
winter precipitation in the Tigris-Euphrates watershed the fluvial dynamics of the Tigris-Euphrates river sys-
as a whole would have increased river volume in the tem. One such effect was that, by reducing the overall
spring, making both canal and flood-recession irrigation length of the rivers, the intrusion would have aggravated
easier throughout the southern lowlands. Increased pre- the rivers natural tendency to meander and overflow
cipitation would have fallen on the alluvium itself at their banks (Hole 1994) at the same time that it raised
this time, including some rain in the now barren summer the level of the water table in the surrounding alluvial
months. Wetter winters with warmer average tempera- plain (Sanlaville 1989:18). This would have increased the
tures would have allowed winter grain crops to mature size of the areas subject to flooding without the need for
earlier than they do today, thus minimizing production substantial human intervention at times of overflow.
losses due to heat. Cooler summers with cloud cover The importance of flood-recession irrigation for the
associated with the monsoonal regime of the time would initial crystallization of Mesopotamian civilization
have decreased soil moisture loss throughout the allu- should not be underestimated. Using ethnographic and
vium, thus increasing the likelihood that some high- economic data from Senegal and elsewhere, Thomas
value crops could have been grown successfully in the Park (1992) has shown that recession irrigation is gen-
area well into the summer. erally the most productive form of agriculture known in
The second factor serving to heighten the natural ad- terms of units of labor invested, irrespective of the crops
vantages in yield and reliability of the Mesopotamian being exploited. He argues that this practice represents
alluvium during parts of the 4th millennium was the a powerful spur for the evolution of social stratification
behavior of the Tigris-Euphrates fluvial system at this
time. New and ongoing research by Robert McC. Adams 5. One of the long-term effects of the Persian Gulf transgression
(1999) and Jennifer Pournelle (1999) confirms earlier sug- noted earlier would have been to increase overbank sedimentation
in the areas between the two rivers through the 4th millennium
gestions by Adams (1981:1617) and others (e.g., Gibson as a result of reduced river length, gradient, and velocity (Butzer
1973) that the main channels of both the Tigris and the 2001). This natural process contributing to the buildup of sediments
Euphrates have moved considerably over the course of separating the two rivers would have been compounded by the un-
the past 6,000 years or so. Using newly declassified sat- intended consequences of man-made irrigation efforts. As noted by
Pournelle (1999 and personal communication, 2000), by decreasing
ellite images (CORONA), Adams and Pournelle have
the volume of water in the main river channel, Uruk-period irri-
been able to correlate the location of previously surveyed gation efforts would have reduced the rivers ability to carry its silt
4th-millennium sites in the south with relict river chan- load, thus contributing to a further increase in sediments deposited
nels that are visible in the new images but were not in the surrounding alluvium. Additionally, because irrigation ef-
identifiable with precision in previously available air forts at the time naturally focused on the intervening areas between
the Tigris and the Euphrates, those efforts must have heightened
photos or LANDSAT images of the area. From this they levee buildup along artificial channels in the intervening areas as
conclude that large portions of the main channels of the well as increased the silt loads deposited in preferentially flooded
Tigris and the Euphrates were actually located within a fields within those areas.

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
204 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

in societies practicing it because of the particularly high were, in effect, at the head of an enormous dendritic
variability of output that it creates between well-irri- transportation system created by the north-to-south-
gated, poorly irrigated, and unirrigated lands. Thus, flowing rivers. This allowed them to procure informa-
flood-recession irrigation is likely to have been impor- tion, labor, and commodities from areas within the vast
tant in the initial development of population agglom- Tigris-Euphrates watershed more efficiently than any po-
erations in the alluviumparticularly in its northern tential upstream competitors or rivals away from the
portion, where the rivers came closest to each other. Not rivers (Bairoch 1988:11, 14). To be sure, exports from the
coincidentally, this is precisely the portion of the allu- alluvium still had to move by means of relatively inef-
vium in which Adamss (1981) surveys document the ficient donkey caravans following the course of the rivers
most precocious development of Uruk urban centers northward, but the crucial edge of southern cities lay in
(Early Uruk period). their ability to import needed commodities in bulk from
Although it never totally disappeared, the overall faraway resource-producing areas in the surrounding
southern edge in yield and reliability per unit of land highlands at low cost, transporting them on rafts or boats
provided by irrigation would have diminished somewhat downstream on the rivers, tributaries, and canals (British
after the Uruk period for several reasons. First, as the Admiralty 1917:29192; Potts 1997:12238; Sauren
gulf intrusion receded (lowering the water table across 1966). Of equal importance, the network of canals sur-
the alluvium) and as the main channels of the rivers rounding Mesopotamian cities and connecting them
separated because of natural and man-made levee with the main courses of the rivers allowed them to
buildup following the Uruk period (see n. 5), the extent move bulky agricultural commodities across their im-
of areas exploitable by flood-recession agriculture would mediate dependent hinterlands with great efficiency
have been reduced. This would have necessitated the (Weiss 1986:94). In contrast, societies in the Mesopota-
construction of ever larger and more expensive canals in mian periphery had to rely wholly on less efficient modes
order to make up in grain production for the decline in of overland communication, such as donkeys or carts,
higher-value crops. Second, after centuries of irrigation, both for their long-distance exchange needs and for the
the higher water-table levels of the 4th millennium movement of subsistence resources across their imme-
would naturally have resulted in varying degrees of sal- diate hinterlands. The natural transportational advan-
inization of parts of the alluvial plain (Jacobsen and Ad- tages of southern cities help explain, in part, why those
ams 1958; Adams 1981:15152). This largely unavoidable cities could grow, on average, significantly larger and
process would have been compounded by attempts to more differentiated than their peripheral counterparts
shorten fallow (Gibson 1974) and to bring ever more mar- throughout the Chalcolithic and Bronze Ages.6
ginal lands under cultivation as competing Early Dy-
nastic polities tried to gain advantage over their peers by
further increasing agricultural production within their A Synergistic Cauldron
territories.
At the same time that overall yields were eroding in The developmental takeoff of southern Mesopotamia in
the south, developments outside of the Mesopotamian the 4th millennium b.c. can only be understood against
alluvium were helping increase agricultural yields across a background combining the extraordinary transporta-
the periphery, thereby contributing to a lessening of yield tional advantages offered by the Tigris-Euphrates fluvial
differences between the two areas after the Uruk period. system, the unique density and variety of the subsistence
As noted by Wilkinson (1994), the higher average south- resources provided by the southern alluvial environment
ern yields per unit of land were eventually partly cir- of the time, and the absence from that environment of
cumvented in the Syro-Mesopotamian plains, at least in other necessary resources, such as metals, timber, and
the short term, by the intensive application of manure status-validating exotics. The synergy created by these
on cultivated areas near settlements and by an increase conditions spurred the creation of high levels of social
in the overall amount of land under cultivation (on this and economic differentiation, promoted unprecedented
point, see also Weiss 1986). However, these forms of in-
tensification required the formation of small territorial 6. Early Dynastic Warka, for instance, was somewhere between 400
states able to draw on agricultural resources from rela- and 600 ha in extent (Finkbeiner 1991)a size not reached by any
city in northern Mesopotamia until Nineveh grew to the enormous
tively broad areas through several tiers of dependent set- size of 700 ha and became the center of the Neo-Assyrian empire
tlements, and there is no incontrovertible evidence for in the 8th and 7th centuries b.c. (Stronach 1994). Wilkinson (1995)
such states in those areas until the middle of the 3d argues inductively, from pertinent survey evidence, that throughout
millennium b.c. Be that as it may, what is relevant here the Bronze Age there was a 100-or-so-ha natural size limit for
urban centers in Syro-Mesopotamia. He contends that the breaking
is that throughout the 4th millennium the south still
of this limit that took place in Neo-Assyrian times was due to a
had a clear and uncontested advantage (per unit of land) combination of (1) more intensive coercive policies that increased
in the yield, reliability, and resilience of its primary sub- the rate of surplus extraction from the countryside, (2) a resettle-
sistence resources. Uruk elites could therefore extract ment program fueled by deportees from throughout the Near East
relatively larger surpluses per unit of labor than their that brought lands previously too marginal for agricultural use into
cultivation, and (3) a more flexible economy that succeeded in over-
contemporary counterparts in the north. riding the until-then-normal limitations on population size in the
The third advantage of alluvial Mesopotamia was north caused by the frictional effects of overland transport of bulk
transportational efficiency. The cities of the alluvium agricultural products.

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 205

population agglomerations within the alluvium, and se- resources external to the system are incorporated into
lected for the creation of new forms of social organization it, and how developments that initially may have been
and technologies of social control that until then had independent join in inherently unpredictable and un-
never existed in human societies. To understand why foreseen ways to cause further differentiation. Jacobs ex-
the ecological and geographical framework of Mesopo- plains that in both types of systems differentiation is an
tamia had such radical social consequences, we must open-ended and self-amplifying process, since each new
briefly review the nature of urban development and its differentiation constitutes the basis from which further
causes. differentiation can eventually emerge. Expansion occurs
Particularly pertinent to this review is the work of the as the processes generating diversity are repeated again
iconoclastic urban expert Jane Jacobs, whose ideas about and again.
the role of cities in human development have already More specifically, Jacobs argues that what determines
influenced some anthropologists interested in the dy- a settlements ability to grow is a positive feedback loop
namics of urban growth in early civilizations (e.g., Kurtz initiated by its capacity to generate exports by combining
1987) and are now gaining increasing currency among some of its imports or preexisting resources with human
mainstream economists (Nowlan 1997). Though Jacobs labor and capital. This generates economic diversity at
is best known for her often controversial views about the the same time that it makes it possible for growing set-
future of the urban experience in America (Jacobs 1961, tlements to acquire more and different imports, some of
1984), her work also includes a variety of more abstract which can again be used to generate further exports. This
contributions about the nature of urban economies process creates co-developments in the form of an in-
(1969, 2000) that are applicable to attempts to understand creasingly large, skilled, and diverse workforce (i.e., hu-
the dynamics of early social complexity in Mesopotamia. man capital), and this, in turn, creates the potential for
In the more theoretical aspects of her work, Jacobs is further economic diversification by adding new types of
ultimately inspired by ideas first enunciated by Herbert work and new ways of working. As both work and di-
Spencer well over a century ago. Spencer believed that versity expand, so does population density within the
a tendency toward increasing differentiation was inher- affected settlements. This increase commonly takes
ent in all features of the universe, including the character place at the expense of nearby rural populations, which
of human societies. He argued that as societies became is why cities are always the economic and physical shap-
naturally more diverse through time, relations of inter- ers of their hinterlands. Eventually, when their own mar-
dependency were created among their diverse social el- ket has developed sufficiently to justify producing some
ements and that this produced emergent properties that of the imports that had previously been acquired from
were not predictable a priori (Spencer 1967[1876,1882]: other places, expanding settlements commonly have ac-
8). In a similar vein but with a narrower focus, Jacobs quired both the skills and capital to do so. In this manner,
sees economic differentiation as central to processes of by replacing imports with local manufactures in a second
social change and urban growth. For Jacobs, social dif- burst of economic expansion, growing centers generate
ferentiation results from economic differentiation, and even greater diversity and employment, thereby setting
social evolution ultimately depends on economic expan- the stage for further economic and demographic growth
sion. She is one of a small number of scholars who see and for an even sharper restructuring of settlement pat-
human economies as sharing many characteristics with terns in their immediate vicinity (Jacobs 1969, 2000).
biological ecosystems (see also Mokyr 2000 and Ziman While exchange between independent societies will
2000 for in-depth discussions of similarities and differ- always have an impact on all of the polities involved,
ences between biological and technological evolution). the beneficial multiplier effects of the two-step eco-
The most salient of these similarities are that (1) the nomic process just described will disproportionally affect
degree of resiliency and stability of the two types of sys- societies in which imports consist mostly of raw re-
tems and their ability to expand are directly related to sources while exports consist mostly of value-added
the degree of diversity present (Jacobs 2000:22, 37); (2) goods. This is so because economic diversity, employ-
expansion ultimately depends on capturing and using ment, and skills expand doubly as a result of the need
external energy, principally light in the case of ecosys- to process both the imports and the exports in those
tems and exogenous resources in the case of human so- societies. This, in turn, is significant for the development
cieties, and the more diverse means a system possesses of sociopolitical complexity in such societies because the
for using, modifying, and passing around energy/re- division of labor generates incentives for cooperation be-
sources, the larger the cumulative consequences to the tween diverse individuals with common interests (Lich-
system as a whole (p. 47); and (3) development takes place bach 1996), as well as incentives for competition be-
as part of a larger web of co-developments; the greater tween societal factions with conflicting or overlapping
the internal diversity of the system, the more numerous interests (Brumfiel 1994).
and intricate the co-development relationships that will The export-driven model for social and urban devel-
exist within it and the greater the number of emergent opment that Jacobs proposes is particularly applicable to
properties that will be spawned (pp. 1922). the study of how and why early Mesopotamian civili-
Given these similarities, for Jacobs the development zation emerged. Cities and city-states were, in fact, the
of social and ecosystemic complexity is studied by ex- most typical and enduring political formations through-
ploring how diversity is created within the system, how out the history of that civilization (Stone 1997, Yoffee

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
206 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

1995). Moreover, rich as the Mesopotamian alluvium ity of the textiles that merchant families based in the
may have been in agricultural, pastoral, and maritime northern Mesopotamian city of Assur exported to north-
resources, it still lacked a substantial proportion of the ern Syria and Anatolia were actually of southern Me-
nonsubsistence material requirements for the highly sopotamian origin (i.e., Akkadian). Since the area
stratified social systems that emerged there by the Uruk around Assur was perfectly capable of supporting the
period (Algaze 1993). Thus, historically, the southern cit- necessary wool industries, the fact that Assyrian mer-
ies imported from highland areas on the alluviums pe- chants felt compelled to import textiles from faraway
riphery many resources that required a significant degree polities in the south reveals how highly prized these
of skilled processing before they could be incorporated southern Mesopotamian products were in the areas
into the economy. Most prominent among these labor- where they marketed their goods. No doubt this was
intensive imports were roofing-grade timber, wood, var- partly the result of the superior workmanship and pres-
ious types of metal ores, various utilitarian, semipre- tige of southern textiles, since the areas where those
cious, and exotic stones, and bitumen, among others. textiles were consumed, too, could have supported com-
Likewise, traditional exports from the southern cities, plex textile industries.
whether destined for other cities within the alluvium or Once in place, the self-amplifying consequences of pat-
for distribution in faraway markets, were also almost terns of production and trade such as these are easy to
entirely labor-intensive and consisted principally of sur- visualize. First, the exchange would have promoted con-
plus grain, leather products, dried fish, dates, processed siderable economic differentiation and associated co-de-
dairy fats, and, most important, finished textiles (see Al- velopments in the alluvium because of the need to pro-
gaze 1993:6374; Larsen 1987; van de Mieroop 1997: cess both imports and exports (Jacobs 1969, 2000). This,
19596; Yoffee 1981, 1995). in turn, would have created incentives for the emergence
The production of textiles, traditionally the most im- of factions within growing southern polities and in-
portant export from the Mesopotamian alluvium, pro- creased the likelihood of competition within and be-
vides us with a perfect case in point as to the applicability tween them (Brumfiel 1994). Second, it would have stim-
of Jacobss model to the Mesopotamian context. As prac- ulated the acquisition and maintenance of the
ticed in ancient Mesopotamia during historical times, (dependent) workers that, in a Mesopotamian cultural
textile production combined imports of wool from hin- context, were needed to ensure the production of labor-
terlands surrounding individual cities with a substantial intensive exports. Third, it would have spurred the ex-
amount of human labor and capital to create commod- pansion and institutionalization of the bureaucratic su-
ities that were both consumed domestically and exported perstructure needed to organize and maintain the labor,
long distances. Textual and iconographic evidence sug- to record its production, and to redistribute the resulting
gest, in fact, that textile production was already an im- commodities across the landscape (Wright and Johnson
portant urban industry in southern Mesopotamia during 1975). Fourth, it would have promoted the development
the second half of the 4th millennium. Many of the ear- of steeper settlement hierarchies within the alluvium,
liest pictographic tablets that appear by the end of the since an adequate flow of local agricultural resources was
Uruk period (the Archaic Texts), for instance, deal either required for export. Thus, the larger centers capable of
with the disbursement of finished textiles or with the conducting the exchange would have taken steps to at-
acquisition of raw wool (Nissen 1986). By the same to- tract and appropriate, by whatever means necessary, the
ken, depictions in seals and sealings of female workers agricultural and pastoral production of rural communi-
(pigtailed figures) attending horizontal looms are com- ties in their immediate hinterlands (Adams 1981:8081).
mon in Uruk-period levels at a variety of sites (Amiet What still needs to be clarified, however, is how ex-
1972:nos. 67374; 1980:nos. 31920). port-driven economies in southern Mesopotamia
However, our most detailed evidence for the impor- evolved in the first place. What were the initial exports
tance of textile production to the economy of Mesopo- that brought in the initial imports, thus setting into mo-
tamian cities comes from economic texts dating to the tion the export/import positive feedback loops described
3d and early 2d millennia b.c. These documents show by Jacobs? Here, I believe, is where the greater variety
that each major Sumerian city-state had a palace-organ- and density of subsistence resources offered by the south-
ized weaving establishment in which thousands of de- ern Mesopotamian landscape and the particularly une-
pendent women and children labored to process wool ven distribution of some of these resources during the
imported into the city from the surrounding countryside 4th millennium came to serve as necessary conditions
into finished fabrics and garments (Jacobsen 1970[1953], for the Mesopotamian takeoff. The considerable agri-
Maekawa 1980, Waetzoldt 1972). The texts reveal that cultural, pastoral, and maritime resources of the area
the amount of time and human effort spent in the pro- acted in effect as unearned imports, acquirable only
duction of these fabrics, earmarked for both domestic through human efforts (Jacobs 2000:54). Exports of initial
consumption and foreign markets, was astonishingly stocks of diverse starter resources in different concen-
high. According to Larsen (1987), simple fabrics took al- trations throughout the Tigris-Euphrates lowlands were
most a month to complete while particularly elaborate what allowed individual southern polities to begin to
pieces, intended for export, took, on occasion, well over develop export-driven economies as a result of intra-al-
three years. Larsens analysis of Old Assyrian texts of luvium trade before polities in surrounding regions could
early-2d-millennium date clearly shows that the major- do so. In this manner, southern societies acquired a de-

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 207

velopmental head start over their neighbors which was competitive emulation would account for the diffusion
neither planned nor foreseen but was to have long-term of technologies and practices that were initially devel-
consequences for the developmental trajectories of both oped by individual centers exploiting specialized niches
groups of societies. but soon came to be perceived as highly advantageous
by many of the centers in competition. Foremost among
these quickly diffused activities would have been the
manufacture of textiles, an industry present in every
The Evolution of Export-Driven Economies in Mesopotamian polity of any consequence in the 3d and
Southern Mesopotamia 2d millennia b.c. Adding to the attraction of textiles is
the fact that they lend themselves particularly well to
Although detailed evidence is still lacking, Jacobss the expression of the multiple statuses and local styles
model allows us to visualize a still speculative though that are the natural outcomes of the processes of internal
ultimately testable scenario to account for the preco- and regional differentiation described earlier (D. Tuzin,
cious urban growth that took place in the Mesopotamian personal communication, 2000).
alluvium in the 4th millennium. In this scenario, the To be sure, some measure of trade with areas outside
positive feedback economic loops responsible for that the Mesopotamian alluvium, allowing Mesopotamian
growth evolved over centuries as a result of exchange polities to acquire needed utilitarian and exotic resources
that was at first largely internal between growing south- and goods not locally available, must have existed
ern centers and later complemented and amplified by a throughout this process. A case in point is the import of
significant measure of external trade between those cen- flint and obsidian obtained from areas on the periphery
ters and less developed polities in the Mesopotamian of southern Mesopotamia, which is attested throughout
periphery. For heuristic purposes, this evolving process the Ubaid period in the south (G. Wright 1969). This case
may be divided into a number of discrete stages, although is important because it offers us what is perhaps the
substantial overlaps clearly existed between them. earliest example of import substitution within the al-
As already noted, the initial impetus for the growth of luvium, as imports of raw flint and chipped stone tools
export-driven southern economies with their attending were partly replaced by locally manufactured clay sickles
multiplier effects would have been inadvertently pro- throughout the Late Ubaid and Uruk periods (Benco
vided by burgeoning trade between polities exploiting 1992).
the various rich ecological niches that existed within the Nonetheless, external trade becomes a significant fac-
Tigris-Euphrates alluvial lowlands during the Late Ubaid tor in the overall economy of southern societies only in
phase and the earlier part of the Uruk period (late 5th to a third stage of the process, datable to the Middle and
early 4th millennium). Each of these polities would have Late Uruk periods (ca. 36003100 b.c.). This stage was
naturally specialized in the production of a small number fueled by the material and human capital accumulated
of crops or commodities for which it had a competitive during the earlier stages of largely internal exchange.
advantage owing to its location within the alluvial ec- Specifically, what made possible the intensification of
osystem. Products traded in this initial stage would have external trade at this time was the predevelopment and
included (1) woven and dyed textiles, goat-hair products, diffusion of industries that were originally intended to
leather goods, dairy fats, and other pastoral resources satisfy consumption requirements within the alluvium
distributed by polities situated at the margins of the bet- but easily adapted for export markets outside it. No
ter-watered parts of the alluvium, where they would doubt, woven and dyed textiles were the principal com-
have enjoyed preferential access to pastoral and nomadic modity fulfilling this double role in the 4th millennium,
groups producing these various commodities, (2) garden as they were later on in the historic periods. Other ex-
and grain crops produced by polities in the northern por- ports of the time are more easily documented in the
tion of the Mesopotamian alluvial plain, where the com- archaeological record. These include bitumen from
bined flow of the Tigris and the Euphrates made irriga- southern Iraqi and southeastern Iranian sources
tion agriculture and horticulture both more likely and (Schwartz, Hollander, and Stein 1999) and processed ag-
more profitable, and (3) dried, salted, and smoked fish, ricultural (wine, unguents, aromatic oils?) and pastoral
reeds, and other marsh or littoral resources preferentially (animal fats) commodities contained within the various
produced by polities near the Persian Gulf littoral. types of Uruk ceramic containers (four-lugged, spouted,
A second stage in the process would have been marked and pear-shaped jars) that are often found in many in-
by an emerging elite awareness of the social implications digenous Late Chalcolithic sites across the Mesopota-
of the trade patterns in place until that point in time. mian periphery (Algaze 1993:6374; 1995; Badler, Mc-
This stage was characterized by a decrease in regional Govern, and Glusker 1996; Englund 1998:16169).
specialization within the alluvium as each competing This third stage of the process saw the establishment
polity used the material surpluses and human skills ac- of various types of southern outposts at strategic loca-
quired during the first stage to replace some imports from tions of significance for transport across the Mesopota-
nearby centers by creating their own productive capac- mian periphery. These outposts served as collection and
ities for those products, thus setting in motion the fur- transshipment points for the increasing amounts of pe-
ther growth spurt that accrues from the import-substi- ripheral commodities imported into the alluvium in the
tution mechanism discussed by Jacobs. In this stage, later part of the Uruk period and as distribution points

