Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 15

HOME

Chapter 5

Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice


Peter Howie

Introduction
The final product demand curve and the level of consumption
Final product demand and its determinants
Mineral resources and derived demand
The mineral demand curve
Shifts in the mineral demand curve
Elasticity of mineral demand
Own price elasticity of mineral demand in the short run
Income elasticity of mineral demand in the short run
Cross-price elasticity of mineral demand in the short run
Elasticity of mineral demand in the long run
Conclusions

INTRODUCTION
Minerals are widely used in the modern economy. How In fact, the slogan a diamond is forever, is widely
these uses change as the result of changing economic, considered the most recognised and effective slogan of
political and technological circumstances is the subject the 20th century (Otnes and Pleck, 2003).
of mineral demand. Because the demand for minerals The growth in demand for jewellery is highly
is multifaceted, it is also essential to have a good correlated with the demand for gold and other precious
knowledge of the fundamentals that affect mineral metals in the USA, Asia and the Middle East. Consumers
demand so as to analyse and forecast output and price in the developed markets of the west buy jewellery
behaviour. primarily for adornment and often for sentimental
The demands for minerals are commonly separated reasons; whereas, in the developing markets of Asia
into three categories for ease of presentation: derived, and the Middle East, they purchase it for investment as
created and historical. Industrial demand for minerals well as adornment.
predominantly derives from their unique physical Investment demand is, for the most part, historical
and chemical properties that enable their use in and relies on international currency movements and
varied applications. Discussions of mineral demand inflation. The monetary demand for gold and, to a lesser
particularly recognise this characteristic. There is a extent, other precious metals, has derived value from
strong link between these uses and economic growth, providing stability and security to overall investments.
and this relationship is likely to continue into the future. This chapter is organised to permit an orderly
For many of the minerals sold as jewellery, demand presentation of the basic topics of mineral demand,
has been created and requires constant promotion. separated into four parts. The first presents the concept
The most famous example of created demand is the of final-product demand and introduces some of the
association of diamonds with love and commitment, economics required to understand subsequent sections.
developed by De Beers Consolidated Mines in The second focuses on the derived demand for minerals
association with NW Ayer and Son (Pequignot, 2010). and the characteristics of such demand. The third

Mineral Economics 51
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

introduces the concept of elasticity and progresses, with we break the question: how many and which pairs
an in-depth examination of the sensitivity of mineral of gold earrings should Ms Kumar purchase? into a
demand to changes in prices and income. This section series of questions.
also examines the effect of time on mineral demand. Before doing this, let us make two simplifying, but
The fourth section offers some concluding comments. realistic, assumptions:
1. Ms Kumar budgets a certain amount of money to
THE FINAL-PRODUCT DEMAND CURVE AND buy gold earrings and she spends all of this money
THE LEVEL OF CONSUMPTION either on gold earrings or on another product.
This section presents some necessary economic tools 2. Benefits from the purchases are expressed in terms
as well as generating both individual consumer and of money. This means that all benefits, both sensual
market final-product demand curves. Economists as well as intellectual, from the purchase of gold
define a final product as a product that is produced for jewellery are measured in terms of equivalent
its final user and not as a component of another good money value.
or service. For example, an Apple iPad, a pair of gold Key questions to be asked are:
earrings and gold bullion used for investment are final
How much is Ms Kumar willing to pay for the first
products; however, copper wiring in the iPad and gold
pair of earrings?
in the earrings are intermediate products or inputs. To
help with the formal development of the final-product How much is Ms Kumar willing to pay for a second
demand curve, let us introduce the hypothetical pair of gold earrings?
scenario of Ms Sangeeta Kumar, a Senior Manager at How much is Ms Kumar willing to pay for each
the Tata Group in India. Ms Kumar is interested in subsequent pair of gold earrings?
purchasing gold earrings for the upcoming year. This type of questioning examines the effects of
Since most goods are scarce and Ms Kumar cannot changes in happiness with each additional purchase.
have everything that she wants, she must make tough It allows us to determine the number of dollars (or
choices. The science of economics tells us that every Rupees) that Ms Kumar regards as equivalent to each
time we make a choice, because resources are scarce, pair of earrings. It is a direct measurement of the
something else must be given up. That is, when Ms benefits she receives from each pair of earrings.
Kumar purchases one good she is giving up the As Table 5.1 shows, Ms Kumar derives $300 worth of
opportunity to purchase another good or service benefit from one pair of earrings, $550 worth of benefit
with the money she spends. Furthermore, economics from two pairs of earrings, and so on. So she receives
provides us with a set of tools that can help make the $300 of benefit from the first pair of earrings, $250 from
best decision available. This set of tools is based upon the second pair, and so on. The additional benefit that
the philosophy of utilitarianism. The foundation of a consumer receives from consuming the next unit of
utilitarian philosophy is: a product is referred to as marginal benefit. For Ms
actions are right in proportion as they tend to Kumar, marginal benefits are the amounts of money
promote happiness; wrong as they tend to produce that she is willing to pay to enjoy the attributes of an
the reverse of happiness. (Mill, 1863) additional pair of gold earrings. For example, the
marginal benefit from the third pair of earrings is $204.
In other words, utilitarian philosophy suggests that
Ms Kumar makes decisions with the ultimate objective Table 5.1 also shows that as Ms Kumar buys more
of maximising her happiness, both intellectual and and more pairs of earrings, the benefits that she derives
sensual. from each additional pair will be less than that from
the previous pair. Therefore, the graph of her marginal
Commonly people believe that choices they make are
benefits from earrings is downward sloping (see
in the form of the following question: which and how
Figure5.1).
many pairs of earrings should I purchase? The answer
to this question is believed to be that the Ms Kumar Table 5.1
decides to purchase the pairs of earrings that she likes Marginal and total benefits.
the best so long as they are within her budget.
Pairs of earrings Total benefits Marginal benefits
Economists suggest that such questions should be
0 0 -
answered by comparing all the costs, not only money
costs but also the costs associated with an inability to do 1 300 300
something else. Therefore, when Ms Kumar purchases 2 550 250
earrings, economists suggest that she compares all costs 3 754 204
and benefits. Often, however, it is difficult or impossible 4 918 164
to list all the available purchase options within a
5 1048 130
persons budget. Luckily, economics provides us with
a simple way to approach this problem. It suggests that 6 1148 100

52 Mineral Economics
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

350 As Demand Bs Demand Market Demand

300
$/unit $/unit $/unit
Marginal benefits (dollars)

250

200
130
150
100
100

50
Q/t Q/t Q/t
5 6 6 8 11 14
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Fig 5.2 - Individual and market demand curves.
Pairs of gold earrings per period

