Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 16

Semiglobalization and International Business Strategy

Author(s): Pankaj Ghemawat


Source: Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 34, No. 2, Focused Issue: The Future of
Multinational Enterprise: 25 Years Later (Mar., 2003), pp. 138-152
Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3557149 .
Accessed: 22/06/2011 12:19

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at .
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=pal. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Palgrave Macmillan Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of
International Business Studies.

http://www.jstor.org
X1. Journalof International
BusinessStudies(2003)34, 138-152
ll*~~tr-~ 2003 PalgraveMacmillan
0~?C) Ltd. Allrightsreserved0047-2506 $25.00
www.jibs.net

and international business


Semiglobalization
strategy

PankajGhemawat Abstract
If markets were either completely isolated by or integrated across borders,
HarvardBusinessSchool,Boston,MA,USA there would be little room for international business strategy to have content
distinctive from 'mainstream' strategy. But a review of the economic evidence
Correspondence: about the international integration of markets indicates that we fall in between
Dr P Ghemawat, Harvard Business School,
these extremes, into a state of incomplete cross-border integration that I refer
Soldiers Field Road, Morgan Hall 227,
to as semiglobalization. More specifically, most measures of market integration
Boston, MA 02163, USA.
Tel: +1-617-495-6275; have scaled new heights in the last few decades, but still fall far short of
Fax: +1-617-495-0355; economic theory's ideal of perfect integration. The diagnosis of semiglobaliza-
E-mail: pghemawat@hbs.edu tion does more than just supply a relatively stable frame of reference for
thinking about the environment of cross-border operations. It also calls
attention to the critical role of location-specificity in the prospects of distinctive
content for international business strategy relative to mainstream business and
corporate strategy. In addition, it flags factors/products subject to location-
specificity as being salient from the perspective of international business.
Finally, it highlights the scope for strategies that strive to capitalize on the
(large) residual barriersto cross-border integration, as well as those that simply
try to cope with them.
journal of International Business Studies (2003) 34, 138-152. doi:10.1057/
palgrave.jibs.840001 3

Keywords: semiglobalization;globalizationmarketintegrations;marketinperfections;
firmstrategy
location/location-specificity;

Introduction
The first of the three postulates on which Buckley and Casson
(1976, 32) based their theory of the multinational enterprise was
that 'firms maximize profit in a world of imperfect markets.' This
structural insight has proved as fruitful in international business
strategy as it has in 'mainstream' (single-country) business strategy,
where it has been in circulation for even longer. What is somewhat
odd, however, is that work in this vein in international business
strategy has tended to focus on the same sources of market
imperfections as mainstream business strategy: small numbers and,
often related, the business/usage-specificityof key activities,
resources, competencies, capabilities, knowledge, etc., or their
firm-specificityin the sense of being collectively held by the firm's
managerial hierarchy or employee pool and inalienable from it.
However, the obvious potential source of market imperfections
added by the international dimension - the possibly limited cross-
Received: September 2001
Revised: June 2002
border integration of markets or, more generally, the possible
Accepted: August 2002 location-specificityof key activities, resources, etc. - has received less
Online publication date: 27 March 2003 attention. Location-specificity of the specific sort wrought by
Semiglobalization and international business strateqy PankajI Ghemawat
139

market segmentation at national boundaries is at be granted elevated status. Finally, the essay high-
the core of this paper.1 lights the scope for strategies that strive to capita-
This paper consists of two halves. The first half lize on the (large) residual barriers to cross-border
contains a broad - and therefore inevitably com- integration, as well as those that simply try to cope
pressed - review of the empirical evidence on the with such barriers.The treatment is meant as much
cross-border integration of markets of different to stimulate and direct further research as to
types: for products (via both trade and FDI), capital, summarize research efforts to date.
labor, and knowledge. The review points to the It is worth adding that the first half of this paper -
conclusions that, on the one hand, the observed the next two sections - focuses on reviewing the
levels of cross-border integration of these types of economic evidence about the cross-borderintegra-
markets are significant and in many cases have tion of markets of different types. The economic
recently reached highs without historical prece- perspective is adopted because economics offers
dent, but that, on the other hand, the observed both a relatively well-developed conceptual frame-
levels of cross-border integration are also very far work for the analysis of market integration and
from complete and, extrapolating from historical some empirical basis for making judgments about
rates of increase (not to mention recent setbacks), levels of and changes in cross-borderintegration of
are likely to remain that way for a long time. This the kinds that occupy its attention. Thus the next
condition of incomplete cross-border integration, section of this paper looks at the cross-border
referred to here as semiglobalization, is more com- integration of product markets, and the section that
plex than the extremes of total insulation and total follows at markets for various types of resource or
integration because it involves situations in which factor - capital, labor, and knowledge. The questions
the barriers to market integration at borders are asked about each type of market concern changes in
high, but not high enough to insulate countries its level of international integration, measured in
completely from each other. Another way of putting terms of quantity and price outcomes, over recent
this is that semiglobalization covers the range - decades or the course of the 20th century, as well as
apparently broad as well as complex - of situations its absolute level of international integration at the
in which neither the barriersnor the links among millennium. Fora more specific delineation of what
markets in different countries can be neglected. is included in and excluded from the review, see
The second half of this paper can be read as a Table 1. While there is arguably a logic to the
short essay on the implications of the empirical pattern of inclusions and exclusions, the more
finding of semi-globalization for international fundamental point is simply that one cannot talk
business strategy. It begins by noting that semi- about everything in Table 1 in a paper of this scope.
globlization is a sufficient condition for location-
specificity to matter. Although complete market Product market integration
insulation also suffices, it is a less challenging
condition since, under it, international business This section begins by looking at the most obvious
strategy could simply be chunked up into applica- quantity measure of the cross-borderintegration of
tions of mainstream (that is, single-location) strat-
Table I Dimensions of integration
egy, performed location by location - although
some problems of coordination would still remain. Dimension Possible
Thus semi-globlalization is the underlying structur- emphases
al condition most conducive to thinking in careful
Criteria for evaluating _ Non-economic
ways about competing across multiple locations integration
and how that might differ from competing at a Key boundaries Others
single location. The essay elaborates on this and Continents/regions
other, more specific, implications of the general Localities
diagnosis of semi-globalization. It discusses the Locus of integration Others
balance to be struck in international business Firms
Networks
strategy between attention to location-specificity
and other types of-specificity, and examines the Type of markets .S .
Input/output emphasis 0 . - D
conditions under which imperfections in particular Outcome variables -
:.S -' ..
types of market (especially knowledge, which was
emphasized by Buckley and Casson, 1976) should Darkshading = primaryemphasis. Gray shading = secondary emphasis.

journal of International Business Studies


* 14-
ra0l
JC|0|lVVIIIII
SOMinlnhAI;7Atl;nn
IIILIUII
1
angi
U inti
IlIL
rnatnnanl
IILIIIIUonal
hime;nipec
C
LI
etr:tionv
z ILCy, PAnleAi
j illll
r.homAwAlt