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
208 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

for the exports from the alluvium exchanged for them. materials in areas close to the pertinent raw materials
The outposts need not be conceived as the product of a (Kohl 1987a:16). Cases in point are provided by a small
single master plan. Rather, they are best considered as number of elaborate obsidian vessels found in layers un-
resulting from an organic process of action and counter- der the White Temple at Warka (Heinrich 1937:pl. 59)
action, with individual Uruk polities scrambling to oc- which closely resemble examples found in Late Chal-
cupy specific positions in order to secure access to the colithic tombs at the small northern Mesopotamian site
critical lines of communication through which resources of Tepe Gawra (cf. Tobler 1950:pl. 53 B-C) and which
were obtainable and, of equal importance, to deny their were almost certainly imported as finished products.
local rivals such access (Algaze 1993, 2001; but see John- Also in the same category is at least one javelin or har-
son 198889, Oates 1993, Pollock 1992, Rothman 1993, poon-head made of an unusual copper-silver alloy (over
Schwartz 1988, Surenhagen 1986, Stein 1999, and Roth- 25% silver) found in the Riemchengebaude at Warka
man 2001 for varying views about the nature and func- (Muller-Karpe 1991:109, fig. 3). This weapon is almost
tion of the outposts). certainly imported from the Taurus region of Anatolia,
By the later half of the Uruk period, regular access to since weapons made of the same type of alloy are com-
external resources became necessary because of the need mon in Levels VIA and VIB at Arslantepe, a small Late
to supply the increasingly differentiated and dense urban Chalcolithic chiefly center near Malatya (Palmieri,
populations emerging in the southern alluvium. Imports Hauptmann, and Hess 1997).
of roofing-grade timber and copper (for the manufacture However important finished imports may have been
of cutting tools) must have been crucial at this point to to the overall economy of Uruk city-states in the early
satisfy the substantial building requirements of rapidly phases of the evolving exchange, it is clear that it did
growing Uruk cities. It has been estimated, for example, not take long for further phases of import-substitution
that somewhere between 3,000 and 6,000 m of roofing- processes to take hold in the south. A case in point is
grade timber would have been necessary to roof the provided by metals, which almost certainly were first
Limestone Temple at Warka (Eanna V), dated to the Late imported largely as finished products. While evidence of
Uruk period (Margueron 1992).7 This is but a single struc- metalworking and metal-processing installations in
ture (albeit a large one: ca. 27 # 80 m p 0.21 ha) in a Uruk-period sites is still relatively rare, Moorey (1994:
city that, at this point, occupied an area estimated at 243) attributes this paucity to the use of simple but ef-
somewhere between 200 and 250 ha (Finkbeiner 1991). fective technologies such as crucible smelting that have
Equally important would have been a steady supply of largely escaped the attention of archaeologists looking
precious and semiprecious stones and base and exotic only for more substantial installations such as furnaces.
metals, which, like some of the better-made textiles, Nonetheless, the pictogram for a smith (showing a smelt-
were needed to mark and legitimize the ever more di- ing furnace with attached blowpipes) is already attested
verse and unequal social statuses evolving within Uruk in the earliest Archaic Texts (Uruk IV script), which date
cities. Substantial amounts of such exotic materials to the very end of the Uruk period (Moorey 1994:243).
have, in fact, been recovered at a variety of Late Uruk- Additionally, there are some archaeological indications
period sites. A storeroom with various types of semipre- that metal artifacts began to be produced locally in
cious stones (including several kilos of lapis lazuli) and southern Mesopotamia during the Uruk period (still us-
some copper ingots, for instance, was found at Jebel ing, of course, imported raw materials). At Warka, for
Aruda, an Uruk outpost in northern Syria (Rouault and instance, both copper ores (Heinrich 1938:25) and a cop-
Massetti-Rouault 1993:435). Even more impressive was per-processing installation (Nissen 1970:114) are re-
the hoard of exotic and semiprecious stones used as in- ported in Uruk levels. Similarly, more recent excavations
lays in furniture recovered from the Riemchengebaude at several intrusive Uruk outposts in the Upper Euphra-
structure in the Eanna (Level IV) precinct at Warka, tes portion of Syria have yielded substantial and clear
which may represent either a temple (Forest 1999) or a indications for metal processing in Mesopotamian so-
storehouse associated with a nearby temple (Nissen cieties of the Uruk period. Tell Sheikh Hassan, for ex-
1988).8 ample, has provided evidence for smelting crucibles in
While the great majority of imports into the alluvium a Middle Uruk-period level (Boese 1995:175, pl. 13a).
throughout the 4th millennium required some degree of From Late Uruk-period levels at Jebel Aruda, in turn,
processing, it is likely that some finished goods made of comes a hoard of eight copper axes (Rouault and Mas-
exotic materials were also being imported at this time. setti-Rouault 1993:fig. 115), which almost certainly
These would have been made by peripheral societies served as ingots (G. Stein, personal communication,
with a long tradition of extracting and working those 2000).9 Finally, Habuba Kabira-sud, the largest intrusive

7. The large range in Marguerons estimate is due to the various 9. The axes in question were of more or less equal weight in spite
potential ways in which the building could have been constructed of variations in size and were found in a storeroom that also con-
(i.e., number of levels, whether the courtyard was roofed, and po- tained a variety of exotic stones and minerals (Rouault and Mas-
tential differences in beam interval). setti-Rouault 1993:435), suggesting that they were being catego-
8. It is also very likely that many of the exotics contained in the rized as raw materials rather than as tools. Buttressing Steins
so-called Sammelfund Hoard, which was discovered in a Jemdet suggestion that the axes served as ingots is the fact that the Mari
Nasrperiod level (Eanna III) at Warka, were heirlooms of Uruk- texts of early-2d-millennium date actually refer to copper ingots in
period date (Heinrich 1936). the form of axes (Yener 1980:32). Additionally, as Yener (pp. 3435)

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 209

Late Uruk site on the Syrian Euphrates, has yielded ev- population densities in a Mesopotamian context), there
idence for the use of a fairly elaborate cupellation process can be no doubt that the Uruk city-state constituted the
to extract lead and silver from polymetallic ores im- largest single agglomeration of population under a single
ported into the site. These metallurgical activities are ruler for its time not only in the Near East but in the
reported from several locations within the northeastern world. Moreover, the city of Uruk was hardly alone
quarter of the site (Kohlmeyer 1997:447). within the Mesopotamian alluvium in the Late Uruk
period. Multiple interacting urban sites (ca. 2040 ha)
existed across the surveyed portions of the southern Mes-
The Urban Takeoff of Southern Mesopotamia opotamian alluvium at this time, all situated alongside
canals and within relatively short distances of each other
How closely the emergence of social complexity in (Adams 1981). Additionally, at least two further Uruk
southern Mesopotamia followed the developmental path urban polities existed in the Susiana Plain of south-
just suggested is a subject for future research. What is western Iran.
clear is that, by the end of the 4th millennium, substan- There is some debate about the nature of the political
tial developmental asymmetries had emerged between system within which these various polities existed. Flan-
societies in southern Mesopotamia and surrounding ar- nery (1995) and Marcus (1998) explicitly assume that all
eas. These asymmetries are most easily gauged by a com- pristine states emerge from a crucible of conflict as ear-
parison of rates of population agglomeration in the two lier regional chiefdoms are consolidated into a single
areas at this time. Although detailed and systematic sur- much larger and complex polity. They suggest that Uruk
vey coverage is still lacking for large portions of the north was the capital of a territorial state by the Late Uruk
and northwestern periphery of alluvial Mesopotamia, period, pointing to the fivefold size differential between
there can be little doubt that throughout the 4th mil- Uruk and its nearest second-tier settlements as sup-
lennium southern Mesopotamia had a substantial ad- porting evidence. This is a plausible interpretation of the
vantage over areas on its periphery in the proportion of available evidence from the Mesopotamian alluvium,
its population living in urban agglomerations and their which, unfortunately, outside of Uruk itself, still con-
immediate vicinity. Adamss calculations indicate that, sists largely of surface survey data. Equally plausible at
depending on the area, somewhere between 40 and 70% this point, however, are interpretations that see the
of the total population in the Mesopotamian alluvium emergence of early Mesopotamian civilization as a case
in the later half of the Uruk period lived in settlements in which a number of rival statelets evolved in parallel
that can be classed as towns or cities (i.e., 10 ha or larger; as a result of common factors such as the multiplier
cf. Adams 1981:75, table 4). These results are now but- effects of trade. From this perspective, the various urban
tressed by a recent reassessment of the same data by centers across the Mesopotamian alluvium in the Late
Pollock (2001:table 5), who tries to correct Adamss data Uruk period are seen as independent polities ancestral
by counting only sites likely to have been occupied si- to the competing city-states that characterized the area
multaneously during any one period. Her more conser- throughout the 3d millennium and for much of its his-
vative results suggest that the ratio of population living tory (Adams 1981, Baines and Yoffee 1998).
in agglomerated settlements throughout the surveyed Of the two interpretations, I believe the latter is more
portions of the alluvium during the later half of the Uruk likely. In the first place, processes of urban growth
period may have been even higher than Adams had orig- through the Uruk period appear to have resulted in the
inally reckoned (ca. 6977% depending on the area). creation of buffer zones between some of the emerging
The most telling example of the disparities in popu- urban polities of the time. These uninhabited areas sug-
lation agglomeration between southern Mesopotamia gest competition and strife rather than an overarching
and peripheral areas in the 4th millennium is the city political unity. The clearest instance of this pattern is
of Uruk, which, as already noted, had reached the ex- that documented by Johnson (1987) for the Susiana Plain.
traordinary size of 200250 ha by the Late Uruk period. His surveys document the abandonment of all Middle
Adamss (1981; Adams and Nissen 1972) surveys show Urukperiod villages along a 15-km-wide arc by the Late
that Uruk was surrounded by an irregular array of de- Uruk period, separating what appear to have been two
pendent towns and villages located within a 1315-km rival states, centered at Susa and Chogha Mish, respec-
radius of the city that accounted for an additional 280 tively. These sites thus appear to have been independent
ha of occupied settlement. This, of course, almost cer- of each other and almost certainly were also independent
tainly substantially underestimates the actual popula- of contemporary polities in the Mesopotamian allu-
tion density of the Uruk countryside, since normal al- vium.10 In the second place, later literary traditions, such
luviation patterns in southern Mesopotamia would 10. A further area of village abandonment can be observed between
naturally obscure a large proportion of the smaller sites the northern (Nippur-Adab) and southern (Uruk) regions of the Me-
(Wilkinson 1990b). However one estimates the popula- sopotamian alluvium surveyed by Adams (1981:compare figs. 12
and 13). Whether this can also be interpreted as a buffer zone be-
tion of this megalopolis and its dependencies (see Post-
tween competing polities or sets of polities is, however, more am-
gate 1994 for a discussion of the pitfalls of estimating biguous than the comparable case in Susiana because the area of
the alluvium in question was one also affected by river course
points out, the use of standardized tool or artifact forms as ingots changes that may have contributed to the observed population shift
is well attested in a variety of ethnographic cases in Africa. (Adams 1981:63).

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
210 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

as the Sumerian King List (Jacobsen 1939), explicitly con- Hawa at 30 ha (Wilkinson and Tucker 1995).12 How-
ceptualize the earliest Mesopotamian political configu- ever, those settlements were not embedded in complex
rations as composed of independent cities, each with its settlement grids as southern centers were. Tell Hawa,
own ruler. If a primordial state centered at Uruk that for example, was surrounded in the Late Chalcolithic
held sway over the whole of the Mesopotamian alluvium period by a corona of uniformly small village- or hamlet-
existed in the Late Uruk period, it left no mark on later sized sites (Wilkinson and Tucker 1995:fig. 35, top). A
literary traditions that appear interested precisely in doc- more complex three-tiered settlement pattern structure
umenting, however fancifully, the flow of political power appears in the vicinity of Hawa and the Sinjar area only
within Mesopotamia. Finally, political paramountcy is after the onset of contacts with the Uruk world (Wil-
not the only thing that can account for the size differ- kinson and Tucker 1995:fig. 35, bottom). A similar case
appears to obtain for Tell Brak, which was clearly a sub-
ences between Uruk and smaller contemporary urban
stantial indigenous settlement during most of the 4th
settlements. Steinkeller (1999) has recently called atten-
millennium (Area TW, Levels 1913), before some sort
tion to a handful of Jemdet Nasrperiod tablets showing
of a southern Mesopotamian presence was introduced
individual Sumerian cities sending resources to Uruk as into the site during the Late Uruk period (Area TW, Lev-
ritual offerings to Inanna. He sees these tablets as evi- els 1211; Oates and Oates 1993, 1994, 1997). The Late
dence for the operation of a precursor of the BALA dis- Chalcolithic phases of Brak have been described as doc-
tribution system that would keep the religious institu- umenting a regionally integrated urban polity compa-
tions of Nippur supplied with offerings and resources rable to but even earlier than those of Uruk-period south-
during the Ur III period, a millennium or so later. If this ern Mesopotamia (Oates and Oates 1997, Emberling et
is indeed true, it means that Uruk functioned as the al. 1999, Lamberg-Karlovsky 1999). This claim is based
religious capital of Sumer through the 4th millennium, on the extent of the site in the Late Chalcolithic period,
and, if later historical practice may be projected back- the fact that a small number of suburb areas where spe-
wards, this would have precluded a political dimension cialized production took place surrounded the site at the
for the city at this time.11 time, and the substantial nature of the architecture un-
Leaving aside the nature of political systems in the covered in the small exposures that have been practi-
Mesopotamian alluvium during the Late Uruk period, cable thus far in relevant levels (Area TW, 1317 and
Adamss data clearly show that by that time multiple 1819). Nonetheless, the available survey evidence from
interacting urban settings had already characterized the the immediate hinterland of Brak, though much less de-
Mesopotamian alluvium for centuries. In fact, his sur- tailed than that available from the vicinity of Hawa,
veys of the Nippur-Adab area of the alluvium show that shows that during the Late Chalcolithic period the site
at least four separate 40-ha centers existed along three was surrounded by uniformly small village- or hamlet-
separate branches of the rivers during the Early Uruk sized sites (Eidem and Warburton 1996:5960).13 Unless
larger dependent sites existed around Brak and Hawa that
period (Adams 1981:fig. 13). To this must be added the
are thus far undocumented, the bipolar regional settle-
site of Uruk itself, farther downstream, which was cer-
ment pattern that characterized both areas lacks the
tainly of comparable size at this point. These centers did
depth and range of settlement size variability found to
not exist in isolation. When the relevant survey data are surround contemporary southern Mesopotamian urban
tallied, it appears that complex three- and four-tiered sites and is most parsimoniously interpreted as reflecting
settlement structures already characterized the surveyed a chiefdom-level organizational structure. Finally, recent
areas of the alluvium by the Early Uruk period. These attempts to characterize the Late Chalcolithic settle-
data indicate that the proportion of the population living ment of Arslantepe (Period VIA) as a state-level society
in urban agglomerations in the alluvium at that time (Frangipane 1997, 2001) are also unconvincing because
was already close to the 50% mark according to Adamss of the small overall size of the site (4 ha) and the absence
(1981:75, table 4) calculations. If Pollocks (2001:table 5) of detailed information about contemporary settlement
reassessment of the same data is preferred, that number patterns in its vicinity.14
is as high as 80%. The fact remains that when we look at those areas of
When the settlement structure of the Mesopotamian
alluvium throughout the various phases of the Uruk pe- 12. Often-repeated claims that the site of Hamoukar in northeast-
riod is compared with that of contemporary societies in ern Syria was 90 ha in extent during the Late Chalcolithic period
neighboring areas, the contrast could not be starker. Ad- (Surenhagen 1986) are now discredited by recent work showing that
its actual extent was but 13 ha (Gibson 2000).
mittedly, some individual Late Chalcolithic settlements 13. The sites in question overwhelmingly appear to be 1.5 ha or
of substantial size did exist in the Upper Khabur and less in total extent. The only exceptions to this are four sites con-
Jebel Sinjar areas of Upper Mesopotamia, such as Tell taining Late Chalcolithicperiod remains that vary in extent from
Brak at somewhere between 40 and 65 ha in extent 2.3 to 2.8 ha (Sites 23, 25, 29, 32) and one site that is 5 ha in size
(Site 38). However, the actual extent of the Late Chalcolithicperiod
(Oates and Oates 1997, Emberling et al. 1999) and Tell occupation of these latter sites cannot be ascertained from the pub-
lished data (Eidem and Warburton 1996:5660, fig. 2).
11. Nippur, the acknowledged pan-Sumerian religious capital of the 14. The one source available (Conti and Persiani 1993) lists numbers
Mesopotamian alluvium throughout the 3d millennium, was never of sites but gives no indication of their extents or of the extent of
a key political player during that time. occupation of the relevant period within them.