Fig 5.1 - Marginal benefit curve. or service to fall as its price increases. One is that many
people will switch to a substitute good. If the price of
Ms Kumars marginal benefit curve from gold gold jewellery was to rise, some consumers may switch to
earrings (or any individual product or service) is platinum jewellery, others to silver jewellery. The second
identical to her individual demand curve for gold reason is that consumers are unable to buy as much as
earrings (or any individual product or service). That is, before. Incomes usually do not fluctuate with the price of
the demand curve for gold earrings shows the marginal an individual product and when the price of a good goes
benefits received from consuming gold earrings during up, it is not possible to buy as much as before unless the
a certain period of time. consumer purchases less of something else.
It is also possible to derive the market demand Similar to the market demand curve, the market
curve for gold earrings. Table 5.2 provides a simplified supply curve represents the behaviour of suppliers
example of the gold earrings market if there were only during a given period of time. The market supply curve
two consumers. At $130 per pair of earrings, consumer shows the total number of units of a good or service
A demands five pairs per period and consumer B that sellers are willing to deliver to the market at every
demands six pairs per period. Therefore, the market possible price during a given period. Market supply
demand for gold earrings at $130 is 11 pairs of earrings.
curves generally slope upward, indicating that sellers
Similarly, at $100 per pair of earrings, consumer A
are willing to supply a higher quantity as the price rises.
demands six pairs and consumer B demands eight
pairs; therefore, the market demand is 14 pairs. This When the price is such that the quantity that buyers
procedure of generating the market demand is often want to buy is the same as the quantity that sellers
described as announcing a price and adding up the want to sell the market is said to be in equilibrium.
individual quantities demanded at that price. This If consumers wish to consume more than producers
procedure is the same whether there are only two wish to produce, there will be buying pressure and the
consumers in a market or many millions. quantity demanded will exceed the quantity supplied.
As a result, price will rise. Conversely, if consumers
Table 5.2 wish to consume less than producers wish to produce,
Individual and market demand. there will be selling pressure and the quantity supplied
will exceed the quantity demanded. With this scenario
Price Consumer A's Consumer B's Market price will fall. Such changes will continue until
($/pair) demand demand demand equilibrium is achieved quantity demanded equals
160 4 4 8 quantity supplied. The price that accomplishes this is
130 5 6 11 termed the equilibrium price and the corresponding
100 6 8 14 quantity the equilibrium quantity.
70 7 10 17 Final-product demand and its determinants
40 8 12 20 Recall that the demand curve shows that if there is an
increase in the price of goods, consumers will purchase
less of the goods, all other things equal. In other words, if
Figure 5.2 provides a graphical representation of the price goes up, quantity demanded will go down; if price
market demand for gold earrings outlined in Table 5.2. goes down, quantity demanded will go up. This is the
It is important to understand why the market demand concept that economists refer to as the law of demand.
curve is drawn as it is. Along the demand curve only It indicates that if there is an increase in the price of a
price and quantity demanded are allowed to change, product, then there will be a leftward movement along
while income and the prices of related goods are held its demand curve, and vice versa. Economists refer to
constant. Furthermore, there are two independent movements along the demand curve as changes in the
reasons for the market quantity demanded of a good quantity demanded.

Mineral Economics 53
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

It is important to realise that the demand curve by importance of the role of expectations by institutional
itself isolates the impact of price on the quantity of a investors is made clear by the actions of these after
product demanded. Because the law of demand is September 2008. On 17 September 2008, spot gold
one-dimensional (that is, it only examines the impact jumped by nearly $90 an ounce, a record one-day gain,
of quantity demanded caused by changes in the price as these investors sought safety amid turmoil in stock
of the good and vice versa) it leaves out elements markets. Furthermore, during the week of 8 September
that shift the demand curve. For example, the law of 2009, purchases of long positions of gold futures
demand cannot fully explain the increase in the price contracts reached their greatest number for the 2000
of gold from around US$800/oz in November 2008 to - 2010 period as institutional investors worried about
more than US$1800/oz in August, 2011. That is because the weakness of the US dollar and concerns over the
the quantities consumed and produced are not solely economic recovery (United States Commodity Futures
determined by price. Trading Commission, 2011).
One key to the higher gold price lays in changes of Finally, the level of income and prices of related goods
investors preferences for gold due to the concerns are also important to the demand for gold. Chinas
about the global economy and sovereign debt issues, demand for gold jewellery increased from just over
particular those of the United States. After November 500 000 oz in the late 1980s to over 12 Moz at the end
2008, investors became increasingly worried about the of 2010, in spite of the price of gold going from $200
safety of their US dollar-denominated money and there to $1500/oz. This rise in consumption coincided with a
was an increase in the preference to hold gold as an dramatic rise in Chinas per capita income from $350 in
alternative. 1991 to $3650 in 2009 (World Bank, 2011).
In addition to the growing investment demand for
MINERAL RESOURCES AND DERIVED
gold bullion, gold jewellery demand has seen recent
increases due to changes in consumer preferences. DEMAND
Even with a 23 per cent increase in the price of gold Up to now, we have discussed the consumer demand
during 2010, the World Gold Council estimated that for final goods and services. However, most minerals
the consumption of gold was up 22 per cent in tonnage are not final goods. Consumers do demand precious
terms (or 53 per cent in dollar terms) in 2010 (World metals and gems as final goods, but these uses are a
Gold Council, 2011). small fraction of total mineral demand. For the most
part, minerals are used as inputs for final goods and
A change in preferences of consumers (ie consumers
services. Therefore, the demand for most minerals
of gold jewellery) and investors who are consumers of
is derived from the demand for the final goods and
gold bullion is only one of several non-price factors that
services for which the mineral is an input. Demand of
change the quantity of a good that is consumed. These
this type is known as derived demand. For example,
non-price factors shift the demand curve. Specifically,
the demand for copper in mobile telephones is derived
the demand curve: from the demand for mobile telephones. Consumers
shifts to the right if a non-price factor causes the of the final product, here mobile telephones, are not
quantity consumed to increase concerned about which inputs are used as long as the
shifts to the left if a non-price factor causes the mobile telephone meets their specifications.
quantity consumed to decrease.
Other non-price factors that shift the demand curve
The mineral demand curve
include the level of income, the prices of related goods There is a clear relationship between final-product
and expectations. demand and the derived demand of a mineral to make
these final products. Recall that determining final-
The expectations of final consumers are very impor-
product demand involves the ultimate objective of
tant to gold jewellery demand. A large proportion of
maximising a consumers happiness, determined by
the 17per cent increase in gold jewellery demand by
the prices of goods and by the income available for
the worlds largest consumer of gold jewellery, India,
their purchasing. In contrast, for our mobile telephone
during 2010 was due in part to a widespread expectation manufacturer, who requires inputs for its production,
of higher gold prices (World Gold Council, 2011). China, mineral demand is a special case of demand in which
the second largest consumer of gold jewellery, witnessed the purchased goods are the inputs for production.
13 per cent growth in jewellery consumption, especially
As a result, the demand for minerals is linked closely
in the pure gold (24 carat) segment, suggesting that
with firms production processes. Our firms mobile
expectations of higher gold prices were playing an
telephone production process, and its demand for
increasing role in the demand for gold jewellery for the
copper, expresses a relationship between its inputs
Chinese (World Gold Council, 2011).
and its outputs. Economists formally represent this
Institutional investors use gold as a hedge against production relationship by the production function.1
inflation or a fall in the US dollar. Remember that
gold transactions are denominated in US dollars. The 1 We have introduced the production function in Chapter 2.

