Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 11

AGRICULTURAL

ECONOMICS

Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89

Is agriculture the engine of growth?


Richard Tiffin∗ , Xavier Irz
Department of Agricultural and Food Economics, University of Reading, Earley Gate, P.O. Box 237, Reading, RG6 6AR, Reading, UK
Received 3 February 2004; received in revised form 12 January 2005; accepted 3 June 2005

Abstract
We seek to address formally the question raised by Gardner (2003) in his Elmhirst lecture as to the direction of causality between agricultural
value added per worker and Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita. Using the Granger causality test in the panel data analyzed by Gardner for 85
countries, we find overwhelming evidence that supports the conclusion that agricultural value added is the causal variable in developing countries,
while the direction of causality in developed countries is unclear. We also examine further the use of the Granger causality test in integrated data
and provide evidence that the performance of the test can be increased in small samples through the use of the bootstrap.

JEL classification: C22, C23, O41

Keywords: Agriculture and growth; Granger causality; Unit roots in panel data; Bootstrap

1. Introduction Section 2 reviews the literature on the relationship between


agricultural and economic growth. The testing procedures we
In his Elmhirst lecture, Gardner (2003) considers the sources employ are discussed in general in Section 3 while the specific
and constraints on agricultural growth. As part of the paper he details of the procedure we employ are given in Section 4.
investigates the relationship between the growth in agricultural Section 5 presents the results and Section 6 concludes.
value added per worker and GDP per capita for 52 develop-
ing countries. He provides evidence of a positive relationship 2. Insights from the literature
between these growth rates and poses the question: “What is
the direction of causality?” There is a substantial literature that Most early development strategies, advocated by Rosenstein-
provides conflicting evidence in answering the question. For Rodan, Nurkse, and Hirshman among others, emphasized in-
example some suggest that the export of surplus resources from dustrial development as the main source of economic growth
agriculture leads to agriculture driving economic growth. Oth- and were biased against the agricultural sector (Schiff and
ers suggest that increases in the nonagricultural wage lead to Valdez, 1998). However, the poor growth performance of many
relocation and increases in agricultural productivity thereby newly independent countries, particularly in the 1970s, chal-
implying that causality runs from general economic growth to lenged this view, and the need for agricultural growth became
agriculture. Gardner (2003) provides limited information con- part of the conventional wisdom with the Berg report (World
cerning the methods used to answer this question, however, it is Bank, 1982a) and the 1982 World Development Report (World
concluded that an “investigation of lags . . . does not show agri- Bank, 1982b). This new orthodoxy considers that agricultural
culture as leading.” In this article our aim is to further investigate growth is causally prior to industrial development, based on
the question posed by Gardner using the data he analyzed. Our conceptual arguments and some empirical evidence that we
analysis employs the Granger causality test and as such com- now review.
plements recent work by Gemmell et al. (2000) by applying a Following the classical analyses of Kuznets (1964), Johnston
similar approach to a panel of countries. and Mellor (1961), and Schultz (1964), several contributions of
agriculture to overall economic growth and development are
usually acknowledged. There is, of course, the direct contribu-
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +44 118 378 89651; fax: +44 118 975 64671. tion that an increase in agricultural value added makes to Gross
E-mail address: j.r.tiffin@reading.ac.uk (R. Tiffin). Domestic Product (GDP), which, once expressed in growth rate,


c 2006 International Association of Agricultural Economists
80 R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89