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 211

the Mesopotamian periphery for which quantifiable sur- sequences of the greater concentration of polities that
vey evidence is availablesuch as portions of the Eu- existed in the Mesopotamian alluvium throughout the
phrates basin in southeastern Anatolia (Wilkinson 700-year-or-so duration of the Uruk period. As Colin
1990a, Wilkinson in Algaze, Misir, and Wilkinson 1992, Renfrew and his colleagues have repeatedly argued (Ren-
Algaze 1999, Algaze, Breuninger, and Knudstad 1994) and frew and Cherry 1986), the long-term presence of mul-
northern Syria (Wilkinson 1994, Danti 1997), portions of tiple polities within relatively short distances of each
the Upper Tigris basin in southeastern Anatolia (Algaze other invariably engenders important processes of com-
et al. 1991), portions of the Upper Khabur basin of Syria petition, exchange, emulation, and technological inno-
(Stein and Wattenmaker 1990, Eidem and Warburton vation. The social evolutionary impact of these mutually
1996, Kouchoukos 1998), and portions of the Sinjar plains reinforcing processes has been explained by Robert
of northern Iraq (Wilkinson and Tucker 1995)we fail Wright (2000:16568), who notes that in situations where
to find evidence for settlement hierarchies across the antagonistic but mutually communicative polities exist,
north in the Late Chalcolithic period comparable in scale social and economic innovations that prove maladaptive
and complexity to contemporary Uruk-period develop- in any one society are likely to be weeded out more
ments in the south. Moreover, whatever large Late Chal- quickly than in less competitive settings. Conversely,
colithic settlements existed across the north were es- innovations that prove advantageous are more likely to
sentially isolated from one another. The compact and spread quickly across the various polities in competition,
long-lived systems of closely interacting urban settle- thus accelerating the overall pace of change of the system
ments embedded in complex settlement grids which as a whole.
characterized the south during the various phases of the
Uruk period simply did not exist in the less densely set-
tled landscape of the Mesopotamian periphery at that
time, and such systems would not arise in the periphery
The Domestication of Human Labor and Its
until the middle of the 3d millennium (Wilkinson 1994). Associated Technologies

The Jacobs model of urban development clearly explains


how the geographic and environmental advantages of the
The Further Synergies of Density and Mesopotamian ecosystem promoted patterns of com-
Propinquity modity production and exchange within 4th-millennium
southern societies that led to the creation of more ag-
Multiple consequences would have arisen from the dif- glomerated and differentiated settlements than existed
ferences in population density and distance between pol- elsewhere. The same model explains how larger markets,
ities typical for southern Mesopotamia and areas on its larger pools of labor, new skills and new forms of work,
periphery throughout the 4th millennium. One of the and repeated opportunities for cooperation and conflict
consequences of the greater density of population in within and between polities were created in the south.
towns, cities, and their immediate hinterlands of the These conditions explain why the final and ultimately
south was the compounding of the natural advantages most important asymmetry that existed between Uruk-
in transport efficiency of the alluvial environment by period societies and communities on their periphery
further savings in transport costs and efficiencies in com- emerged. This was a disparity in the abilities of Meso-
munication arising from the increasingly compact ar- potamian and peripheral societies to resolve the inevi-
rangement of the inhabitants of the area. This, in turn, table managerial conflicts that large-scale population ag-
must have spurred further economic differentation and glomerations entail, to store and process information
its associated multipliers, because, as Adam Smith (writing and associated reckoning systems), and to com-
(1954[1776]:bk. 1, chaps. 13) explained more than 200 mand and organize diverse labor pools. Here southern
years ago, gains in the efficiency of transportation and polities held a definite technological edge over their
communication in human societies always act as a spur contemporaries that was, in effect, the sufficient con-
for division of labor, economic growth, and technological dition for the crystallization of Mesopotamian civiliza-
innovation. Additionally, greater density provided south- tion. This edge was made possible by important inno-
ern polities with a larger number of easily recruited la- vations in administrative technologies that took place
borers (for both agriculture and construction), craft spe- throughout the Uruk period (H. T. Wright 1978). While
cialists, soldiers, and potential colonists than could be this advantage would disappear in the 3d millennium as
marshaled by their less densely agglomerated competi- many northern societies adopted forms of social control
tors in the periphery. When coupled with the higher pro- and writing systems ultimately derived from southern
ductivity per unit of labor in the alluvium and the higher models (Postgate 1988), in the 4th millennium Uruk pol-
reliability of that production, the larger pools of deploy- ities were still more efficient than their neighbors in
able labor in the south meant that Uruk rulers could extracting labor from dependent workers and better at
extract and amass much larger surpluses than those deploying those workers where most needed, appropri-
achievable by even the most centralized of the northern ating their production, and converting their output into
polities. socially useful commodities.
Equally important for southern societies were the con- Borrowing a page from V. Gordon Childe, we may use

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
212 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

the term Labor Revolution to describe this crucial shows that the second-most-frequently mentioned com-
combination of socioeconomic advantages. Underlying modity was SAL (female slave), with 388 attestations (for
this transformation was a conceptual shift in the way comparative purposes, barley, the most frequently noted
some categories of human labor were looked at in south- commodity, had 496 attestations). To this must be added
ern Mesopotamian societies. Southern elites came to 153 attestations of laborers described as ERIM (captives)
view and use fully encumbered laborers in the same ex- and 113 attestations of laborers described as KUR (male
ploitative way that human societies, over the immedi- slaves).
ately preceding millennia, had viewed and used the labor A less direct measure of the importance of encumbered
of domesticated animals. This represents a new paradigm labor to the Uruk economy may also be available. Many
of the nature of social relations in human societies. I of the Archaic Texts record disbursements of textiles and
suspect that a comparable shift in the way in which hu- grain to individuals and presumably represent rations
man labor is perceived (and exploited) is integral to all given to some sort of fully or partly dependent workers
cases of early state formation, but in reality we do not (Englund 1998:17879, fig. 67). Again, the contribution
know exactly when this perceptual change occurred in of such workers to the Uruk economy cannot be gauged
the Mesopotamian case. All we can say for certain is that with any precision, but if we presume that Nissen (1970,
it had already taken place by the end of the Uruk period, 1976) is correct in assuming that the ubiquitous beveled-
as can be observed in the Archaic Texts. Scribal sum- rim bowls were used as ration bowls, their incidence in
maries detailing the composition of groups of foreign and southern cities, where typically they are found in
native-born captives used as laborers describe them with amounts that defy quantification, suggests that the num-
age and sex categories identical to those used to describe ber of workers receiving state rations in return for their
state-owned cattle (Englund 1998:17681). Because these labor during the second half of the 4th millennium must
parallels are repeated in numerous texts, they cannot be have been quite substantial indeed. Access to pools of
explained away as either accidents or scribal idiosyncra- dependent labor of comparable scale does not appear to
sies. Rather, it would appear that the two classes of labor have existed in indigenous societies on the northern
(captive others and domestic animals) were considered Mesopotamian periphery at this time. While redistri-
equivalent in the minds of Uruk scribes and in the eyes bution of rations is attested to at some pertinent sites,
of the institutions that employed them. Early Near East- most notably at Arslantepe VIA (Frangipane 1997) and
ern villagers domesticated plants and animals. Uruk ur- Tepe Gawra VIIIC (Rothman 1994), the much smaller
ban institutions, in turn, domesticated humans. quantities of mass-produced bowls found at those loca-
In practical terms, the perceptual shift just described tions suggests a much smaller number of individuals re-
meant that Uruk elites probably had a greater variety of ceiving rations than that typical for southern sites.
encumbered laborers at their disposal than did their Similarly, there is ample epigraphic (the Titles and Pro-
northern counterparts, that they could extract more en- fessions List [attested already in Uruk IV script]) and
ergy from those laborers, and, more important, that they administrative (seals, sealings, reckoning devices) evi-
were better able to organize them in nontraditional ways dence for both the extraordinary level of economic and
so as to take advantage of increases in productivity and social differentiation that had developed within Uruk
other economies of scale arising from the specialization societies and the depth of the controlling bureaucracy
of individuals according to principles of comparative ad- that had emerged in southern Mesopotamia by that time.
vantage (Snooks 1996:165). These qualitative advantages When measured against this evidence, bureaucratic and
would have been magnified further by the sheer force of administrative practices across the Mesopotamian pe-
numbers. While available documentation is not suffi- riphery during the second half of the 4th millennium are
cient to quantify the contribution of slaves, prisoners of found wanting. By the second half of the Uruk period,
war, and other types of encumbered workers to the econ- the south had greatly outpaced the periphery in admin-
omy of Uruk city-states with any degree of precision, it istrative technologyin spite of the fact that sealed clay
would appear that their number was significant. One bullae, used as records of commodity shipments, had
recently published Archaic Text fragment (Uruk IV actually been in use in northern sites at a much earlier
script), for instance, is a summary of several smaller in- date (Halaf) than in any comparable southern context
dividual accounts and refers to a total of 211 male and (von Wickede 1990, Lamberg-Karlovsky 1999). The
female captive laborers (Englund 1998:17879, fig. 66). great leap forward of the south over neighboring so-
Admittedly, there is no way to know how representative cieties in technologies of social control and in economic
this tablet is. However, a crude but perhaps useful mea- complexity is brought into relief by the fact that no pe-
sure of the relative importance of slaves and encumbered ripheral site has yet provided any evidence for the ex-
workers to the portion of the Uruk economy that was istence of formal reckoning and writing systems com-
being recorded by state scribes may be obtained by look- parable in their complexity to those that had emerged
ing at the number of individual attestations of the per- in southern Mesopotamia and the Susiana Plain. This is
tinent signs for the various categories of captive laborers most clearly seen when we compare accounting proce-
in the Archaic Texts (5,820 complete and fragmentary dures in use within MiddleLate Urukperiod levels of
tablets to date, including Uruk IV and III scripts). Robert sites such as Warka and Susa in the south (Nissen, Dam-
Englunds (1998:70) comprehensive list of every known erow, and Englund 1993, Amiet 1972, Dittmann 1986)
attestation of each nonnumerical sign of this corpus and those in use in roughly contemporary Late Chal-

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 213

colithic-period levels at the sites of Arslantepe (Period much greater precision. More important, because the
VIA: Ferioli and Fiandra 1983[1988]) and Tepe Gawra new pictographic tablets could also express nuances of
(Levels XIVIII: Tobler 1950, Rothman 1994) in the time, location, persons involved, and action effected,
northern periphery. The thousands of sealings found dis- they allowed Uruk scribes to convey a range of economic
carded at various locations within the Period VIA com- information that was at the time unprecedented. More-
plex at Arslantepe, for instance, commonly bear the im- over, the greater informational content and flexibility of
pression or impressions of but a single seal. A similar the new tablets also allowed southern scribes to abstract
case obtains in the Late Chalcolithic levels of Tepe Ga- and summarize detailed data about collections and dis-
wra. At both sites, impressions of more than one seal on bursements of goods and labor in a form usable by them-
a single sealing surface are exceptional (Fiandra 1994: selves at a later time, by higher-level supervisory officials
168; M. Frangipane, personal communication, 1999; M. at any time, and by later generations of similarly trained
Rothman, personal communication, 1999). bureaucrats. A final difference is that, although rare, the
In contrast, contemporary procedures in Uruk cities new lexical lists that also appear at this time (Uruk IV
in the south and in Uruk outposts in the north regularly script) gave southern Mesopotamian scribes the ability
exhibit the imprints of multiple seals, particularly in the to organize, categorize, and transmit information about
case of balls and bullae (Delougaz and Kantor 1996). their material and social world beyond that contained in
These differences are relevant because the number of the economic tablets that constituted the totality of ear-
impressions of different seals in a single sealing gives us lier records (Nissen, Damerow, and Englund 1993, En-
a glimpse of the number of agents and, possibly, wit- glund 1998).
nesses involved in the transaction. Additionally, if Nis- In short, by the end of the Uruk period, cumulative
sen (1977) and Dittmann (1986) are correct in seeing the innovations in the ways knowledge was gathered, pro-
seals as encoding information about the hierarchical cessed, and transmitted through time and space provided
ranking of specific authorizing individuals and the in- southern Mesopotamian decision makers and the urban
stitutions they worked for, then the much greater fre- institutions they worked for with a flow of varied and
quency of complex devices with multiple impressions of reliable economic data of the sort that is necessary for
different superimposed seals in Uruk centers can be the formation, maintenance, and effective expansion of
taken as a proxy for the greater number of levels of bu- large-scale economies and social groups. More impor-
reaucratic control and accountability that existed within tant, these data allowed Uruk elites to deploy available
those centers compared with the much smaller northern labor and goods where they were needed most in order
sites (Pittman 1993). The northern counterpart of the to maximize their revenues, extend their power, and
impressed balls and numerical notation tablets of the shore up the stability of the social system they were in
south is but a few tallying slabs at Arslantepe VIA, with the process of transforming. This furnished southern
evenly sized indentations on their surfaces (presumably Mesopotamian societies with an important competitive
representing numbers), which appear to have served as advantage over contemporary neighboring polities, in
mnemonic devices (Liverani 1988[1983]:figs. 14). These which similar breakthroughs in accounting, accounta-
devices could convey only a fraction of the information bility, and classification appear to have been absent. In
that could be transmitted by the more elaborate reck- fact, indigenous systems of administrative control equiv-
oning systems of southern societies at this time, which alent in their sophistication to those used in southern
relied on complex combinations of numbers and images Mesopotamia already in the second half of the 4th mil-
(seal impressions). Moreover, unlike the more complex lennium would not be attested in the Near East until
southern systems, which were capable of conveying in- the rise of the Proto-Elamite state in southwestern Iran
formation at a distance and across time, the mnemonic at the beginning of the 3d millennium and would not
systems of the north were incapable of communicating appear in Syro-Mesopotamia for at least 600 years or so
any information beyond their immediate institutional after the end of the Uruk periodand when they ap-
and temporal context. peared it was in the form of an imported technology that
The disparity in efficiency and complexity between relied wholly on the cuneiform writing system and as-
the accounting systems of the two areas (and by inference sociated accounting procedures elaborated centuries be-
the divergence in the scale and complexity of their econ- fore by southern societies (Postgate 1988).
omies) becomes even more marked by the very end of
the Uruk period with the appearance of the earliest Ar-
chaic Texts in the south (Uruk IV script: ca. 1,900 out Conclusions
of 5,820 tablets and fragments [Englund 1998:86]). This
took place at a time that appears contemporary with In a recent review of the relationship between scale and
Arslantepe VIA on the basis of available radiocarbon complexity of social organization in cases of pristine
dates (Wright and Rupley 2001). The new pictographic state formation, Gary Feinman (1998) argues that the
tablets of the final phase of the Uruk period not only form such states take at the outset is largely dependent
gave southern administrators a way to record inflows and on the particular combination of factors most central to
outflows of commodities in a form transmissible through their creation. If this is the case, then geography, envi-
space and timeas the earlier balls and numerical no- ronment, and trade can be seen as the most important
tation tablets had donebut allowed them to do so with factors helping shape the initial nature of social com-

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
214 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

plexity in the Mesopotamian alluvium. Geography and the nascent city-states of Uruk Mesopotamia (Oates and
environment would have been central not in a direct Oates 1997, Lamberg-Karlovsky 1999) or that they pos-
deterministic sense but rather in the sense that they pro- sessed an equivalent level of organizational complexity
vided the opportunities and incentives that made it prob- (Frangipane 1997) incorrectly minimize the existence
able that self-aggrandizing individuals and groups would and importance of scalar and organizational asymmetries
use trade as one of the most efficient strategies at their between southern and peripheral polities.
disposal in their quest to achieve wealth, status, and Arguments that minimize scalar differences gloss over
power. Though we still lack much of the pertinent ev- the fact that, while some individual Late Chalcolithic
idence for early trade in southern Mesopotamia in the sites in the north did achieve substantial size, as a group
ill-understood Late Ubaid and Early Uruk periods, it is the Late Chalcolithic polities were no match for con-
not difficult to speculate on the impact that such trade temporary Uruk societies in the Mesopotamian allu-
would have had on the formation of early southern Mes- vium either in terms of intrasite scale (extent and ar-
opotamian cultural complexity. Trade would have been chitectural monumentality) and complexity (social and
crucial because its varied and self-amplifying social ram- economic differentiation) or in terms of the density,
ifications would have created a situation in which the depth, and extent of their associated regional settlement
parallel development of multiple independent centers networks. The number of individual polities in close
was a likely outcome. Each of these centers would have proximity within southern Mesopotamia through the
taken advantage of its particular location within the al- Uruk period was simply unparalleled. Further, by the
luvial ecosystem to exploit a particular resource niche second half of the Uruk period the large, walled urban
or a particular transportation route in and out of the polity of Uruk and its corona of dependent towns, vil-
alluvium, both on principles of comparative advantage. lages, and hamlets were of a completely different order
The localization of resources across the greater Meso- of magnitude from anything the periphery could offer.
potamian landscape and the resulting salient role of Also without counterparts in contemporary peripheral
trade, first internal and then external, in the processes societies were the scale and extent of the public struc-
of urban growth and state formation in the Tigris-Eu- tures at the very center of Uruk at this timethe 89
phrates lowlands help explain why Mesopotamia became ha of walled-off ceremonial and administrative buildings
a civilization characterized by competing urban-centered in the Eanna precinct and, in a separate part of the city,
statelets throughout most of its history and why the ear- the massive Anu Ziggurat and associated temple, which
liest political development of Mesopotamian civilization towered over the site and the surrounding plain (Nissen
differs from that of other pristine civilizations (e.g., 1988).
Egypt, Monte Alban, Moche), in which warfare and con- Arguments that minimize organizational differences
flict appear to have been more important motors of social pay insufficient attention to the constraints and oppor-
evolution than trade and unitary territorial states were tunities of geography, the ways in which humans can
the initial form of political organization (Marcus 1998). exploit their environment to gain and expand their social
The same factors may also partially explain why the ear- standing, and the power of ideas. Such arguments com-
liest Mesopotamian writing systems were almost en- monly start from the premise that there were no essen-
tirely economic in their initial impetus, as opposed to tial differences in the material technologies available to
the early writing of other pristine civilizations, which the two groups through the 4th millennium (Kohl 1987a,
often was more political or religious in function. Stein 1999). This premise is correct only in the narrow
We can only speculate about the historical conse- sense that the transportational and craft technologies
quences of the early political balkanization of the Mes- available to both groups throughout the second half of
opotamian alluvium, but many scholars see political di- the fourth millennium were comparable and misses the
vision as an important factor selecting for accelerated mark in four important respects.
social change. Patricia Crone (1989:161), for instance, First, the premise should be rejected on principle, for
argues that political fragmentation and interpolity com- it implies that economic changes caused by advances in
petition were crucial for what she perceives as the unique material technology are the sole force underpinning so-
vitality of developmental rates in European polities of cial change. This reductionist viewpoint fails to take into
the late medieval and early modern eras as compared account the fact that technological innovation not only
with those characteristic of other areas of the world at acts on society but is itself contingent on socioeconomic
that time: Far from being stultified by imperial govern- forces.
ment, Europe was to be propelled forward by constant Second, it fails to take note of the geographical advan-
competition between its component parts. So, too, pre- tages in transportation of the southern alluvium over
sumably, ancient Mesopotamia. However, the socio-ev- neighboring areas. If, as Jacobs argues, a key cause of
olutionary critical mass created by the compact and development is imports added to capital and labor which
competitive social environment of the Tigris-Euphrates produce value-added exports, then southern Mesopota-
alluvial lowlands in the Uruk period was absent from mian societies had a substantial and irrevocable advan-
neighboring areas at the time. Complex as some indi- tage over peripheral polities in that both labor and capital
vidual Late Chalcolithic polities may have been during (agricultural, pastoral, and piscatorial surpluses and
the 4th millennium, they were essentially isolated. status-marking exotics) were more easily mobilized and
Claims that such polities were comparable in scale to redistributed in the south than elsewhere because of the

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 215

inherent superiority of southern water-borne transport flung societies in control of coveted resources. The var-
systems. ious ideational technologies of social organization that
Third, it fails to acknowledge the environmental ad- made this possible were certainly selected for and thus
vantages in productivity of the southern alluvium over made more likely by the multiplier effects of the export-
neighboring areas, advantages that were particularly pro- driven economies that had taken root in the rich and
nounced through the 4th millennium. These advantages diverse environmental framework that characterized the
provided the opportunities that elite groups exploiting southern Mesopotamian alluvium during the formative
the alluviums rich and diverse ecological niches needed stages of Sumerian civilization. As Jacobs (2000:63)
to amass the initial surpluses that set in motion the notes, diversity expands naturally in inherently rich en-
export-driven economies that characterized southern vironments, which are made richer by the diverse use
Mesopotamian polities throughout much of their his- and reuse of received energy.
tory. These groups neither understood nor foresaw the As rules of historical development would have it, the
consequences of the exchange patterns they initiated. initial southern Mesopotamian edge in ideational tech-
Rather, they were merely attempting to do what elites nologies of socioeconomic organization and control did
naturally do in all human societies, namely, sanction not and could not last long. With disparity in organiza-
existing social inequalities, legitimize their right to con- tional complexity came disparities in power, both real
tinue demanding and receiving unequal access to re- and perceived, and with them came opportunities for the
sources, maximize the amounts and varieties of com- expansion of Middle and Late Urukperiod polities by
modities and labor at their disposal, and increase their means of colonial outposts at strategic locations across
political power. The richness of the ecological context the Mesopotamian periphery. In great part as a result of
of the alluvial lowlands of the Tigris-Euphrates system processes of competitive emulation initiated across the
of the 4th millennium made such attempts both more Mesopotamian periphery by the Uruk expansion, Subar-
likely and more likely to succeed than would have been ians (Gelb 1944, Michalowski 1986), Hurrians (Gelb
the case in less resilient environments. 1944, Steinkeller 1998), Elamites (Carter and Stolper
Fourth, and most important, it overlooks the fact that 1984), and other 3d-millennium groups (Sollberger and
differences in ideologies of social organization and in Kupper 1971, Grayson, Frame, and Frayne 1987, Hirsch
associated technologies of social control are as capable 1963, Lebeau 1990) were soon to master for themselves
of creating significant developmental asymmetries be- the fine art of creating truly effective social systems of
tween societies as are imbalances in material technology the few, by the few, and for the few. This, too, was an
(Goody 2000). By the second half of the 4th millennium opportunistic adaptive response on their part but one
southern Mesopotamian societies enjoyed a variety of which was promoted largely by a social landscape and
revolutionary organizational advantages not possessed at historical context that had been dramatically trans-
that point by any of their contemporaries. These advan- formed by the earlier emergence of Sumerian societies.
tages partly fall in the realm of what Jack Goody (2000)
refers to as technologies of the intellect, what Michael
Mann (1986) terms technologies of power, and what
John Baines and Norman Yoffee (1998) refer to as high Comments
culture. The most salient of these advantages were the
conceptual shift earlier described as the Labor Revo-
lution, novel and much more efficient procedures of b. brentjes
information recording and processing, and economies of Eberhardstr. 3, D 10367 Berlin, Germany, 26 x 00
scale arising from the specialized production of com-
modities by dependent laborers organized according to The main thesis of this paperthe importance of trade
principles of comparative advantage. When added to the in the early phase of civilization in Mesopotamia and
aforementioned advantages in the number of potential especially the interrelation of society and ecosys-
laborers, compactness, and ease of transportation, these temcan be accepted, but there are some details which
organizational innovations gave Uruk societies an im- can be questioned:
portant edge over neighboring polities. 1. Algaze insists on the absolute primacy of southern
In other words, by the second half of the 4th millen- Mesopotamia as the nucleus of world civilization, but
nium, cumulative gains in economic and social differ- the beginnings of the development in the Indus Valley
entiation arising from centuries of asymmetrical and farther east may not have been later than the late
exchange patterns and import-substitution processes had 4th millennium b.c. and did not depend on Sumer.
created societies in the Mesopotamian alluvium that 2. Algaze stresses the importance of the availability of
were not only substantially larger in scale and regional natural resources in southern Mesopotamia, and this is
reach than their contemporaries but intellectually better correct, but no less important were the shortages of raw
prepared to deal with the complexities of supporting materialswood, stone, and metalsthat forced the pur-
large-scale agglomerations of population as well. They suit of imports.
were also more capable than their neighbors of resolving 3. The role of climatic changes cannot be denied, but
the inevitable managerial conflicts that such agglomer- the monsoon from the Indian Ocean, which was turned
ations entail and managing multiple contacts with far- more to north than today, brought rain to the Indus