54 Mineral Economics
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

The production function is a non-monetary telephones generated by each unit of copper employed
relationship that correlates physical inputs to physical the average physical product (APP) is rising along
outputs. Prices and costs are not considered. A typical the production function between the origin and pointA.
production function for a firm with only one variable Point A defines the starting point beyond which the
input, say copper, and a set level of fixed inputs appears number of mobile telephones produced increases at
in Figure 5.3. In this example, the fixed inputs those a decreasing rate when additional units of copper
inputs whose quantities cannot be readily changed in are employed. This corresponds to declining MPP of
an effort to alter the rate of output include pieces of copper beyond point X.
equipment and machinery, the factory space available
Point B is the starting point beyond which the average
for production, the know-how of managerial personnel
amount of telephones produced by each unit of copper
and all labour. The vertical axis shows the total output
employed starts to decrease. This trend is shown by the
of the final good (mobile telephones), and the horizontal
declining slope of the APP curve beyond point Y.
axis shows the units of copper employed.
To simplify the interpretation of a production function,
Quantity of mobile it is common to divide its range into two stages. In
telephones per time period Stage1 (from the origin to point B) the average number of
mobile telephones generated by both the variable input,
here copper, and the fixed inputs is rising reaching a
maximum at point B. Because the average number of
B
mobile telephones generated by both the variable and
fixed inputs is increasing throughout Stage 1, the firm
A will always try to operate beyond this stage. It turns out
Units of copper
that in Stage 1, fixed inputs are underutilised.
per time period In Stage 2 (beyond point B), the output of mobile
X telephones increases at a decreasing rate. That is, both
Y the additional amount of mobile telephones generated
by each additional unit of copper used and the average
APP amount of mobile telephones generated by each unit
of copper used are decreasing. However, the average
number of mobile telephones generated by the fixed
MPP
inputs is still rising. It turns out that the optimum
Units of copper
per time period copper/mobile telephone combination will be in
Stage 1 Stage 2 Stage2. Therefore, a profit-maximising firm will always
operate somewhere in Stage 2. As a result, from here on,
Fig 5.3 - The production function.
our discussion of the marginal physical product curve
refers to the downward sloping portion in Stage 2.
All points above the production function are
The next step is to determine how many units of
unobtainable with current technology, all points below
copper a profit-maximising firm will employ. The
are technically feasible and all points on the function
answer is straightforward: our firm will employ any
show the maximum quantity of output obtainable at
unit of copper that produces greater revenue than
the specified levels of inputs. From the origin, through
points A and B, the production function is rising, the copper adds in cost. That is, the firm will use an
indicating that as additional units of copper are used, additional unit of copper when the benefits from its use
the quantity of mobile telephones also increases. are greater than its additional costs. For simplicity let
us assume that:
From the origin to point A, as the firm uses additional
units of copper, the number of mobile telephones the added cost equals the market price of the copper
produced increases at an increasing rate. In economics, (which implies that the buyer of copper is a price
we call the increase in output generated by adding taker)
an additional unit of the variable input the marginal the price of mobile telephones is held constant.
physical product (MPP). For the mobile telephone The value that copper contributes to the mobile
manufacturer, MPP is the increase in output of mobile telephone manufacturer depends on two things: how
telephones caused by increasing the amount of copper much the output of mobile telephones increases by
by one unit. As the number of mobile telephones is adding an additional unit of copper and the extra
increasing from the origin to point A, then the firms revenue that each additional mobile telephone brings
marginal physical product is also increasing, as shown to the firm. In economics, we call the value that an extra
by the increasing marginal physical product of copper unit of variable input contributes the marginal revenue
form the origin to point X. The average amount of product (MRP) as opposed to the MPP. The MPP of

Mineral Economics 55
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

copper is simply the added revenue or benefit to the example and attempt to put ourselves in the position
firm of employing an extra unit of copper. For our of the mineral suppliers the copper producers. If the
mobile telephone manufacturer, this benefit equals the price of copper increases, copper producers are willing
marginal physical product of copper, multiplied by the to supply more copper to the market.
market price of the mobile telephone. As a result, the mineral supply curve is positively
The cost of the copper, by the above assumption, sloped. That is, at a higher price there will be a greater
is its market price. Therefore, the mobile telephone quantity of copper supplied. If we combine this supply
manufacturer will employ additional units of copper information with our information on mineral demand
until the benefit that an extra unit of copper contributes we get a diagram such as Figure 5.4, which describes
(the MPP) equals the market price or cost of an extra the achievement of equilibrium in the mineral market.
unit of copper.
A numerical example may help to clarify this idea. $/unit
S
Nokia, a leading firm in the mobile telephone industry,
has a mobile telephone assembly factory in Chennai,
India. Suppose Nokia pays US$12/kg for copper wiring
and it receives 540 rupees (equivalent to US$12) for
P*
each telephone. Adding another kilogram of copper
will allow Nokia to make two more mobile telephones
per hour. Is it worthwhile to add another kilogram of
copper? Using the rule discussed above, one sees that D
the extra value to Nokia is 2 US$12 or US$24. The Q/period
extra cost to Nokia of another kilogram of copper is Q*
US$12. Therefore, it is profitable for Nokia to add the Fig 5.4 - Equilibrium in a mineral market.
extra copper. After this kilogram of copper is added,
Nokia may find that adding another kilogram of copper This analysis is similar to the supply-demand analysis
will add only one more mobile telephone. In this case we explored earlier for gold earrings. The market will
Nokia is indifferent to adding an extra kilogram of tend toward the equilibrium where mineral supply
copper because to generate an extra US$12 of income equals mineral demand. At any other price a shortage
costs US$12. It is not in Nokias interests to employ any (price too low) or a surplus (price too high) will occur
additional units of copper because the extra value that and there will be adjustments in the price to bring the
the additional unit of copper would generate is less market to the equilibrium.
revenue than the price of copper.
Shifts in the mineral demand curve
An important characteristic of the marginal revenue
product curve of a mineral is that it corresponds to a In the section Final-product demand and its
manufacturers demand curve for the mineral. Nokias determinants, we discussed factors that shift the final-
mineral demand curve identifies the amount of copper product demand curve. A parallel discussion for the
it chooses to employ at different prices, holding mineral demand curve is necessary as some of the factors
everything else constant including the price of mobile that cause it to shift are different from the factors that
telephones. shift the final-product demand curve. These different
factors reflect the derived nature of the input demand
Now let us examine the market demand curve
curve. In this discussion we discuss three factors that
for copper. If we assume that the price of mobile
cause the mineral demand curve to shift. They are:
telephones and the price of copper remain constant,
then market mineral demand curve for copper is the 1. changes in demand for a final product
horizontal sum of individual firm copper demand 2. changes in technology
curves. However, if the demand for copper increases 3. changes in the mix of inputs.
the market price of copper, then the result is a change
First, let us consider changes in consumer demand
in the quantity, price, or both the price and quantity
of mobile telephones. As a result, the market mineral for a final product. As you would expect, there is a
demand curve, when mineral price changes, tends direct positive relationship between final-product
to have a steeper slope than the one obtained from demand and mineral demand. That is, an increase in the
the simple horizontal summation of individual firm demand for mobile telephones will increase the demand
copper demand curves (Campbell, 1985). for copper. On a graph, this translates to a rightward
shift of the mineral demand curve. A decrease in the
We now have one half of our market for minerals demand for mobile telephones will reduce the demand
mineral demand and the market mineral demand for copper. On a graph, this equates to a leftward shift
curve. We now need to briefly look at the supply side of of the mineral demand curve.
the minerals market2. We can once again use the Nokia
Second, let us think about changes in technology. Recall
2 We will do this in more detail in Chapter 6. that the production function is constructed assuming:

56 Mineral Economics
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

constant technology in the minerals industry Technological changes that develop new products can
constant technology in the final product industry. either increase or decrease the demand for a mineral.
For example, optical fibre cables, which are now used
Within the minerals industry, changes in technology
have led to increased availability and utilisation of widely in telecommunications, have replaced huge
capital equipment and minimised non-productive tonnages of copper wire. Comparisons indicate that
work hours. More generally, they have brought more an optical fibre can carry over a quarter million times
cost-effective mineral exploration, mine development more information than a similarly sized copper wire
and mineral processing. The result is a rightward shift (Dulay, 2004). In contrast, renewable energy projects
in the mineral supply curve (discussed in Chapter 6). consume significant amounts of copper. On average,
a one megawatt wind turbine contains 3.9 t of copper
By contrast, technological changes in a manufacturing
and a photovoltaic installation approximately 4 kg of
process for a downstream intermediate or final product
copper per kilowatt of installed capacity (European
that uses a mineral such as copper as an input will
Copper Institute, 2008). In 2008, this group estimated
cause a shift in the copper demand curve. There are two
types of technological changes in these manufacturing that the wind turbines installed in the European Union
processes that may cause the copper demand curve to contained 190 000 t of copper and the photovoltaic
shift. They are: installations nearly 19 000 t. The decision by Germany to
close down its 17 nuclear power plants, which generate
1. the refinement and improvement of existing
one-quarter of the countrys electricity (approximately
processes
151 TWh), by 2022 and shift to renewable sources
2. the development of new products. should greatly increase the installed amount of copper
The steel smelting industry provides a good example for energy production, and in turn copper demand,
of refinement and improvement technological change. over the next ten years (Federal Statistical Office of
During the early 1960s, technological innovation in the Germany, 2011; Wiesmann, 2011).
injection of pulverised coal into blast furnaces reduced The third factor that causes the mineral demand curve
coking coal rates by 36 per cent per tonne of steel. By to shift is a change in the price of other inputs, which
the beginning of the 1990s injection rates of coking coal causes a change in the mix of the inputs used. The effect
had declined by an additional 15 per cent per tonne of
of a change in the price of one mineral, say aluminium,
steel (Mitchell, no date). When technological change
on the demand for another mineral, say copper, may
permits the use of a smaller quantity of mineral inputs
be uncertain. Aluminium and copper are often used
to obtain a given level of output, the final-product
together in coaxial cable, with copper as the centre
production function, here the production function for
conductor and aluminium as the shield. However,
steel, shifts leftward, as shown in Figure 5.5, and the
aluminium is a substitute for copper in electric motor
mineral demand curve will shift to the left.
rotors and many other electrical applications.
Quantity of steel output When aluminium is a complement of copper, a
per time period decrease in the price of aluminium causes a rightward
Production
shift in the mineral demand curve for copper and an
Production function
function after before technological increase in the price causes a leftward shift.
technological change
change Price changes for a substitute mineral are more
complicated. There is a direct effect as well as an
indirect effect of the price change. A higher price of
aluminium destined for the electric rotor industry may
Units of coal result in a direct increase in the use of copper because
per time period copper will be substituted for aluminium. However,
Fig 5.5 - Technological change shifting final-product production function. the higher price of aluminium may cause copper use
to decline indirectly because copper may not be able to
Even though refinement and improvement completely replace all aluminium. The indirect effect of
technological changes directly reduce the demand the increase in the price of aluminium is caused by the
for coal in the production of steel, it also indirectly increase in the cost of producing the final product, which
increases the demand for coal in the production of steel. in turn leads to lower production and less demand for
An important result of refinement and improvement both aluminium and copper. The final result of a price
technological change is its ability to lower the cost of change for a substitute mineral depends on which effect
delivering an extra unit of steel to market. This will is larger, the direct or indirect, and varies from product
increase the quantity of steel demanded, which will also to product.
increase the demand for coal. Hence, the coal demand
curve will shift to the right. To conclude, the final result ELASTICITY OF MINERAL DEMAND
of refinement and improvement technological changes When there are price movements along the demand
on a specific minerals demand curve is uncertain. curve as well as shifts in demand, it is important to

Mineral Economics 57
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

have an estimate of the magnitude of these changes. An important consideration between the short and
Economists use the concept of elasticity of demand to long run is that the definitions do not include a definite
indicate the quantitative impact of the factors affecting time period. The definitions are based on the degree of
demand. Even though it is a simple concept, elasticity is flexibility to which firms have to change their inputs
one of the most powerful devices used by economists. and consumers have to change their lifestyles. One of
It is simple because it is no more than a form of the consequences of the definitions is that the relevant
measurement that tells how sensitive one variable is to time period that distinguishes the short run from the
another. It is powerful because of the way economists long run will vary from industry to industry.
make use of how benefits and costs change by very
small changes in specific variables such as prices and Own-price elasticity of mineral demand in the
income. The concept of elasticity can be used to help short run
answer questions such as: The definition of own-price elasticity of demand is the
Will an increase in the price of a firms product make percentage by which quantity demanded changes if its
the firm more or less profitable? price increases by one per cent, all other things being
If the price of a particular good increases, will the equal. The simple formula is:
amount of the good purchased change significantly % change in quantity demanded
or minimally? Own price elasticity of demand =
% change in price
Economists have identified three main types of Own-price elasticity of demand is negative because
elasticity of mineral demand: of the inverse relationship between price and quantity
1. own-price elasticity of demand, which measures demanded, as indicated by the law of demand.
how the quantity demanded of a mineral changes if
If demand is elastic, the ratio of percentage change
its price changes
in quantity demanded resulting from a one per cent
2. income elasticity of demand, which measures how change in price will have an absolute value greater
the quantity demanded of a mineral changes if than one4. If demand is inelastic, the ratio will have an
income increases absolute value between zero and one.
3. cross-price elasticity of demand, which shows how Generally, demand for luxury goods is price inelastic,
the quantity demanded of one mineral changes if as are the demands for essential products such as petrol
the price of another mineral changes. and food since people generally buy them even if
The discussion of elasticity is separated into two their price goes up. In contrast, the demands for many
parts because elasticity is determined, in part, by the consumer goods such as gold jewellery and housewares
time period involved. Therefore, part one introduces us are elastic, since people can easily find substitutes or do
further to the concepts of elasticity of mineral demand without them.
and applies the concepts of elasticity to the short run. Figure 5.6 illustrates two demand curves: one for gold
Part two then shows how the elasticities of mineral jewellery and the other for petrol. From the diagram,
demand change over time and presents how economists when the price of gold jewellery rises from P1 to P2,
use long-run elasticities. the per cent change in the quantity demanded of gold
Economists commonly separate economic periods jewellery from Au1 to Au2 is greater than the percent
into the short run and the long run3. The short run change in price. Therefore, gold jewellery is own-price
is a period in which at least one factor or aspect of market elastic at point Au1. Conversely, when the price of petrol
conditions is fixed. rises from P1 to P2, the per cent change in the quantity
Campbell (1985) argues that a firms lease, existing demanded of petrol from P1 to Pet1 to Pet2 is less than
production capacity, agreed-upon labour contracts and the per cent change in price. Therefore, petrol is own-
several other operating conditions are fixed in the short price inelastic at point Pet1.
run. When considering mineral demand, fixed factors
Gold Jewellery: Petrol:
in the short run would include the capital stock of Elastic Demand Inelastic Demand
companies using a specific mineral in the manufacture $/unit $/unit

of a final product. small percentage


change in quantity
By contrast, the long run has no such fixed costs and large percentage change demanded large
in quantity demanded percentage change
conditions; everything is free to change. Given more time, small percentage change in price
manufacturers can develop new strategies for adjusting in price
P2 P2
production processes such as substituting copper for P1 P1
aluminium; or consumers can adjust personal lifestyles DAu
DPetrol
such as purchasing 18-carat white gold instead of
Au2 Au1 QAu/period Pet2 Pet1 QPetrol/period
platinum jewellery.
Fig 5.6 - Sensitivity of mineral demand to price changes.
3 In Chapter 6, we use the related classification of the immediate run, the short run,
the long run and the very long run. 4 Absolute value means ignoring the sign. The absolute value of -1 is 1.

