Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 37

Slides for Chapter 10:

Exchange Rate Policy and Unemployment

International Macroeconomics

Schmitt-Grohé Uribe Woodford

Columbia University

May 1, 2016

1
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Sudden Stops and the Real Exchange Rate

Case Study: The End of the Argentine Convertibility Plan

What was the Argentine Convertibility Plan? April 1991-December


2001, 1 peso = 1 dollar

’99-’01 ’02
GDP Growth Rate -2.8% -10.9%
Inflation -1.3% 41%
S P eso/$ 1.0 3.5

Dec. 2001 Argentina defaults on its (domestic and) foreign debt. →


leads to a cutoff from international capital markets. [This is called
a Sudden Stop.]

2
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

What happens to the RER?

Peso/$ S Peso/$P U S
e =
P Arg

Take log differences

%∆ePeso/$ = %∆S Peso/$ + %∆P U S − %∆P Arg


= 250% + 2.5% − 41%
' 200%.

⇒ After the default Argentina experiences a real depreciation of


about 200%.

3
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

How can we understand this?

– Tariff? — No, not really.

– Balassa Samuelson — Not that likely an explanation.

Here is a different explanation: The Sudden Stop (CT ↓) caused the


real depreciation.

The next slides provide some evidence in support of the claim that
Argentina experienced a sudden stop in 2002.

4
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Interest Rates shoot up

5
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Current Account Reversal

(the graph shows −CAt)

• we see current account deficits until the year 2000

• then drastic current account reversal beginning in 2001 with


current account surpluses in 2001 and 2002

6
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

7
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Large Real Exchange Rate Depreciation

8
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Large Contraction in GDP

9
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

All graphs are taken from: “The IMF and Argentina, 1991-2001,”
prepared by a team headed by Shinji Takagi, Washington, D.C.:
International Monetary Fund, Independent Evaluation Office, 2004.

10
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Why did the Real Exchange Rate Depreciate so Much ?


Recall

Peso/$ S Peso/$P U S
e =
P Arg
φ(P U S, P U S)
= S Peso/$ T
arg
N
arg
φ(PT , PN )
φ(1, PNus /P us )
= T
arg arg
φ(1, PN /PT )

Taking log differences

%∆ePeso/$ = α %∆(PN us /P us ) − %∆(P arg /P arg )


h i
T N T
arg arg
' 0% − α %∆(PN /PT )
arg arg
200% ' −0.75 %∆(PN /PT )

11
⇒ So the question of why did the real exchange rate depreciate so
much becomes: “Why did the relative price of nontradables fall so
much in Argentina after the Sudden Stop”.
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

What happens in a Sudden Stop?

Narrative: Argentina had a large trade deficit before the Sudden


Stop. With the default it has no more access to international
capital markets. The CA must swing into balance, or surplus,
CA ≥ 0 and there must be a trade balance reversal from deficits
to surplus, T B => 0. With a trade balance reversal domestic
demand for traded goods falls, and absent any relative price changes
domestic demand for nontraded goods also falls. Weak domestic
demand for nontradables will lead to a decline in the relative price
of nontradables bringing about a real depreciation.

We will embed this narrative into a theoretical model next.

12
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

The TNT Model

2 goods: QT and QN
QT = traded output
QN = nontraded output
PT = domestic currency price of traded good
PN = domestic currency price of nontraded good

Law of one price holds for traded goods: PT = SPT∗

13
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Production

Production of Tradables:

QT = FT (LT ); FT0 (·) > 0; ; FT00 (·) < 0;

LT = labor input in the traded sector

Production of Nontradables:

QN = FN (LN ); 0 (·) > 0; ;


FN 00 (·) < 0;
FN

LN = labor input in the nontraded sector

14
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Labor Supply

Fixed Labor Supply: L = LT + LN

L = total labor supply

Increase in labor input in the traded sector must be compensated


one for one by decreases in the nontraded sector

dLT = −dLN (1)

15
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Construct the Production Possibility Frontier

dQT = FT0 (LT )dLT (2)

0
dQN = FN (LN )dLN (3)

[insert graph]

What is the slope of the PPF?

Divide (3) by (2) and use (1) to obtain:


dQN 0 (L )
FN N
=− 0
dQT FT (LT )

16
This equations says that the slope of the PPF is equal to the
marginal rate of transformation between traded and nontraded goods.

Suppose we move down the PPF, producing more tradables. Then


LT must rise and LN must fall. This raises the marginal product
of labor in the nontraded sector, FN 0 (L ), and lowers the marginal
N
product of labor in the traded sector, FT0 (LT ). This is so because
we are assuming that the production functions display decreasing
returns to scale, which is to say we assume that the marginal product
of labor is decreasing with labor.

