Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 11

Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82

Successful and sustainable business partnerships:


How to select the right partners
Mario Rese *
Marketing Department, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Ruhr-University Bochum, Universitaetsstrasse 150, D- 44780 Bochum, Germany

Received 1 March 2005; received in revised form 2 July 2005; accepted 10 August 2005
Available online 7 October 2005

Abstract

In more and more industries it becomes true that value creating networks compete against each other with relatively stable relations between
suppliers inside the network. Managers all over the world are searching for the most efficient and effective coordinative forms for their relations
with OEMs or suppliers within such a value-creating networks. This paper gives a normative guideline to decide if or if not a partnership is the
right coordinative form for OEM-supplier relations within a value-creating network. Based on the existing mainly positivistic research in this field,
two aspects are highlighted as the main drivers for the suitability of a partnership as a well working governance mechanism for value-creating
networks: (i) individualization vs. standardization of the delivered components combined with the potential of the end customers to identify
quality differences or not and (ii) the possibilities to allocate the revenues made by the value-creating network on the several Fpartners_ within the
network. All aspects were integrated in a decision model for managers to find out if partnership as the coordinative form is really the best choice in
a given situation.
D 2005 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Network competition; OEM-supplier-partnership; Governance mechanisms; Revenue distribution among the partners; Decision model

1. Introduction ing competition between standards and the successful


implementation of such standards determines market
The formation of partnerships with the aim of improving success. For example, someone who already owns a
competitiveness for all partners is currently the subject of camera with a Sony memory stick, will also consider
intense debate. In any marketing related journal, one constantly buying a mobile phone from Sony Ericsson or a laptop
encounters hymns about partnerships as the ideal coordina- from Sony in order to use the memory stick for these
tion mechanism for suppliers in a value-creating network. Two other appliances as well (Katz & Shapiro, 1994).
reasons above all, are likely to be responsible for the (ii) The second reason lies in the development of relation-
renaissance of this not necessarily new idea (e.g., Axelsson ships between OEMs and their suppliers. In order to
& Easton, 1992; Hakansson, 1989; Johanson & Hallen, 1989; evade the rising pressure from OEMs for greater
IMP conference proceedings between 1990 and 1999): efficiency, suppliers have developed very effective
strategies which, in some cases, impact negatively on
(i) The first reason derives from an observation in the sector the quality and reliability of future products of OEMs.
of goods with network effects, of which there are Reversing this trend, while at the same time maintaining
progressively more over time. Due to interface incom- the pressure to be efficient, currently ties up substantial
patibilities between products in different networks, the resources in monitoring and controlling enterprises by
very powerful binding effect on the customer means that both suppliers and OEMs. Against this background, a
it is no longer products, but complete systems that partnership among peers without massive monitoring
compete with one another. We are experiencing increas- activities on both sides seems to constitute an insur-
mountable obstacle. A value-creating network can only
* Tel.: +49 234 32 26 596. be mutually successful where likeminded interests
E-mail address: mario.rese@ruhr-uni-bochum.de. prevail for all parties (Jap, 1999). That is, it is necessary
0019-8501/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.indmarman.2005.08.009
M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82 73

to achieve joint success in competing against rival value- relations is frequently seen from only one side that of the
creating chains or networks. In such a situation, it would OEM or the supplier (Cannon & Perreault, 1999; Jap, 1999).
indeed be possible to eliminate the bulk of monitoring Here, we discuss the choice of coordination mechanism as a
costs (Gadde, Huemer, & Hakansson, 2003). two-sided problem. Both parties must agree. Therefore, while
considering a partnership as a suitable coordination mecha-
In fact, in several industries, the idea of a partnership in nism, an OEM must take into account the situation of the
business relationships between companies within a value- supplier and vice versa. The fourth section turns to the issue of
creating network is becoming progressively more important how the potential profits derived from a value-creating network
(Dietl & Royer, 2003, Hunt & Morgan, 1994). Yet, within should to be divided internally. This is an important stability
these networks, the entire range of potential relationships can factor within coordination mechanisms and therefore of
be found: trustful partnerships (with relatively low levels of considerable significance in terms of its sustainability. This
transaction costs because of less monitoring etc.) on the one aspect has largely been ignored in the literature up to the
hand and highly governed relationships embedded in a present. One of the few papers dealing directly with this
complex of contracts and monitoring activities the Fclassical problem is from Kulmala, Paranko, and Uusi-Rauva (2002). In
style_ on the other. contrast to our argumentation here and as a representative of
Against the background of these developments, a number of the opinion in the literature up to now they see the cost
questions arise: management as the key for the revenue or profit distribution.
The final fifth section integrates and transfers the results of the
1. How exactly should one understand a partnership in a value- analysis into a decision model which tests supplier suitability
creating network? As a very special so-called hybrid governance for a partnership. Thus, the theoretical considerations can be
mechanism, how can it be differentiated from the Fordinary_ converted into a normative decision tool for managers.
forms of coordination according to Williamson (1985): market,
hierarchy, Fclassical style_ business relationship? 2. On the fundamentals of partnership-based coordination
2. Is partner-based coordination suitable for any business within a value-creating network
relationship? When and under what circumstances is this
special form of coordination or governance advantageous? The discussion at issue is only really justified if the
3. What requirements must potential partners fulfill so that a phenomenon is in fact new. Therefore, the new aspects need
partnership based coordination mechanism functions effec- to be extracted and analyzed. The existence of different forms
tively? What are the drivers of stability for this form of of governance between market and hierarchy is certainly not
coordination in the long run? new (Anderson & Weitz, 1992; Heide & John, 1992; Lal,
1990; Lusch & Brown, 1996). These governance structures,
In this article, we intend to focus on the third group of referred to as hybrids by Williamson (1975, 1985) and
questions. However, before proceeding to do so, we wish to Williamson (1991), have been debated intensely. According to
reveal the underlying basis and general understanding of the various investigations, several influential factors the
partner-based coordination. In contrast to most current posi- degree of specific investments, symmetry of investments on
tivistic research papers, this should be carried out with a the side of OEM and supplier, phase of relationship life cycle,
normative impetus. As long as we are striving towards the most etc. influence the choice of a special governance
efficient and effective management solutions for OEM-supplier mechanism. Consequently, relationships are arguably the most
relations, a positivistic view what is really done in the prominent governance mechanism (Gronroos, 1999; Hakans-
markets is not sufficient. What can be learned from the son & Snehota, 1995; Heide & John, 1990). However, it is
available empirical investigations is that the degree of specific also true that the term relationship subsumes many different
investments on the buyer and/or supplier side, is the most forms of explicit coordination. Therefore, when we talk about
important driver for the choice of appropriate governance partnership, we mean a very special type of coordinative form
mechanism (Cannon & Perreault, 1999; Jap & Genesan, 2000) under the banner of a broad understanding of the term
that is, the suitable coordinative form and viable relationship relationship, which is defined in the following section (see
form. Fig. 1).
Accordingly, in the following section, partnership, as a The reason that partnerships constitute something special,
special type of relationship seen as a governance mechanism, lies more in the implications associated with the notion of
with its responsibilities and potential benefits, is differentiated competition between value-creating networks, than in the
briefly from other forms of coordination with respect to the novelty of the monitoring problem (Farrell, Monroe, &
buyer seller relationship in general and the degree of specific Saloner, 1998). Competition between different networks will
investments in particular. The third section then deals with the only work if the suppliers integrated into such a network,
characteristics of suitable suppliers for a partnership. The issue always operate in one market at a time and within one network.
will be addressed as to what sort of supplier is likely to provide Acting on the assumption that each partner makes a contribu-
substantial advantages for this special form of coordination. tion to the competitive advantage of the entire network,
This is the second aspect which differentiates this paper from supplying other networks simultaneously would be counter-
many others. The problem of coordinating OEM-supplier productive. The contribution to competitive advantage would
74 M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82