58 Mineral Economics
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

Before discussing the determinants of own-price own-price elastic. Economists traditionally examine the
elasticity of mineral demand, it is important intuitively response of mineral demand to a final-product price
to understand own-price elasticity. Suppose Nokia change by assuming that the proportions of inputs are
spends a portion of its budget on copper wiring. If the fixed. When the demand for the final product is own-
price of copper wiring rises by five per cent, Nokia may price elastic, say -1.5, then the demand for the final
buy less, but does the company buy six per cent less or product changes 50 per cent more proportionally than
just two per cent less? In the first case, demand would the price. However, when the demand for the final
be own-price elastic, in the second, own-price inelastic. product is own-price inelastic, say -0.5, then quantity
Clearly in the case of petrol, a rise of five per cent in the demanded of the final product changes only half as
price would not cause a buyer to reduce his consumption much proportionally as the price. Therefore, when the
of petrol by more than five per cent. That is, there is a demand for a final-product is own-price elastic, there
small effect of a price change on rates of consumption. will be a greater reduction in the use of all inputs.
The argument would be similar for copper wiring. A good example for the first Hicks-Marshall law is
The demand curves for most minerals are own-price the use of silver in jewellery and dental filling alloys.
inelastic that is, steeply sloped if we are considering The estimated demand for silver jewellery is strongly
the short run because manufacturers and consumers own-price elastic (Venkatesh, 2002; GFMS Limited,
that use minerals as inputs are constrained by their 2004) whereas the estimated demand for dental services
existing plants, equipment, and vehicles. is own-price inelastic (Eriksson, 2003; Grytten, 2005;
In contrast, a higher gold price would cause a Manning and Phelps, 1978)5. As the own-price elasticity
consumer to buy significantly less new gold earrings of demand for silver jewellery is own-price elastic, an
or other jewellery if her own-price elasticity of gold increase in the price of silver jewellery will result in
were elastic. That is, a rise of five per cent in the price a large reduction in the quantity demanded of silver
of gold jewellery would cause the consumer to reduce jewellery. This will, in turn, cause a large reduction in
her consumption of gold jewellery by more than the use of silver. Therefore, an increase in the price of
fivepercent. silver jewellery will result in a large reduction in the
quantity of silver demanded for silver jewellery. In
A good way to examine the factors affecting the own-
contrast, the demand for dental services is own-price
price elasticity of the mineral demand curve is to use
inelastic; therefore, an increase in the price of silver
concepts developed in the four Hicks-Marshall laws of
dental fillings will result in only a small reduction in
derived demand. These four laws are named after the the quantity of silver demanded for silver dental filling
two distinguished British economists, John Hicks and alloys.
Alfred Marshall, who are closely associated with their
development. In his Principles of Economics, Marshall The second Hicks-Marshall law states that mineral
(1920) formulated four rules on the determinants of demand is own-price elastic when it is relatively easy
own-price elasticity of derived demand. Hicks (1966, to substitute other inputs to replace the mineral under
pp 241-247) re-examined Marshalls four rules in The consideration. One measure of substitutability between
Theory of Wages, describing own-price elasticity of inputs considers how much input proportions change
derived demand for labour in terms of substitutability when the price of one of the inputs, say copper, changes,
of inputs and own-price elasticity of final-product holding output of the final product at a fixed level.
demand. While full statements of the four laws are When it is easy to substitute other inputs for copper
quite complex, brief and simplified versions of them then a small change in the price of copper will cause a
yield invaluable insights into the determinants of own- large change in the proportion of the inputs used. On
price elasticity of mineral demand. the other hand, when it is difficult to substitute other
inputs for copper then a small change in the price of
The four Hicks-Marshall laws of derived demand copper is probably not going to cause a firm to replace
conclude that the demand for a mineral will be own-price a unit of copper with a unit of another input.
elastic when:
Decisions about the substitution between a specific
1. the demand for the final product, in which it is an mineral and other inputs depend on two general
input, is own-price elastic factors: technology and relative prices. Different
2. it is relatively easy to substitute other inputs for the combinations of inputs will produce different levels
mineral of output. The results of different combinations of a
3. the supply of other production inputs is own-price mineral such as copper and the remaining inputs to a
elastic final product reflect the technology that is available to
the manufacturer.
4. the mineral accounts for a relatively large share of
total costs of producing the final product. One example of the second Hicks-Marshall law is
seen with naturally-occurring rutile being substituted
Let us examine each of these laws in turn. The first
Hicks-Marshall law states that mineral demand will be 5 In their study of the USA, Manning and Phelps estimated that own-price elasticity for
own-price elastic when the demand for the final product is dental visits was -0.7.

Mineral Economics 59
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

by synthetic rutile which is produced from ilmenite However, if the supply of aluminium is inelastic, the
in the titanium dioxide white pigment, metal and increase in demand for aluminium will substantially
welding-rod coatings markets (Ward, 1990). As it increase its price and the additional quantity of
is relatively easy to substitute synthetic rutile for aluminium supplied to the market will be small. In this
naturally-occurring rutile, a price increase in naturally- case, a manufacturer would not increase its profits by
occurring rutile will result in a large reduction in the increasing its use of aluminium and decreasing its use
quantity of naturally-occurring rutile demanded. of copper.
The third Hicks-Marshall law states that mineral A good example of the third Hicks-Marshall law
demand will be own-price elastic when the supply of other applied to manufacturing in the Former Soviet Union
factors of production is relatively own-price elastic. It is during the 1990s, ie in the early years of transition from
worth digressing for a moment to discuss own-price socialism to capitalism. One of the impacts of inefficient
elasticity of supply (also discussed in Chapter 6). Soviet central planning was that industry became
The responsiveness of supply to changes in price of heavily dependent on energy priced far below world
a good or service is its own-price elasticity of supply, levels (Platts, 2004; European Bank of Reconstruction
as illustrated in Figure 5.7. The definition of own- and Development, 2002). During the 1990s, energy
price elasticity of supply is the percentage by which a consumption fell principally as the result of the severe
products quantity supplied would change if its price decline in output in the early 1990s. For example,
were to increase by one per cent, all other things being Kazakhstans net energy consumption decreased
equal. The simple formula is: by 45per cent between 1992 and 1998 (United States
Energy Information Administration, 2003). As a result,
% change in quantity sup plied during the 1990s there was abundant excess capacity in
Own price elasticity of sup ply
% change in price
electricity generation and the supply of electricity was
quite elastic. A large increase in demand for electricity
$/unit
Elastic Supply
$/unit
Inelastic Supply
in the Former Soviet Union would result in a large
increase in electricity use and a relatively small increase
S in its price.
By contrast, when the supply of electricity is relatively
P2
S inelastic as has recently been in Chile6 increases in
P2
P1
demand drive up electricity prices by a relatively large
P1
amount, but the quantity of electricity used by industry
increases only minimally. The increase in the price of
D
D D D
D
D electricity limits the amount of additional electricity
Q1 Q2 Q/period Q1 Q 2 Q/period
that can be used as a substitute for another fuel mineral.
Fig 5.7 - Own-price elasticities of supply. The fourth Hicks-Marshall law states that mineral
demand is own-price elastic when the mineral accounts for
When supply is inelastic, a change in demand affects a relatively large share of total costs. In this situation, a
the price more than the quantity supplied. The reverse price increase of the mineral will have a large effect on
is the case when supply is elastic a change in demand a manufacturers costs and, therefore, a large effect on
is met with a small change in market price. the price of the final output. With this large increase
The third Hicks-Marshall law examines the ease with in the price of the final product, the decrease in the
which a mineral can be substituted by other inputs. From quantity of the final product demanded will be large
the discussion of the Hicks-Marshall second law it can be and, consequently, the reduction in the minerals use
seen that substitution between a mineral and other inputs will also be large, all other things equal.
generally depends on technology and relative prices. The use of aluminium and palladium in motor
However, substitution of one mineral input for another, vehicles explains the idea in the fourth Hicks-Marshall
say aluminium for copper, can be also affected by spare law. In 2008, a typical family automobile contained
capacity in an input industry as well as the level of stocks 248kg of aluminium and between three and six grams
or inventories of the other inputs. If there is plenty of of palladium (Ducker Worldwide, 2008 and Loferski,
spare capacity of aluminium or if its stocks are high, a 2011). If palladium costs account for 0.25 per cent of
manufacturer will find it more beneficial to substitute total costs of an automobile, a doubling of its price will
aluminium for copper, all other things being equal. Spare increase the total cost by 0.25 per cent. By contrast, if
capacity and a high level of stocks correspond to elastic aluminium inputs account for two per cent of total costs
supply. Therefore, if the price of copper increases and the of an automobile, a doubling of its price will increase
supply of aluminium is own-price elastic, the increase in total costs by two per cent. As a result, aluminium has a
demand for aluminium will have little effect on the price higher own-price elasticity of demand than palladium
of aluminium and a manufacturer may significantly in the automobile industry.
increase profits by increasing its use of aluminium and 6 Energy prices in Chile have nearly tripled in the last five years. This has caused copper
decreasing its use of copper. mines to rely more heavily on diesel-powered generation (Haynes, 2011).