140

18 for the ratio of merchandise trade to total GDP are


16 - increases for only six of the 11 countries, a median
14 -
change of +2 percentage points from an initial
12 - median value of 20%, and total unweighted
10- increases less than one-half as large as total
8-
,-??i
unweighted decreases.
6' One interpretation of the historical patterns is
4- that:
2
. . . . . (1) trade had taken off in many commodities by the
1820 1840 1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 beginning of the 20th century;
Year
Source: 1820-1992: Angus Maddison, Monitoringthe WorldEconomy 1820-1992, OECD 1995 1993-1998: (2) there were substantial increases in the trade of
World Trade Organization and InternationalMonetary Fund data.
manufactures over the course of the 20th
Figure 1 Exports divided by GDP. Source: 1820-1992, Maddi- century, particularly its second half; and
son (1995); 1993-1998, World Trade Organization and Inter- (3) the service sector continues to be a very large
national Monetary Fund data. bottleneck for trade-relatedflows even though it
is growing.
product markets: trade flows. It then looks at
Irwin's (1996) comparison of the composition of
foreign direct investment (FDI) stocks and, finally
and very briefly, at cross-borderprice integration. US merchandise trade over a century is suggestive
in this regard:see Table 2. While this neat ordering
of the globalization of commodities, manufactures
Trade flows and services is obviously an oversimplification, it is
To begin with a very long-run perspective, consider nevertheless useful.
data on world exports divided by world GDP (the So trade has clearly increased over the last 50, 100
usual normalization) over the last two centuries and 200 years. But it is useful to supplement this
based on and updated from data in Maddison observation with some data about the absolute
(1995). As Figure 1 indicates, this ratio increased level of integration of product markets through
from about 1%at the beginning of the 19th century trade. Economists who study international trade
to nearly 10% towards the beginning of the 20th
generally do not regard trade intensity as very high
century, and, despite a period of stagnation and in absolute terms. In fact, they tend to find the
decline bounded by the two World Wars, has since issue of why there is not much more trade more
managed to edge up towards 20%. Trade intensity interesting than the new records being set. To see
has clearly reached new heights in the last quarter the room for increase, consider a hypothetical
of the 20th century.
benchmark, suggested by Frankel (2001), in which
The increase in trade intensity over the course of national borders did not affect buying patterns at
the 20th century looks all the more remarkable all. In such a situation, buyers in a particularnation
when one accounts for the increasing share of GDP
contributed, especially in developed countries, by
two sectors that account for relatively little trade - Table 2 Commodity composition of US merchandise trade
services and government. One way of stripping out
Year Percentage distribution
the effects of these 'non-traded' sectors is to remove
them from the calculations and focus on the ratio Exports Imports
of merchandise trade to merchandise value added.
This leads to striking increases in measured trade Agricultural goods
1890 42.2 33.1
exposure, as illustrated by Feenstra's(1998) sample 1990 11.5 5.6
of 11 relatively developed countries between 1913
Raw materials
and 1990. Over this period, the ratio of merchan- 1890 36.6 22.8
dise trade to merchandise value added increased for 1990 11.6 14.8
nine of these countries; the median change was Manufactures
+22 percentage points, compared with an initial 1890 21.2 44.1
median value of 36%, and total unweighted 1990 77.0 79.6
increases were close to 20 times as large as total Figures may not total to 100 due to rounding. Agriculturalgoods
unweighted decreases. The corresponding statistics includes processed foods. Source:Irwin(1996).

Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies
Semiqlobalization and international business strateqy PankajI Ghemawat
141
141

100
95-
border and language (mostly) and have friendly
90- relations with each other, making theirs the
85
80- largest bilateral trading relationship in the world
(McCallum, 1995). The free trade agreement signed
-_ 75-
I
70-
* BEL
;
C
65-
60-
I in 1988 between the two countries did reduce this
C 55-
. I
domestic multiple by the mid-1990s, but only to 12
50- NET

4 45- (and with the multiple remaining stuck at 30-40 in


40-

MEX
*CAN
WSWE
the case of services) (Helliwell, 1998, Chapter 2).
SWI - --: KOR
JK
Cruderdata suggest a multiple of about six for trade
: GER
within as opposed to between the member states of
SP
RUS . o. i.i..
.. FR
AUS :::: CHi IT
10-
ARG
US
I
the European Union (Helliwell, 1998, Chapter 3).
5

0
BR
IBR
I
JAFp

I I I I I Given the regionalization of world trade that has


0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Share of World GDP (%)
70 80 90 100
been under way, the multiples of domestic-to-
Sources:GNP Rankingsbased World Development Bank'sWorld DevelopmentIndicators. international economic exchange would obviously
2000.Import/ExportData from WTO. be higher if one were comparing trade within
Figure 2 Actual vs perfect product market integration through countries with trade outside the regional blocs to
trade. which they belong.
To sum up, trade intensity has clearly reached
would be as prone to obtain goods and services unprecedented levels, but still reveals significant
from foreign producers as from domestic ones, and impediments to the cross-border integration of
the share of imports in total domestic consumption product markets.
would equal 1 minus the nation's share of world
product. For example, as the US economy accounts Foreign direct investment
for about one-quarter of gross world product, the Tradeis not the only way in which the cross-border
US import/GDP ratio would, at this benchmark, integration of product markets might be accom-
equal 1 minus the US share of world production, or plished: FDI, which involves product-specific
0.75, as would, under the first-orderassumption of investment across borders, is an obvious alterna-
balanced trade, the US export/GDP ratio. However, tive. To start with a long-run perspective, consider
the actual ratios are only about one-sixth as large as data on FDI stocks divided by GDP over the last
these hypothetical levels!2 century based on calculations in WorldInvestment
The line with slope -1 in Figure 2 traces out this Reportsissued by the UN Center on Transnational
hypothetical benchmark of perfect product market Corporations. As Table 3 indicates, FDIsurvived the
integration as national shares of world product interwar years better than trade (it even came to
vary. It also plots the position of the 20 largest substitute for the latter as tariff barriers rose), but
nations in these terms. Notice that most of the did not take off again quite as rapidly in the
nations cluster close to the origin, and all fall well immediate postwar years. FDI has surged, however,
below the hypothetical maximum - including the since 1980 and, by 1997, had come to exceed the
two high-fliers, Belgium and the Netherlands. previous (prewar) peak in its share of gross world
While the hypothetical benchmark suggests sig- GDP by a significant margin: 12% to 9%. Despite
nificant barriers to cross-border product flows, it the declines in the ratio of outward FDI stock to
also embodies a number of extreme assumptions. A GDP exhibited by the UK and France, the largest
real example that points in the same direction is foreign investors prior to World War I, the aggre-
provided by Canadian provinces' patterns of trade gate comparison is suggestive of an increase to
with each other compared with their trade with the unprecedented levels. In sectoral terms, FDI has
USA. In addition to the fact that data for these mirrored trade over this time period by shifting
patterns are available, they have the added advan- away from natural resources and raw materials (the
tage of involving (international) trading partners 'primary'sector) towards manufacturing and, more
that are close to each other along a number of recently, services.
dimensions. As of 1988, trade linkages between Obviously, such historical comparisons come
Canadian provinces were 20 times as large as their with some caveats. For one thing, they are affected
linkages with the 30 US states that traded the most in important ways by fundamental shifts in relative
intensively with Canada. This was true despite the exchange rates (and purchasing power). For
fact that Canada and the USAshare a common land another, they are based on book values rather than

Journal of International Business Studies


Semialobalization and international business strateav .PankaiGhemawat
......
*
142 .142. .