Partnership as a special hybrid form

Market: Hybrids: Hierarchy:


price mechanism contracts, trust, rules and
as the co-ordinative commitment as the instructions as the
force co-ordinative force co-ordinative force

Low Level of Investment Specificity High

Fig. 1. Partnership as a special hybrid coordination form between market and hierarchy.

then also accrue to the competitor. The outcome is a reduction regions has developed entirely differently to that of Japan, for
in potential differentiation. example. Here, suppliers are generally far less dependent on
As a consequence, there would barely be any competition single OEMs (Head, Ries, & Spencer, 2004). Normally, a
between suppliers of a specific component, for example. Each supplier has more OEM-customers within the same industry
supplier would always belong to a network operating within than in Japan. In consequence, the distribution of power
one market segment. A supplier who does not belong to any between OEM and supplier and the closeness of the relations
network at all, will be forced to leave the market in the long with the OEMs differ significantly. Furthermore, the stability
run. If the partners within a traditional supplier relationship of such value-creating networks must also be questioned,
have won a bid for a project in a situation of economic because only a stable network promises lasting success. These
competition, they will now as a partner in a value-creating aspects will be considered below.
network almost automatically be the supplier of a specific
component from one product generation to the next. In this 3. On the suitability of suppliers for a partnership
sense, partnership converges more with the coordination form
of hierarchy, than with the classic business relationship often As a starting point, it is necessary to note that in reality,
discussed in transaction-cost related literature (Menard, 2004; several industry sectors are indeed developing along the lines
Sollner, 1999). of competition between value-creating networks (e.g., Dietl &
Changing the composition of partners is, strictly speaking, Royer, 2003). Nonetheless, there are also converse examples,
only possible through radical innovation (Schumpeter, 1939) in where suppliers do not perceive signs of a partnership long
a situation in which completely new capabilities are required, term cooperation with OEMs. Moreover, they complain
which no partner possesses and simultaneously, capabilities about rising pressure from OEMs. For example, suppliers are
already existing in the network are no longer of use. Precisely forced to participate in online auctions to win always the next
this concept of the value-creating partnership can currently be delivery to the OEM. The manufacturer uses the market
observed in the Japanese Automobile Industry (Hunt & mechanism. Partnership is not desired at all. For instance, this
Morgan, 1994). is true for many German automotive suppliers (Mercer
Against this background, Fbusiness partnership_ is referred Management Consulting, 2001).
to below as a form of cooperation (and not only in terms of In fact, it is important to consider under which conditions
coordination and governance) in which all participating firms will search for partnership-based coordination in reality.
partners act in the interest of the network. The reason is that This is equivalent to the question of when it is advantageous to
all partners depend heavily on the success of the community. establish a partnership-based form of coordination within a
Consequently, monitoring activities are evidently necessary on value-creating network. Mutual advantageousness is a precon-
a smaller scale than in other relationship-oriented governance dition for sustainability, which, in turn, is a condition for the
forms, where each actor focuses on his own individual long-term survival of partnership-based coordination forms in
advantage, because he has several alternative OEMs and/or the real world.
suppliers with whom he can interact. The focus of our observation is a comparison of different
This description sounds somewhat economically paradoxi- coordination forms within a value-creating network. How are
cal. The principle of competition is breached internally in order these internal relations structured? What are the drivers for
to achieve greater external competitive advantage. The choosing one particular form of coordination as opposed to
question arises, however, as to whether a partnership-oriented other alternatives?
form of coordination is generally possible in Western Europe or From a strictly economic perspective, it is to be expected
North America. After all, the industrial landscape in both that the OEM, as the integrative force in a value-creating
M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82 75