is proportional to the sector’s share of the economy; however, In addition to the above direct effects, increased production
this accounting relationship does not imply causality as the in agriculture has an impact on other sectors through a series
two variables (agriculture value added and GDP) then evolve of linkages. These include production links, both “upstream”
simultaneously. from the farm in demand for inputs and services for agriculture
The generation of a surplus, i.e., resources that can be ex- and “downstream” from the farm in the demand for processing,
ported from agriculture to the rest of the economy to support storage, and transport of produce. There are also consumption
the process of development, seems much more important to ex- links as farmers and farm laborers spend their increased incomes
plain a potential causality from agricultural to general economic on goods and services that are provided by the nonagricultural
growth. First, it is necessary for the agricultural sector to pro- sector. While conceptually simple, these growth linkages are
duce food for the workers engaged in other areas of economic difficult to measure but most empirical studies have estimated
activity and, even if this argument weakens in the context of large multipliers, explained primarily by the strength of the
an open economy, it remains valid as many agricultural goods consumption linkages (Thirtle et al., 2003). Furthermore, these
retain a degree of nontradability. It follows that agricultural ideas have been developed to support the design of so-called
growth can form a pre-condition for the release of labor from agriculture-led industrialization strategies that stress the impor-
agriculture to the rest of the economy. In addition to this direct tance of agriculture in creating a market for industrial products
transfer of resources away from agriculture, output growth in (Adelman, 1995).
agriculture is also likely to result in a decrease in the price of From the previous discussion, the potential for agriculture to
food, which is a wage good, and hence induces economic growth cause general economic growth seems compelling, particularly
through two mechanisms. A relatively low price of food allows in the context of developing countries. It is necessary, however,
industrialists to pay low wages, which boosts the profitability to recognize that several arguments presented in the literature
and competitiveness of the industrial sector, and might result suggest that the causality might run in the opposite direction,
in increased savings and investments (as in Lewis’s celebrated i.e., from nonagricultural to agricultural growth. The main the-
dual-economy model, [Lewis, 1954]), as well as the creation of sis relates to the work initiated by Gardner and Mundlak, who
nonagricultural jobs. Furthermore, a decline in the price of food emphasize adjustments in the labor market as the engine of
effectively increases the real income of net-purchasers of food growth in agricultural value added per worker and agricultural
and the resulting disposable income can help stimulate demand income. Simply stated, an increase in the nonagricultural wage
for nonagricultural products. rate results in a reallocation of labor from agriculture to non-
In a similar vein, agriculture can supply the capital necessary agriculture, which in turn increases labor productivity and
to finance industrial development or the provision of public value-added per worker in the agricultural sector. According
goods by the state. This remains important because, in spite of to this view, there exists a fundamental surplus of labor in
the recent liberalization of capital markets, it is well established agriculture and raising living standards in that sector can only
that for a large majority of countries, investment relies primar- be achieved by growth in the nonfarm economy to which farm
ily on domestic savings (Ventura, 1997). Although this transfer workers have access (Gardner, 2000). Empirical support for this
of resources can rely on voluntary savings by the agricultural idea originates both from developed and developing countries.
population, given the right set of incentives (Griffin, 1979), Hence, Gardner (2000) establishes from a historical analysis of
many governments have historically accelerated the process by U.S. agricultural development that income growth in the non-
taxing agriculture directly or indirectly. Hence, early industri- farm sector is more fundamentally important in increasing farm
alization in Japan in the last decades of the nineteenth century income than any specifically agricultural variable. Estudillo and
was largely financed by a land tax, representing over 80% of Otsuka (1999) find that growth in the nonfarm economy is the
fiscal revenues at the time (Ghatak and Ingersent, 1984), and in key driver of growth in agricultural wage rates in the Philip-
many developing countries, agriculture still makes a substan- pines. Mundlak et al. (2004), in a comparison of agricultural
tial net contribution to government revenue (Schiff and Valdez, development in Indonesia, the Philippines, and Thailand, con-
1992). Similarly, scarcity of foreign exchange in low-income clude in favor of the presence of a clear oversupply of labor
countries may restrict the purchase of capital goods and other in agriculture that is only reinforced by recent technological
imports essential to investment. Here again, growth in output of change in the sector. Finally, Butzer and Larson (2002) con-
tradable farm commodities can make a contribution by either clude from a study of inter-sectoral migrations in Venezuela
substituting food imports or increasing exports. Finally, agricul- that “as labor migrates from agriculture to nonagriculture, labor
ture is a source of raw materials for several industrial subsectors productivity in agriculture increases, reducing the inter-sectoral
that can therefore potentially benefit from agricultural growth. difference.” Another reason why agriculture might benefit from
This argument appears most important for countries at early nonfarm growth is that agricultural growth depends largely on
stages of development, because the textile, food processing, the provision of “modern” inputs and technology from the in-
and other agriculturally based industries require little technol- dustrial sector (Hwa, 1988). As a consequence, growth gen-
ogy and physical capital but are relatively labor intensive, and erating technological change in the manufacturing sector can
hence “fit” the resource endowment of these countries particu- spill-over to agriculture and hence cause growth in that sector
larly well. (Gemmell et al., 2000).
R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89 81