Table 3 Outward FDIstock as a percentage of GDP


1914 1938 1960 1980 1985 1990 1995 1997

France 21.1 27.8 6.8 2.7 6.0 9.2 12.0 13.6


Germany 11.1 0.8 1.1 5.3 9.7 9.2 11.1 14.4
Japan 0.8 9.9 1.2 1.9 3.3 6.9 4.7 6.5
UK 52.3 38.5 15.0 15.0 21.9 23.8 28.3 29.1
USA 7.2 8.5 6.2 8.1 6.2 7.9 10.0 10.6
World 9.0a 4.4 4.8 6.4 8.5b 11.8
a1913 data. b1991 data.
Figurefor 191 3 is an estimate. Sources:1913-1991, World Investment Report 1994; 1997, World Investment Report 1999.

on market values of FDI. The magnitude of this 100.0-

omission seems to be large: data compiled by the 90.0'

US Commerce Department suggest that measure- 80.0

ment on the basis of market values rather than 70.0

book values doubles the estimated values of both -


60.0
US FDI abroad and FDI in the USA. One could argue >, 50.0
SWE
a, " NET
that this omission leads to greater underestimation (5
.E
C~ 40.0' BEL
of the true values of FDI stocks towards the end of u.
30.0 UK
the 20th century than towards its beginning, BR
because of higher inflation rates (until relatively MEX 20.0
ARG
xCAN
- "
CH
AUS
RUS
KOR
swI 10.0 +I FR
recently) in the modern period and the increased SP- IN; GER JAP & US
I'l
importance of intangible assets that are more prone u.u
0.0
I
10.0
',
20.0 30.0
...
40.0
.
50.0
.
60.0
.
70.0
.
80.0 90.0
-

100.0
to slip through accountants' nets. Share of World GFI
Source: EIU Country Data
Once again, it is useful to look at the current level
of integration of product markets through this Figure 3 Actual vs perfect product market integration through
channel in absolute terms, not just in relation to FDI. Source: EIU country data.
the levels experienced earlier. Assume, as in the
analogous calculation undertaken earlier for trade, perfect cross-border integration of product markets
that inflows/outflows are, to a first approximation, through this channel.
balanced, and consider a country that accounts for
x% of world investment. Then, if national borders Price integration
did not affect investment patterns at all, foreign Viewed in terms of prices rather than quantities,
capital would account for (100-x)% of total the ultimate in market integration is achieved
investment in that country. The line with slope when two (or more) markets are yoked together
-1 in Figure 3 traces out this hypothetical bench- by the so-called law of one price (LOP) - that is,
mark of perfect integration as a function of national prices equalize across them. Implicit in LOP is a
shares of gross fixed investment (x). It also plots the (strong) zero-arbitrage-profits principle. Note that
position of the 20 largest nations in these terms, the degree of price integration of product markets
based on their recorded FDI inflows. As in the case can be high even when the quantity flows across
of trade, most of the nations cluster close to the them are limited - for example, for some commod-
origin, and all fall well below the hypothetical ities whose local prices are pegged to world
maximum. Also note that this broad conclusion benchmark prices, including ones with high value-
would not be affected by looking at FDI outflows, to-weight ratios. As a result, economists often treat
although the positions of individual countries tests of market integration based on prices as being
would shift substantially. China, for instance, more definitive than tests based on quantities.
would be less of a high-flier. Quantity-based tests of cross-border market inte-
Overall, FDI intensity has, like trade intensity, gration predominate, nonetheless, because, except
reached unprecedented levels while continuing to for (nearly) perfect commodities, tests of price
fall far short of the levels that would be implied by integration are generally hampered by the lack of

Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies
Semiqlobalization and international business strateqy PankajGhemawat
143

data on local currency prices of identical products recent decades, but was higher still around the
across countries. The relatively few studies of beginning of the 20th century (see Table 4). Note
products and services that meet these objections that the impressive performance 100 years ago was
generally indicate substantial, sustained departures accomplished in spite of informational and con-
from LOP.Cross-country price dispersions tend to tracting problems. Such problems were, most likely,
be large and to die down at a slow pace, and there is much more severe given the lack of generally
little evidence of recent movement toward smaller accepted accounting principles and commensu-
dispersions or speedier dampening (Rogoff, 1996). rately weak reporting requirements.
In conjunction with the data presented earlier Of course, not all capital flows are equally
concerning integration through trade and FDI important from the perspective of economic globa-
flows, an overall inference that product market lization. In particular, the recent period has seen a
integration has increased significantly in recent surge in short-run flows, or at least transactions,
decades, while continuing to fall far short of that is most strikingly evident in the volume of
perfection, seems most plausible. foreign exchange transactions, which exceeds $1
trillion daily. Foreign exchange trading can, how-
Factor market integration ever, be regarded as a response to a source of
Product markets are not the only type of market volatility - exchange rate risk - that was mitigated
whose cross-border integration one might find significantly in the earlier period by the prevalence
interesting; factor markets of various types are also of the gold standard. For this reason, and because
candidates for attention. This section presents and most trades of this sort seem to be purely spec-
discusses evidence on the extent of cross-border ulative, it is problematic to use the size of foreign
integration of markets for capital, labor, and exchange markets today to infer a much greater
knowledge, in that order. Both quantity-based and level of cross-border integration of capital markets
price-based measures of integration are looked at than at the beginning of the century.
wherever possible. This suggestsfocusing attention on long-run capital
flows, which include portfolio investment as well as
Capital FDI. Portfolio investment has increased significantly
The previous section's discussion of FDI can be in absoluteterms in recent decades,but seems to have
broadened to look at international capital flows failed to keep pace with FDI, with its share slipping
over the last 100 years.3 Because of identities in from about two-thirds of total long-run cross-border
national income accounting, countries' net capital investment in the early 20th century to about one-
flows can be measured as the reverse of their half today (Bloomfield,1968). Nevertheless,the range
current account balances. Data assembled by of securities traded today across borders is much
Obstfeld and Taylor (1997) on absolute net capital broader,in type as well as in number - a shift that,
flows divided by GDPs for 12 countries suggest that some argue,has contributedto increasedcross-border
this index of capital mobility has increased in integration along this dimension.

Table 4 Size of net capital flows since 1870 (mean absolute value of currentaccount as percentage of GDP, annual data)
Period Arg Aus Can Den Fra Ger Ita lap Nor Swe UK USA All

1870-1889 18.7 8.2 7.0 1.9 2.4 1.7 1.2 0.6 1.6 3.2 4.6 0.7 3.7
1890-1913 6.2 4.1 7.0 2.9 1.3 1.5 1.8 2.4 4.2 2.3 4.6 1.0 3.3
1914-1918 2.7 3.4 3.6 5.1 11.6 6.8 3.8 6.5 3.1 4.1 5.1 a
1919-1926 4.9 4.2 2.5 1.2 2.8 2.4 4.2 2.1 4.9 2.0 2.7 1.7 3.1
1927-1931 3.7 5.9 2.7 0.7 1.4 2.0 1.5 0.6 2.0 1.8 1.9 0.7 2.1
1932-1939 1.6 1.7 2.6 0.8 1.0 0.6 0.7 1.0 1.1 1.5 1.1 0.4 1.2
1940-1946 4.8 3.5 3.3 2.3 3.4 1.0 4.9 2.0 7.2 1.1 3.2a
1947-1959 2.3 3.4 2.3 1.4 1.5 2.0 1.4 1.3 3.1 1.1 1.2 0.6 1.8
1960-1973 1.0 2.3 1.2 1.9 0.6 1.0 2.1 1.0 2.4 0.7 0.8 0.5 1.3
1974-1989 1.9 3.6 1.7 3.2 0.8 2.1 1.3 1.8 5.2 1.5 1.5 1.4 2.2
1989-1996 2.0 4.5 4.0 1.8 0.7 2.7 1.6 2.1 2.9 2.0 2.6 1.2 2.3
Source:ObstfeldandTaylor(1997).
a: Average with some countries missing.