network, would select the alternative which would yield the and to what extent the various potential suppliers for a special
greatest profit, whether through increasing revenue and/or product or component differ in terms of quality.
reducing costs. As a supplementary condition, it is necessary Type A represents suppliers which create specific compo-
that no single supplier becomes worse off by joining the nents (based on specific investments) for the OEM, and where
partnership. Otherwise, these actors would not agree to quality does not differ between potential suppliers. Various
partnership-based coordination, as long as they have a choice module suppliers such as Benteler Automotive or the Draxl-
as to the prevailing form of cooperation (Johnson, 1982). maier Group are good examples from the automotive industry.
If one considers more carefully where the advantages of a They produce individualized products for each OEM, but
partnership-oriented network lie, two points are ultimately quite barely differ in quality perceived by the customer. It is
evident. Firstly, where there is trust and commitment (Sollner, precisely here that conforming to the generally prevailing
1999), coordination costs can be reduced, in contrast to the network production quality is essential and is indeed already
competitive cat and mouse game which often prevails between the case. For this group of suppliers, a possible reduction in
OEMs and suppliers. Secondly, the productivity of the value- coordination cost, while changing the coordination form to one
creating network can be raised in comparison to other networks of partnership, would be welcome. These potential new
(Dietl & Royer, 2003). The condition is that, within a network, partners do not need to fear a delivery ban to other OEMs
the most efficient and/or effective actors which include both (forced by the OEM under consideration), however, as long as
suppliers and OEMs, must be united and the supplier must offer they offer genuinely highly specific components which are not
its positive contribution exclusively to only one network in one readily substitutable. Ultimately, it may not matter to the OEM
market. In such a case, the network as a whole can create a that, for example, vehicles are manufactured by other
superior market offering and accordingly gain market share and/ automotive companies using different components manufac-
or demand a price premium (Hunt & Morgan, 1997; Porter, tured by the same supplier. The diametrical opposite applies to
1980). the case of fixed overhead costs R&D could serve as an
Precisely what settings offer an advantage to the OEM, example advantageous for all OEMs on the delivery list of a
depends on the situation of the supplier. For the following single supplier, if several projects are developed concurrently.
observation of different situations, the relationship between the This leads to a reduction in per-unit overhead costs. All in all, it
OEM and the various suppliers must be investigated. The seems both quite feasible and productive to initiate a
starting point is that of traditional competitive coordination partnership with the suppliers from group A, when monitoring,
the use of the market mechanism by the OEM (transaction and therefore, transaction cost advantages, are expected.
buying). The issue arises as to whether it is worthwhile for the The perspective changes for suppliers of Type B in Fig. 2. If
OEM and supplier to reformulate the governance structure there are substantial quality differences between various
(Williamson, 1985) into one of partnership. potential suppliers of a specific component and the module/
With respect to the supplier of an OEM, a differentiation component quality influences the satisfaction of final custo-
should be made between four different groups (Fig. 2). mers, it is essential to integrate the relatively best supplier in
The matrix demonstrates that, for the purposes of further terms of efficiency and/or effectiveness into the network. The
observation, suppliers must be differentiated according to supplier HJS/Bosch, which is responsible for the particle filter
whether or not they need to invest specifically (Klein et al., for diesel emissions for Peugeot, is a good example. Only such
1978) in order to produce the necessary output for the OEM integration will guarantee the benefits for the value-creating
network as a whole. In addition, the best supplier must agree
not to supply other OEMs or value-creating networks (in the
same market), so as to maintain the competitive position of the
Supplier Delivers
network under consideration. Such a supply ban means a
reduction in turnover for the selected supplier, which would
Specific Standardized
have to be compensated through the network. Otherwise, the
Components Components
supplier would have no incentive to participate. Yet, this
compensation can only derive from a greater market share and/
or higher prices, which the value-creating network achieves
Customer perceives a differ-

through integrating the best supplier and thus the greatest


same components from dif-
ence in quality between the

No Type A Type C
achievable competitive advantage.
ferent suppliers

Type C represents the suppliers of standardized components,


which are obtainable worldwide in roughly the same quality.
Flexible brake hoses for car manufacturing might serve as a
suitable example. For the OEM, and thus for the value-creating
Yes Type B Type D network, these commodities are least significant with respect to
the potential for product differentiation. Even in the case of
allocation to a value chain, they do not make a significant
contribution to creating a unique position through product
Fig. 2. Differentiation of suppliers. differentiation. By contrast, their value lies in achieving the most
76 M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82