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
216 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

Valley, Baluchistan, and Afghanistan and not to Meso- vat 1993, 1997) have pointed to the conclusion that the
potamia, far to the northwest. The Indian Ocean mon- economic base of the Late Uruk elite was so diffuse and
soon that reached southern Arabia first moved west, was lacking in any visible signs of having been organized
diverted to the north, over Ethiopia, crossed Yemen, and intentionally from a single central point that it gives the
reached Oman and other countries from the south. It impression of the elites having adjusted to the existing
cannot have been important for irrigation in Mesopo- complexities of the communitys subsistence activities
tamia, which depended on precipitation over Asia Minor rather than developing its own distinctive entrepreneu-
and northwestern Iran and received its winter rain from rial culture.
the northwest. If there really was summer rain in south- There is, to be sure, one innovation that might have
ern Iraq, it might have had sources in the northwest, too. caused the Late Uruk elites to turn towards exploitation
4. I doubt the inefficiency of caravans, given the traffic of the full potential of their host landscapes, and this is
from Assyria to Asia Minor in the early 2d millennium a purely spiritual one. The belief that the fertility of
b.c.and why they should have used their boats only nature will be fully realized only if it is triggered by
downstream? It would have been inefficient to return the NA2 ceremony (probably a predecessor, or possibly
the boats empty or on donkeys, and dragging or rowing an ancestor, of the sacred marriage rite) performed by
is quite possible. The Mesopotamian (and Elamite) trade the pontifical couple, the EN and the NIN, seems to
to the east and the overland trade of the Indus civiliza- represent an invention of the (Late?) Uruk period, as I
tion crossed high mountains and steppes for thousands shall be arguing in my forthcoming study of the icono-
of kilometers up to the Ferghana Valley and to Chorezm. graphical sources for the emergence of statehood in the
5. It would have been useless to carry bitumen from ancient Near East (see also Charvat 1997). I believe that
southern Mesopotamia to the norththe area of Mosul the Late Uruk phenomenon was a revolution of human
had enough for export itself. souls and minds rather than of hearts and stomachs.
6. Algaze does not mention Uruks dual structure, with
two central temples instead of one as usual in Sumer.
Was it a combination of two former nuclei as some c l a u d i o c i o f fi - r e v i l l a
believe? Department of Political Science, University of
Colorado, Boulder, Colo. 80309-0333, U.S.A.
(cioffi@colorado.edu). 27 xi 00
p e t r c h a rv a t
Oriental Institute, Academy of Sciences of the Czech The origins and early evolution of governmentin Mes-
Republic, Prague, Czech Republic. 14 ix 00 opotamia, China, Peru, and Mesoamericaare among
the most fundamental puzzles in political science, al-
This is certainly a very interesting assessment of the though in recent decades such investigations have
opportunities offered by the environment to the leaders tended to gravitate towards the disciplines of archae-
of both northern and southern Mesopotamian commu- ology, anthropology, or anthropological archaeology. It is
nities for the amplification of the potential to usher in therefore intriguing and stimulating to see these puzzles
major social transformations. The advantageous starting addressed by modern scientific scholars such as Guil-
position of the south is well argued, and I hardly believe lermo Algaze. Significant advances by archaeologists in-
that any modern scholar would contest the logic of Al- vestigating the origins of government in ancient socie-
gazes conclusions. The crux, as I see it, is why. ties, especially when produced through comparative and
What would have induced the southerners to apply so interdisciplinary methodologies, are crucial not only for
much energy to embarking on a journey that is well archaeological theory and research but also for political
known to us but absolutely original, new, and therefore science and allied social sciences.
potentially dangerous for them? I am more and more As a political scientist who shares many of the sci-
convinced that the truly revolutionary changes and entific interests as Algaze and his colleagues in archae-
transformations take place in human heads and, at that, ology, I must applaud his systematic effort to gather data,
in the beginning in a single one. A promising environ- formulate hypotheses, and rigorously test theories of the
ment will hardly fulfil its potential if the humans living origin and early evolution of political complexity. Since
in it simply do not perceive this promise or prefer their we have the same basic epistemology, albeit not the same
traditional way of life to something that might be ad- disciplinary background, I shall focus my comments on
vantageous but conflicts with traditional norms and cus- a set of political science issues aimed at providing some
toms. Asked why they would not engage in agriculture, plausible suggestions for further theoretical and empir-
the San of the Kalahari simply replied, Why should we ical development.
work in the fields if there are so many mongongo nuts I find the model developed by Algaze in this study,
in the world? This response is fairly typical for prestate including his emphasis on the causal role of physical
and preindustrial societies. Humans had lived in south- ecological variables, essentially correct but somewhat
ern Mesopotamia for millennia prior to the Late Uruk incomplete in a number of aspects. That is to say, the
period, and no traces of the multiplier effect proper to story is still missing a set of critical events that should
the latter culture can be observed in the evidence it left be added for a deeper understanding of government for-
(at Tell Awayli; see Forest 1996). My own studies (Char- mation. As some readers and Algaze himself might an-

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 217

ticipate, the missing elements are political, not environ- chiefdoms, states, and eventually empireswas a pro-
mental, although this is not to say that political cess of fundamental importance not just for archaeology
scientists have done a good job of highlighting and ex- and political science but for virtually all areas of human
plicating these missing political pieces of the puzzle with knowledge. Studies such as Algazes give us solid hope
the necessary scientific precision. that we may be close to some important new break-
In essence, environmental variables and events such throughs in scientific explanation and understanding
as those identified by Algaze (and Adams) are best seen through greater interdisciplinary collaboration.
as remote (or ultimate) causes of the origins of political
complexity, whereas political variables and events, in-
cluding mechanisms of decision making, are best seen rene dittmann
as proximate causes of political complexity. The for- Westfalische Wilhelms-Universitat, Schlossplatz 2, D-
mation and maintenance of government in any given 48149 Munster, Germany (dittmre@unimuenster.de).
society constitute a process or sequence of contingent 21 xi 00
events. Foremost among the political events embedded
in the process of government formation, whether in an- Having worked on aspects of the Uruk period, I have
cient Mesopotamia or elsewhere, is what political sci- found it fascinating to read this stimulating and excel-
entists, economists, and sociologists call collective ac- lent paper. I have always viewed the Uruk horizon as
tion, which is not a physical event although it may be part of a longue duree development from the Ubaid to
related to or ultimately caused by prior or contempora- the Early Dynastic and finally the Akkad and Ur III com-
neous physical events. In this context, collective action plexes. Therefore, as I see it the Uruk, especially the Late
is caused by the emergence of leaders (elites) and follow- Uruk complex, is to some extent the culmination of the
ers (commoners) that jointly produce a system of gov- Ubaid development and in many respects the beginning
ernment. In turn, both leaders and followers emerge by of the processes that led to the Early Dynastic and later
a variety of processes or mechanisms, including decision- aspects. Consequently I never use the term colonies
making calculations. For example, the actors involved for Uruk settlements outside Babylonia, because for
may undergo a decision-making calculus of costs and most of Greater Mesopotamia the Uruk is simply the
benefits (the so-called rational-choice model) or may de- only complex that existed at this period, with nothing
cide to act through other mechanisms (such as deontic local in the immediate neighbourhood (sites such as Ha-
obligation or instinctive responses to social or physical buba, Gebel Aruda, and earlier Tell Sheikh Hassan, Tell
environmental stimuli). Although this is not the appro- Bleibis, and others but of course not Godin, Hacinebi, or
priate venue in which to detail a collective-action pro- Arslantepe). Our understanding of the network of Middle
cess of government formation with the desirable rigor, and Late Uruk sites, especially in Syria and southern
suffice it to say that a system of government cannot form Turkey, is focused on settlements along the Euphrates;
without leaders and followers solving a collective-ac- almost nothing is known about its hinterland. We have
tion problem. Moreover, such actions sometimes suc- sitesand very strange onesthat are very small, like
ceed and sometimes fail, as archaeologists have docu- farms (for example, Shavi Hoyuk II, Nevala Cori, and
mented for many cases. sites in the Incesu Valley). Further, Hassek Hoyuk is
Besides key ideas from the theory of collective action, really not, in its structure, a settlement in the sense of
including Lichbachs (1995) important new work cited a village. In order to understand the Uruk network, then,
by Algaze, other key pieces of the puzzle of government we should look at each site and try to understand its
formation include the classical choice-lottery distinction structure and possible function within the system, and
from decision theory and game theory, the opportunity- we should investigate the hinterlands of the major river
willingness principle (Cioffi-Revilla and Starr 1995, Starr systems. If we do this, I am convinced, we will find a
1978), and principles of political uncertainty (Cioffi-Re- lot more variation in the Uruk system. I suspect that
villa 1998). For example, the first of these is used for Algazes claim of an imbalance between southern and
parsing the complex process of government formation northern sites will be complemented to some extent in
into states of Nature (produced by lotteries) and hu- the future by a deeper understanding of the complexity
man acts (produced by decisions or games). Each of within the system. This definitely requires much further
these, in turn, is modeled by specific variables and study.
events. The opportunity-willingness principle is used for Algazes suggestion that the Late Uruk period is al-
modeling human acts subject to environmental con- ready characterized by a system of separate and possibly
straints, such as climate change, resource availability, competitive city-states seems not impossible to me. It
and other significant conditions discussed by Algaze. is obvious from the glyptic material available at the mo-
Principles of political uncertainty specify the dynamics ment that we have many conflict scenes at Uruk but
produced by probabilistic causes, often in counterintui- almost no economic scenes, the latter being found al-
tive ways, such as the effects of multiple decision mech- most exclusively elsewhere (signs of a kind of dendritic
anisms on leaders and followers choices in the emer- economic network?) This could be a hint of what Algaze
gence of political complexity. suggests in the sense that Uruk, as the religious and
The emergence of political complexity in Mesopota- economic centre, may have tried to dominate smaller
mia between the 6th and 3rd millennia b.c.the rise of emerging centres at the end of the Uruk period by force

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
218 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

in order to prevent centrifugal processes within the sys- role may have been. Some of these are translated into
tem. The almost canonical representations and motifs of technologies, technologies of power, related to the forms
the Uruk glyptic on the whole seem to me to reflect a of literacy, administrative organization, etc., but are
former (Middle and beginning of Late Uruk) high level these regionally specific differences or effects of the de-
of integration in the Uruk system not only economically velopment process itself? The argument is not clearly
but surely also ideologically. In this respect it would be spelled out here.
understandable that the quality of the representations Trade is taken up as a factor in this argument, equiv-
on Uruk artefacts is comparable in naturalism and re- alent in a sense to geography and productivity, but this
alism only to that on Akkadian ones and that the motifs is, we suggest, a misconstrual. Accumulation of wealth
have an almost unlimited geographical distribution. The based on trade is not a mere factor that can be listed
Uruk system seems to have had a panregional under- along with environmental and other conditions, since
standing of the four corners of the world, and this, I this underplays the systemic relation between trade,
suggest, was at once the legacy of the long Ubaidian technology, slavery, expansion, and almost all of the
development and the romantic goal of the later, region- other factors mentioned. Jacobss model of export-led
ally limited political systems. With the collapse of the growth is not, of course, new or even specific to Jacobs,
Uruk system, the iconological uniformity broke down although she had the daring insight to apply it to ancient
as a result of the increasing development of local sym- urban economies as well as to modern ones. As we un-
bolic systems by the emergingor consolidat- derstand the use of this model, it entails that an elite
ingneighbouring city-states. The form changed, but has a specific strategy of accumulation of wealth, status,
the contents of the iconography of the Uruk period be- or something that requires economic growth, a some-
came an essential part of the Greater Mesopotamian thing specifically social and cultural that is not speci-
symbolic complex. fied here. The model is based on modern Western capi-
talism, and it is not clear that it is applicable to the early
city-state without a further argument, which we have
jonathan friedman and kajsa ekholm also made, for some basic similarities. In any case, this
friedman dynamic is not a mere factor that enabled the emergence
Department of Social Anthropology, University of of Uruk but the very form of that development, one that
Lund, Box 114, 221 00 Lund, Sweden organized geographical, technological, and other factors
(jonathanfriedman1@compuserve.com). 22 xi 00 in an expanding system.
For anthropologists a crucial question here would be
This substantial systematization of argument and data the actual organization of this dynamicits sociocul-
on the initial emergence of southern Mesopotamia is tural form. Quite a few years ago we suggested that this
sure to take its place as a timely contribution to the kind of export/import-based economy might have grown
issues. The author argues that the reason civilization out of an earlier regional system based on a strategy of
emerged in the southern alluvium is that this zone pro- monopolizing the circulation of prestige goods. While we
vided a set of comparative advantages that led to a syn- dont necessarily want to defend such a model today, we
ergetic development that could not be matched in other would stress the ultimate need at least to attempt a more
parts of the Near East. It reintroduces the once very pop- specific characterization of the social processes involved.
ular issue of ecology and environmental factors not in The resource-differentiated southern plain may indeed
the usual cultural materialist or determinist way but in have afforded an arena for intensification of trade, but
one close to the general arguments that developed within there is evidence that more far-reaching trade was also
certain versions of structuralist Marxist and later global present from the earliest periods. An aspect of the dis-
systemic anthropologies. Concentrating on recent and cussion that we find most interesting is the suggestion
not so recent data on resource diversity and stability, of a tendency toward import substitution in the takeoff
relative productivity, and ease and therefore productivity period of urbanization. While this is a normal phenom-
of water transportation, Algaze argues that the condi- enon in modern capitalist economies in their protec-
tions for increasing density, differentiated economies, tionist phases, it may also, in this case, mark a major
trade, and competition were quite special to this area. transformation of items prestigious because of their for-
This statement of the approach is basically selective, eignness into more mundane practical ones, that is, the
expressed as distributions of constraints and, as he emergence of an increasingly commercial economy. In
writes, opportunities. The simplest form of the argument order to make any such suggestion, however, we need
is that the same strategy succeeds differentially in dif- to know how the goods are distributed or not distributed.
ferent initial situations and that southern Mesopotamia The entire region including northern Mesopotamia is
is the most advantageous place for things to kick off. characterized by the early existence of regional trade, by
This assumes that the strategies, let us say, of accu- tendencies toward the use of slavery, and by similarities
mulation, expansion, etc., are basically the same, so that in urban formation. Are we dealing here with a common
the environment becomes crucial in locating the initial structure that becomes differentially organized along
takeoff. Is this what is meant here? In other parts of the something like center-periphery lines, in which the cen-
article it is suggested that there are significant social and ters and even the centrality of regions shift over time?
cultural differences as well, but it is not clear what their The fact that city-states develop throughout the entire

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 219

region raises a number of questions, such as the nature tempt to understand past peoples and societies has long
of initial conditions in these later contexts and the im- been integral to both archaeology and anthropology. Cri-
port of the explanatory model if we do not assume that tiques of environmental determinism stem in part from
this social organization simply diffused. realizing that social patterns and human activities were
If this is the case, then it might be profitable to work affected by diverse and interrelated factors, not just ad-
out a dynamic model for the region, one that tends to- aptation or reaction to the environment. The inclusion
ward the formation of commercial city-state systems of of social theory in archaeology helped to bring about a
intensive wealth accumulation. The contrast with areas more nuanced understanding of the ways in which the
such as Egypt and even South America suggested here environment impacts and is impacted by human action.
may have to do with the historical specificities of a vast Social approaches also adopt an interpretive framework
region between the Mediterranean and South and Cen- based on the irreducibility of the human-environment
tral Asia in which trade may have been decentralized relationship, itself framed and characterized by human-
from a very early period, with the result that pristine ecodynamics (McGlade 1995) rather than by some self-
territorial states would have been unable to establish a regulating, equilibrium-seeking system.
monopoly over the flows of wealth in the regiona sit- Eco-environmental approaches are widely regarded as
uation that could be overcome only by empire formation. being reductionist or deterministic, but often the cri-
Decentralized conditions of accumulation have been ar- tique of reductionist models or assumptions is presented
gued to have been crucial in the development of Western as an either/or proposition: either you use reductionist
Europe. models and underdescribe the reality of the past or you
Algaze makes crucial progress toward a more adequate accept the inability to know the past because of its ram-
understanding of Mesopotamian development, and our ified and situated nature. In fact reductionist models are
questions, typically anthropological, press for more spec- a first step towards a nuanced description of the past:
ificity if possible. Yes, by and for the elites, but what are they require a data set to which they can be applied, and
they up to? regional survey often forms a critical component of cre-
ating such a data set.
Algaze draws in part upon the rich regional survey data
a. bernard knapp accumulated for the Mesopotamian lowlands by Adams,
Department of Archaeology, University of Glasgow, reassessed more recently by Susan Pollock. He also
Glasgow G12 8QQ, Scotland, U.K. (b.knapp@ draws upon a wealth of other field datasite reports, clay
archaeology.arts.gla.ac.uk). 17 xi 00 bullae, Archaic texts from Uruk and cuneiform records,
iconographic evidence, satellite imagery, and moreto
In this stimulating, nicely written essay, Algaze returns substantiate his main thesis, namely, that the develop-
from fieldwork in the periphery to synthesis in the core ment of a primary, complex state-level society in south-
(heartland) of Mesopotamia, a subject area he knows ern Mesopotamia during the mid-4th millennium b.c.
well and one in which, increasingly, he plays a leading should be understood as a technological innovation, one
interpretive role. At the outset he quotes R. McC. Adams spurred by social and economic differentiation, unequal
to the effect that contemporary archaeologistsin the exchange, and import substitution. Within the periph-
throes of a social archaeologyno longer see fit to ex- ery of northern Mesopotamia/Syria, southwestern Iran,
amine the interrelationship between natural ecosystems and elsewhere, such developments came only later, dur-
and human beings. It seems odd to read this, coming out ing the 3d millennium b.c. The spatial and environ-
of the American anthropological tradition in archae- mental situation of the alluvial south gave it pride of
ology, where the environment has loomed large for an place in the region and, together with informational and
entire (processual) generation and continues to do so (at managerial developments (ideational technologies),
least from my European vantage point). Perhaps, though, helped to ensure that Sumerian elites maximized all the
this is a perspective more specific to Near Eastern ar- resources at their disposal in establishing and perpetu-
chaeology as taught and studied in America; given the ating their own rule.
diversity of material culture and texts associated with As we found in attempting to set the stage for a series
such levels of social complexity as are found in Meso- of papers on archaeologies of landscape (Knapp and Ash-
potamia, the singularly ecosystemic approach of anthro- more 1999: 1213), ideational is a term at once com-
pological archaeology never worked very well anyway. prehensive and vague; it has been equated with every-
Or, perhaps, Adams (and Algaze) might have benefited thing from the sacred landscape to landscapes of the
from looking more closely at work being conducted else- mind. Algazes use of the term seems to me much more
where in Europe (the Old World), in particular at long- coherent and meaningful when applied to the technol-
standing traditions in regional survey and rural archae- ogies and organizational advantages discussed in his pa-
ology in the Mediterranean, where the dynamic between per and is certainly preferable to the alternatives
people and their environment, between tradition and in- he mentionstechnologies of the intellect (Goody),
novation, between urban and rural, has long held sway technologies of power (Mann), or high culture (Yoffee).
(e.g., Ward-Perkins 1964, Cherry, Davis, and Mantzour- Algazes essay is a substantial and engaging contri-
ani 1991, Barker and Mattingly 19992000). bution to contemporary archaeology. It succeeds in com-
Employing an eco-environmental approach in the at- bining spatial, environmental, empirical, and social pa-