Journal of International Business Studies


Semiglobalization and international business strateqy PankajI Ghemawat
144

International financial crises represent the flip side prior to 1914, the breakdown of that integration in
of international capital mobility. Once again, the interwar period, and its slow restoration in the
historical comparisons suggest that international postwar period. Qualitatively similar conclusions
financial crises, particularly in emerging markets, are suggested by comparing real rather than
are not without precedent. Thus data on the nominal returns, although that does increase the
currency and banking crises experienced by 21 standard deviation of the dispersion of returns,
countries between 1880 and 1998 indicate that the presumably reflecting the effects of currency risk,
most severe crises, on average, were in the interwar both nominal and real.5 At a more macro level,
period, followed by the prewar period; postwar studies of returns, such as Bekaert and Harvey
crises, in contrast, have been milder in terms of the (1995), indicate that the cointegration of capital
drops in output experienced, and shorter-lived markets varies greatly in its level and extent over
(Bordo et al., 1999). And even when the sample is time.
restricted to emerging countries, recent levels of Overall, like product market integration, capital
instability do no worse than 'match' prewar levels, market integration has increased significantly in
in which the gold standard acted as a crisis recent decades, but seems to continue to fall far
transmission belt, and emerging countries, at least, short of perfection.
tended to lack lenders of last resort.4
In addition to these historical comparisons,
quantity-based measures also permit some infer- Labor
ences about the absolute level of cross-border Data on the cross-border integration of labor
integration of capital markets. As in the case of markets are sparser than for product or capital
trade, the professional curiosity of economists has markets. However, they generally suggest that the
focused on smaller-than-expected flows (or stocks). number of international migrants (defined as
Probably the most famous 'anomaly' of this sort is people residing in foreign countries for more than
the one uncovered by Feldstein and Horioka (1980), 1 year) has grown with world population in recent
who calculated a 90% correlation between domes- decades, but represents a smaller share of world
tic savings and domestic investment across a panel population than 100 years ago. With regard to the
of countries. Their estimate is much higher than first point, there were, according to the World
benchmark models that assume perfect capital Migration Report, an estimated 150 million long-
mobility would lead us to expect. Another anomaly term international migrants in 2000, or 2.5% of
that points in the same direction concerns what is world population (Martin, 2000). The comparable
called home-country bias: investors in each country numbers for 1965 were 75 million migrants and
hold much largerproportions of their wealth in the 2.2% of world population.
form of domestic securities than they would with Over a longer time frame, the period between
internationally well-diversified portfolios. Thus, by 1880 and 1915/1920 stands out as the heyday of
one estimate, US investors should have held more international migration. During these years, 32
than half their wealth in foreign equities in the million people migrated from Europe, most of
1980s, instead of the less than 10% that they them to the USA (Kenwood and Lougheed, 1989).
actually held (Lewis, 1995). In addition, there were 6-8 million net migrants -
Price-based measures of capital market integra- mostly 'coolie' or indentured labor - from India,
tion - with price integration reinterpreted in terms
of the equalization of rates of return on common or
3.50
comparable securities across national boundaries - 3.00-
supply additional evidence about the continued 2.50 -
segmentation of capital markets. One benchmark 2.00 -
example is provided by Obstfeld and Taylor's(1997) 1.50
comparison of 1-year interest rates on sterling- 1.00-
denominated assets sold in London and in 0.50 -
New York over the last 100-plus years. Figure 4 II IIII
1880 1902 1916 1922 1928 1935 1943 1952 1962 1974 1985 1993
tracks the standard deviation of differences in Source: MauriceObstfeldand AlanTaylor,"TheGreatDepressionAs A Watershed:International
returns in the two cities as an inverse measure of CapitalMobilityOverthe LongRun,"NBERWorkingPaper 5960, March1997.

capital market integration. The data indicate sig- Figure 4 Standard deviation of nominal return differentials.
nificant cross-borderintegration of capital markets Source: Obstfeld and Taylor (1997).

journal of International Business Studies


Semiglobalization and international business strategy Pankaj Ghemawat
145

China, and other Asian countries to the rest of the Taking a somewhat longer view, it is worth
world (Held et al., 1999, 293-295, 311). Adding in emphasizing that the 19th century apparently saw
other cross-bordermovements could push the total a divergence, rather than a convergence, of
past 45 million, or 3% of world population in 1900. incomes across countries that has been only
Higher migration rates 100 years ago are also evident partially reversed in the 20th century (Baldwin
in country-level data - for example, for the largest and Martin, 1999). So, over that kind of time frame,
receiver,the USA.Thus census data indicate that 14% the dispersion of incomes across countries
of the US population was foreign-bornat the turn of increased, in net terms, instead of decreasing. This,
the century,comparedwith 10%today (Dune, 2001). along with the other data presented in this
Note that, through a substantial part of the earlier subsection, would seem to imply skepticism about
period, a number of large receivers, including the the extent to which labor markets have integrated
USA,placed no restrictionson immigration. across national boundaries.
Turning from quantity-based to price-based mea-
sures, the most obvious indicator of cross-border Knowledge
integration of labor markets would be the cross- The other types of cross-border flows that have
border convergence of wages. Data on the evolu- been discussed already can carry knowledge across
tion of average per capita incomes (a rough and national borders as well, since it can be congealed
ready proxy for average wages) indicate that, while in products, embedded in capital equipment,
incomes in industrialized countries have tended to vested in skilled personnel, etc. Given the topics
converge over the last few decades, a few Asian already covered in this paper, this subsection will
'tigers' have been the only countries able to break focus on cross-border flows of knowledge in pure,
away from the rest of the developing world and disembodied form. In addition to rounding out the
catch up with the industrialized world (see coverage, this focus has the advantage of offering a
Figure 5).6 More sophisticated tests confirm this relatively simple benchmark: as disembodied
conclusion, and indicate that the failure of most knowledge has a 'non-rival' character - that is, as
developing countries to catch up can be reconciled its use in one market, whether defined in geo-
only with a weaker notion of convergence - graphic or product-related terms, should not pre-
conditional convergence (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, clude its application to others - perfect cross-border
1995). Conditional convergence allows for differ- integration in this context should imply that
ences in the steady-state incomes toward which knowledge, once developed anywhere in the world,
different economies are trending, based on differ- is available everywhere else as well.
ences along dimensions such as investment, educa- The conceptual simplicity of focusing on disem-
tion, and population growth. Human capital turns bodied knowledge flows does, however, exact an
out, in attempts to fit conditional convergence empirical toll: because of their intrinsic intangibil-
models to the data, to have a particularly marked ity, such flows are particularlyhard to measure. The
effect on the predicted extent of convergence. evidence presented in this subsection is corre-
spondingly sketchy. It tentatively suggests, how-
ever, that there have been substantial increases in
sO18,000
In(tlustrialized Countries
cross-border knowledge flows over time and, a bit
$16.000
,. Asian lTigers*
more definitely, that cross-border integration in
:' :: inciludiesHonLg
S14.000
.
Kollng.
Sollth
Silngapore
Korlca. and
this regard nevertheless remains very incomplete.
Consider these inferences in turn.
With regard to technological knowledge, cross-
S.o00))
border licensing provides one indicator that
supports the inference of increased cross-border
$6.0()0 '- .......... Other D)eveloping
:". - COUl trieS

.48z. . ' Sub-Saharlan Afrl-ica knowledge flows over time. Such licensing is not
$2.000

India
new - international royalties accounted for a
significant component of James Watt's receipts
$()

1950() 1953 1956 1959 1962 1965 196X 1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995