We are therefore left with two opposing views of the role of is essential, at early stages of development, either to overcome
agriculture in the process of economic growth. Traditionally, the Malthusian forces of diminishing returns to a growing labor
agricultural economists consider that growth in the farm sector force operating on a fixed resource base, or to provide an outlet
provides the food, raw materials, labor, capital, and foreign for industrial products.
exchange necessary to finance subsequent growth in the rest DGE models have also been used to explain how the es-
of the economy, while simultaneously generating an additional sential nature of food consumption can explain the growth dy-
demand for industrial goods and services. Lately, arguments namics of low-income countries. Steger (2000) establishes that
have been presented that support the reverse causality, with the transitional dynamics of the neoclassical growth model are
growth in per capita GDP generating an increase in value-added dramatically modified when subsistence consumption is intro-
per worker in agriculture via migration of farm workers to the duced, with early stages of development characterized by low
other sectors of the economy. savings, little investment, and, as a result, slow growth. It fol-
Recently, the question has been addressed by developing lows that the ability of the agricultural sector to produce beyond
dynamic general equilibrium (DGE) models where different the subsistence needs of its population has dynamic effects as
sectors, including agriculture, interact in the process of growth. it increases the aggregate saving rate. Steger (2000) formalizes
The appeal of this approach arises from its internal consis- this idea in a two-sector model of exogenous growth where the
tency in piecing together the ideas outlined above, but this often importance of Engel’s law is recognized. Finally, Steger (2000)
comes at the cost of making a number of simplifying assump- takes a slightly different avenue to reach the identical conclu-
tions. Some important themes emerge from this line of work, sion that the structural change of an economy (i.e., the change in
in particular with respect to the importance that agricultural its sectoral composition induced in part by productivity growth
productivity plays in triggering the process of industrialization in agriculture) is crucial in raising its saving rate.
and development or in influencing the long-term rate of eco- A last group of DGE studies emphasizes externalities as
nomic growth. Hence, Murphy et al. (1989) demonstrate that the key to understanding the contribution of agriculture to the
an increase in agricultural productivity is necessary for the ini- growth process. An original model by Wichman (1995) inves-
tiation and continuation of the growth process. The result is tigates the dynamic implications of an empirically plausible
explained primarily by the assumption of increasing returns to positive relationship between nutrition and labor productivity.
scale in the industrial sector, due to high fixed costs, which In this framework, agricultural growth increases food consump-
implies that the size of the market for industrial goods deter- tion, improves nutrition, and, ultimately, raises labor productiv-
mines whether the sector can operate profitably. In this context, ity in all sectors. When the externality is dynamic, meaning that
the demand generated by agriculture for industrial products is better nutrition not only raises labor productivity instantly but
crucial in making the industrial sector, which ultimately drives also improves learning, the importance of agricultural produc-
the growth process, viable. Along similar lines, a new strand tivity growth in the development process is amplified. Piñeres
of the growth literature concerns itself with the escape from a (1999) extends the human capital models of endogenous growth
“Malthusian trap,” i.e., a regime of growth where any increase to a multisector setting to investigate the ability of the farm sec-
in productivity is negated by population growth, hence prevent- tor to generate long-term growth. The empirical application to
ing any real increase in living standards. For instance, Kogel Columbia concludes that growth in the nontraditional agricul-
and Prskawetz (2001) establish in a model with endogenous fer- tural export sector is superior to manufacturing growth in rais-
tility and technological progress, that an exogenous increase in ing the long-term rate of economic growth. Finally, Matsuyama
the rate of agricultural productivity growth is all that is needed (1992) demonstrates in a two-sector endogenous growth model
to explain the stylized facts of the UK industrial revolution. In a how the benefits from a one-time productivity gain in agricul-
similar vein, Gollin et al. (2002) calibrate a two-sector growth ture depends on the trade regime of the country. In a closed
model to demonstrate that a one time increase in agricultural economy framework, an increase in agricultural productivity
productivity can have dramatic consequences for the speed of a leads to a reallocation of labor away from agriculture because
country’s development, and therefore identify agricultural pro- of Engel’s law; since the postulated engine of growth is learning-
ductivity as a key determinant of underdevelopment. Irz and by-doing in manufacturing, this reallocation induces a rise in the
Roe (2000) reiterate the finding that a minimum rate of produc- rate of economic growth. On the contrary, in an open-economy
tivity growth in agriculture is necessary to counter population framework, increased agricultural productivity reinforces the
growth and avoid the Malthusian trap and, more importantly, country’s comparative advantage in agriculture, induces labor
that the demographic and technological characteristics of sev- to reallocate away from manufacturing where the learning ef-
eral sub-Saharan countries are broadly consistent with such a fect takes place and therefore reduces the long-term rate of
poverty trap. It follows that an agricultural revolution is nec- growth.
essary in that part of the world to trigger sustained economic Altogether, the DGE literature reinforces the idea that, for
growth. Escape from the Malthusian trap is also analyzed by low-income countries, agricultural growth plays a central role
Hansen and Prescott (2002), Lucas (1998), and Gallor and Weill in launching the development process and stresses the impor-
(1999). Altogether, these studies tend to confirm the consensus tance of productivity growth in the sector. We also note that
among development economists that agricultural productivity we are not aware of any DGE study establishing that general
82 R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89