60 Mineral Economics
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

Income elasticity of mineral demand in the between mineral demand and the state of its economy,
short run particularly its investment spending. Large fluctuations
in investment are often considered the driving force
Income elasticity of demand is a measure of the
of business cycles measured by fluctuations of
sensitivity of demand to changes in consumers income.
GDP over time. Expansions and booms are generally
It is the percentage by which demand will change if
characterised by high levels of investment, whereas
consumers incomes change by one per cent, all other
troughs are generally characterised as low investment.
things being equal. Its simple formula is:
During economic downturns mineral demand is
% change in quantity demanded commonly low as investment spending on buildings
Income elasticity of demand
% change in income and structures, transportation equipment, heavy
For many products, as income rises, demand machinery and consumer durables is greatly reduced.
increases. Goods and services with income elasticities Conversely, mineral demand is commonly very high
above one are called income elastic. The demand for during economic upturns as the consumption of capital
many minerals is income elastic. This is a direct result goods and consumer durables swells. This pattern
of the demand for final products being income elastic. suggests that, at least in the short run, mineral demand
in most developed countries is strongly income elastic.
These final products things such as automobiles,
houses and refrigerators are items that consumers For major mineral exporting countries, such as
are more inclined to buy during economic upturns. Australia9, the implications of short-run mineral
Purchases of these durable goods (often also known as demand being income elastic are significant. Generally,
discretionary goods) usually increase when consumers short-run income-elastic mineral demand causes the
feel wealthier. mineral demand curve to shift sharply over the business
cycle prompting mineral output, prices, revenues and
However, the demand for some minerals such as
profits to fluctuate greatly (Pei and Tilton, 1999). The
crude oil and industrial minerals are income inelastic7.
resulting volatility can have significant impact on a
Consider, for instance the demand for residential
countrys management of its macro-economy because
electricity as compared to gold jewellery8. Purchasing
of sudden swings in exchange rates and in tax revenues
gold jewellery is more of a discretionary purchase than
from the mining sector (Humphreys, 2000).
purchasing electricity for home use. Accordingly, we
expect the demand for electricity to be income inelastic In addition, because Australia is a commodity exporter
and the demand for gold jewellery to be income elastic and an importer of consumer durables and investment
(see Figure 5.8). goods, its economy does not always conform to the
general country-level models. Australias mineral sector
Quantity Quantity is to a great extent linked with the manufacturing,
demanded demanded
construction and transportation sectors of other
Normal good:
Normal good:
income inelastic
countries. The International Monetary Fund (2011)
income elastic
found that a one per cent change in emerging Asias
GDP over the 2000 - 2010 period lead to a 0.33 per cent
increase in Australian GDP10. As a result, the linkage
between income levels and the demand for minerals
in the case of Australia should be examined at a multi-
Income/period Income/period country scale.
Fig 5.8 - Income elasticities of demand.
Cross-price elasticity of mineral demand in the
Resource economists commonly apply the concept
short run
of income elasticity of demand to analyse the It is also possible to use the concept of elasticity to
effect of changes in national income levels using indicate the effect of price changes in related products.
measures such as Gross Domestic Product (GDP) The relevant concept here is the cross-price elasticity
on the demand for minerals. For example, they may of demand. It relates the percentage change in quantity
investigate how changes in national income influence demanded for a mineral, say gold, with the percentage
iron ore demand. Year-to-year instability in a countrys change in the price of another mineral, say platinum, all
mineral consumption is due, in part, to the strong link other things being equal. The simple formula is:

7 The demand for a mineral is income inelastic if the ratio of the change in quantity 9 This argument applies also to countries such as Chile, as well as many oil exporting
demanded resulting from a one per cent change in income is between zero and one. nations and several other mineral dependent developing nations.
Income elastic goods have a ratio greater than one. 10 From 2000 to 2010, Australia benefited significantly from emerging Asias robust
8 Data show that non-monetary demand for gold is income elastic and the demand for commodity demand. In particular, urbanisation and industrialisation in China and India
residential electricity is strongly income inelastic (Pulvermacher, 2005; Fell, Li and boosted demand for commodities, especially iron ore and coal that account for one-third
Paul, 2010). of Australias exports (International Monetary Fund, 2011).

Mineral Economics 61
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

% change in quantity demanded of good 'A' demand. Du Pont argued that cellophane was not a
Cross price elasticity of demand
% change in price of good 'B' separate market, since at prevailing prices its demand
was cross-price elastic, with respect to aluminium
The cross-price elasticity of demand can be positive or
foil, wax paper and polyethylene. This meant that
negative, depending on whether we observe a change
what seemed to be a single seller or monopoly in the
in the price of a substitute or a complement. If the two
cellophane market looked like a much more modest
minerals are substitutes, an increase in the price of one
share of the wrappings market. The court found that
will increase the demand for the other, so the cross-
Du Pont did not have monopoly power despite control
price elasticity will be positive. For example, gold and
of 100 per cent of the cellophane market because
platinum can be considered substitutes in the jewellery
cellophane made up only 20 per cent of the wrappings
market in India (Johnson Matthey, 2009) where the sales market (Cueller, 2000).
of platinum jewellery are closely linked to the relative
platinum/gold price (Watts, Clarke and Aitlan, 2010). Elasticity of mineral demand in the long run
The surge in platinum jewellery sales in 2008 was, in Because minerals are inputs in durable and non-durable
part, due to the large decrease in the relative platinum final products, from the construction of buildings to the
gold price when platinum lost around 25 per cent of its manufacture of prescription drugs, it is important to
value (Johnson Matthey, 2009). Figure 5.9 illustrates a discuss the effect of adjustment time on the elasticities of
positive cross-price elasticity of demand for gold with mineral demand. Commonly, economists examine only
respect to platinum. long-run own-price and income elasticities of demand.
However, over the long run, minerals do exhibit
$/unit
some cross-price responsiveness because certain
Price of palladium, a Price of platinum, a
complement mineral, substitute mineral, rises. equipment choice decisions include the consideration
rises. Demand for gold Demand for gold increases.
Positive cross-price
of minerals, especially fuel minerals. An example
decreases. Negative
cross-price elasticity of elasticity of demand is the decision to use natural gas instead of electric
demand water heaters. Some equipment choices are based on
more than just the price of a single mineral and these
results in measurable long-run cross-price elasticities.
Notwithstanding such cases, this discussion of long-
run elasticities is restricted to own-price and income
elasticities of mineral demand.
D1 D2 A significant percentage of industrial minerals are
D0
used in nondurable final products. These include clays
Quantity of gold/period in animal feedstuffs and medicines, as well as limestone
Fig 5.9 - Cross-price elasticity of demand. in paper.
Generally, for nondurable final products, the longer
By contrast, if two minerals are complements, an the time that buyers have to adjust, the larger will be the
increase in the price of one will reduce the demand for response to a price change. Accordingly, the demand
the other; therefore, the cross-price elasticity will be for such goods will be more own-price elastic in the
negative. The demand of 18-carat white gold, which is long run than in the short run. Figure 5.10 illustrates
an alloy made by mixing 75 per cent gold with 25per the short- and long-run demand for a nondurable good.
cent other metals, such as silver and palladium, is A nondurable final product worth highlighting
sensitive to the prices of gold, silver and palladium is petrol. To the extent that petrol has no short-run
(Gilletts Jewellers, 2004). Therefore, if the price of substitutes, the short-run demand is own-price inelastic.
palladium rises by 50 per cent, the demand for gold will
decrease, as is illustrated in Figure 5.9. $/unit

Cross-price elasticity of demand is a common


analytical tool to identify markets in anti-trust inquiries.
By examining the cross-price elasticity of demand it
is possible to measure how much a firm can raise its
prices without consumers defecting to some substitute long run
and other firms altering their production processes and demand
supplying similar products at lower prices. If there are
close substitutes, then the price increase initiated by the
firm will lead to a large reduction in its sales, and its short run
profits will fall, as a consequence. demand
The 1956 USA anti-trust case against Du Pont is a Q Q/period
classic example of the use of cross-price elasticity of Fig 5.10 - Short- and long-run demand for a nondurable final product.