Source: Bruce Scott, Economic Strategies of Nations, adapted from the


from his steam engine patents in the early nine-
PennWorldTablesandthe WorldBank. teenth century, for example. However, the available
Figure 5 Convergence? GDP per capita across economic data, along with informational and contracting
groups, 1950-1997 (PPP-adjusted). Source: Scott (2000), problems that were even more acute early on than
adapted from the Penn WorldTablesand the World Bank). they are now, suggest that the voluntary transfer of

Journal of International Business Studies


* - Vam-SlAl*hAi17tatinn
sIIIILuIa/iV all/ll
anti ;IIILI
aU
-ntornat;innal
n IILI,11
hriMAinpc
oI/IIIsN,
rrsatAnv
L ILtqy Pknie;i (C.h,-mAvAt
ra iKaj 1IncmlVawat
146

knowledge across national borders is far more (Keller, 2000). The importance of locally dense
common than it used to be. Concerning more information flows is also evident in inter-
general managerial knowledge, the post-World War nationally successful geographic clusters.7 Such
II period, in particular,has seen the development of perspectives remind us that, although the avail-
new types of organizations and organizational ability of information transmission capacity may
forms that have also facilitated knowledge transfer. help knowledge to travel across national borders, it
Franchising, which really emerged in its modern is far from sufficient to make knowledge perfectly
form in the USA in the 1950s, is one example. And portable.
management consulting firms, which began their
international expansion at roughly the same time, Semiglobalization as a research program
are regardedas having evolved into major channels In summary, most measures of cross-border eco-
for the international diffusion of new managerial nomic integration have increased significantly in
techniques (Micklethwait and Wooldridge, 2000). the last few decades, but still fall far short of the
Of course, the spread of multinational enterprises, theoretical extreme of total integration. This
intent on applying the same technological and empirical conclusion of semiglobalization is valu-
managerial knowledge to more and more markets, able in and of itself given the ongoing debate
points in the same direction. So, arguably,does the between two polar perspectives: one maintaining
explosion in cross-borderinformation transmission that we have achieved a state of (near) globality, in
capacity since the early 1980s. which there is so much integration across national
These increases in cross-border knowledge flows borders that the latter can, for many practical
notwithstanding, there are also numerous indica- purposes, be ignored, and the other professing
tions of the continued geographical localization of skepticism that there is anything fundamentally
knowledge. The survey evidence on the size of new about the levels of cross-border integration
knowledge transfer costs, although not altogether that have been achieved to date (Giddens, 1996;
satisfying, is suggestive. An influential study by Held et al., 1999). It seems possible to achieve some
Teece (1977) concluded that transfer costs closure to this debate, at least in the economic
accounted for an average of 19% of total project arena.
costs - and ranged from 2 to 59% - in a sample of As a bonus, semiglobalization affords - unlike
technology transfers in the chemicals, petroleum alternate possibilities - room for international
refining, and machinery sectors. Outcome-based business strategy to have content that is distinctive
perspectives that point in the same direction are from 'mainstream' (single country or location)
numerous. Through the 1980s, nearly 90% of the business strategy or, for that matter, corporate
US patents taken out by the world's 600 largest strategy.To make this point as precisely as possible,
corporations listed the inventor as a resident of the it is useful to classify the field of strategy into the
corporation's 'home base' (Patel and Pavitt, 1994). domains depicted in Table 5. Note the somewhat
Patents whose inventors reside in the same country paradoxical character of domain 1, mainstream
are typically 30-80% more likely to cite each other business strategy: by assuming total specificity, it
than inventors from other countries, and, on allots the least attention to understanding either
average, these citations come 1 year sooner (Jaffe business/usage-specificity or location-specificity. As
and Trajtenberg,1999). A recent study of R&D and a result, we have to look to domain 2, that of
productivity spillovers across large OECD econo- mainstream corporate strategy, for interesting ana-
mies estimated the average elasticity of such spil- lyses of variations in the extent to which key firm
lovers with respect to distance as -1 to -2.4% activities, resources or knowledge are business-
Table 5 Strategydomains

Increasingattention to business-specificity/non-specificity
Focus Single business Multiplebusinesses

Increasingattention to Single country/location 1. (Mainstream) 2. (Mainstream)


location-specificity/non-specificity business strategy corporate strategy
Multiple countries/locations 3. International 4. International
business strategy corporate strategy

Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies
CSmPMnlnhall7At;nn anti ;ntornat;^nn:l
n an1U h..eZirs s+wa+vxv D:-ni- r.--m^lt
acmIIIIY.iiVz.LIoV IIICIIIIIIl UUslllns. slraLeqy rallIdJ unllItIlaWdL
147

specific as opposed to generic (fungible across Looking more broadly across domains 1-3, Table5
businesses). And we must also look to domain 3, indicates that location-specificity must be invoked
that of international business strategy, for analyses to distinguish domain 3 from mainstream strategy
of variations in the extent to which activities, of the business and corporate varieties (domains 1
resources or knowledge are location-specific as and 2). Semiglobalization ensures such location-
opposed to free-flowing (fungible across locations). specificity, and therefore supplies a conceptually
Domain 4, featuring international corporate strat- coherent foundation for further analyses at the
egy, purports to combine both business/usage- market and firm levels.
specificity and domain-specificity, but it is the one
about which we currently know the least. Market/factor-level issues
The key point to be made here is that semigloba- The preceding argument is equivalent, in some
lization and the location-specificity or geographic respects, to saying that international business
segmentation of markets implicit in it is critical to strategy should pay more attention to market
the possibility of domain 3 having content qualita- imperfections involving location-specificity rather
tively distinct from domains 1 and 2. Begin by than business/usage-specificity. Those who work
comparing domains 3 and 1. The critical role of primarily on the latter are likely to be somewhat
semiglobalization can be illustratedby contrasting it skeptical. One frequently cited concern in this
with the extreme alternatives of markets totally context is the argument that business/usage-speci-
insulated from each other by national boundaries or, ficity affords more room for firm-specific advan-
at the opposite extreme, perfectly integrated with tages (and disadvantages) than location-specificity.
each other across them. Obviously, with complete But given complementarities among activities,
market insulation, firms could simply decompose resources, etc., this argument is a bit of a red
their choice problems into country-sized chunks. herring.
And if marketswere completely integrated with each To see why, consider a stylized example in which
other, the analysis of multiple countries could, once there are two factors - knowledge, denoted by N (to
again, be folded back to the single-country base case avoid confusion with K for capital), and labor,
that is the staple of mainstream business strategy denoted by L, with N entirely business/usage-
(domain 1), as there would effectively be a single specific and subject to internalization pressures as
large country. Situations with intermediate levels of a result, and L entirely location-specific. Given
cross-borderintegration cannot be dealt with in the complementarities between L and N, profit-max-
same way, however, in that they do not lend imizing firms cannot afford to ignore the labor cost
themselves to purely country-level analysis.8 differences across their various cross-borderoptions
Next, compare domain 3 with domain 2. The role even if their management of L itself does not offer
of semiglobalization or, more precisely, location- the prospect for sustainable firm-specific advan-
specificity in affording scope for international tages. In particular,if cross-borderdifferences in the
business strategy to have content distinctive from cost of L loom sufficiently large, economic viability
mainstream corporate strategy is, perhaps, subtler will require either that they be capitalized on or
but no less important than in the previous case. that some powerful way of countering them be
Specifically, note that the insights into firm bound- found. It is hard to see how creative thinking along
aries and expansion derived, respectively, from either of these lines is fostered by suppressing
Coase (1937) and Penrose (1959), were not only consideration of location-specificity, even if it
worked into international business strategy by applies only to a 'generic' factor, L. And even if
Buckley and Casson (1976), among others, but also labor-cost variations cannot underpin sustained
into mainstream corporate strategy by, in particu- competitive advantages for the firms that exploit
lar, a large body of work on corporate diversifica- them because all competitors tap into them,
tion. So, although such insights have been very exploitation of them may be necessary to avoid
valuable, they do not by themselves imply content unsustainable disadvantages. The whole point of
for domain 3 that is conceptually or otherwise incomplete integration, after all, is that such factor
qualitatively distinct from that of domain 2; they price equalization will occur, if at all, only in the
are a common element of both. For that, what is very long run and cannot, therefore, be assumed in
needed is attention to operations across multiple decisions being made in the short-to-medium run.
locations that are distinct from, but not entirely Analogous points can be made in the context of K
independent of, each other. as opposed to L. Note that if capital markets were