economic growth causes agricultural growth. Furthermore, adjustment model showing that in China, agricultural growth
though insightful, this literature sheds little light on the direc- causes growth of the industrial sector, but the industrial sector
tion of the causality between agricultural and general economic does not contribute to the growth of the agricultural sector. This
growth in countries with relatively high living standards. reflects the “squeeze” that the Chinese state exerted on agricul-
Finally, the inter-relationship of sectors in the process of ture from 1950 to 1980 by imposing artificially low agricultural
development has also been analyzed econometrically for cross- prices among other policies. Altogether, these studies fail to
sections of countries or for particular countries in a time-series identify a unique causal relationship between agricultural and
framework. Taking the former approach, Stern regresses the (av- economic growth; we also note that, to the best of our knowl-
erage) rate of economic growth on the rate of agricultural growth edge, the literature does not present any rigorous cross-country
for a sample of developing countries to find a significant and analysis of this relationship. This is a gap that we aim to fill.
positive relationship for the period 1965–1980 but not for the
period 1980–1990 (Stern, 1996). Echevarria (1997) establishes
3. Tests for integration, cointegration, and noncausality
that in a sample of 62 countries, there is evidence of a positive
relationship between average rate of growth and agriculture’s
When a time series has a unit root in its autoregressive repre-
share of GDP over the 1970–1987 period. Though suggestive
sentation it is subject to a stochastic trend and is consequently
of interactions among sectors in the process of growth, these
nonstationary. Such a series is said to be integrated. When the
studies ignore the developments in time-series econometrics of
stochastic trend is common to multiple time series a linear
the last two decades.
combination of the series exists, which is not integrated and
Several country studies take a more rigorous stance in tack-
the series are said to be cointegrated. Procedures for testing for
ling the same question. Most relevant to our endeavor is
integration 1 and for cointegration 2 have been widely applied. It
Gemmell et al. (2000) who investigate the importance of inter-
is recognized, however, that these procedures often have limited
sectoral linkages for agricultural growth in Malaysia. They first
power to reject a false null hypothesis. A growing literature now
extend the growth model of Feder (1982) to derive an estimable
exists presenting the case for the use of panel data to increase
equation that relates agricultural value-added to only manufac-
the power of tests for integration and cointegration.
turing value-added in the two-sector version of the model, or
Maddalla and Wu (1999) present a comparison of the Levin
to manufacturing value-added and services value-added in the
et al. (2002) and Im et al. (1997) procedures for testing for unit
three-sector version. This model is important in that it justifies
roots in panel data. They also introduce an alternative based on
the estimable equation detailed in the next section. The problem
a procedure for testing a joint hypothesis using the combined
of endogeneity of the variables is circumvented by the adoption
significance levels from the tests of the constituent hypotheses.
of a VAR approach to the estimation of the model, which also
Maddalla and Wu (1999) note that the Im et al. (1997) test
allows for an analysis of Granger causality among the model’s
can be viewed in such a light where the joint hypothesis to be
variables. The empirical results demonstrate that expansion of
tested is that all the series in the panel are subject to a unit root.
manufacturing output causes negative agricultural growth in
The procedure requires the significance levels (πi ) from tests of
the short run, as sectors compete for a fixed endowment of
the null hypothesis that there is a unit root in each of the series
resources, but positive agricultural growth in the long run, sug-
in the panel. It is noted that, because the significance level (π i )
gesting that manufacturing growth spills-over to the farm sector.
of a test is a uniform random variable on the interval 0 − 1,
By contrast, expansion of the agricultural sector does not affect
−2 ln π i has a χ 2 distribution with 2 degrees of freedom distri-
the other sectors of the economy. The findings are interpreted
bution and hence
as indicating that manufacturing growth stimulates demand for
agricultural commodities and provides the agricultural sector 
N