62 Mineral Economics
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

The short-run effect of price changes on the quantity Consequently, the difference between short and long
demanded will discourage people from purchasing an run elasticities of demand for minerals used in durable
additional car or driving to work. Over time, however, products depends on the interaction between the time
people will purchase more fuel-efficient automobiles needed to adjust to the new final-product prices and the
and find alternative means of transportation. replacement frequency for the final products.
Accordingly, the demand for petrol will be more own- We have just seen how time can affect the elasticities
price elastic in the long run. The short-term own-price of mineral demand. Now let us examine if the nature of
elasticity of petrol has been estimated to be between income elasticity of mineral demand over the long term
-0.034 to -0.077 (Hughes, Knittel and Sperling, 2008), can help make long-range forecasts about the demand
and the long-term elasticity has been estimated at -0.46 for minerals. It was concluded above that economic
(Brons et al, 2008). If we combine this information with booms tend to increase the demand for minerals in
the first Hicks-Marshall law mineral demand will be the short run; however, prolonged economic growth
own-price elastic when the demand for the final product is that is, continuing increases in the real GDP can
own-price elastic the long-run demand for crude oil, correspond with a decrease in the demand for minerals
which is used as an input in petrol, will be more own- per person in the very long run.
price elastic than the short-run demand for crude oil. Economists commonly make mineral demand fore-
Even though many minerals are used in the casts by examining a minerals intensity-of-use to a
manufacturing of nondurable final products, the countrys per capita income. Intensity-of-use reflects the
predominant use of minerals, especially metals, is as demand of a mineral (usually measured in physical units
inputs in the manufacturing of durable final products, like tonnes) per unit of income discounted over time for
such as motor vehicles. The effect of adjustment time inflation (usually measured in billion dollars of GDP). In
on the demand for many durable final products is general, a countrys intensity-of-use of a mineral follows
different than for nondurable final products. Similar to an inverted U-shape when plotted against per capita
the demand for nondurable final products, the demand GDP. Figure 5.11 shows a representative curve.
for durable final products is more own-price elastic
tonnes/billion $US of GDP

in the long run than in the short run as buyers need


30
time to adjust to new prices. However, an opposing
effect can lead final-product demand to be relatively 20
more elastic in the short run. This opposing effect is
especially strong for large changes in income. That is, 10
the demand for some durable final products tends to
tonnes

be more income elastic in the short run than in the long 0


run. As a consequence, the demand for minerals used in 0 1000 2000 3000 4000

some durable final products is likely to be more income Per capita GDP ($US)
elastic in the short run than in the long run. Fig 5.11 - Intensity-of-use curve.
A second example involving motor vehicles illustrates
that the adjustment time for durable final products is Tilton (2003) identifies the two factors that cause
somewhat different than nondurable final products. this U-shape of intensity-of-use curves as changes in
Commonly, people purchase new automobiles at the product composition of income and changes in
intervals of several years. Now, suppose that there the mineral composition of products. Changes in the
is a fall in income, referred to here as a decrease in a product composition of income occur because of changes
persons purchasing power11. Some buyers will defer in consumer preferences as per capita incomes rise. At
their plans to replace their cars, keeping their present low levels of development (low levels of per capita
models a little longer. Therefore, a decrease in income GDP), when subsistence agriculture predominates,
will cause purchases of new cars to fall, all other things mineral use tends to be minimal. Urbanisation and
being equal. In the long run, buyers eventually need to industrialisation propels an increase in mineral
replace their cars and the effect of a decrease in income demand to build basic infrastructure such as roads,
may be minimal. As a result, a decrease in income railways, bridges, factories, pipelines and power grids.
will cause demand for minerals used in motor cars As development continues (per capita GDP increases
to decrease more sharply in the short run than in the further), the need for basic infrastructure declines
long run. Similarly, if incomes rise, people will replace the replacement frequency for basic infrastructure is
their cars more frequently. Therefore, an increase in very low and consumer demand shifts increasingly
incomes will tend to cause demand for minerals used in towards services and nondurable final products,
automobiles to increase more sharply in the short run which are less mineral-intensive. The transition from
than in the long run. a manufacturing-based economy to a service-based
11 A reduction in a persons purchasing power can be caused by either a decrease in wage economy slows and eventually reverses the trend of
earnings, an increase in inflation without an equivalent increase in wages, or both. consumption of minerals as a function of income.

Mineral Economics 63
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

The mineral composition of products refers to the The chapter also demonstrated that elasticity of
amount of minerals used to produce particular goods mineral demand is important from the standpoint of
or services. The changes in the material composition understanding the magnitude of changes in mineral
of products are driven by material substitution and demand caused by changes in price, income and the
technological advancement. One major caveat of the prices of related products. The short-run demand
relationship shown in Figure 5.11 is that per capita for most minerals is own-price inelastic because
GDP is not a reasonable proxy for the underlying forces manufacturers and consumers that use minerals as inputs
technological progress that determine the trend are constrained by their existing plants, equipment and
in changes in the material composition of products. vehicles. Also, the short-run demand for most minerals
This trend is more likely correlated with time than is strongly income elastic as a result of high demand
with income. As a result, the inverted U-shape is not for final products being strongly income elastic. As the
stable, but rather typically shifts downward over time demand for most minerals is own-price inelastic and
(Guzman, Nishiyama and Tilton, 2005). Therefore, income elastic, many minerals having steeply sloped
there is no simple relationship between long-run demand curves that experience significant shifts over
mineral demand and income. The true relationship is the business cycle. Two important consequences of these
complicated by a complex interaction between price features are severe fluctuations in the market prices of
differences between materials, technological change, minerals and profits for mineral industry firms.
material life-cycles, consumer tastes, changes in lifestyle
and other such factors (Campbell, 1985). To complete the discussion of elasticity of mineral
demand it is important to examine the effects of time.
The Japanese economy provides a clear example of a Mineral demand tends to be more own-price elastic over
change in the product composition of income. In 1984, the long run because buyers have more time to adjust
for every inflation-adjusted billion yen of industrial their behaviour. Also, the demand for some minerals
production, Japan consumed only 60 per cent of the the ones used as inputs in durable final products are
raw materials that were consumed for the same volume likely to be more income elastic in the short run than in
of industrial production in 1973 (Drucker, 1986). This the long run.
trend corresponded to the switching away from heavily
material-intensive products to more high-technology Finally, this chapter has demonstrated that the
products. demand for minerals is multifaceted. Understanding
the demand side of the mineral markets is essential
The change in the material composition of products for both analysts and policymakers so that they can
is clearly visible with the trend towards more use of understand the economic implications of changes in
aluminium and plastics and less steel in automobiles. mineral markets.
In 1960, an average US domestic automobile consisted
of two per cent aluminium and one per cent plastics, REFERENCES
while in 2008 these percentages had increased to six and
Brons, M R E, Nijkamp, P, Pels, E and Rietveld, P, 2006. A
one-half per cent for aluminium and eight per cent for meta-analysis of the price elasticity of gasoline demand:
plastics (Kandelaars and van Dam, 1998; Davis, Diegel A system of equations approach, Tinbergen Institute
and Boundy, 2010). The substitution of aluminium and discussion paper TI 2006-106/3.
plastics for steel in automobiles has caused a reduction Campbell, G A, 1985. Theory of mineral demand, in Economics
in the use of steel per automobile produced. of the Mineral Industries, fourth edition (ed: W A Vogely)
Today, economists are using the intensity-of-use (American Institute of Mining, Metallurgy, and Petroleum
Engineers: New York).
approach to forecast mineral demand in China and
India. For example, Wrrel and Olsson (2009) used this Cueller, S S, 2000. Is Microsoft a monopoly? Sonoma State
University Working Paper.
approach to determine where both India and China
Davis, S C, Diegel, S W and Boundy, R G, 2010. Transportation
were on the intensity-of-use curve in 2008.
Energy Data Book, Edition 29 [online]. Available from:
<http://info.ornl.gov/sites/publications/files/pub24318.
CONCLUSIONS pdf> [Accessed: 11 July 2011].
As demonstrated in this chapter, most minerals Drucker, P F, 1986. The changed world economy, Foreign
are demanded as inputs for final products, such as Affairs, 63(4):768-791.
automobiles, buildings, transportation infrastructure, Ducker Worldwide, 2008. Aluminium Association auto and
mobile telephones and jewellery. As a result, there are light truck group 2009 update on North American light
characteristics of mineral demand that are different vehicle aluminium content compared to the other countries
from usual final-product demand. In particular, and regions of the world Phase II [online]. Available from:
<http://www.drivealuminum.org/research-resources/
mineral demand is strongly dependent on existing
PDF/Research/2009/2009-Ducker-Report.pdf> [Accessed:
production technologies as well as on competing and 4 July 2011].
complementary inputs of production. Furthermore, the Dulay, N, 2004. Fiber optic interconnections within computer
demand for minerals depends on changes in demand systems [online]. Available from: <http://www.doc.
for final products, changes in technology and changes ic.ac.uk/~nd/surprise_97/journal/vol3/si1/answer.html>
in the mix of inputs. [Accessed: 24 June 2011].