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
220 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

rameters in a thoroughly readable (and to me convincing) views of Sahlins (1974:68) on why state complexity did
essay on the emergence of socially complex early Mes- not emerge in Polynesia are directly relevant:
opotamian culture, one that all archaeologists would
Had the Polynesian gods been more demanding,
benefit from reading.
temple building might well have generated new so-
cial and political roles here as it did in Sumeria; but
c. c. lamberg-karlovsky for one reason or another they were too complacent.
Peabody Museum, Harvard University, Cambridge, One suspects that they were too complacent pre-
Mass. 02138, U.S.A. (karlovsk@husc4.harvard.edu). cisely because a perfectly satisfactory tribal system
7 xi 00 existed; differently put, one suspects that state struc-
tures emerged among the Sumerians all the more
While disavowing geography as destiny, Algaze privi- easily in that no tribal organization had been
leges three environmental/geographic advantages in developed.
southern Mesopotamia: (1) a denser and more varied
concentration of exploitable subsistence resources, (2) Gods should not appease, and bureaucrats must be de-
the higher and more reliable agricultural yields, and manding if they are to establish exploitative central-
(3) the efficiency of transport allowed by the river system. place coercion. What Algaze refers to as the Labor Rev-
His discussion of these three items and the complexity olution has a distinct social settingthe subordination
of their interaction with the social order is the most of the population by divinely sanctioned rules written
compelling part of his thought-provoking essay. There is by the bureaucratic elite.
both teleology and tautology in this argument: environ- Algaze appears to find positive value in hierarchical
mental benefits bring about social complexity while, in settlement patterns, writing, and complexity. The per-
turn, social complexity is able to take increasing advan- ception of each in the past, however, may have been
tage of its environment. Environments present con- different from what it is today. (1) In southern Meso-
straints and restraints. The richness of an environment potamia settlement hierarchies went unnoticed. There
does not ensure the transition to cultural complexity. are no words distinguishing city, town, and village; uru
Environments are filtered, transformed, and given their simply designated a place, without distinction as to its
material reality by the beliefs and practices of a society.
size. In an effort to emphasize the correlation of settle-
The emphasis in this essay is on complexity and its
ment size and complexity Algaze notes that Uruk was,
mechanisms, not on society. Algaze refers to the Eanna
in its day, the largest community in the world. Not so!
precinct but does not credit it with responsibility for
The Tripolye Culture in Ukraine, dated to the first half
structuring the social organization of the city of Uruk.
of the 4th millennium, had several communities of equal
The temples with their resident bureaucrats were the
or larger size, among them Dobrovody (250 ha), Majda-
center of an administrative bureaucracy utilizing and in
neckoe (270 ha), and Taljanki (400 ha). While these com-
some cases inventing and/or perfecting what I have
munities were as large as the later Mesopotamian city-
called a technology of social controlwriting, seals, seal-
ings, and standard units of measureto manage labor states, they did not endure as long or reach the same
and monitor the production, consumption, and redistri- level of social complexity. By the middle of the 4th mil-
bution of goods. Algaze speaks of ideational technol- lennium Uruk, at 250 ha, was a city of substantial com-
ogies but nowhere expands upon the structures of belief plexity, while Taljanki, at nearly twice its size, main-
that organized and gave meaning to both the social and tained a level of complexity characteristic of village life.
the natural environment. Settlement size, like hierarchy, is significant only in the
The organization of people is effected by concepts, and context in which it is situated. It is not a universal at-
these differ in different societies. The organization of tribute which alone signifies complexity. (2) Writing
tribal societies and chiefdoms structures a political com- originated as a tool for controlling labor, production, con-
munity based on kinship, and this organization is en- sumption, and redistribution. The unanticipated conse-
tirely comprehensible. The structure of an emerging quence of its invention was the poetry, hymns, reports
state is very different; I do not know of a single one that of divination, and king-lists that were to appear some
was not formed by recourse to the supernatural. In south- 500 years later. (3) Valuing complexity merely articulates
ern Mesopotamia the gods owned the land, lived in the a belief in cultural evolution, the placing of one stage
temples, and presided as patrons over the city. The EN upon another, often without accounting for the social
(chief bureaucrat), as a steward of the gods, was respon- mechanisms responsible for the transitions between
sible for feeding both the gods and the people of the them. Social complexity requires permanent institutions
community. The sacred Eanna precinct was home to bu- whose authority emanates from specific ideologies. In
reaucrats whose authority was legitimized by the gods. southern Mesopotamia these institutions were the tem-
The structure of the relationship that legitimized these ples, which preceded the Uruk period. To an earlier com-
bureaucrats was as important a feedback loop and plexity the Uruk period added the invention of writing
synergy as the relationship of exports to human labor (seals, sealings, and standard units of value were earlier
and capital or of population agglomerations to settle- inventions), a process that Adams (1981) calls hyperur-
ment hierarchies discussed by Algaze. In this regard the banization, and a powerful ideology that sanctioned the

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 221

successful centralization of authority under the tutelage joy mc corriston


of the gods. The sacred precinct was set apart from the Department of Anthropology, Ohio State University,
community, and perhaps, as Strayer (1970:18) states for Columbus, Ohio 43210-1364, U.S.A. (mccorriston.1@
the medieval European state, a realization of this sep- osu.edu). 25 xi 00
arateness was an essential ingredient of state building.
Finally, Algaze would have us believe that the peoples Algaze addresses with new theoretical insight the long-
of southern Mesopotamia were intellectually better standing question of why the Mesopotamian state
prepared to deal with the complexities than the inhab- emerged early in the southern lowlands. He has once
itants of the periphery. I have long wondered why people again found much to strengthen current archaeological
of the periphery did not assimilate the complexity evi- approaches with a new theoretical application from an-
dent in the south. Once exposed to writing, as they as- other discipline. His paper offers an original, nuanced,
suredly were throughout the century-long Uruk and later effective, geographically-environmentally situated ex-
Proto-Elamite expansions, why did virtually every dis- planation of Mesopotamian social development. In their
tinctive community on the periphery reject the use of ultimate assessment of Algazes fine contribution, schol-
writing? With so many different archaeological cultures ars will ponder several basic points: How good is the
exposed to the complexity of southern Mesopotamia, one model, and how good are the data? I mention only a few
could argue that the rejection of complexity was a con- aspects of each.
scious act. What was the reason for it? Algazes article makes me want to read Jane Jacobss
Perhaps the gods of the north were, like the Polynesian economic work, for although I find his arguments com-
gods referred to by Sahlins, simply less demanding. Per- pelling, it remains difficult for me to assess the under-
haps, far from being intellectually less qualified to deal lying plausibility of human economies developing in a
with complexity, the peripheral peoples were smart fashion comparable to ecosystem development, with its
enough to avoid its oppressive command structure for at explicitly biological evolutionary mechanism of adap-
least another 500 years, when it was imposed upon them tation through natural selection. Advocates of an ex-
by military conquest initiated, naturally enough, from plicitly evolutionary archaeology (e.g., Dunnell 1980,
the south. In every instance the periphery initially re- OBrian 1996, Rindos 1986) might reasonably suggest
jected the adoption of complexity even after direct ex- that selection, an underlying mechanism in biological
posure to it. In time, the development of the state made evolution, should be manifest also in human economies
possible such concentrated control of human resources if they are to be described by models that link cultural
that no other type of social organization could avoid be- and biological evolution. In Mesopotamia, archaeology
ing relegated to a subordinate role. Fundamental social has depended heavily on settlement data to infer patterns
change is rare, for it goes against the grain of social actors of social and political complexity, but these patterns do
and their organizations. There is no inexorable logic that not in themselves indicate mechanisms of change. Se-
leads to social change or to social complexity. As Gellner lectionor, indeed, any other mechanism of cultural de-
(1988) has argued, most significant social change is velopmentwill be manifest at the household level of
brought about through fortuitous openings. Individuals analysis, where individual decision-making and its con-
and/or institutions that attempt to impose fundamental sequences for reproduction can be best deciphered from
social changes are best characterized as adaptive failures. data that are of high resolution both chronologically and
The people on the periphery chose to avoid complexity spatially. If Algazes thesis is testable, then household
and, in so doing, avoided the cage of the state for another archaeology, albeit logistically difficult in southern Mes-
half-millennium. Perhaps southern Mesopotamias eco- opotamia, provides the scale and locus at which it can
logical circumscription had something to do with both best be tested. A household approach also serves to bal-
the loss of tribal ties and the harshness of its conception ance emphasis on archaeologically and historically
of the divine. highly visible elites in explanations of Mesopotamian
Complexity is a double-edged sword. Globalization is state building.
our modern complexity. Today in Pakistan, where I am Algaze does an admirable job of building a geograph-
excavating a site, the newspapers debate whether the ically patterned model that explains a nevertheless his-
country should accept International Monetary Fund torically contingent developmental sequence. Tension
loans. Such loans, according to one argument, allow rich between developmental predictability and system his-
Western nations to keep Third World nations perma- tories must be faced in all ecosystem models and, indeed,
nently in debt. In not taking those loans they avoid the in evolutionary theory itself (Gould 1986, 1994). As Al-
new complexity: globalization. Complexity is more than gaze notes, in the Mesopotamian case geographic pre-
an evolutionary stage of the initial; it is a moving tar- dictability (propinquity and diversity) must be balanced
get that requires a more detailed understanding of the with significant historical contingency, specifically, dra-
social. matic climate and environmental change during the 4th
millennium b.c. Nevertheless, his model, perhaps influ-
enced by Jacobss interest in Spencer, leans toward a pro-
gressivist and linear approach to economic development
with its emphasis on resiliency, expansion, and feedback
loops to explain the inevitability of trade imbalances and

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
222 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

Uruk social hierarchies. I would like to read the argu- write that other history. I am happy to see that such
ments for loss of complexity too. Why would not random an attempt has been made on at least one of the most
dramatic change, such as supposed loss of summer rain- crucial questions which I tried to answer: why the Mes-
fall, from the environmental advantages enjoyed in the opotamian urban civilization emerged where and when
4th millennium b.c. at least sometimes and in some it did. In particular, I welcome the attempt to focus on
areas have resulted in social homogenization and a two advantages which I have always considered im-
heightened emphasis on subsistence production? Addi- portant but not important enough to my argument to
tionally, where adjacent areas with comparable resources merit a lengthy discussion. However, instead of opening
show very different developmental trajectories, might a different line of argument, Algaze only reverses
not greater emphasis on historical contingencies explain priorities.
intraregional variation? Of his two advantages, fertility is for me one of the
There will always be hand-wringing over the data not attractions for those new settlers whowherever and
available from southern Mesopotamia and disputes whenever they had entered the alluviumhad caused
about those that are. For example, high percentage es- the enormous population density which we observe in
timates of population concentrated in large settlements the southern Mesopotamian plain by the end of the 4th
cannot but be affected by preservation factors that buried millennium b.c. The favorable situation for exchange or
smaller sites during periods of aggradation and deflated trade, in contrast, has long been recognized but as es-
them thereafter. I do not concur with Algazes suggestion sential not for the emergence but for the shaping of this
that millets and sesame were cultivated (implicitly with early civilization. Though of great importance at one or
decrue techniques all adopted from Africa in a summer- another point in the development, these advantages both
cropping regime): evidence to support this simply is not fail to offer any explanation for the initial ignition. Wher-
available from Mesopotamia, Arabia, or South Asia at ever these settlers had obtained their experiences, they
this date. All of us wish that more data were available were acquainted with both agriculture and exchange.
from early households. Textiles as exports and metals as The new conditions offered by the alluvium certainly
imports have long histories of scholarly debate and short made life easier and in the long run could have led to
archaeological finds catalogues. In the case of Uruk tex- new forms of organization, but it is difficult to imagine
tiles, early weaving skills along might not account for that these conditions could have created the pressure
the value-added workmanship attested almost 2,000
necessary to bring about changes of such magnitude as
years later in Assyrian documents. I suggest that Uruk
we see happening between the Ubaid and the Late Uruk.
weavers, who found flax in short supply, depended rather
Arranging our information differently, I maintain that
heavily on wool as a novel basic textile fiber with an
rather than the confrontation with favorable conditions
important new characteristic: wool, in contrast to linen,
it was the challenge of coping with the problems of the
readily accepts a dye. Many dyes, such as those from
vast alluvial plain and the totally unprecedented popu-
safflower, marine gastropods, and indigo, come from
lation and settlement density that resulted in urban com-
widespread sources linked only by Mesopotamian trade
plexity. Fertility is not only one of the incentives for
(McCorriston 1999, Edens 1994, Zarins 1989). Although
such dyes became archaeologically visible only in the 3d occupying this plain in the first place but also responsible
millennium, they offer the very raw resources that Al- for the fact that on it less acreage was required to feed
gaze cites as critical energy captured for value-added ex- each person. This in turn enabled settlements to draw
ports. Dyed textiles surely imply that wool emerged as closer together, eliminating safety distances between the
the major surplus textile fiber, a process with significant settlements and thus creating new problems, which de-
geographical and ecological parameters (McCorriston manded new solutions, and so forth.
1997). But these are mere details: Algaze has given us Not denying that exchange/trade was an important
much to ponder and an important, coherent new solution factor, I am challenging the reasons for Algazes assertion
to the old problem of environmental determinism and that it was one of the prime movers. On the one hand,
the Mesopotamian state. I question two of the three points where he sees the main
differences from the neighbouring areas: (1) Rather than
offering a more varied concentration of exploitable sub-
hans j. nissen sistence resources, a vast plain with identical but close-
Institute of Near Eastern Archaeology, Free University ranged soil and climatic conditions has a more limited
of Berlin, Huettenweg 7, D-14195 Berlin, Germany range of animal and plant species than the topographi-
(nissen@zedat.fu-berlin.de). 20 xi 00 cally and climatically diversified regions of the neigh-
boring areas. (2) While on the local level a division of
When I wrote my Grundzuge einer Geschichte der Fruh- labor between fishermen, herders, and farmers would
zeit des Vorderen Orients (subsequently translated as have led to some exchange, I cannot see any path leading
The Early History of the Ancient Near East, 90002000 to an exchange or even a trade system between the var-
b.c. [1988]), I specifically used the wording a history, ious regions of the alluvium and the citiesespecially
emphasizing that this was only one possible way of con- since the near-identical soil and climatic conditions
ceptualizing a history of the ancient Near East: I had in throughout the alluvium almost certainly resulted in
mind that either I or someone else would eventually identical animal and plant populations. I simply cannot

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 223

see any reason for asymmetric relations arising between period. This can equally be said of the northern plain,
the cities within the alluvium. where the dating criteria are rather more secure than
I could not agree more with what Algaze says about those used in the southern surveys. Indeed, Adamss
the difference in scale between the Mesopotamian al- Early Uruk type fossils are not early in the sense
luvium and the neighboring regionsin particular be- that the term is used in the north, where evidence for
cause I have stressed this point myself over the years four very sharply differentiated 4th-millennium-b.c.
(Nissen 1988, 1995, 1999). However, I have the feeling phases can be identified. This is not to criticize Adams,
that as much as Oates and Oates (1997), Lamberg-Kar- whose pioneering work is fundamental to our under-
lovsky (1999), and Frangipane (1997) may have overstated standing of state formation in the south, but only to
their argument in order to find a balance to the alleged point out a fact of life known equally well to himthat
total supremacy of southern Mesopotamia in earlier archaeologists can only work with the evidence that is
days, Algaze also pushes too far. As I tried to show some available.
time ago (Nissen 1995), we are confronted with shifting Algaze cites a small survey in the immediate vicinity
networks in which all parts respond to any changes any- of Brak as indicating a settlement pattern that lacks the
where within their areas. Undoubtedly, the Mesopota- depth and range of settlement size variability found to
mian alluvium was driven to greater complexity at one surround contemporary southern Mesopotamian urban
point. But because of its limited and uneven resolution, sites; in this he compares survey data that are hardly
our archaeological material tends to fool us when it comparable. Moreover, the sites indicated on Adamss
seems to present us with evidence for continuing major (mislabelled) figure 13 (1981) are identified by criteria
disparities. that are in northern terms Middle Uruk in date. At
this period Brak is a site of some 100160 ha, if one
includes the area of the small sites which immediately
joan oates surround it. Some 80 km to the east is 15-ha Hamoukar,
McDonald Institute for Archaeological Research, with the estimated 30-ha Hawa only some 3040 km
University of Cambridge, Downing St., Cambridge farther east. Middle Uruk material is found also at the
CB2 3ER, England (jlo29@cam.ac.uk). 23 xi 00 very large sites of Tell Barri, Shaikh Names, and Farfara
(106 ha), with distances measured from Brak of 9, 15, and
This paper must be welcomed as an important, well- 28 km (Meijer 1986); unfortunately, at these sites the
informed, and thoughtful contribution to the study of overburden of later occupation makes size estimates im-
state formation in Mesopotamia. As someone who has possible. I should also add that the earliest phase of the
long been interested in the economic and social potential tripartite Eye Temple was built in the indigenous Mid-
of its irrigation economy, I am particularly pleased to see dle Uruk phase, well before the southern Uruk intru-
the environmental dimension reintroduced. I have no sion. An examination of the contemporary pattern rep-
argument with Algazes primary thesis, although it resented by Adamss figure 13 reveals a generally similar
seems to me that the scale of the arable landscape con- but far less dense pattern of small sites, one with far
stitutes a further limiting/enabling factor (compare Catal fewer moderately large sites and the very few 40 ha
Hoyuk) and that in this Brak and Hamouker are very sites situated at a distance of 80 km or more upstream
significantly different from Warka. Indeed, it remains ob- from Warka. I have no space to develop this point further,
vious that the complexity of the site of Warka in the but it seems clear that in this early urban phase the
second half of the 4th millennium b.c. is not paralleled evidence from the north is as compelling as that from
elsewhere and that this precocity owes much to the po- the better-surveyed south; moreover, there is no evi-
tential of its landscape. My major criticism is that Algaze dence for a complex, hierarchically organized system
seems to have returned to an ecologically driven centre- in the immediate vicinity of Warka. Even more signifi-
and-periphery and that this view of the development of cant is the Early Uruk phase at Brak, with possible
complex society in wider Mesopotamia is misleading. evidence of a city wall and certainly of a monumental
On current evidence the background to the complex re- walled compound on a site estimated at some 45 ha
cording and administrative systems of Late Uruk Warka (Oates and Oates 1997, Emberling et al. 1999). At the
and, indeed, to the stone and metal technology that cre- same time (ca. 4000 b.c.) there is occupation at Ha-
ated the outward symbols of its elite lies not in the south moukar spread over approximately 300 ha (J. Ur, personal
but in the north (Duistermaat 2000; Esin 1989, 1994; communication).
Oates 1996). One has only to look at sites like Gobekli, A second crucial question involves the role played by
Nevali Cori, and Cayonu to observe a level of ritual and people of the Ubaid period in the north both in the de-
technological development so far entirely absent in the velopment of the administrative techniques later to play
south. This in no way invalidates Algazes general thesis, an important role in the south but not as yet attested
but it does bring into question his repeated assertions there and in the earliest organized acquisition of the re-
about backward and less developed polities in the sources of adjacent areas of Anatolia (e.g., Layer 7 at
north and their wider role. Degirmentepe, for which the evidence strongly suggests
Algaze writes that multiple interacting urban settings the presence of an Ubaid outpost [Esin 1985, 1989]).
of comparable scale had actually characterized the Mes- I agree that in none of these areas do we see a develop-
opotamian alluvium for centuries before the Late Uruk ment of complexity that can be compared with Late

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
224 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

Uruk Warka, but it is here that Algazes ecological ar- Once these regional economies were established, a
guments prevail. My point is that before the Late Uruk new social dynamic was created that transcended many
period the north played a more important role in the of the constraints of geography. This new dynamic con-
wider framework of social and economic development stitutes the social determinist component of Algazes
in Mesopotamia than is acknowledged in Algazes oth- model. It is implied in concepts such as multiplier ef-
erwise excellent paper. fects, competitive emulation, self-aggrandizing elites,
Minor points: (1) It is unlikely that grain was a major and the creation of socioeconomic asymmetries. One
export (Potts 1986). (2) Doubts about both manuring and could argue that the adoption of information technolo-
the degree of 3d-millennium salinization are expressed gies, a critical factor in his model, is best understood
elsewhere (Powell 1985, Oates 1994); for example, the within a social deterministic framework as well. In
site of Ur flourished in the same geographical position short, the nature of the physical environment (combined
for some 5,000 years, hardly an argument for rapid loss perhaps with correspondingly high population densities)
of soil fertility. (3) Brak should be added to the Late Uruk explains the initial development of political and eco-
metalworking sites (Oates and Oates 1997: fig. 16). nomic complexity in the region. It furthermore consti-
tutes the context in which all subsequent cultural evo-
lution was nurtured and constrained. But a set of social
charles stanish processes explains the emergence and maintenance of
Department of Anthropology, University of California, more complex political economies later on, a process
Los Angeles, Calif. 90095, U.S.A. (stanish@anthro that cannot be reduced merely to a type of environmental
.ucla.edu). 22 xi 00 determinism.
In reality, most contemporary archaeological theories
Since I am not a specialist in Old World archaeology, I of the origin of complex society combine elements of
will restrict my comments to what I believe are the im- both environmental and social determinism. In histori-
portant theoretical implications of this paper. Algaze, cal terms, this represents a shift in thinking from view-
citing a recent review by Robert McC. Adams, notes that ing cultural behavior strictly as the unconscious mani-
much of contemporary archaeological theory can be festation of underlying evolutionary principles to the
characterized as social determinism. This body of the- incorporation of conscious human agency into proces-
ory locates the source of cultural change in social inter- sual models. The real challenge for anthropological ar-
actions between cognizant actors and plays down the chaeology, in my view, is incorporating human agency
determinative role of the physical environment. In con- into testable models of cultural evolution.
trast, earlier neoevolutionary theories viewed the envi- In response to this challenge, many of our colleagues
ronment as a key agent in cultural change and humans have too quickly abandoned comparative analysis and
as more passive agents that adapt to changes in their scientific logic. In spite of what some anthropologists
environment. Algaze offers us a sophisticated approach have suggested, the recognition of human agency in ev-
that represents a compromise between these two epis- olutionary processes does not automatically require a
temological positions. For him the natural environment particularistic or historically contingent view of cul-
is important as the critical context in which humans tural change. The empirical fact is that the more closely
interact. Geography does not directly determine culture. we look at regional sequences with more refined chro-
Rather, it provides a suite of opportunities and con- nologies, the more we see striking parallels between cul-
straints for people interacting within a broad physical tural evolutionary patterns in different areas of the
and cultural landscape in space and time. From this per- world. There simply are a limited number of effective
spective, some geographical areas are more conducive to ways to organize complex societies. Over time, people
the development of political and economic complexity, independently and consciously arrived at these solutions
selecting, supporting, and/or promoting certain technol- in a number of regions around the world. While I disagree
ogies and social organizations. As Algaze notes, these with Algaze on some specific theoretical points, I agree
areas have natural advantages and are the loci of a with the general focus and epistemological assumptions
unique conjuncture of resources. of his argument, and I commend his effort to provide a
In Algazes analysis, a unique combination of geo- testable model of the evolution of complex society in
graphical features in the alluvial lowlands of the Tigris Mesopotamia using both social and environmental fac-
and Euphrates Rivers provided the initial impetus, the tors. It is a welcome contribution to anthropological
initial developmental takeoff, or the head start for theory.
the emergence of complex society in the late 5th mil-
lennium b.c. Building on the seminal work of Adams
and echoing the theoretical perspective of Elman Service, t. j. wilkinson
Algaze suggests that a mosaic of ecological niches would The Oriental Institute, 1155 East 58th Street, Chicago,
have promoted economic specialization by individual Ill. 60637, U.S.A. (t-wilkinson@uchicago.edu). 20 xi 00
communities. This specialization, in turn, promoted ex-
port-driven trade economies inducing both cooperation Algazes paper takes up a theme that is periodically ad-
and competition between these groups and ultimately dressed in the literature on Mesopotamia (Gibson 1992,
driving an increase in political and economic complexity. Hole 1994), and the author has made a welcome attempt