significant economies of scale in comparison to other suppliers suppliers for the coordination form Fpartnership_. Yet, this is
offering the same products, such as brake hoses, and transferring not sufficient for evaluating the suitability of partnership as a
this value, with the minimum profit margin, to the relevant coordinational form within value-creating networks. The
value-creating network. The best means of achieving this is necessary next step entails answer a second important question:
through highly efficient and competent procurement manage- how should the revenue earned by the network be divided
ment. As long as the OEMs always have the option of amongst the various partners? Where previously, individual
purchasing from other suppliers, competitive pressure via the behavior under competitive pressure was the primary determi-
pure market mechanism (transaction buying), will only be nant of profits accruing to each actor, a means must now be
disadvantageous to a limited degree in terms of poor quality. found to substitute this distribution mechanism. This second
Furthermore, for this group (Type C), the problem of revenue problem will be discussed in the next section.
participation does not arise. Profits can be distributed asymmet-
rically in favor of either the network or the OEM and to the 4. On the stability of partnerships: different forms of
disadvantage of the commodity supplier. Therefore, the use of revenue distribution and their consequences
the market mechanism improves the position of the OEM. A
partnership is not at all suitable for the purpose of coordination. One of the most important aspects of the sustainability of a
Type D comprises those suppliers which deliver relatively partnership is how the revenue of the value-creating network as
standardized components to several OEMs. Such suppliers are a whole should be allocated between the various partners. A
characterized by very substantial quality or technological focus on revenue is necessary, because of the asymmetry
differences in international comparison. With its diesel fuel between cost and revenue origin. Costs arise through the
injectors for automobiles, Bosch serves as a good example. For production by each individual partner, whereas the revenues
these components, the OEM will normally be unable to achieve are generated by the entire network. In competition, the
a partnership-oriented integration of the supplier in combina- revenue distribution is an outcome of the negotiation processes
tion with a supply ban to competitors. Yet, this is necessary to based on the various competitive positions of the actors within
improve the relative competitive position in comparison to each transaction or relationship within the network. In a non-
other value-creating networks. Only if the value-creating competitive partnership, this mechanism ceases to function.
network is the only one to offer the particular beneficial There is no longer any direct and individual competitive
component, is it possible to create an advantage in the final pressure to serve as a regulatory force. Such regulation must
market. However, this contradicts with the fact that the therefore be replaced by alternative distribution mechanisms.
economies of scale achieved so far by the supplier are reduced, In the previous discussion, it became evident that the
because of the supply ban to competitors, given that the individual advantages accruing to potential partners are
supplier must initially reduce production. Nevertheless, this has determined across two dimensions: revenue and cost effects.
two effects. Firstly, the profit for this particular supplier would On the revenue side, there is a change relating to the
decline because of the quantity effect, and secondly, it would quantitative component. The network as a whole acquires a
decline even further on the basis of the now higher unit costs competitive advantage and is able to sell more and/or for a
that is, the allocation of overheads between the now limited higher price. These aspects have already been discussed with
number of products. To return to our example, if the OEM or respect to the motivation of potential partners to participate in a
network as a whole does not compensate Bosch for these non-competitive partnership.
higher costs and quantity disadvantages, they are hardly likely On the other hand, the internal transfer prices each supplier
to agree to a partnership-based integration into the value- gains for his efforts are crucial in this context. The decision on
creating network. Finally, however, the risk for the supplier individual output (quantity) is determined externally through the
rises, if they are linked only to one or a few OEMs. The reason level of demand from final customers. The distribution of total
is that the success of a value-creating network does not depend unit revenue is the main internal problem amongst partners.
only on one actor, but on all others as well. If, for example, the Ultimately, one cannot expect to derive one generally
OEM makes design errors or another supplier provides poor applicable and valid rule for determining how to allocate total
quality goods, this can jeopardize the entire network. It is revenue between the various partners. On the one hand, we
precisely the integration of this supplier type D, which seems have techniques applying simple calculation rules, such as that
difficult for these reasons. However, if suppliers are allowed all actors get the same. These techniques do not take into
the freedom to supply more than one OEM, the concept of account the individual contributions of the network participants
advantage or the notion of competition between different and therefore will not be accepted by the parties involved. On
value-creating networks, becomes diluted. the other hand, we can assume only two possible forms of
If one considers all the issues raised so far, it is evident that internal revenue distribution, if we consider the asymmetric
not only advantages, but also disadvantages are associated with contributions of the network partners:
partnership in a value-creating network. These lie in the
sacrifices that must be made by individual suppliers in order to an externally driven customer value-based distribution
contribute to the success of the network. From a managerial each actor acquires a share of revenue, in relation to the
perspective, it seems necessary to analyze the conditions customer value he contributes or
mentioned above in order to determine the nature of suitable an internally driven cost-based distribution.
M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82 77