Journal of International Business Studies


Semialobalization and international
--l- -11--- business strateav
- ---=pi
Pankai Ghemawat
. -
--)
....... - . . - I

148
148

perfectly integrated, there would be one global pool Having said that K and L merit more attention
of capital available to fund ventures, and decisions than they have historically attracted, it must be
on whether to proceed with investments could be added that this is not necessarily inconsistent with
separated from decisions about how to finance the focus of much of the relevant literature,
them. Such separation of investment and financing including Buckley and Casson (1976) early on, on
decisions, while often assumed domestically, does knowledge, or as the key factor underlying the
not fare well in an international context. Foreign market imperfections that are most critical for
investment is, to a significant extent, financed international business. Instead, what the discussion
locally in the host country. Thus Feldstein (1995) implies in this regard is that claims of special status
concluded that only 20% of the value of assets for N as a factor in international business strategy
owned by US affiliates abroad was financed by (domain 3 in Table 5) have to be based on the
cross-border flows of capital from the USA, with an location-specificity of N. Otherwise, international
additional 18% accounted for by retained earnings business strategy and multimarket corporate strat-
and the rest representing financing with foreign egy will be difficult to differentiate. Also note that
debt and equity. In such a context, it is hard to in some cross-border contexts, at least, considera-
believe that MNEs allocate capital globally to tions of location-specificity do seem to dominate in
equalize marginal returns on investment projects knowledge-related decision making (e.g. Alcacer
wherever they are undertaken. Instead, firms' and Chung, 2001). Nevertheless, there would seem
investments in real assets seem to be affected by to be great demand for additional research on this
local financing possibilities - or wealth effects. And much-discussed topic.
the impact of financial variables on real ones may
be more than marginal: some major merger and Firm-level issues
acquisition waves, for example, seem to have been In addition to flagging factors/products subject to
driven, in large part, by changes in exchange rates location-specificity as being salient from the per-
(e.g. Blonigen, 1997). This is just one of many areas spective of international business strategy, the
for additional research related to semiglobalization diagnosis of semiglobalization sheds some light
- in this case, concerning segmented international on the content of such strategy at the firm (as
markets for capital and how they interact with real opposed to market) level. Most broadly, semigloba-
(non-financial) variables.9 lization significantly enriches the strategy space
The broader point that emerges from this discus- open to firms relative to the straitjacketing struc-
sion is that semiglobalization or incomplete inte- tural extremes of (1) complete isolation at the
gration is often underplayed because of inadequate borders, which would dictate localization, and (2)
attention to the location-specificity of L and K on complete integration, which would dictate standar-
the grounds that they are generic factors of dization. Cases intermediate to 'one country' and
production incapable of sustaining firm-specific 'one world' present decision-makers with more
advantages. Capital also seems to get pulled down, than one obvious strategy option. Therefore these
as markets for it are supposed to be subject to a high cases require some higher-level decisions about
degree of cross-border integration10 and labor how their firms are going to compete to add value.
because it is seen to represent a 'low' basis for There are many specific ways in which firms
cross-border competition. In any case, whatever the might try to add value through cross-border opera-
precise reasoning, the effect is to devalue capital tions under conditions of incomplete integration,
and labor for being relatively non-specialized but they can be grouped in terms of two funda-
factors and to focus attention on knowledge. This mental economic functions - in the sense of
may seem a reasonable approach. However, recall mechanisms for adding value, as opposed to
that it is controverted by the evidence, summarized marketing, production, etc. - that organizations
in the previous section, that markets for capital and try to fulfill by crossing borders. The first function,
labor, just like markets for knowledge, exhibit aggregation, involves exploiting the similarities
significant barriers to cross-border integration. As across countries, while somehow side-stepping the
a result, even the apparently unspecialized factors differences among them, so as to tap increasing
of capital and labor are specialized at the level of returns to scale. The second, arbitrage, involves
location, if in no other sense. Thus they can assume exploiting differences among countries by taking
strategic importance in an international context advantage of variations in absolute costs or will-
and should be attended to. ingness-to-pay. The prototypical aggregator is a

Journal of International Business Studies


Semiglobalization and international business strateqy Pankaj Ghemawat
149

firm that takes advantage of (partly) locationally differences in the cost of capital. They can arbitrage
mobile resources subject to increasing returns to labor cost differences by relocating labor-intensive
perform roughly the same activities in different activities to countries with low labor costs. And
countries (a 'horizontal' MNE). The prototypical they can try to harness knowledge differences and,
arbitrageurtakes advantage of international differ- more broadly, geographically dispersed knowledge
ences by geographically separating activities in an by making asset-seeking (rather than asset-exploit-
integrated vertical chain (the vertical MNE). ing) investments in critical locations - a task that
Arbitragewas the function that dominated early involves detailed coordination across multiple
international economic activity, as evident in the locations rather than, as some would have it, the
operations of the trading companies chartered in death of geography.
the 16th and 17th centuries, the whaling fleets of The aggregation function also lends itself to
the 18th century, and the vertically integrated unbundling. Here, there are continua of possibili-
agriculturaland extractive (mining) companies that ties ranging, as noted above, from the complete
emerged in the 19th century (Ghemawat, 2000). In localization of a business by country at one
contrast, aggregation first came to the fore - with extreme to complete standardization across coun-
the possible exception of a few international bank- tries at the other. Interestingly distinct - and
ing chains that emerged earlier in the 19th century progressively less researched - intermediate possi-
- with the manufacturing multinationals that bilities include:
began to appear in the second half of the 19th
century. Despite this late start, however, casual (1) adaptation, in which the business model origi-
evidence suggests that aggregation has comman- nated in the 'home base' becomes the basis for
deered researchers'attention to the point where the local modification;
arbitrage function is often ignored. The long- (2) platform or front-to-back approaches, in which
running discussion of the tensions between inte- certain core features of a business model (the
gration and responsiveness and their resolution is a 'platform') are preset globally, while others can
good example (Prahalad and Doz, 1987). These be altered in light of local conditions; and
issues are salient in the context of aggregation, but (3) clustering, which emphasizes grouping coun-
not in the context of arbitrage, which is often tries - regionalization is a subcase - in order to
passed over in silence as a result. Note that such a pursue commonalities more aggressively than
bias towards aggregation would lead to suboptimal would be possible with pure country-by-country
responses to conditions of incomplete integration adaptation.
because of an undue emphasis on treating impor-
tant differences across countries as sources of Developing a contingency theory of choice that
difficulty to be ignored or minimized (as part of operates this level of disaggregation would seem to
an aggregation approach) rather than as possible be a high priority.
sources of value (as part of an arbitrage approach). An additional assumption that is worth discuss-
To consider all possible levers of value, it is ing in this context is the textbook distinction
important to supplement horizontal approaches between horizontal MNEs that emphasize aggrega-
that emphasize aggregation with vertical tion and vertical MNEs that emphasize arbitrage.
approaches that seek to capitalize on (as opposed This dichotomy assumes that it is often possible -
to merely cope with) differences - that is, that and useful - to distinguish firms in terms of the one
emphasize arbitrage. function that is economically central, over long
Unbundling the two functions should help in periods of time, to their strategies for adding value
this regard. To start with the one that tends to get by competing around the world.l1 If one accepts
overlooked more, arbitrage,the schema used earlier this, then it is clear that there are two mutually
in this paper to distinguish among markets for exclusive approaches to achieving geographic
products, capital, labor, and knowledge also sug- coherence or fit - the international business
gests a correspondingly broad array of arbitrage- analogue of mainstream business strategy's focus
based mechanisms for (potentially) adding value. on internal and external fit at the level of the
Firms can arbitrage the incomplete integration of individual business, and corporate strategy's focus
product markets across borders by becoming tra- on fit or coherence across businesses. But there also
ders. Capital market differences provide them with seem to be indications that large multinationals
a strong incentive to account for international engage, at least to some extent, in both aggregation