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 225

to factor the environment back into the development of stream decrease in discharge, can result in abrupt chan-
civilization without taking a deterministic stance. Here nel shifts that can be catastrophic to the inhabitants
I confine my comments to landscape productivity, re- (Gibson 1973:454). However, localized cleaning and
gional asymmetries of population, and the significance management of the node of avulsion or bifurcation could
and development of transport systems. have maintained flow in both channels rather than one,
Algaze highlights three advantages that southern Mes- thereby substantially increasing the water supply and
opotamia had over neighboring regions. The first, greater transportation network. This would have provided the
resiliency resulting from more varied resources, means potential for increases in land use and population. It is
that there is inbuilt insurance against subsistence fail- not clear which of these mechanismslarge-scale canal
ure. Although this should result in greater system sta- digging or the semimanaged avulsion of anastomosing
bility, in certain complex systems it may lead to desta- channelsproduced the network that nourished the
bilization (McGlade 1999:464). In the Mesopotamian early cities, but either would have encouraged or allowed
case, rivers raised above flood basins by levees might for increased population levels and would have contrib-
break their banks, resulting in instabilities that called uted to the growth of polities in the south. Algazes syn-
for adroit administration. ergistic cauldron may therefore benefit from the consid-
In the context of land use productivity, irrigation re- eration of these two human-environmental interactive
sults in increased crop yield per unit area, but whether systems.
this also results in increased labor productivity has been Algaze correctly points out that water transport sys-
much debated. Hunt (2000:27475) argues for traditional tems provided an advantage to southern Mesopotamia
rice cultivation that labor productivity can be higher over peripheral areas such as northern Mesopotamia, but
with more complex technologies (such as irrigation), should we, as he asserts, assume developmental asym-
thereby allowing for increased agricultural surpluses. If metries between north and south? Available settlement
this argument holds for irrigated cereals, the resultant survey data suggest that during the Ubaid period esti-
surplus could have fed the increased labor required for mated population densities in parts of the peripheral
Algazes industries or for increased public works such as regions exceeded those in the southern alluvial plains
canal cleaning. and maximum site size was probably similar to that in
Transport has long been regarded as a fundamental ad- the south. By the early 3d millennium b.c. southern set-
vantage that southern Mesopotamia had over neighbor- tlements were considerably larger, although estimated
ing regions, and Algaze is correct to emphasize its im- population densities were less than is often assumed
portance. His assumption that the progradation of the (Wilkinson 2000a:244, 249). Thus during the 4th millen-
Gulf would have necessitated the construction of ever nium b.c. the balance of urbanization may have shifted
larger and more expensive canal systems requires fur- from the rain-fed north to the irrigated plains of the
ther scrutiny, however. In part this is because the piece- south. This shift may have resulted from processes dis-
meal construction and extension of canals can cause ma- cussed by Algaze or, alternatively, it may have fueled
jor engineering problems that entail considerable further growth of settlement in the southern plains. The
reexcavation (Doolittle 1990:153). Algaze, quite reason- question of regional asymmetries of settlement therefore
ably and as have many before him, does not make a clear needs to be addressed more explicitly by future studies.
distinction between rivers and canals. Thus Adams By skillfully weaving together the physical environ-
(1981) regards large-scale canal construction as taking off ment and social and economic factors in one interactive
in the 3d millennium b.c., and Nissen (1988) for the same system, Algaze has made an important contribu-
time period states that mobilization of labor was fun- tion to the study of the development of the Sumerian
damental to the construction of canal systems. Never- civilization.
theless, it remains unclear just how much of the channel
systemup to 250 km in lengthwas actually excavated
and how much labor was required for such public works.
If the canals were dug, their construction could have Reply
exhausted the local labor supply that was normally en-
gaged in cleaning and maintaining local canal networks.
Such works would therefore have required the import of guillermo algaze
labor from surrounding regions, thereby fueling further La Jolla, Calif., U.S.A. 11 xi 00
population growth. An alternative mechanism for the
development of the multiple channel systems charac- I am grateful for the many insightful comments and clar-
teristic of Sumer and Akkad is the enhancement of a ifications raised by the various commentators, especially
natural process of bifurcation by local management. The those of Friedman and Ekholm Friedman, who have cho-
low-gradient plains crossed by river channels raised by sen to examine in detail the speculative model that I
levees provided ideal conditions for the abrupt shift or proposed to explain the evolution of the import/export
avulsion of channels that results in such anabranching trade patterns characteristic of early Mesopotamian civ-
systems (Verhoeven 1998:174; Jones and Schumm 1999; ilization. In brief, the model postulates three broad but
Morozova and Smith 2000). These conditions, enhanced overlapping phases in this evolution: a first phase char-
by substantial within-channel sedimentation and down- acterized by largely internal trade between southern pol-

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
226 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

ities exploiting varied ecological niches unique to 4th- more than 20 years ago. The evolutionary sequence for
millennium Mesopotamia along principles of the initial development of import/export economies in
competitive advantage, a second phase in which import- southern Mesopotamia proposed in this paper is emi-
substitution processes serve to homogenize the produc- nently testable, and I hope that improved artifact-recov-
tive capabilities of alluvial polities, and a third phase ery methodologies and changed historical circumstances
characterized by heightened competition between poli- in Iraq will soon allow a new generation of researchers
ties that then possessed broadly comparable productive to do exactly that.
capabilities. In the course of this latter phase, individual Some of the commentators raise points of disagree-
southern polities appear to have made efforts to open ment which I believe are more apparent than real and
external markets for now widely diffused industries eas- result from inadequacies in the exposition of my ideas.
ily adapted for export (principally the new dyed woolen Nissen, for instance, argues that environmental advan-
textiles, as McCorriston insightfully notes) and to con- tages fail to explain the Uruk takeoff. Instead, he sees
trol the flow of external resources brought into the south. the challenge of large populations coping with an evolv-
Both steps can be seen as ways to legitimize evolving ing alluvial environment as a trigger for social complex-
social transformations and out-compete regional rivals. ity. In fact, our positions are not as dissimilar as Nissen
Friedman and Ekholm Friedman agree in seeing the believes, although I do think that he underestimates both
many ramifications of trade as central to processes of the degree of ecological variability of the southern al-
social evolution in early Mesopotamia but call for a more luvial plain in the 4th-millennium b.c. and the economic
detailed characterization of the specific social processes potential of marshes, lagoons, and estuaries. I see geo-
whereby the advantages in trade of Mesopotamian so- graphical and environmental advantages and social prob-
ciety were translated into technologies of power. Spe- lems as causally and evolutionarily connected. In brief,
cifically, they note the need for a thorough review of the my argument is that the inherent transportational ad-
systemic relationships between trade, forms of labor or- vantages of the southern Mesopotamian landscape, its
ganization, slavery, information-processing technolo- greater fertility and reliability, and the unique density
gies, and external expansion during the Uruk period. and variability of its exploitable resources during the 4th
While their points are well taken, we should remember millennium created the conditions wherein unprece-
that the level of specificity required to prove causal re- dented population densities could emerge. Propinquity,
lationships between evolving trade patterns and specific in turn, is what created new social problems requiring
sequences of social change is simply not achievable in resolution, and these problems were solved through the
the Mesopotamian case for the period in which Uruk invention of revolutionary ideational technologies,
civilization first crystallized. There are three reasons for principally new forms of managing labor that empha-
this: (1) the lack of detailed textual documentation, (2) sized economies of scale and new forms of information
the fragmentary and unrepresentative nature of the ar- processing and record keeping.
chaeological evidence at our disposal, and (3) our con- Other commentators raise important issues not prop-
tinuing inability to subdivide the Uruk period into an- erly addressed in my paper. Both Tony Wilkinson and
ything more precise than 200300-year phases. Joan Oates, for instance, suggest that I erred in my char-
Falling, as I do, into the formalist camp in debates acterization of the nature of Upper Mesopotamian so-
about the nature of premodern economies (Polanyi 1957), cieties during the prehistoric periods. Oates notes that
I found it gratifying that Friedman and Ekholm Friedman by the Neolithic period (8th7th millennium b.c.), an
see potential value to the use of the concept of import early northern advantage in integrative institutions such
substitution to explain the socioeconomic processes in as cultic buildings/temples existed over the then sparsely
operation in protohistoric societies. They properly ques- inhabited south and that by the Late Neolithic and Halaf
tion, however, whether the available evidentiary base is periods (6th5th millennium b.c.) the north held an ad-
strong enough to justify the use of concepts developed vantage over the south (Early Ubaid) in site size and in
for the explanation of modern capitalist economies in the complexity of administrative technology, as seen
the context of preindustrial societies. While this crucial from the glyptic of the time. Wilkinson notes further
question cannot be adequately addressed with the flawed that the available survey data suggest that during the
data at our disposal, the use of modern economic models Late Ubaid period (late 5th millennium b.c.), estimated
in an ancient Near Eastern context is justified on two population densities in parts of Upper Mesopotamia ex-
counts. The first is that these models are not put forth ceeded those in the southern alluvial plains and maxi-
as a prescription of conditions that must of necessity mum site sizes were probably similar in the two areas.
have occurred; rather, as Knapp notes, they are intended In retrospect, it seems to me that Oates and Wilkinson
as hypotheses to be tested against the available archae- are entirely correct when they argue that the north
ological data, which all too often are fragmentary and played a more important role in the wider framework of
difficult to interpret. The second is that changes result- social and economic development in (Greater) Mesopo-
ing from the emergence of modern capitalism may have tamia before the Uruk period than is acknowledged in
greatly intensified and brought into sharp focus relation- my paper. Perhaps the time has finally come to abandon
ships of asymmetrical exchange leading to unequal de- the concept of the pristine state or civilization and to
velopment but by no means created those relationships, acknowledge that processes of social evolution are al-
as Ekholm and Friedman (1979) themselves suggested ways the results of regional and transregional patterns

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 227

of interaction (Kohl 1987b). The early social evolution Oates also misses some of the uniqueness of the Uruk
of Greater Mesopotamian polities before the 4th millen- phenomenon when she argues that the scale and density
nium is thus best conceptualized as a process of parallel of occupations in the north in the Late Chalcolithic pe-
development in which constant interaction between dif- riod, spanning most of the 4th millennium b.c., were
ferent regions and cultural traditions fuels widespread comparable to or even exceeded those of the south. She
processes of competitive emulation. This, in turn, serves argues, for instance, that Tell Brak was somewhere be-
roughly to equalize the rate and direction of the evolu- tween 100 and 160 ha in extent during the Middle
tionary trajectories of otherwise very different polities Uruk phase. This figure presumes that the totality of
exploiting very different ecosystems. In this, the for- the intervening area between the main mound and the
mative phases of Mesopotamian civilization appear sim- ring of satellites surrounding it was occupied. Recent
ilar to those of Mesoamerica, with its multiple but dis- work in this area, however, found no evidence for such
tinct traditions of social complexity (the Maya, Monte an occupation (Emberling et al. 1999:1617, 25) and sug-
Alban, Teotihuacan) developing independently but in gests that a substantial portion of the intervening area
tandem as a result of comparable socio-evolutionary pro- consisted of large clay pits excavated in support of build-
cesses made widespread by extensive long-distance con- ing activities at the main site (Wilkinson 2000b:127).
tacts (Marcus 1992). Also problematic is Oatess claim that the density of
The corrections to my characterization of social evo- Late Chalcolithic sites around Brak and the depth of the
lution in Greater Mesopotamia prior to the Uruk period site hierarchy in its vicinity surpassed those character-
introduced by Oates and Wilkinson serve to highlight istic for Uruk-period southern Mesopotamia, particu-
even further the abruptness of the Sumerian takeoff larly those typical for the northernmost portions of the
of the 4th millennium, when the balance of urbaniza- alluvium surveyed by Adams. This should be qualified
tion, sociopolitical complexity, economic differentia- in two ways. First, the Nippur-Adab region of the allu-
tion, and ability to project power at a distance shifted vium, where Oates notes the apparent absence of small
dramatically to the irrigated plains of the south. Nothing and medium-sized Uruk-period settlements, is precisely
better epitomizes this shift than the MiddleLate-Uruk- one of the areas of southern Mesopotamia with the
period expansion of southern populations into selected greatest amount of recent alluvial deposition, which nat-
portions of Upper Mesopotamia, although, as Dittmann urally tends to obscure the smaller sites (Adams 1981,
notes, we still have much to learn about the scale and Reichel 1997, Wilkinson 1990b). Absence of evidence is
variability of that phenomenon. not evidence of absence. I take it as a given that the
Regrettably, some of the commentators fail to ac- various 40-ha urban sites along parallel branches of the
knowledge the uniqueness of the Uruk revolution. Lam- Tigris-Euphrates fluvial system in the Nippur-Adab re-
berg-Karlovsky, for instance, notes that several sites gion throughout the Uruk period did not exist in isola-
comparable to or larger than late-4th-millennium Uruk tion from their hinterlands. Each must have been at the
existed at the time in the context of the Tripolye culture apex of a variegated settlement structure, even if the
in Ukraine. The even earlier Neolithic site of Mehrgarh, lower levels of that structure are now obscured by sed-
in Pakistan, estimated at 200 ha in extent (Jarrige and iments deposited since the 4th millennium.
Meadow 1980), could also be added to his list. Oates, Second, while Oates is correct is noting that large sites
similarly, notes the existence of what she calls a 300-ha with Late Chalcolithic-period materials do exist in the
occupation of early Late Chalcolithic date (late 5thearly Upper Khabur area at reasonably short distances from
4th millennium) at Tell Hamoukar, in northeastern Sy- Brak, the sites in question have not been surveyed in a
ria. These parallels are neither pertinent nor comparable. way that allows us to ascertain their nature or their ex-
In trying to arrive at a cross-culturally valid definition tent at the time. Clearly the time has come for an ex-
of what is urban, Fox (1977) has noted that settlement tensive and coherent survey of the Jaghjagh branch of
size is one of the least important criteria and argued that the Upper Khabur, where Brak is located, that would go
the defining characteristics lie in the degree of internal beyond the area covered by Eidem and Warburton (1996).
diversity and complexity within a settlement. Thus de- Ideally, such a survey should follow the site recognition
fined, Uruk was certainly unparalleled by a second half and recording guidelines established by Wilkinson dur-
of the 4th millennium. The Ukrainian sites never sur- ing earlier work in the Sinjar Plains of northern Iraq (Wil-
passed the village level of social complexity. Mehrgarh kinson and Tucker 1995, Wilkinson 2000a) and now used
is also largely undifferentiated, and its excavator explains in ongoing surveys elsewhere in the Upper Khabur area
its anomalous size as the result of horizontal stratig- of Syria around Tell Beidar (Wilkinson 1998) and Tell
raphy created as a much smaller settlement periodically Hamoukar (Gibson 2000). It may very well be that such
shifted its location within a small area over time. Sim- future work will support Oatess contentions about the
ilarly, the excavator of Hamoukar, McGuire Gibson (per- nature of the Late Chalcolithic settlement hierarchy
sonal communication, 2000), believes that a large por- around Brak, but at present we have no reliable evidence
tion of the 300-ha scatter of early Late Chalcolithic to consider beyond that discussed in my paper.
remains at that location is also largely the result of hor- An important issue raised by some of the commen-
izontal stratigraphy, possibly resulting from the use of tators is that of the role of religion in the transformations
the site as a center for the seasonal aggregation of no- attending the Uruk revolution. A full examination of
madic tribal groups. religion as a factor in the rise of early Mesopotamian

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
228 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

civilization was never my intention in this paper. Rather, their societies that their interests were cotermi-
my goal was to use Jacobss ideas to gain insight into the nouswhat Cioffi-Revilla refers to as the collective-
precociousness and unique vitality of processes of urban action problem. One way to approach this conundrum
growth and socioeconomic differentiation in Uruk-pe- would be a systematic analysis of the available ethno-
riod Mesopotamia. I am quite aware that my discussions historic record of the modern era to explore how the
of the reasons underpinning the Uruk takeoff do not ad- collective-action problem was solved in documented
dress the crucial issue of how the new ideological con- cases where chiefdom-level societies were transformed
structs of the states emerging in alluvial Mesopotamia into states. This analysis could then serve as a source of
at the time came into being. In any event, I fully concur testable hypotheses applicable to analyses of social dy-
with the comments of Charvat and Lamberg-Karlovsky namics at the time the worlds earliest states and civi-
as to the centrality of religion in the transformations that lizations emerged.
gave rise to Mesopotamian civilization. The central po- Agreeing with Cioffi-Revilla on the need for expla-
sition that cultic structures occupy at the very core of nations that take into account the decisions of conscious
Uruk cities, as seen at Warka, allows for no other inter- actors, Stanish argues that the principal challenge in an-
pretation. Further, Lamberg-Karlovsky is entirely correct thropological archaeology today is finding a way to in-
when he argues that ideologies about the relationship corporate the vagaries of human agency and historical
between the rulers and the supernatural affect the re- contingency into testable and cross-culturally applicable
lationship between the rulers and the ruled and that this models of social evolution. While I am less optimistic
represents a synergy as important as the socioeconomic than he about our ability to identify agency in the ar-
and demographic ones highlighted in my discussion. chaeological record, I believe that an approximation in
Returning to topics more directly addressed in my pa- the aggregate can indeed be achieved. In my paper I tried
per, I would like to expand on a comment by Brentjes to meet Stanishs challenge by suggesting that some
that struck me as particularly important. This is the is- types of human actions, such as the will to accumulate
sue of the dual structure of the city of Uruk, with its status, wealth, and power, are predictable across both
parallel ceremonial areas, Eanna and Kullab. Here again cultures and time (Hayden 1995:2023) and that some
is a case where understanding the importance of early geographical areas are more conducive to achieving these
trade in Mesopotamia may help us better understand the goals than others. This naturally results in differential
specific trajectory of early Mesopotamian urbanism and levels of probability for the development of initial social
the form of early Sumerian civilization. Adams (personal complexity across the landscape. Southern Mesopotamia
communication, 2000) has suggested that early Meso- in the late 5th and 4th millennia b.c. proved to be par-
potamian twin cities such as Uruk and Kish may result ticularly fertile ground for precisely such a development.
from a conflation of two initially independent towns ad-
jacent to but on opposite sides of a major canal or river
branch. The growth of such (Ubaid) towns, initially
founded along natural crossing points, into major (Uruk
and later) cities can be understood in terms of the self-
amplifying mechanisms discussed by Jacobs. Adams ar-
References Cited
gues that twin-town-type settlements would have ex-
panded in tandem with improved crossing facilities a d a m s , r . m c c . 1966. The evolution of urban society. Chi-
cago: University of Chicago Press.
between them such as multiple boat ferries. In so doing . 1978. Strategies of maximization, stability, and resilience
they would have grown further as they attracted an even in Mesopotamian society, settlement, and agriculture. Proceed-
larger proportion of long-distance traffic from hinter- ings of the American Philosophical Society 122:32935.
lands on either side, with their embankments becoming . 1981. Heartland of cities. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
docks for transfer of shipments from boats to caravans
. 1999. Archaeological surveys of the Mesopotamian
and vice versa. plains: Discoveries and issues still in prospect. Paper delivered
I would like to close by turning to issues raised by at the Oriental Institute, Chicago, March 27.
Cioffi-Revilla and Stanish regarding the role of agency . 2000. Scale and complexity in archaic states. Latin
in human history. Cioffi-Revilla argues that the envi- American Antiquity 11:18793.
a d a m s , r . m c c . a n d h . - j . n i s s e n . 1972. The Uruk coun-
ronmental, geographic, demographic, and socioeconomic tryside. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
variables that are the focus of my paper and of compa- a l d e n , j . 1982. Trade and politics in Proto-Elamite Iran. cur-
rable efforts by like-minded colleagues studying the or- rent anthropology 23:61328.
igins of early states and civilizations elsewhere fail to a l g a z e , g . 1993. The Uruk world system: The dynamics of
expansion of early Mesopotamian civilization. Chicago: Uni-
address the proximate causes of the phenomena we seek
versity of Chicago Press.
to comprehend, which he sees as entirely political and . 1995. Fourth-millennium trade in Greater Mesopotamia
historically contingent. He is certainly correct. However, and the question of wine, in The origins and ancient history
because of the nature of the evidence at our disposal for of wine. Edited by S. Fleming, P. McGovern, and S. Katz, pp.
early pristine civilizations across the world, we re- 8996. New York: Gordon and Breach.
. 1999. Trends in the archaeological development of the
grettably will never be able to reconstruct in detail the Upper Euphrates Basin of southeastern Anatolia during the
various strategies used by elites in the earliest states that Late Chalcolithic and Early Bronze Ages, in Archaeology of
appeared across the world to convince commoners in the Upper Syrian Euphrates: The Tishrin Dam area. Edited by