64 Mineral Economics
chapter 5 Mineral Demand The Theory in Practice

Eriksson, R, 2003. The effects of deregulating prices for dental Mill, J S, 1863. Ulitarianism [online]. Available from: <http://
services, Swedish Institute for Social Research working www.utilitarianism.com/mill2.htm> [Accessed: 4 July
paper. 2011].
European Bank of Reconstruction and Development, 2002. Mitchell, G D, no date. Coal utilization in the steel
Transition report 2001: Energy in transition, European industry [online]. Available from: <http://www.
Bank of Reconstruction and Development, London. steel.org/Making%20Steel/How%20Its%20Made/
European Copper Institute, 2008. The development of Processes/Processes%20Info/Coal%20Utilization%20
renewable energies is stimulating demand for copper in in%20the%20Steel%20Industry.aspx> [Accessed:
Europe [online]. Available from: <http://www.eurocopper. 24 June 2011].
o r g / f i l e s / p r e s s _ r e l e a s e _ c o p p e r _ i n _ r e n e wa b l e s _ Otnes, C C and Pleck, E H, 2003. Cinderella Dreams: The Allure of
final_29_10_2008.pdf> [Accessed: 26 January 2012]. the Lavish Wedding (University of California Press: Berkeley).
Federal Statistical Office of Germany, 2011. Share of
Pei, F and Tilton, J E, 1999. Consumer preferences, technological
renewable energy sources in gross consumption of
change, and the short-run income elasticity of metal
electricity and primary energy from 1991 [online].
demand, Resources Policy, 25:87-109.
Available from: <http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/
portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/Statistics/ Pequignot, J L, 2010. Creating an engaging tradition: NW Ayer
Energie/Tabellen/Content50/ErneuerbareEnergie.psml> & Son and De Beers advertising campaigns in the United
[Accessed: 2 June 2011]. States from 1939 to 1952, Masters of Arts thesis, Miami
Fell, H, Li, S and Paul, A, 2010. A new look at residential University.
electricity demand using household expenditure data, Platts, 2004. Country profiles Kazakhstan [online]. Available
Resources for the Future discussion paper, 10-57. from: <http://www.platts.com/Electric%20Power/Resour
GFMS Limited, 2004. Publication of platinum and palladium ces/News%20Features/worldcap/kazakprofile.html>
survey 2004 [online]. Available from: <http://www.gfms. [Accessed: 5 August 2004].
co.uk/Press%20Releases/GFMS_PGMsurvey04_PR_ Pulvermacher, K, 2005. What are commodities? [online].
Highlights.pdf> [Accessed: 3 August 2004]. Available from: <http://www.gold.org/download/pub_
Gilletts Jewellers, 2004. White gold versus platinum: White archive/pdf/what_are_commodities_0305.pdf> [Accessed:
gold and platinum information [online]. Available from: 4 June 2011].
<http://gilletts.com.au/information.php?info_id=13> Tilton, J E, 2003. On Borrowed Time? Assessing the Threat of
[Accessed: 11 July 2011]. Mineral Depletion (Resources for the Future: Washington).
Grytten, J, 2005. Models for financing dental care, Community United States Commodity Futures Trading Commission,
Dental Health, 22:75-85.
2011. Futures only reports [online]. Available from: <http://
Guzman, J I, Nishiyama, T and Tilton, J E, 2005. Trends in the www.cftc.gov/MarketReports/CommitmentsofTraders/
intensity of copper use in Japan since 1960, Resources Policy HistoricalCompressed/index.htm> [Accessed: 30 May
30(1):21-27. 2011].
Haynes, B, 2011. Costly Chile power may jolt renewable United States Energy Information Administration, 2003.
energy, Reuters, February 10.
Kazakhstan country analysis brief [online]. Available from:
Hicks, J R, 1966. The Theory of Wages, second edition <http://www.eia.gov/countries/country-data.cfm?fips=kz>
(St Martins Press: New York). [Accessed: 5 August 2004].
Hughes, J E, Knittel, C R and Sperling, D, 2008. Evidence of a Venkatesh, R, 2002. Indias consuming interest in silver,
shift in the short-run price elasticity of gasoline demand, Alchemist, 28.
The Energy Journal, 29(1):113-134.
Ward, C, 1990. The production of synthetic rutile and by-
Humphreys, D, 2000. Mining as a sustainable economic
product iron oxide pigments from ilmenite processing, PhD
activity, paper presented at the OECD, Paris, 9 February
thesis (unpublished), Murdoch University, Perth, Western
2000.
Australia.
International Monetary Fund, 2011. Regional economic
outlook, Asia and Pacific, Washington. Wrrel, L and Olsson, A, 2009. Trends and developments in the
intensity of steel use: An econometric analysis, presented
Johnson Matthey, 2009. Platinum jewellery demand surging
at Securing the Future and 8th ICARD, Skellefte, Sweden,
in India [online]. Available from: <http://www.platinum.
23 - 26 June.
matthey.com/news-and-events/news-articles/2009/
january/22nd/platinum-jewellery-demand-surging-in- Watts, J C, Clarke, B and Aitlan, O, 2010. Jewellery shocks
india> [Accessed: 11 July 2011]. from China and India, paper presented to the Fourth
Kandelaars, P and van Dam, J D, 1998. An analysis of variables International Platinum Conference, The Southern African
influencing the material composition of automobiles, Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, Sun City, South Africa,
research memorandum 1998-51S Amsterdam Free 11 - 13 October.
University. Wiesmann, G, 2011. Germany to scrap nuclear power by 2022,
Loferski, P J, 2011. Personal communication, 7 June 2011. Financial Times, 30 May.
Manning, W G and Phelps, C E, 1978. Dental care demand: World Bank, 2011. China: GNI per capita, Atlas method
Point estimates and implications for national health (current US$) [online]. Available from: <http://search.
insurance, Rand Corporation document No R-2157-HEW. worldbank.org/data?qterm=china%20gni%20per%20
Marshall, A, 1920. Principles of Economics, eighth edition [online] capita&language=EN> [Accessed: 1 June 2011].
(Macmillan: London). Available from: <www.econlib.org/ World Gold Council, 2011. Gold demand trends: First quarter
library/Marshall/marP1.html> [Accessed: 4 July 2011]. 2011.

Mineral Economics 65

Вам также может понравиться