In the following section, both possibilities are analyzed in suppliers. Here, a distinction can be made between three
terms of their feasibility, weaknesses and potential for situations:
offering opportunistic behavioral scope to the various
different partners. 1. Each component, module, or service provided by a supplier
The first revenue-allocation option consists of distributing represents exactly one part-worth measured from customer
revenues according to the relative degree to which the behavior.
different partners benefit the customer. In this case, revenue 2. A group of suppliers is responsible for a component, module
would be allocated according to the contribution to customer or service- which the customer perceives as being self-
benefit, with the result that a desired increase in profit share contained and with respect to which, accordingly, a part-
is associated with a relatively greater customer benefit. worth can be identified.
Disregarding, for the moment, the viability of this approach, 3. Supplier performance benefits the customer only in combi-
this rule certainly acts as an incentive mechanism in the nation with components of other suppliers. That is, no part-
right direction: each partner tries to maximize its share of worths can be directed to single partners or segregated
total customer benefit the part-worth of the overall utility groups of partners. Only the network as a whole creates
of a product/service in order to obtain a greater share of single elements, which can be evaluated by the customers.
total revenue (Green & Srinivasan, 1978). This benefits both
the customer and the competitive position of the network. Situation 1 is realistic if different performance elements
This fundamentally good idea seems beset with imple- really exist. This is the case if, for example, one supplier offers
mentation difficulties. Firstly, customer benefit must be hardware, the second offers software and the third, a service. In
measured and converted into monetary value. Secondly, and such a situation, it is clearly possible to measure part-worths for
this may be an even greater challenge, each part-worth from each performance element perceived by customers and to use
each partner, translated into monetary value, must be them as basis for allocating revenues. By so doing, a
calculated individually in order to formulate the distributional substantial additional benefit is generated simultaneously.
basis for the ultimate revenue shares. Only in a very small Through integrating the offer from the strongest competitor
number of situations, can customer benefit be calculated into the measurement, the competitive position could be
directly in monetary terms. Especially in some business-to- revealed in the sense of benchmarking.
business markets, the net present value approach can be used Furthermore, the selection of partners or, more precisely, the
to calculate the relative economic advantage a customer interest in the value-creating network, can be scrutinized by
obtains from various different offers (Oxenfeldt, 1975). In all each partner. If the part-worth converted into the share of
other cases, it is necessary to find a different solution for part- revenue falls below the firms own costs, the partner must
worth measurement and allocation of monetary values. consider to what extent it can alter this situation. In principle, it
The conventional instrument for identifying part-worth is possible to increase benefit through modifying performance
values is conjoint analysis. By means of this process, the or reducing cost. At any rate, which partner generates value
part-worth for the different product/service elements can be within the entire value-creating network, becomes evident. It
calculated with respect to customers bringing different also becomes clear that information about part-worth guides
product offers (each described on a card) with different the incentive mechanism in the right direction. Each partner
levels of performance parameters into an ordinal range aims at raising his own margin, either through cost reduction or
according to their subjectively perceived attractiveness. increasing customer benefit. Even exceeding customer expec-
Additionally, with the aid of the so-called Flimit card tations is only attractive if costs do not simultaneously increase
concept_ (Voeth, 1998), willingness to buy can also be at a similar rate.
observed. The integration of the limit card (into the set of the In Situation 2, an additional benefit of conjoint analysis
ordinal ranged cards describing the product offers) is (CM) can be expected as well. Nevertheless, compared to
important, because a preference order alone does not provide Situation 1, the benefit is limited. Here, several suppliers are
any information on the purchasing probability. For applica- jointly in charge of an exactly definable element of the
tion conditions and assumptions underlying conjoint analysis, product bundle. Therefore, a part-worth for the partner group
see Hair, Anderson, Tatham, and Black (1998) and Green and thus the revenue rate as well, can be calculated, whereas
and Srinivasan (1978). the distribution within the group cannot be determined.
Discussing the extent of the usability and suitability of the Conjoint analysis is suitable when only a few module
conjoint analysis approach for the problem at issue here, firstly, sourcers 1st tier suppliers are in charge of the main
it can be stated with confidence that conjoint analysis would be performance elements.
useful for the value-creating network in general, in order to If the module suppliers are also interested in a partner-
monitor which elements of the product bundle generate oriented strategy at the 2nd tier-level, it is conceivable that a
customer value. conjoint analysis be performed for single sub-components.
In order to use conjoint analysis results additionally for However, the prerequisite is that downstream suppliers are in
revenue distribution purposes, it is necessary that the turn responsible for elements of the module which represent a
identified part-worths measured from customer behavior part-worth for 1st tier suppliers and can be assessed
reveal a clear congruence with the components of individual individually.
78 M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82

The problem in this context is not the implementation, but overhead costs for every product group. If the assignment of
rather the credibility of the module suppliers judgment. When profit from the value-creating network depends on the level of
the final customer no longer evaluates the benefits, but rather cost, the partner will allocate as much of his overheads as
one supplier upstream in the value creation hierarchy, the possible to the product group, which is part of the production
evaluated partner must anticipate opportunistic behavior. The process within the network. This leads to profit maximization
reason is that all partners ultimately strive towards as large as across all product groups, also to those beyond the network
possible a share of revenue obtained from the customer. (Hess & Schumann, 2000). Only if each partner acts in this
Consequently, the use of conjoint analysis is only realistic if manner and if the possibility to shift costs is open to all, will
the distribution of revenue, taking into account part-worth there be no distortion of profit distribution. However, a cost
information, is conducted at the 1st tier-level of module disadvantage for the network as a whole arises, even if only
suppliers. The partnership oriented coordination can be due to calculation tricks, e.g., calculating with higher hourly
successful if restricted to these actors. fees for the workforce (compared to reality) or with higher
The third situation is the least attractive from the perspective prices for input goods. Both strategies lead (in the case of
of identifying part-worth for allocating revenues to the various discovery by the others) to distrust and a re-introduction of
partners. Here, there is no match between the part-worths costly monitoring activities within the circle of partners.
perceived by customers and the suppliers offers. Each element The second effect focuses directly on the cause of costs and
evaluated separately by the customers, results, more or less, is thereby more dangerous than the first, because the basic
from the cooperation of several actors within the value-creating attractiveness of the network business to the customers is at
network. This is the case where there are highly integrated stake. The incentive created by the Fcost_ allocation mechanism
product bundles with a diverse and widespread supplier conveys entirely the wrong market signals. Those who create
pyramid. Especially in such a situation, the assignment of more cost, acquire a greater share of revenue! Creating cost
customer benefit to individual suppliers becomes impossible, efficiency is no longer an attractive goal, with the consequence
with the consequence that the allocation of revenue in terms of that the profit margin of the entire value-creating network
part-worths, cannot work. shrinks. It is difficult to provide accurate information about
If allocation according to identified customer values does cost inefficiency to other participants. In order to do so,
not function effectively, the revenue allocation according to specific knowledge about the production conditions of the
cost, remains a second option. In contrast to the first customer Fpartners_ becomes necessary. This in turn increases monitoring
oriented form of measure, this is an input-related measure. The costs.
advantages and disadvantages of this approach will be This aspect has been held responsible by both practitioners
discussed below. and researchers for significantly increasing transaction costs in
Taking the costs as the allocational measure for revenues, it conventional competitive OEM-supplier relations and was the
is assumed that each partner makes approximately the same reason for seeking alternative forms of cooperation by OEMs
profit or loss relative to her portion of added value of the whole and/or suppliers. The only and remaining threat for the residual
network. Under the assumption that the revenues obtained by network is supplier substitution. However, this threat turns out
the value-creating network exceed total costs, each partner to be more impractical, the more the enterprise has invested
participates in the success in shares that are relatively equal in specifically in the partner or the more difficult it is to replace
terms of his costs. Conversely, each is affected in relatively the partner adequately and/or to obtain acceptable costs in the
equal shares in the event of a loss. This could be described in short term.
terms of the concept of distributive justice (Aquinas, 1274). In summary, due to the individual influence of each partner
One advantage is that all partners receive a contribution. on its own cost position as the measure of revenue allocation,
Furthermore, costs can be determined in retrospect, so that cost barely comes into question as an appropriate revenue-
there is also a valid basis for allocation. allocation base. The key point is that ultimately, the system
Nonetheless, it is precisely here that there are some rewards the most inefficient partner. At the very least, it does
problems. These refer to the allocation of costs on the one not punish them, and supports free riders. A cost monitoring
hand, and to the motivation to save costs on the other. Thus, the system within the value-creating network for avoiding these
real cause of costs is at issue. Regarding the first point, the negative effects would in turn lead to transaction costs, thus
costs incurred by one partner cannot be determined precisely in eroding the expected benefits of the partnership based
terms of his share of performance. This is true whenever a coordination within the network.
supplier (or OEM) offers more than one component, product Only an integrated ERP system providing cost transparency
module or service for sale. The overhead costs must be allotted throughout the network would create effective monitoring. Yet,
pro rata to the different product groups according to an in such a situation, the network would come closer to
overhead rate base (Plinke & Rese, 2002). Here, the supplier integration/hierarchy again, which contradicts the fundamental
has a degree of autonomy in choosing the basis for marking up idea of partnership between autonomous enterprises (Menard,
the overheads. A rationally acting Fpartner_ has a clear 2004). The problem of breaking down joint costs would only
motivation to choose the basis according to the total outcome be solved if all partners bear a relatively high share of direct
of the enterprise which is in his best interests, rather than costs. However, this situation tends unlikely in many busi-
according to factual considerations the Fright_ amount of nesses and against the background of current production
M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82 79