Journal of International Business Studies


Semialobalization
-
and international
..----
business strateav
--- -'
Pankai Ghemawat
150

and arbitrage. This naturally raises the question of cross-border integration instead of frequently
the extent to which it is possible to mix and match announcing changes in its direction or speed.
across aggregation-oriented and arbitrage-oriented Specifically, the empirical review indicated that
activities. Or to put matters more starkly, how most measures of market integration have scaled
feasible are transformation strategies that exten- new heights in the last few decades, but still fall far
sively exploit both aggregation opportunities and short of economic theory's ideal of perfect integra-
arbitragepossibilities? tion. Looking forward, levels of cross-border inte-
A final question concerns whether intra-firm gration may increase, stagnate or even suffer a
cross-bordereconomic activity should be seen as a sharp reversalif the experience between and during
substitute for or driver of market integration. It is the two World Wars is any indication of the
customary to think of (cross-border) firms as possibilities: while technological changes may be
remedies for the infirmities of (cross-border) mar- irreversible, political changes need not be. But
kets. However, the importance of intra-firm trade given the parameters of the current situation, it
and FDI, in particular, hints that it might make seems unlikely that increases will any time soon
sense to shift towards seeing firms as global yield a state in which the differences among
connectors or conduits responsible, to a significant countries can be ignored, multinationals' best
extent, for cross-border integration rather than as efforts to connect markets across borders notwith-
islands embedded in seas of market relationships. standing. Or that decreases could soon lead to a
Of course, whether firms' cross-border activities state in which cross-border linkages can be for-
substitute for or complement the cross-border gotten about. So, one does not have to make a
integration of markets is yet another open and precise forecast to diagnose that semiglobalization
obviously important agenda item for future as a condition is sufficiently broad to persist for
research. some time to come. Achieving similar stability in
attitudes toward cross-border operations would
Conclusions seem preferable to manic-depressive swings in
Accounts of the cross-borderintegration of markets attitudes about the outlook, if only for purely
have tended to get very wrapped up in the times in pragmatic reasons.
which they were written - perhaps too much so. The diagnosis of semiglobalization does more
Thus Deutsch and Eckstein (1961) emphasized that, than just supply a relatively stable frame of
by the 1950s, the internationalization of transac- reference for thinking about the environment of
tions had declined significantly since the beginning cross-border operations. Semiglobalization also
of the 20th century, and averredthat this trend was calls attention to the critical role that location-
unlikely to be reversed any time soon. Contrary to specificity plays in the prospects of distinctive
their predictions, cross-border economic activity content for international business strategy relative
surged in the 1960s onward and, as it breached to mainstream business and corporate strategy. In
prewar records, inspired forked responses. Global- addition, it flags factors/products subject to loca-
ists stressed that international economic integra- tion-specificity as being salient from the perspec-
tion had reached new heights, while skeptics tive of international business. And, finally, it
insisted that it had barely returned to levels highlights the scope for strategies that strive to
experienced nearly a century earlier. Globalists capitalize on the (large) residual barriers to cross-
gained confidence with the fall of the Berlin Wall border integration, as well as those that simply try
in 1989 and the rapid growth in much of Asia to cope with them.
through much of the 1990s. But then came the Such considerations motivate the modest
Asian financial crisis, episodes of instability in proposal that semiglobalization or location-
Russiaand Latin America, a perceived 'globalization specificity merits the status of a major research
backlash,' a global economic slowdown, and the program in international business. In other words,
war on global terrorism. By mid-2002, the mood, at that a significant volume of researchactivity should
least among practitioners, seemed to be one of be redirected along lines that take explicit account
skepticism rather than optimism about globaliza- of both the importance and the incompleteness of
tion. the integration of markets across borders. In
The empirical evidence reviewed in this article addition to reflecting empirical reality, a research
suggests that it might be preferable to take a more program of this sort would directly address the
measured, historically self-conscious perspective on apparent dearth of 'big research questions' in

Journal of International Business Studies


Semiqlobalization and international business strateqy PankajGhemawat
151

international business. As Buckley (2002, 370) 5For further discussion of currency risk, see Frankel
recently put it: (1992).
6Note the caveat that the extent of catch-up by the
International business has succeeded because it has focused
on, in sequence, a number of big questions, which arise
Asian tigers would look somewhat less remarkable if
from empirical developments in the world economy. The the data in Figure 5 were updated to take account of
agenda is stalled because no such big question has currently the Asian currency crisis.
been identified. This calls into question the separate 7The other (overlapping) reasons for the localization
existence of the subject area. It raises the old problem of
of international competitiveness identified by Porter
the relationship between international business and other
functional areas of management and social science. (1990) are sophisticated local demand and the local
availability of specialized inputs and complements as
From this perspective, the issue is not whether a well as basic factors of production.
big research question is needed at this juncture in 8This point can be demonstrated formally in the
the development of international business, but, context of standard supply-demand analysis. To start at
instead, what it should be about: semiglobalization / one extreme, with complete insulation between two
location-specificity or something else? country markets, the price and quantity outcomes can
be pinned down (under the assumption of atomistic
Acknowledgements competition) at the intersection of supply and demand
This paper has benefited from research assistance by curves in each market. At the other extreme, with
Jamie Matthews and Raluca Lupu, helpful comments complete integration - that is, zero extra costs of
by David Collis, Beulah D'Souza, Vijay Govindarajan, trading, transporting, transacting and so on across
Mauro Guillen, Tarun Khanna, Walter Kuemmerle, national boundaries - one could still add up the supply
Christos Pitelis, Ravi Ramamurti, Louis T. Wells Jr., curves for the two markets on the one hand and their
George S. Yip and, especially, Bernard Y. Yeung, as demand curves on the other and use the point of
well as from presentation of material at the AIB Panel intersection of the two aggregate curves to determine
Session, in summer 2002, celebrating Buckley and the (common) prices and the quantities in the unified
Casson (1976). The Division of Research at the Harvard market. But the continuum of situations between zero
Business School provided financial support. and complete economic integration that I refer to as
semi-globalization creates additional challenges. Given
Notes semi-globalization, the analysis of prices and quantities
'While location-specificity can also operate at the in the two markets cannot be reduced to supply-
local or (intranational) regional level, a full treatment demand analysis of an individual market. Instead,
of it at all these levels of analyses is beyond the scope attention has to be paid to distinct markets that are
of this paper, even though many of the analytical neither totally segmented nor totally integrated - an
issues that arise are similar. intrinsicallymore complex, and interesting, setup.
2The disparity is even greater if one recognizes that 9For further discussion along these lines, see Caves
the denominator of the ratio should really be a (1998).
measure of gross sales rather than a value-added '?Such integration would make access to a global
measure like GDP. pool of capital a 'given' for any worthy enterprise and
3Foreign direct investment currently accounts for thereby limit the scope for purely financial sources of
roughly one-half of total foreign investment, but its advantage or disadvantage.
share was significantly smaller at the start of the 20th "Caves (1996) also identifies a third, residual
century. See Bloomfield (1968, 3-4), cited in Bordo category of multinational enterprise: international
et al. (1999). diversifiers whose operations in different countries
4Note that the spread of domestic safety nets does are neither horizontally nor vertically related to each
increase the likelihood that banking crises will turn into other. These can be thought of as falling in domain 4
currency crises. of Table 5 rather than domain 3.