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 229

G. del Olmo Lete and J.-L. Montero Fenollos, pp. 53572. Bar- World. Edited by E. M. Brumfiel and J. W. Fox, pp. 314. Cam-
celona: Editorial Ausa. bridge: Cambridge University Press.
. 2001. The prehistory of imperialism: The case of Uruk b r y s o n , r . a . , a n d r . u . b r y s o n . 1997. High-resolution
period Mesopotamia, in Uruk Mesopotamia and its neigh- simulations of regional Holocene climate: North Africa and
bors: Cross-cultural interactions and their consequences in the the Near East, in Third millennium b.c. climate change and
era of state formation. Edited by M. Rothman. Santa Fe: Old World collapse. Edited by H. Nuzhet Dalfes, G. Kukla,
School of American Research Press. and H. Weiss, pp. 56594. Berlin: Springer Verlag.
a l g a z e , g . , r . b r e u n i n g e r , a n d j . k n u d s t a d . 1994. . 1999. Holocene climates of Anatolia as simulated with
The Tigris-Euphrates Archaeological Reconnaissance Project: archaeoclimatic models. Turkiye Bilimler Akademisi Arkeoloji
Final report of the Birecik and Carchemish Dam survey areas. Dergisi 2:114.
Anatolica 20:196. b u t z e r , k . w. 1995. Environmental change in the Near East
a l g a z e , g . , r . b ru e n i n g e r , c . l i g h t f o o t , a n d m . and human impact on the land, in Civilizations of the an-
r o s e n b e r g . 1991. The Tigris-Euphrates Archaeological Re- cient Near East. Edited by J. Sasson, J. Baines, G. Beckman,
connaissance Project, 198990. Anatolica 17:175240. and K. Rubinson, pp. 12351. New York: Scribner.
a l g a z e , g . , a . m i s i r , a n d t . w i l k i n s o n . 1992. San- . 2001. Geoarchaeological implications of recent research
liurfa Museum/University of California excavations and sur- in the Nile Delta, in Egypt and the Levant: The 4th-millen-
veys at Titris Hoyuk, 1991: A preliminary report. Anatolica 18: nium background. Edited by E. van den Brink and T. E. Levy.
3360. London: Leicester University Press.
a m i e t , p . 1972. Glyptique susienne. Memoires de la Delega- c a r t e r , e . , a n d m . w. s t o l p e r . 1984. Elam: Surveys of
tion Archeologique Francaise en Iran 43. Paris: Geuthner. political history and archaeology. Berkeley: University of Cali-
. 1980. La glyptique mesopotamienne archaque. Paris: fornia Press.
Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique. c h a r v a t , p e t r . 1993. Uruk IV society: Evidence for the
a r c a r i , e . 1988. The administrative organization of the city script, in Sulmu IV: Everyday life in the ancient Near East
of Ebla, in Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft von Ebla. Edited by (Papers presented at the International Conference, Poznan,
H. Waetzoldt and H. Hauptmann, pp. 12529. Heidelberg: Hei- 1922 September 1989). Edited by J. Zablocka and St. Zawa-
delberger Orientverlag. dzki, pp. 5362. Poznan: Wydawnictwo Naukowe UAM. [pc]
a r c h i , a . 1988. Zur Organization der Arbeit in Ebla, in . 1997. On people, signs, and states: Spotlights on Sume-
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft von Ebla. Edited by H. Waetzoldt rian society, c. 35002500 b.c.. Prague: Oriental Institute. [pc]
and H. Hauptmann, pp. 13138. Heidelberg: Heidelberger c h e r r y, j . f . , j . l . d a v i s , a n d e . m a n t z o u r a n i . 1991.
Orientverlag. Landscape archaeology as long-term history: Northern Keos in
. 1990. The city of Ebla and the organization of the rural the Cycladic Islands from earliest settlement to modern
territory, in The town as regional economic center in the an- times. (Monumenta Archaeologica 16.) Los Angeles: UCLA In-
stitute of Archaeology. [abk]
cient Near East. Edited by E. Aertz and H. Klenglel, pp. 1519.
c i o f fi - r e v i l l a , c l a u d i o . 1998. Politics and uncertainty:
Leuven: Leuven University Press.
Theory, models, and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
a s t o u r , m . c . 1988. The geographical and political structure
versity Press. [cc]
of the Ebla empire, in Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft von Ebla.
c i o f fi - r e v i l l a , c l a u d i o , a n d h a r v e y s t a r r . 1995.
Edited by H. Waetzoldt and H. Hauptmann, pp. 13958. Hei-
Opportunity, willingness, and political uncertainty: Theoretical
delberg: Heidelberger Orientverlag. foundations of politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics 7:
b a d l e r , v. r . , p . e . m c g o v e r n , a n d d . l . g l u s k e r . 44776. [cc]
1996. Chemical evidence for a wine residue from Warka (Uruk) c o n t i , a . m . , a n d c . p e r s i a n i . 1993. When worlds col-
inside a Late Uruk period spouted jar. Baghdader Mitteilungen lide: Cultural developments in Eastern Anatolia in the Early
27:3943. Bronze Age, in Between the rivers and over the mountains:
b a i n e s , j . , a n d n . y o f f e e . 1998. Order, legitimacy, and Archaeologica Anatolica et Mesopotamica Alba Palmieri De-
wealth in ancient Egypt and Mesopotamia, in Archaic states. dicata. Edited by M. Frangipane, H. Hauptmann, M. Liverani,
Edited by G. Feinman and J. Marcus, pp. 199260. Santa Fe: P. Matthiae, and M. Mellink, pp. 361413. Rome: Universita di
School for American Research Press. Roma La Sapienza.
b a i r o c h , p . 1988. Cities and economic development. Chi- c r o n e , p . 1989. Pre-industrial societies. Oxford: Basil
cago: University of Chicago Press. Blackwell.
bar-matthews, m., a. ayalon, and a. kaufman. c u l l e n , h . m . , a n d p . b . d e m e n o c a l . 2000. North At-
1997. Late Quaternary paleoclimate in the eastern Mediterra- lantic influence on Tigris-Euphrates streamflow. International
nean region from stable isotope analysis of speleothems at Journal of Climatology 20:85363.
Soreq Cave, Israel. Quaternary Research 47:15568. d a n t i , m . d . 1997. Regional surveys and excavations, in
b a r k e r , g . , a n d d . m a t t i n g l y. Editors. 19992000. The Subsistence and settlement in a marginal environment: Tell
archaeology of the Mediterranean landscape. 5 vols. Oxford: es-Sweyhat, 19891995, preliminary report. Edited by R. Zett-
Oxbow. [abk] ler, pp. 8594. Philadelphia: MASCA.
b e n c o , n . 1992. Manufacture and use of clay sickles from the d e l o u g a z , p . , a n d h . j . k a n t o r . 1996. Chogha Mish I:
Uruk Mound, Abu Salabikh. Paleorient 18:11934. The first five seasons of excavations, 19611971. Edited by A.
blanchet, g., p. sanlaville, and m. traboulsi. Alizadeh. Chicago: Oriental Institute.
1997. Le Moyen-Orient de 20,000 ans BP a 6,000 ans BP: Essai d e n o b l e t , n . , p . b r a c o n n o t , s . j o u s s a u m e , a n d v.
de reconstitution paleoclimatique. Paleorient 23:18796. m a s s o n . 1996. Sensitivity of simulated Asian and African
b o e s e , j . 1995. Ausgrabungen in Tell Sheikh Hassan. Vol. 1. summer monsoons to orbitally induced varitions in insolation
Vorlaufige Berichte uber die Grabungskampagnen 19841990 126, 115, and 6 kBP. Climate Dynamics 12:589603.
und 19921994. Saarbrucken: Saarbrucker Druckerei und d i t t m a n n , r . 1986. Seals, sealings, and tablets: Thoughts on
Verlag. the changing pattern of administrative control from the Late
b o n e c h i , m . 1993. Repertoire geographique des textes cunei- Uruk to the Proto-Elamite period at Susa, in Gemdet Nasr:
formes 12/1: I nomi geografici dei testi di Ebla. Wiesbaden: Dr. Period or regional style? Edited by U. Finkbeiner and W. Rol-
Ludwig Reichert. lig, pp. 33266. Wiesbaden: Ludwig Reichert.
b r i t i s h a d m i r a l t y, n a v a l i n t e l l i g e n c e d i v i s i o n . d o o l i t t l e , w. e . 1990. Canal irrigation in prehistoric Mex-
1917. A handbook of Mesopotamia. Vol. 1. Oxford. ico: The sequence of technological change. Austin: University
b r u m f i e l , e . m . 1994. Factional competition and political of Texas Press. [tjw]
development in the New World: An introduction, in Fac- d u i s t e r m a a t , k i m . 2000. A view on Late Neolithic sealing
tional competition and political development in the New practices in the Near East: The case of Tell Sabi Abyad, Syria,

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
230 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

in Administrative documents in the Aegean and their Near scale cycle from a speleothem in Nahal Qanah Cave, Israel.
Eastern counterparts. Edited by M. Perna. Naples. [jo] The Holocene 9:67782.
d u n n e l l , r . c . 1980. Evolutionary theory and archaeology. g e l b , i . j . 1944. Hurrians and Subarians. Chicago: University
Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory 3:3599. [jm] of Chicago Press.
e d e n s , c . 1994. On the complexity of complex societies: g e l l n e r , e r n e s t . 1988. Plough, sword, and book. Chicago:
Structure, power, and legitimation in Kassite Babylonia, in University of Chicago Press. [ccl]
Chiefdoms of early states of the Near East. Edited by G. Stein g i b s o n , m c g . 1973. Population shift and the rise of Mes-
and M. Rothman, pp. 20924. Madison: Prehistory Press. [jm] opotamian civilization, in The explanation of culture change:
e i d e m , j . , a n d d . w a r b u r t o n . 1996. In the land of Nagar: Models in prehistory. Edited by C. Renfrew, pp. 44763. Lon-
A survey around Tell Brak. Iraq 58:5164. don: Duckworth.
e k h o l m , k . , a n d j . f r i e d m a n . 1979. Capital imperial- . 1974. Violation of fallow and engineered disaster in
ism and exploitation in ancient world systems, in Power and Mes-
progaganda. Edited by M. T. Larsen, pp. 4158. Copenhagen: opotamian civilization, in Irrigations impact on society. Ed-
Akademisk Vorlag. ited by T. E. Downing and McG. Gibson, pp. 720. Tucson:
emberling, g., j. cheng, t. larsen, h. pittman, t. University of Arizona Press.
s k u l d b o e l , j . w e b e r , a n d h . t . w r i g h t . 1999. Exca- . 1992. The origin and development of Sumerian civiliza-
vations at Tell Brak 1998: Preliminary report. Iraq 61:141. tion and its relation to environment. International Center for
e n g l u n d , r . k . 1990. Organisation und Verwaltung der Ur- Japanese Studies, Tokyo, International Symposium no. 6, pp.
III Fischerei. Berlin: Dietrich Reimer. 127. [tjw]
. 1998. Texts from the Late Uruk Period, in Mesopota- . 2000. Hamoukar: Early city in northeastern Syria. Orien-
mien: Spaturuk-Zeit und Fruhdynastische Zeit. Edited by P. tal Institute News and Notes 166:18, 1819.
Attinger and M. Wafler, pp. 15236. Freiburg Schweiz: Univer- g o o d y, j . 2000. The power of the written tradition. Washing-
sitatsverlag/Gottingen: Vandenhoeck and Ruprecht. ton, D.C.: Smithsonian Institution Press.
e s i n , u fi k . 1985. Some small finds from the Chalcolithic oc- g o u l d , s . j . 1986. Evolution and the triumph of homology, or
cupation at Degirmentepe (Malatya) in eastern Turkey, in Why history matters. American Scientist 74:6069. [jm]
Studi de paletnologia in onore di Salvatore M. Puglisi. Edited . 1994. In the mind of the beholder. Natural History 103:
by M. Liverani, A. Palmieri, and R. Peroni, pp. 25363. Rome. 1423. [jm]
[jo] g r a y s o n , a . k . , g . f r a m e , a n d d . f r a y n e . 1987. Assyr-
. 1989. An early trading centre in eastern Anatolia, in ian rulers of the third and second millennia b.c. (to 1115 b.c.).
Anatolia and the Near East: Studies in honor of Tahsin Ozguc. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Edited by K. Emre, B. Hrouda, M. Mellink, and N. Ozguc, pp. h a r r i s o n , s . p . , d . j o l l y, f . l a a r i f , a . a b e - o u c h i ,
3541. Ankara. [jo] b. dong, k. herterich, c. hewitt, s. joussaume,
. 1994. The functional evidence of seals and sealings of j. e. kutzbach, j. mitchell, n. de noblet, and p.
Degirmentepe, in Archives before writing. Edited by P. Feri- v a l d e s . 1998. Intercomparison of simulated global vegeta-
oli, B. Fiandra, G. G. Fissoro, and M. Frangipane. Torino: Scrip- tion distributions in response to 6 kyr BP orbital forcing. Jour-
torium. [jo] nal of Climate 11:272141.
f e i n m a n , g . 1998. Scale and social organization: Perspectives h a y d e n , b . 1995. Pathways to power: Principles for creating
on the archaic state, in Archaic states. Edited by G. Feinman socioeconomic inequalities, in Foundations for social ine-
and J. Marcus, pp. 95134. Santa Fe: School of American Re- quality. Edited by T. Douglas Price and Gary M. Feinman, pp.
search Press. 1586. New York: Plenum.
f e i n m a n , g . , a n d j . m a r c u s . Editors. 1998. Archaic h e i l b r o n e r , r . l . 1994 (1967). Do machines make history?
states. Santa Fe: School of American Research Press. in Does technology drive history? Edited by M. R. Smith and
f e r i o l i , p . , a n d e . f i a n d r a . 1983 (1988). Clay sealings L. Marx, pp. 5465. Cambridge: MIT Press.
from Arslantepe VIA: Administration and bureaucracy. Origine h e i n r i c h , e . 1936. Kleinfunde aus den archaischen Tempel-
12:455509. schichten in Uruk. Leipzig: Otto Harrassowits.
f i a n d r a , e . 1994. Discussion, in Archives before writing. . 1937. Die Grabung im Planquadrat K XVII. Vorlaufiger
Edited by P. Ferioli, E. Fiandra, G. G. Fissore, and M. Frangi- Bericht uber die von der Deutschen Forschungsgemeinschaft
pane, p. 168. Rome: Centro Internazionale di Recerche Ar- in Uruk-Warka unternommenen Ausgrabungen 8:2755.
chaeologiche Anthropologiche e Storiche. . 1938. Grabungen im Gebiet des Anu-Antum-Tempels.
f i n k b e i n e r , u . 1991. Uruk: Kampagne 3537, 19821984, Die Vorlaufiger Bericht uber die von der Deutschen Forschungsge-
archaologische Oberflachenuntersuchung. Mainz am Rhein: meinschaft in Uruk-Warka unternommenen Ausgrabungen 9:
Philipp von Zabern. 1930.
f l a n n e r y, k . v. 1995. Prehistoric social evolution, in Re- h i r s c h , h . 1963. Die Inschriften der Konige von Agade. Archiv
search frontiers in anthropology. Edited by C. R. Ember and M. fur Orientforschung 20:182.
Ember, pp. 126. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. h o e l z m a n n , p . , d . j o l l y, s . p . h a r r i s o n , f . l a a r i f ,
f o r e s t , j . d . 1996. Mesopotamie: Lapparition de letat, r . b o n n e fi l l e , a n d h . j . p a c h u r . 1998. Mid-Holocene
VIIIeIIIe millenaire. Paris: Mediterranee. [pc] land-surface conditions in northern Africa and the Arabian
. 1999. Les premieres temples de Mesopotamie. British Ar- Peninsula: A data set for the analysis of biophysical feedback
chaeological Reports International Series 765. in the climate system. Global Biochemical Cycles 12:3551.
f o x , r . 1977. Urban anthropology: Cities in their cultural set- h o l e , f . 1994. Environmental instabilities and urban origins,
tings. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. in Chiefdoms and early states in the Near East. Edited by G.
f r a n g i p a n e , m . 1997. A fourth millennium temple/palace Stein and M. S. Rothman, pp. 12152. Madison: Prehistory
complex at Arslantepe-Malatya: North-south relations and the Press.
formation of early state societies in the northern regions of . 1997. Evidence for Mid-Holocene environmental change
southern Mesopotamia. Paleorient 23:4573. in the western Khabur drainage northeastern Syria, in Third
. 2001. The development of a powerful early state centre millennium b.c. climate change and Old World collapse. Ed-
north of Taurus: Continuity and discontinuity in Greater Mes- ited by H. Nuzhet Dalfes, G. Kukla, and H. Weiss, pp. 3966.
opotamia, in Uruk Mesopotamia and its neighbors: Cross- Berlin: Springer Verlag.
cultural interactions and their consequences in the era of h u n t , r o b e r t c . 2000. Labor productivity and agricultural
state formation. Edited by M. Rothman. Sante Fe: School of development: Boserup revisited. Human Ecology 28:25177.
American Research Press. [tjw]
f ru m k i n , a . , i . c a r m i , a . g o p h e r , d . c . f o r d , h . p . j a c o b s , j . 1961. The life and death of great American cities.
s c h w a r c z , a n d t . t s u k . 1999. A Holocene millennial- New York: Random House.