This assumption then implies that the PPF becomes steeper as QT


rises. It follows that the PPF is concave towards the origin,

Our argument is that a Sudden Stop moves the economy down


its PPF, reallocating production from the nontraded sector to the
nontraded sector. The above relation says that the sudden stop
causes the economy to produce at a point where the PPF is steeper.
But we want to link the Sudden Stop to a real exchange depreciations.
Is there a link between the slope of the PPF and the relative price
of nontradables in terms of tradables? We will show that link in the
next slide.
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Traded Goods Sector


Firms choose QT and LT to maximize profits

profits = PT QT − W LT .
subject to
QT = FT (LT ).

Eliminate QT
profits = PT FT (LT ) − W LT
Choose LT to maximize profits
∂profits
= 0 ⇒ PT FT0 (LT ) = W (*)
∂LT

17
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Nontraded Goods Sector


Firms choose QN and LN to maximize profits

profits = PN QN − W LN .
subject to
QN = FN (LN ).

Eliminate QN
profits = PN FN (LN ) − W LN
Choose LN to maximize profits
∂profits 0 (L ) = W
= 0 ⇒ PN F N N (**)
∂LN

18
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Combining (*) with (**) yields

PT 0 (L )
FN
= 0 N (4)
PN FT (LT )

As we move down the PPF its slope becomes steeper and steeper
implying that the relative price of nontradables relative to tradables
falls.

19
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

A Sudden Stop is a situation in which the production of nontradables


must fall and the production of tradables must rise. That is a move
down the production possibility frontier. What will induce firms to
shift production out of the nontraded sector and into the traded
sector? The relative price of nontraded goods must fall.

Hence a Sudden Stop leads to a real exchange rate depreciation.

20
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

In 2008 Iceland experienced a Sudden Stop

1. Interest rates spike

2. Large trade balance reversal

3. Output suddenly stops growing

and ...

as in the case of Argentina in 2001, the sudden stop is associated


with a large real exchange depreciation

Let’s look at the data for Iceland

21
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Interest rates spike

Here we look at Credit Default Swap (CDC) rates.

What is a Credit Default Swap.

Suppose the government of Iceland issues a 10-year bond for $100


with an annual coupon rate of 5 percent. This means that Iceland
must make a payment to the lender of $5 every year and in year 10
must also pay the principal of $100.

In a CDS contract the seller of that contract offers insurance against


default by the debtor (= Iceland). This insurance contract (the
CDS contract) works as follows. Every year that the debtor does
not default the creditor pay the CDS rate, denoted c, to the insurer,
that is, every year the creditor pays c × 100. Now suppose the debtor
defaults. Then the insurer buys from the creditor the defaulted debt
22
at face value, that is, in our example the insurer buys the defaulted
debt from the lender for $100.

CDS rates are often used to measure how borrowing costs increase
for a given country because they are easily available.

The next graph shows Iceland’s CDS spreads between September 1


2008 and October 29, 2008. The units of the vertical axis are basis
points. The horizontal axis measures time. The graph shows that
betwen Sept 1, 2008 and October 11, 2008 the Icelandic CDS spread
increased from 2 percent (200 basis points) to over 14 percent (1400
basis points). This large increase in CDS spreads indicates that
interest rates at which Iceland would have been able to borrow must
have increased significantly.
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

The interest rate increase is accompanied by a dramatic trade balance


reversal

The units on the vertical axis are percent of GDP.

The trade balance goes from a deficit of 15 percent of GDP in 2006


to a surplus of 10 percent of GDP in 2010.

23
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

... and output stops growing

24
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

... And what happens to the real exchange rate? The real exchange
rate depreciates!

25
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

To sum up, Iceland in 2008 represents another example in which a


sudden stop lead to a large real exchange rate depreciation in the
short run.

26
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Third Example of observing a large Real Exchange


Rate depreciation after a Sudden Stop

Case Study: Chile 1979-1985

In 1982 (after the default of Mexico in August) credit dries up for


highly indebted developing countries, particularly in Latin America.
These countries were running large current account deficits. The
Sudden Stop forces them to run TB surpluses to service their existing
debts.
What is the required external adjustment?

QT ↑ and QN ↓

This adjustment caused a large real exchange rate depreciation (and


with it costly reallocations of production away from the nontraded
sector towards the traded sector)
27
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Chile, Real Exchange Rate Depreciation and Trade Balance


Reversal, 1979-1985

∆e TB
GDP
Year % %
1979 -1.7
1980 -2.8
1981 -8.2
1982 20.6 0.3
1983 27.5 5.0
1984 5.1 1.9
1985 32.6 5.3

cumulative RER depreciation of close to 90 percent.

28
International Macroeconomics, Chapter 10 Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, Woodford

Add other examples of sudden stops...

29

Вам также может понравиться