References
Alcacer, j. and Chung, W. (2001) 'Knowledge seeking, human Baldwin, R.E. and Martin, P. (1999) Two Waves of Globalization:
capital and location choice of foreign entrants in the United Superficial Similarities, Fundamental Differences, National
States', Working Paper, Stern School of Business, New York Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, NBERWorking
University. Paper No. 6904.

Journal of International Business Studies


- - --=1 and international business strateav
Semiglobalization----
- - -- - -- ------ -- - - -- -
----f
Pankai Ghemawat
- "-)-
-- - ,-

152

Barro, R.J. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995) Economic Growth, Held, D., McGrew, A.G., Goldblatt, D. and Perraton,J. (1999)
McGraw-Hill: New York. Global Transformations:Politics,Economics,and Culture,Stan-
Bekaert, G. and Harvey, C.R. (1995) 'Time-varying world market ford UniversityPress:Stanford.
integration', Journal of Finance 50(2): 403-444. Helliwell, J.F. (1998) How Much Do National BordersMatter?,
Blonigen, B.A. (1997) 'Firm-specific assets and the link between BrookingsInstitutionPress:Washington, DC.
exchange rates and foreign direct investment', American Irwin,D.A. (1996) 'The United States in a new global economy?
Economic Review 87(3): 447-465. A century's perspective', AmericanEconomicReview86(2): 41-
Bloomfield, A.I. (1968) Patterns of Fluctuationin International 46.
Finance Before 1914, Princeton Studies in International Finance Jaffe,A.B. and Trajtenberg,M. (1999) 'Internationalknowledge
No. 21, International Finance Section, Department of Eco- flows: evidence from patent citations', Economicsof Innovation
nomics, Princeton University. and New Technology8(1-2): 105-1 36.
Bordo, M.D., Eichengreen, B. and Irwin, D.A. (1999) Is Keller, W. (2000) Geographic Localization of International
Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a TechnologyDiffusion,National Bureau of Economic Research:
Hundred Years Ago?, National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, NBERWorking Paper No. 7509.
Cambridge, MA, NBERWorking Paper 7195 (Prepared for the Kenwood, A.G. and Lougheed, A.L. (1989) The Growthof the
Brookings Trade Policy Forum on Governing in a Global InternationalEconomy,1920-1960, Allen & Unwin: London.
Economy, Washington, DC, 15-16 April 1999. Published: Lewis, K.K.(1995) 'Puzzles in InternationalFinancialMarkets',in
shorter version in Austrian Economic Papers, Vols. 1 and 2, G. Grossman and K. Rogoff (eds.) Handbookof International
2000). Economics,Vol. III, Elsevier Science: Amsterdam. pp: 1913-
Buckley, P.J. (2002) 'Is the international business agenda 1971.
running out of steam', Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies Maddison, A. (1995) Monitoringthe WorldEconomy:1820-1992,
33(2): 365-373. Development Centre of the Organization for Economic
Buckley, P.J. and Casson, M. (1976) The Futureof the Multi- Cooperation and Development: Paris.
national Enterprise,Macmillan:London. Martin, S.F. (ed.) (2000) World Migration Report: 2000,
Caves, R.E.(1996) MultinationalEnterpriseand EconomicAnalysis, Copublished by the InternationalOrganization for Migration
Cambridge UniversityPress:Cambridge. and the United Nations.
Caves, R.E.(1998) 'Researchon internationalbusiness: problems McCallum, J. (1995) 'National borders matter: Canada-US
and prospects', Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies29(1): regional trade patterns', American Economic Review 85(3):
5-19. 615-623.
Coase, R.H. (1937) 'The nature of the firm', Economica4(16): Micklethwait,J. and Wooldridge, A. (2000) A FuturePerfect:The
396-405. Challenge and Hidden Promise of Globalization,Crown Busi-
Deutsch, K.W.and Eckstein,A. (1961) 'National industrialization ness: New York.
and the declining share of the internationaleconomic sector, Obstfeld, M. and Taylor, A. (1997) The Great Depressionas a
1890-1959', WorldPolitics13(2): 267-272. Watershed:InternationalCapital Mobilityover the Long Run,
Dune, N. (2001) 'US population is now more than 10% National Bureauof Economic Research:Cambridge, MA, NBER
foreign-born', FinancialTimes,4 January2001, The Americas, Working Paper 5960.
p. 4. Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. (1994) National InnovationSystems:Why
Feenstra, RC (1998) 'Integration of trade and disintegration of they are Important and How they Might be Measured and
production in the global economy', Journal of Economic Compared,Mimeo, Science Policy ResearchUnit, Universityof
Perspectives12(4): 31-50. Sussex.
Feldstein, M (1995) 'The Effects of Outbound Foreign Direct Penrose, E.T.(1959) The Theoryof the Growthof the Firm,Basil
Investment on the Domestic Capital Stock', in M. Feldstein, J. Blackwell,Wiley: Oxford, New York.
Hines and R.G. Hubbard (eds.) The Effects of Taxation on Porter, M.E. (1990) The CompetitiveAdvantage of Nations, Free
MultinationalCorporations,Universityof Chicago Press: Chi- Press: New York.
cago, pp: 43-63. Prahalad, C.K. and Doz, Y. (1987) The MultinationalMission:
Feldstein, M. and Horioka, C. (1980) 'Domestic savings and Balancing Local Demands and Global Vision,Free Press: New
international capital flows', EconomicJournal90(358): 314- York.
329. Rogoff, K. (1996) 'The purchasing power parity puzzle', Journal
Frankel,J.A.(1992) 'Measuring internationalcapital mobility: a of EconomicLiterature34(2): 647-668.
review', AmericanEconomicReview82(2): 197-202. Scott, B. (2000) EconomicStrategiesof Nations, Mimeo, Harvard
Frankel,Jeffrey,A. (2001) 'Assessing the EfficiencyGain from Business School.
FurtherLiberalization',in Porter,Roger B., PierreSauve, Arvind Teece, D.J. (1977) 'Technology transfer by multinationalfirms:
Subramanian & Americo Beviglia Zampetti, (eds.) Efficiency, the resourcecost of transferringtechnological know-how', The
equity, and legitimacy: the multilateraltrading system at the EconomicJournal87(346): 242-261.
millennium,BrookingsInstitution Press:Washington, D.C. UN Center on Transnational Corporations, World Investment
Ghemawat, P. (2000) 'Global advantage: arbitrage, replication, Report(various issues).
and transformation', unpublished note, Harvard Business World Economic Forum,Global Competitiveness Report(various
School, December. issues).
Giddens, A. (1996) 'Keynote address at the United Nations
Research Institute for Social Development, as excerpted in
'Essentialmatter", UNRISDNews, No. 15.

Acceptedby Tom Brewer;outgoingEditor,August 2002.

Journal of International Business Studies

Вам также может понравиться