structures in Europe and the United States (Rese & Herter, the value-creating network. If there are no quality differences,
2004). the argument in favor of exclusive integration is no longer
cogent. Accordingly, a partner-based integration is not desir-
5. A decision model for identifying the right partner for able where there are relatively standardized products, modules
partner-based coordination or services. Seeking the cheapest supplier and using the
conventional market price mechanism, then represents the best
Previous analysis has demonstrated that, partnership as form of coordination. It also gives the supplier the option of
understood here, does not represent the optimal general form of supplying other networks as well and thereby generating
coordination for value-creating networks. It is only one economies of scale from which the network (as well as other
alternative among several and only under very specific OEMs or networks) benefit subsequently.
circumstances, is it likely that a partnership will be successful, The suppliers who invest specifically for the value-creating
that is, superior to other coordination forms. network do not encounter problems where there are no quality
These factors can be divided into the following sets of issues differences. A partnership can be offered without any difficulty
(i) the advantageousness of competition between value-creating if it leads to a decline in transaction costs. Economies of scale
networks (and not between individual actors at all levels of the are unlikely, due to the individuality of the components,
value network) (ii) the respective partner himself. With the basic modules or services. Of greater interest are the two cases
hypothesis of rising network competition, externalities in relating to quality differences between different suppliers
particular, should be taken into account. When considering offering a special good or service. They contribute to the
products with network effects, the notion of competition competitive advantage of the network. The precondition is that
between value-creating networks becomes attractive to potential they be the ones with the optimal mix of cost and quality. In
partners. Only the implementation of standards in a market can testing this, it is necessary to consider if a suitable supplier was
make this market prosper and attractive for the actor who has really chosen. Given that this is the case, the next question
established the standard. Thus, there may be an incentive for about the previous supply structure can be posed. Problems of
suppliers to concentrate their endeavors on only one OEM or one revenue compensation, because of a delivery ban, do not arise
value-creating network. Compensating for lost revenue with as long as the chosen supplier has so far delivered only the
competing value-creating networks, may not only be equalized, OEM in the market under consideration. This supplier is
but also converted into a substantial advantage. Nevertheless, fundamentally suitable for a partnership. However, if he
the risk of betting on the wrong horse should be considered. If supplied other OEMs or value-creating networks in the same
the value network of which a supplier is a member, fails to win market as well, the supplier must be willing to abandon these
the battle of giants in a market, this can signify a Flost market_ for deliveries. Otherwise, the contribution to the competitive
each partner in the inferior network. A competitor had already advantage of the value-creating network is reduced. The
joined the other more successful network. network has to consider whether it is able and willing to
The arguments relating to determining a suitable supplier compensate the potential partner for its revenue reduction.
for integration into a value-creating network requiring a Only if the network is able to compensate the potential partner
partner-based coordination form, took centre stage in this for exclusive delivery, will he be prepared to commit to the
article. In this context, different aspects of suitability were network.
discussed. These can be integrated into an overall picture so As a result, the potential partners comprise three groups,
as to design a decision tool which helps an OEM considering whereas the likelihood of committing to the network via a
a partnership, to test whether the envisaged partner is suitable partnership as the coordinational form, may decline from the
or not (see Fig. 3). left to the right in the first gray shaded result row in Fig. 3,
The first question aims at the degree of specific investment merely because the disadvantages which must be accepted by
as a prerequisite for individualized components or modules. the supplier do not outweigh the potential advantages.
Here, an estimate is made of the level of economies of scale the This first result describes the basic matching of partners for
potential partner could realize, what correlates most with the value-creating networks, but it remains unclear whether this
degree of specificity of the products and the degree of specific will be achieved or be sustainable over time. In order to ensure
investment the supplier has to make. This is significant not sustainability, the allocation of revenue to the network partners
only for the future question of revenue compensation, but also must be clarified. The above discussion has demonstrated that a
in general in terms of whether an exclusive integration within a commensurate distribution of revenue, in the sense of
value-creating network makes sense. The general rule is as commutative justice (Aquinas, 1274), is only possible if the
follows: the greater the economies of scale on supplier side, the respective partial benefits to the customer can be determined in
less attractive an exclusive value-creating partnership for both advance. Possibilities are the net present value approach by
sides. Basically, the advantage of exclusiveness means an Oxenfeldt or the conjoint analysis. If the partial benefits of the
excessive loss of scale advantages. different suppliers are measurable, the conditions for a stable
The next step in the decision process relates to quality value-creating partnership are present. If not, an alternative
differences between the envisaged supplier and its competitors. mechanism for distributing revenues must be determined.
Only if such differences exist, is the potential partner able to The input (cost) orientation represents the only option which
make a significant contribution to the competitive advantage of is not totally independent of the activities of each partner. In
80 M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82