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 231

. 1969. The economy of cities. New York: Vintage. fication, alienation, and social stratification in ancient Meso-
. 1984. Cities and the wealth of nations. New York: Ran- potamia. current anthropology 38:51749. [jm]
dom House. . 1999. Syrian origins of safflower production: New dis-
. 2000. The nature of economies. New York: Modern coveries in agrarian prehistory of the Habur Basin. Proceed-
Library. ings of the International Symposium on the Origins of Agri-
j a c o b s e n , t . 1939. The Sumerian king list. Chicago: Univer- culture, Aleppo, Syria. Edited by A. B. Damania, J. Valkoun, G.
sity of Chicago Press. Willcox, and C. O. Qualset, pp. 3950. Aleppo, Rome, and Da-
. 1970 (1953). On the textile industry at Ur under Ibbi- vis, Calif.: ICARDA, IPGRI, FAO, and GRCP. [jm]
Sin, in Towards the image of Tammuz. Edited by W. L. m c g l a d e , j . 1995. Archaeology and the ecodynamics of hu-
Moran, pp. 21630. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. man-modified landscapes. Antiquity 69(262):11332. [abk]
. 1982. Salinity and irrigation agriculture in antiquity: Di- . 1999. Archaeology and the evolution of cultural land-
yala Basin Archaeological Projects, report on essential results, scapes: Towards an interdisciplinary research agenda, in The
195758. Malibu: Undena. archaeology and anthropology of landscape. Edited by Peter J.
j a c o b s e n , t . , a n d r . m c c . a d a m s . 1958. Salt and silt in Ucko and Robert Layton, pp. 45882. London: Routledge. [tjw]
ancient Mesopotamian agriculture. Science 121:125158. m a e k a w a , k . 1980. Female weavers and their children in La-
j a r r i g e , j . - f . , a n d r . h . m e a d o w. 1980. The antecedents gash: Presargonic and Ur III. Acta Sumerologica 2:81125.
of civilization in the Indus Valley. Scientific American 243: m a n n , m . 1986. The sources of social power. Vol. 1. Cam-
12233. bridge: Cambridge University Press.
j o h n s o n , g . a . 1987. The changing organization of Uruk ad- m a r c u s , j . 1992. Dynamic cycles of Mesoamerican states. Re-
ministration in the Susiana Plain, in The archaeology of search and Exploration 8:392411.
western Iran. Edited by F. Hole, pp. 10739. Washington, D.C.: . 1998. The peaks and valleys of ancient states: An exten-
Smithsonian Institution Press. sion of the dynamic model, in Archaic states. Edited by G.
. 198889. Late Uruk in Greater Mesopotamia: Expansion Feinman and J. Marcus, pp. 5994. Santa Fe: School of Ameri-
or collapse? Origini 14:595611. can Research Press.
j o n e s , l . s . , a n d s . a . s c h u m m . 1999. Causes of avul- m a r g u e r o n , j . c . 1992. Les bois dans larchitecture: Premier
sion: An overview, in Fluvial sedimentology 6. Edited by N. essai pour une estimation des besoins dans le bassin mesopota-
D. Smith and J. Rogers, pp. 17178. International Association mienne. Bulletin on Sumerian Architecture 6:7996.
of Sedimentologists Special Publication 26. [tjw] m a t t h i a e , p . 1988. On the economic foundations of the
k n a p p , a . b . , a n d w. a s h m o r e . 1999. Archaeological Early Syrian culture of Ebla, in Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft
landscapes: Constructed, conceptualized, ideational, in Ar- von Ebla. Edited by H. Waetzoldt and H. Hauptmann, pp.
chaeologies of landscapes: Contemporary perspectives. Edited 7580. Heidelberg: Heidelberger Orientverlag.
by W. Ashmore and A. Bernard Knapp, pp. 130. Oxford: Black- m e i j e r , d . w. 1986. A survey in northeastern Syria. Istanbul:
well. [abk] Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut te Istanbul. [jo]
k o h l , p . l . 1987a. The ancient economy, transferable tech- m i c h a l o w s k i , p . 1986. Mental maps and ideology: Reflec-
nologies, and the Bronze Age world-system: A view from the tions on Subartu, in The origins of cities in dry-farming Syria
northeastern frontier of the ancient Near East, in Centre and and Mesopotamia in the third millennium b.c. Edited by H.
periphery in the ancient world. Edited by M. Rowlands, M. T. Weiss, pp. 12956. Guilford, Conn.: Four Quarters Publishing.
Larsen, and K. Kristiansen, pp. 1324. Cambridge: Cambridge m o k y r , j . 1990. The lever of riches: Technological creativity
University Press. and economic progress. New York: Oxford University Press.
. 1987b. The use and abuse of world systems theory: The . 2000. Evolutionary phenomena in technological
case of the pristine West Asian state. Advances in Archaeolog- change, in Technological innovation as an evolutionary pro-
ical Method and Theory 11:136. cess. Edited by J. Ziman, pp. 5265. Cambridge: Cambridge
k o h l m e y e r , k . 1997. Habuba Kabira, The Oxford encyclo- University Press.
pedia of archaeology in the Near East. Edited by E. Meyers, pp. m o o r e y, p . r . s . 1994. Ancient Mesopotamian materials and
44648. New York: Oxford University Press. industries: The archaeological evidence. Oxford: Clarendon
k o u c h o u k o s , n . 1998. Landscape and social change in Late Press.
Prehistoric Mesopotamia. Ph.D. diss., Yale University, New m o r o z o v a , g . s . , a n d n . d . s m i t h . 2000. Holocene avul-
Haven, Conn. sion styles and sedimentation patterns of the Saskatchewan
k u r t z , d . v. 1987. The economics of urbanization and state River, Cumberland Marshes, Canada. Sedimentary Geology
formation at Teotihuacan. current anthropology 28:32940. 130:81105. [tjw]
l a m b e r g - k a r l o v s k y, c . c . 1996. Beyond the Tigris and m u l l e r - k a r p e , m . 1991. Aspects of early metallurgy in
Euphrates: Bronze Age civilizations. Jerusalem: Ben Gurion Mesopotamia, in Archaeometry 90. Edited by E. Pernicka and
University of the Negev Press. G. A. Wagner, pp. 10516. Basel: Birkhauser Verlag.
. 1999. Households, land tenure, and communication sys- n i s s e n , h . j . - j . 1970. Grabung in den Planquadraten K/L XII
tems in the 6th4th millennia of Greater Mesopotamia, in in Uruk-Warka. Baghdader Mitteilungen 5:10192.
Urbanization and land ownership in the ancient Near East. . 1976. Zur Frage der Arbeitsorganisation in Babylonien
Edited by M. Hudson and B. Levine, pp. 167201. Cambridge: wahrend der Spat-uruk-Zeit, in Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft
Peabody Museum of Archaeology and Ethnology. in Alten Vorderasien. Edited by J. Harmatta and G. Komar-
l a r s e n , m . t . 1987. Commercial networks in the ancient oczy, pp. 514. Budapest: Akademiai Kiado.
Near East, in Centre and periphery in the ancient world. Ed- . 1977. Aspects of the development of early cylinder
ited by M. Rowlands, M. T. Larsen, and K. Kristiansen, pp. seals, in Seals and sealings in the ancient Near East. Edited
4756. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. by McG. Gibson and R. Biggs, pp. 1524. Malibu: Undena.
l e b e a u , m . 1990. Esquisse dune histoire de la Haute Mesopo- . 1986. The Archaic Texts from Uruk. World Archaeology
tamie au debut d lAge du Bronze. Zeitschrift fur Assyriologie 17:31734.
80:24196. . 1988. The early history of the ancient Near East. Chi-
l i c h b a c h , m . i . 1996. The cooperators dilemma. Ann Arbor: cago: University of Chicago Press.
University of Michigan Press. . 1995. Kulturelle und politische Netzwerke des 4. und 3.
l i v e r a n i , m . 1988 (1983). Fragments of possible counting and vorchr. Jahrtausends im Vorderen Orient, in Beitrage zur Kul-
recording devices. Origini 12:51121. turfeschichte Vorderasiens (Festschrift Boehmer). Edited by U.
l i v i n g s t o n e , d . n . 1992. The geographical tradition: Epi- Finkbeiner, R. Dittmann, and H. Hauptmann. Mainz: Zabern.
sodes in the history of a contested enterprise. Oxford: Basil [hjn]
Blackwell. . 1999. Geschichte Altvorderasiens. Munchen: Oldenbourg.
m c c o r r i s t o n , j . 1997. The fiber revolution: Textile extensi- [hjn]

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
232 F c u r r e n t a n t h ro p o l o g y Volume 42, Number 2, April 2001

n i s s e n , h . - j . , p . d a m e r o w, a n d r . k . e n g l u n d . 1993. ture: A critique of the theory of progressive salinization. Zeit-


Archaic bookkeeping. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. schrift fur Assyriologie 75:738.
n o w l a n , d . 1997. Jane Jacobs among the economists, in reichart, g. j., m. den hulk, h. j. visser, c. h. van
Ideas that matter: The worlds of Jane Jacobs. Edited by M. Al- d e r w e i j d e n , a n d w. j . z a c h a r i a s s e . 1997. A 225 kyr
len, pp. 11113. Owen Sound, Ont.: Ginger Press. record of dust supply, paleoproductivity, and the oxygen mini-
n u t z e l , w. 1976. The climate changes of Mesopotamia and mum zone from the Murray Ridge (Northern Arabian Sea). Pa-
bordering areas. Sumer 32:1124. leogeography, Paleoclimatology, Paleoecology 133:14969.
o a t e s , j o a n . 1993. Trade and power in the fifth and fourth r e i c h e l , c . 1997. Changes in the plain levels of Babylonia and
millennia b.c.: New evidence from northern Mesopotamia. the Diyala region from 6000 b.c. onwards: A view from exca-
World Archaeology 24:40322. vated sites. Paper presented at the 64th Rencontre Assyriolo-
. 1994. Comment on: The structure and dynamics of dry- gique, Venice.
farming states in Upper Mesopotamia, by T. J. Wilkinson. cur- r e n f r e w, c . , a n d j . f . c h e r r y. Editors. 1986. Peer polity
rent anthropology 35:51011. [jo] interaction and socio-political change. Cambridge: Cambridge
. 1996. A prehistoric communication revolution. Cam- University Press.
bridge Archaeological Journal 6:16576. [jo] r i n d o s , d . 1986. The evolution of the capacity for culture: So-
o a t e s , j . , a n d d . o a t e s . 1993. Excavations at Tell Brak ciobiology, structuralism, and cultural selection. current an-
199293. Iraq 55:15599. thropology 27:31531. [jm]
. 1994. Tell Brak: A stratigraphic summary. Iraq 56: r o t h m a n , m . 1993. Another look at the Uruk expansion
16776. from the Tigris Piedmont, in Between the rivers and over the
. 1997. An open gate: Cities of the fourth millennium b.c. mountains: Archaeologica Anatolica et Mesopotamica Alba
(Tell Brak 1997). Cambridge Archaeological Journal 7:287307. Palmieri Dedicata. Edited by M. Frangipane, H. Hauptmann,
o b r i a n , m . l . Editor. 1996. Evolutionary archaeology. Salt M. Liverani, P. Matthiae, and M. Mellink, pp. 16376. Rome:
Lake City: University of Utah Press. [jm] Universita di Roma La Sapienza.
p a l m i e r i , a . , a . h a u p t m a n n , a n d k . h e s s . 1997. The . 1994. Seal and sealing findspot, design audience, and
metal objects from the royal tomb dating to 3000 b.c. at Ar- function: Monitoring changes in administrative oversight and
slantepe (Malatya): A new alloy (CU-AG). Arkeometri Sonu- structure at Tepe Gawra during the fourth millennium b.c.,
clari Toplantisi 13:11522. in Archives before writing. Edited by P. Ferioli, E. Fiandra, G.
p a r k , t . 1992. Early trends toward class stratification: Chaos, Fissore, and M. Frangipane, pp. 97119. Rome: Scriptorium.
common property, and flood recession agriculture. American . Editor. 2001. Uruk Mesopotamia and its neighbors:
Anthropologist 94:90117. Cross-cultural interactions and their consequences in the era
p e r r i n d e b r i c h a m b a u t , g . , a n d c . c . w a l l e n . 1963. of state formation. Santa Fe: School of American Research
A study of agroclimatology in semi-arid and arid zones of the Press.
Near East. Geneva: World Metereological Organization. r o u a u l t , o . , a n d m . g . m a s s e t t i - r o u a u l t . 1993.
p e t i t - m a i r e , n . , p . s a n l a v i l l e , a n d z . w. y a n . 1995. LEufrate e il tempo: Le civilta del medio Eufrate e della Ge-
Oscillations de la limite nord du domaine des moussons afri- zira siriana. Milano: Electa.
caine, indienne, et asiatique, au cours du dernier cycle clima- r u s s e l l , k . 1988. After Eden: The behavioral ecology of early
tique. Bulletin de la Societe Geologique de France 166:21320. food production in the Near East and North Africa. British Ar-
p i t t m a n , h . 1993. Pictures of an administration: The Late chaeological Reports International Series 391.
Uruk scribe at work, in Between the rivers and over the s a h l i n s , m a r s h a l l . 1974. Stone Age economics. London:
mountains: Archaeologica Anatolica et Mesopotamica Alba Tavistock. [ccl]
Palmieri Dedicata. Edited by M. Frangipane, H. Hauptmann, s a n l a v i l l e , p . 1989. Considerations sur levolution de la
M. Liverani, P. Matthiae, and M. Mellink, pp. 23546. Rome: basse Mesopotamie au cours des derniers millenaires. Paleo-
Universita di Roma La Sapienza. rient 15:527.
p o l a n y i , k . 1957. The economy as instituted process, in s a u r e n , h . 1966. Topographie der Provinz Umma, nach der
Trade and markets in the early empires. Edited by K. Polanyi Urkunden der Zeit III. Dynastie von Ur. Vol. 1. Kanale und
et al., pp. 24369. Chicago: Henry Regnery. Bewasserungsanlagen. Bamberg: K. Urlaub.
p o l l o c k , s . 1992. Bureaucrats and managers, peasants and s c h w a r t z , g . 1988. Excavations at Karatut Mevkii and per-
pastoralists, imperialists and traders: Research on the Uruk spectives on the Uruk/Jemdet Nasr expansion. Akkadica 56:
and Jemdet Nasr periods in Mesopotamia. Journal of World 141.
Prehistory 6:297336. s c h w a r t z , m . , d . h o l l a n d e r , a n d g . s t e i n . 1999. Re-
. 2001. The Uruk period in southern Mesopotamia, in constructing Mesopotamian exchange networks in the 4th mil-
Uruk Mesopotamia and its neighbors: Cross-cultural interac- lennium b.c.: Geochemical and archaeological analyses of bitu-
tions and their consequences in the era of state formation. Ed- men artifacts from Hacinebi Tepe, Turkey. Paleorient 25:6782.
ited by M. Rothman. Santa Fe: School of American Research s c r a n t o n , p . 1994. Determinism and indeterminacy in the
Press. history of technology, in Does technology drive history? Ed-
p o s t g a t e , j . n . 1988. A view from down the Euphrates, in ited by M. R. Smith and L. Marx, pp. 14368. Cambridge: MIT
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft von Ebla. Edited by H. Waetzoldt Press.
and H. Hauptmann, pp. 11120. Heidelberg: Orientverlag. s i ro c k o , f . , m . s a r n t h e i n , h . e r i e n k e u z e r , h .
. 1994. How many Sumerians per hectare? Probing the l a n g e , m . a r n o l d , a n d j . d u p l e s s y. 1993. Century-
anatomy of an early city. Cambridge Archaeological Journal 4: scale events in monsoonal climate over the past 24,000 years.
4765. Nature 364:32224.
p o t t s , d . t . 1986. Rethinking some aspects of trade in the s m i t h , a . 1954 (1776) The wealth of nations. New York: E. P.
Arabian Gulf. World Archaeology 24:42340. [jo] Dutton.
. 1997. Mesopotamian civilization: The material founda- s n o o k s , g . d . 1996. The dynamic society. London: Routledge.
tions. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. s o l l b e r g e r , e . , a n d j . - r . k u p p e r . 1971. Inscriptions roy-
p o u r n e l l e , j . 1999. The Mesopotamian heartland revisited: ales sumeriennes et akkadiennes. Paris: Editions du Cerf.
Tentative identification of 4th3rd millennium Tigris and Eu- s p e n c e r , h . 1967 (1876, 1882). The evolution of society: Selec-
phrates channels in Sumer and Akkad. MS, Department of An- tions from Herbert Spencers Principles of sociology. Edited by
thropology, University of California, San Diego. R. L. Carneiro. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
. 2000. The littoral origins of Near Eastern civilization. s t a r r , h a r v e y. 1978. Opportunity and willingness as or-
MS, Department of Anthropology, University of California, San dering concepts in the study of war. International Interactions
Diego. 4:36387. [cc]
p o w e l l , m . 1985. Salt, seed, and yields in Sumerian agricul- s t e i n , g . 1999. Rethinking world systems: Diasporas, colonies,

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a l g a z e Initial Social Complexity in Southwestern Asia F 233

and interaction in Uruk Mesopotamia. Tucson: University of w i l k i n s o n , t . j . 1990a. Town and country in southeastern
Arizona Press. Anatolia. Vol. 1. Settlement and land use at Kurban Hoyuk
s t e i n , g . , a n d p . w a t t e n m a k e r . 1990. The 1987 Tell and other sites in the Lower Karababa Basin. Chicago: Orien-
Leilan regional survey: A preliminary report, in Economy and tal Institute.
settlement in the Near East: Analyses of ancient sites and ma- . 1990b. Early channels and landscape development around
terials. Edited by N. Miller, pp. 818. Philadelphia: MASCA. Abu Salabikh: A preliminary report. Iraq 52:7584.
s t e i n k e l l e r , p . 1998. The historical background of Urkesh . 1994. The structure and dynamics of dry-farming states
and the Hurrian beginnings in northern Mesopotamia, in Ur- in Upper Mesopotamia. current anthropology 35:483520.
kesh and the Hurrians: Studies in honor of Lloyd Cotsen. Ed- . 1995. Late Assyrian settlement geography in Upper
ited by G. Buccellati and M. K. Buccellati, pp. 7598. Malibu: Mesopotamia, in Neo-Assyrian geography. Edited by M. Liver-
Undena. ani, pp. 13959. Rome: Universita di Roma La Sapienza.
. 1999. Archaic city seals and the question of early Baby- . 1997. Environmental fluctuations, agricultural produc-
lonian unity, in Thorkild Jacobsen Memorial Volume. Edited tion, and collapse: A view from Bronze Age Upper Mesopota-
by Tzvi Abusch, pp. 112. New Haven: American Oriental mia, in Third millennium b.c. climate change and Old World
Society. collapse. Edited by H. Nuzhet Dalfes, G. Kukla, and H. Weiss,
s t o n e , e . 1997. City-states and their centers: The Mesopota-
pp. 67106. Berlin: Springer Verlag.
mian example, in The archaeology of city-states. Edited by D.
. 1998. Tell Beydar survey, in The Oriental Institute:
L. Nichols and T. H. Charlton, pp. 1526. Washington, D.C.:
19971998, annual report, pp. 1928. Chicago: Oriental
Smithsonian Institution Press.
s t r a y e r , j o s e p h r . 1970. On the medieval origins of the Institute.
modern state. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [ccl] . 1999. Holocene valley fills of southern Turkey and north-
s t r o n a c h , d . 1994. Village to metropolis: Nineveh and the western Syria: Recent geoarchaeological contributions. Quater-
beginnings of urbanism in northern Mesopotamia, in Nuove nary Science Reviews 18:55571.
fondazioni nel vicino oriente antico: Realta e ideologia. Edited . 2000a. Regional approaches to Mesopotamian archae-
by S. Mazzoni, pp. 84114. Pisa: Giardini Editori. ology: The contribution of archaeological surveys. Journal of
s u r e n h a g e n , d . 1986. The dry-farming belt: The Uruk pe- Archaeological Research 8:21967. [tjw]
riod and subsequent developments, in The origins of cities in . 2000b. Remote sensing and geographical information
dry-farming Syria and Mesopotamia in the third millennium systems, in The Oriental Institute: 19992000 annual report,
b.c. Edited by H. Weiss, pp. 743. Guilford, Conn.: Four Quar- pp. 12330. Chicago: Oriental Institute.
ters Publishing. w i l k i n s o n , t . j . , a n d d . j . t u c k e r . 1995. Settlement de-
t o b l e r , a . j . 1950. Excavations at Tepe Gawra. Vol. 2. Phila- velopment in the north Jazira, Iraq: A study of the archaeolog-
delphia: University Museum. ical landscape. London: British School of Archaeology in Iraq.
t u r k e s , m . 1996. Spatial and temporal analysis of annual rain- w r i g h t , g . a . 1969. Obsidian analyses and prehistoric Near
fall variations in Turkey. International Journal of Climatology Eastern trade: 75003500 b.c. Ann Arbor: University of Michi-
16:105776. gan, Museum of Anthropology.
v a n d e m i e r o o p , m . 1997. The ancient Mesopotamian city. w r i g h t , h . t . 1979. Toward an explanation of the origin of
Oxford: Clarendon Press. the state, in The origin of the state: The anthropology of po-
v a n z e i s t , w. , a n d s . b o t t e m a . 1991. Late Quaternary litical evolution. Edited by R. Cohen and E. Service, pp. 4968.
vegetation of the Near East. Wiesbaden: Dr. Ludwig Reichert Philadelphia: Institute for the Study of Human Issues.
Verlag. w r i g h t , h . t . , a n d g . a . j o h n s o n . 1975. Population,
v e r h o e v e n , k . 1998. Geomorphological research in the Mes- exchange, and early state formation in southwestern Iran.
opotamian flood plain, in Changing water courses in Babylo- American Anthropologist 77:26789.
nia: Towards a reconstruction of the ancient environment in w r i g h t , h . t . , a n d e . r u p l e y. 2001. Calibrated radiocar-
lower Mesopotamia. Edited by Hermann Gasche and Michel bon age determinations of Uruk-related assemblages, in Uruk
Tanret, pp. 159245. Ghent: University of Ghent/Chicago: Mesopotamia and its neighbors: Cross-cultural interactions
Oriental Institute. [tjw] and their consequences in the era of state formation. Edited
v o n w i c k e d e , a . 1990. Prahistorische Stempel Glyptic in
by M. Rothman. Santa Fe: School of American Research Press.
Vorderasien. Munich: Profil Verlag.
w r i g h t , r . 2000. Nonzero: The logic of human destiny. New
w a e t z o l d t , h . 1972. Untersuchungen zur neusumerischen
York: Pantheon Books.
Textilindustrie. Rome: Centro per le Antichita e la Storia
dellArte del Vicino Oriente. y e n e r , k . a . 1980. Third millennium b.c. interregional trade
w a r d - p e r k i n s , j . b . 1964. Landscape and history in central in southwest Asia with special reference to the Keban Region
Italy. Oxford: Clarendon Press. [abk] of Turkey. Ph.D. diss., Columbia University, New York, N.Y.
w e i s s , h . 1983. Excavations at Tell Leilan and the origins of y o f f e e , n . 1981. Explaining trade in the ancient Near East.
north Mesopotamian cities in the third millennium b.c. Paleo- Malibu: Undena.
rient 9:3952. . 1995. Political economy in early Mesopotamian states.
. 1986. The origins of Tell Leilan and the conquest of Annual Review of Anthropology 24:281311.
space in third millennium north Mesopotamia, in The origins z a r i n s , j . 1989. The early utilization of indigo along the
of cities in dry-farming Syria and Mesopotamia in the third northern Indian Ocean rim, in South Arabian archaeology.
millennium b.c. Edited by H. Weiss, pp. 71108. Guilford, Edited by C. Jarrige, pp. 46983. Paris: CNRS. [jm]
Conn.: Four Quarters Publishing. z i m a n , j . 2000. Evolutionary models for technological
. 1990. Tell Leilan 1989: New data for mid-third-millen- change, in Technological innovation as an evolutionary pro-
nium urbanization and state formation. Mitteilungen der cess. Edited by J. Ziman, pp. 312. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
Deutschen Orient-Gesellschaft 122:193218. versity Press.

This content downloaded from 23.235.32.0 on Fri, 4 Dec 2015 17:04:18 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Вам также может понравиться