Start

Quality differences Yes Specific investments No Quality differences


among suppliers (on side of the supplier) among suppliers
in the industry? necessary? in the industry?

No Yes Yes No

Performance of No
potential ,partner Search for a
sufficient? matching partner

Yes

No Supplying also
other competitors?

Yes

Yes Revenue
compensation
possible?
No

Integration into business Buying in the market;


Principally suitable for a partnership
relationship possible using price mechanism

Measuring of the No Overhead Costs


Costs exactly
individual part-worth
of partners possible? identifiable?

Yes Direct Costs

Commensurate distribution Input oriented revenue Input oriented revenue


of revenues possible distribution possible distribution possible
Compatible with network goals Diffuse incentive structure Diffuse incentive structure
Manipulation difficult Manipulation difficult Manipulation possible

Stability of partnership decreases

Fig. 3. Decision model for selecting the right partner for a partnership.

this context, it is necessary to determine whether the costs of overheads is allotted to the components, products or services for
producing the components, module or service are caused the value-creating network? The potential partner has an interest
directly by the respective products (direct costs in contrast to in assigning as much overhead cost as possible to the network
overhead costs) and are therefore precisely measurable. In this related products or services, if revenue is allocated on this basis.
case of direct costs, there is a basis for allocation which is Yet, this would not only jeopardize the competitiveness of the
largely free of manipulation by the potential partner. However, network, it would also frustrate the players and create a new
there is an obvious incentive problem, as we have discussed control addiction among the members of the value-creating
intensely above. network. Therefore, it is likely that the stability of value-
If the costs are predominantly overheads, an additional creating partnerships decreases, when there is no potential for
problem emerges. This problem depends on the internal an objective revenue distribution via part-worth or at least direct
allocation of the overheads of one supplier. What portion of costs (the second gray shaded result row in Fig. 3).
M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82 81

On the whole, despite its complexity, this decision model is Hair, J. F., Anderson, R. E., Tatham, R. L., & Black, W. C. (1998). Multivariate
based on many assumptions about the relative attractiveness of data analysis. Upper Saddle River (NJ) Prentice Hall.
Hakansson, H. (1989). Corporate technological behavior cooperation and
a value-creating network and the advantageousness of networks. London.
different governance mechanisms. The decision for or against Hakansson, H., & Snehota, I. (1995). Developing relationships in business
value-creating network competition, different coordination networks. London Routledge.
forms and certain partners, can only be made integratively Hayek, F. A. v. (1978). Competition as a discovery procedure. In F. A.
v. Hayek (Ed.), New studies in philosophy, politics, economics, and
taking into account all mentioned aspects at the same time.
the history of ideas (pp. 179 190). Chicago University of Chicago
Nevertheless, this model can and should help reveal signifi- Press.
cant issues for or against partner-based coordination in a real Head, K., Ries, J., & Spencer, B. J. (2004). Vertical networks and US auto parts
situation when deciding for or against a co-producer. What is exports: Is Japan different? Journal of Economics and Management
quite certain is that, despite declarations of friendship and Strategy, 13(1), 37 67.
faithfulness, the fundamental rules of economics cannot be Heide, J. B., & John, G. (1990). Alliances in industrial purchasing: The
determinants of joint actions in buyer supplier relationships. Journal of
ignored or broken. Marketing Research, 27, 24 36.
In conclusion, it should be noted that, although not discussed Heide, J. B., & John, G. (1992). Do norms matter in marketing relationships?
here, previous analysis has not considered what competitive Journal of Marketing, 56, 32 44.
reactions such a strategic orientation would create on the part of Hess, T., & Schumann, M. (2000). Durch elektronische Markte zu marktor-
other OEMs. As demonstrated in the literature (Tirole, 2001), ientierten Verrechnungspreisen. Controlling, 12(11), 557 562.
Hunt, S. D., & Morgan, R. M. (1994). Relationship marketing in the era of
in the prevailing, mainly oligopolistic structures, the develop- network competition. Marketing Management, 3(1), 19 28.
ment of a network would not occur without a counter-reaction Hunt, S. D., & Morgan, R. M. (1997, Oct.). Resource-advantage theory: A
and the corresponding economic consequences. If the estab- snake swallowing its tail or a general theory of competition? Journal of
lishment of a network with the corresponding exclusion of the Marketing, 61, 74 82.
supplier from delivering to direct competitors is really Jap, S. D. (1999). Pie expansion efforts: Collaboration processes in buyer
seller relationships. Journal of Marketing Research, 36, 461 475.
successful, it is likely that a dominant supplier will emerge Jap, S. D., & Genesan, S. (2000). Control mechanisms and the relationship life
within a particular market segment. The parallel delivery ban cycle: Implications for safeguarding specific investments and developing
creates a barrier which cannot realistically be overcome by other commitment. Journal of Marketing Research, 37, 227 245.
OEMs, as long as there are significant quality differences Johanson, J., & Hallen, L. (1989). Networks of relationships in international
between the suppliers (Baumol, Panzar, & Willig, 1988). industrial marketing. Greenwich.
Johnson, M. P. (1982). Social and cognitive features of the dissolution of
However, whether these quality differences can be maintained commitment to relationships. In S. Duck (Ed.), Personal relationships
over the longer term, also depends on the level of pressure to (pp. 51 73).
innovate, which the competitive situation inevitably forces on Katz, M. L., & Shapiro, C. (1994). Systems competition and network effects.
the competing value-creating networks. The result of such Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(2), 93 115.
Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., & Alchian, A. A. (1978). Vertical integration,
competition is not predictable, and particularly in such
appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law
instances, can lead to nasty surprises (Hayek, 1978). and Economics, 21(2), 297 326.
Kulmala, H. I., Paranko, J., & Uusi-Rauva, E. (2002). The role of cost
References management in network relationships. International Journal of Production
Economics, 79, 33 43.
Anderson, E., & Weitz, B. A. (1992). Make-or-buy-decisions: Vertical Lal, R. (1990). Improving channel coordination through franchising. Marketing
integration and marketing productivity. Sloan Management Review, 27, Science, 9, 299 318.
3 19. Lusch, R. F., & Brown, J. R. (1996). Interdependency, contracting, and
Aquinas, T. (1274). Commutative and Distributive justice, Summa Theolo- relational behavior in marketing channels. Journal of Marketing, 60,
gica; Questions on Law and Justice, Full online text on www.lonang. 19 38.
com/exlibris/aquinas/sum22061.htm Menard, C. (2004). The economics of hybrid organizations. Journal of
Axelsson, B., & Easton, G. (1992). Industrial networks a new view of reality. Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 160, 345 376.
London Routledge. Mercer Menagement Consulting. (2001). Automobiltechnologie 2010. Techno-
Baumol, W. J., Panzar, J. C., & Willig, R. D. (1988). Contestable markets and logische Veranderungen im Automobil und ihre Konsequenzen fur
the theory of industry structure (2nd edR). San Diego Harcourt Brace Hersteller, Zulieferer und Ausruster, http://www.mercermc.de/mapper.
Jovanovich. php3?file=upload_material%2Ftuv%2F3.pdf&name=Technologische_Ver_
Cannon, J. P., & Perreault Jr., W. D. (1999). Buyer seller relationships in nderungen_im_Automobil_und_ihre_Konsequenzen_f_r_Hersteller_Zulieferer_
business markets. Journal of Marketing Research, 36, 439 460. und_Ausr_ster.pdf&type=application%2Fpdf
Dietl, H., & Royer, S. (2003). Intra-system competition and innovation in the Oxenfeldt, A. R. (1975). Pricing strategies. New York Amacom.
international videogame industry. Innovation: Management, Policy and Plinke, W., & Rese, M. (2002). Industrielle Kostenrechnung (6th edR). Berlin
Practice, 5(2 3), 158 169. Springer.
Farrell, J., Monroe, H. K., & Saloner, G. (1998). The vertical organization of Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York The Free Press.
industry: Systems competition versus component competition. Journal of Rese, M., Herter, V. (2004). Prices and Costs Price Assessment in
Economics and Management Strategy, 7(2), 143 182. Business-to-Business Markets, MIB Working Paper No 3, Ruhr Univer-
Gadde, L. -E., Huemer, L., & Hakansson, H. (2003). Strategizing in industrial sity Bochum.
networks. IMM Industrial Marketing Management, 32, 357 365. Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles. Boston, Mass Harvard BP.
Green, P. E., & Srinivasan, V. (1978). Conjoint analysis in consumer research: Sollner, A. (1999). Asymmetrical commitment in business relationships.
Issues and outlook. Journal of Consumer Research, 5, 103 123. Journal of Business Research, 46, 219 233.
Gronroos, C. (1999). Relationship marketing: Challenges for the organization. Tirole, J. (2001). The theory of industrial organization (12th edR). Cambridge,
Journal of Business Research, 46, 327 335. Mass MIT-Press.
82 M. Rese / Industrial Marketing Management 35 (2006) 72 82

Voeth, M. (1998). Limit conjoint analysis a modification of the traditional Williamson, O. E. (1991). Comparative economic organization: The analysis
conjoint analysis. In P. Andersson (Ed.), Proceedings of the 27th EMAC of discrete structural alternatives. Adminstrative Science Quarterly, 36,
conference Marketing research and practice, marketing research (Bd. 5), 269 296.
Stockholm 1998 (pp. 315 331).
Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust Mario Rese is Professor for Business Administration and Marketing at the
implications. New York The Free Press. Ruhr-University Bochum, Germany. He has written widely on competitive
Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York strategy, customer analysis and marketing controlling.
The Free Press.

Вам также может понравиться