with new inputs and technology, but contradicts the conven- λ = −2 ln πi , (1)
i=1
tional wisdom of the agricultural economics literature. On the
contrary, Kanwar (2000) takes a similar econometric approach has a χ 2 distribution with 2N degrees of freedom where N is
to demonstrate that in India, while the agricultural sector affects the number of cross-sectional units in the panel.
the process of income generation in the manufacturing sector, The procedures proposed by Pedroni (1999) for testing
the reverse is not true. Here, the author justifies the finding for cointegration in a panel are based on the cointegrating
by relying on the standard arguments that agricultural growth regression
relaxes the wage goods, raw material, and foreign exchange
yit = αi + βi xit + uit i = 1, . . . , N, (2)
constraints and provides a potentially large market for man-
ufactured products. Although not analyzing causality, Martin where {yit | t = 1, . . . , Ti } and {xit | t = 1, . . . , Ti } are integrated
and Warr (1992) and Martin and Warr (1993) establish in an time series, T i is the number of observations in the time series
error-correction framework that an essential source of growth in of the ith cross-sectional unit, α it represents the deterministic
agricultural income in Indonesia and Thailand is economy-wide
capital accumulation, which pulls out surplus labor from rural 1 For example, the augmented Dickey–Fuller and the Philips Z α and Z t tests.
areas. Finally, Koo and Jinding (1992) estimate a simple partial 2 For example the Engle and Granger and Johansen procedures.
R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89 83

component and may include a constant, trend, seasonal dummy The distribution of the test statistic in (8) in the presence
variables, etc., β i is a parameter, and u it is the disturbance term. of integration and cointegration is considered by Sims et al.
Note that β i and α i are permitted to vary between time series. (1990), Toda and Phillips (1993), and Lutkepohl and Reimers
Two of the tests developed by Pedroni (1999) are essentially (1992). In general, the distribution of the test statistic depends
analogues of the Levin et al. (2002) and Im et al. (1997) tests on the properties of the system. Toda and Yamamoto (1995)
applied to test for a unit root in the u it series. Other tests are in show, however, that when the true model is a VAR(p) and the
a similar vein but are based on the variance ratio and Phillips following VAR(p + d) is estimated:
and Perron tests instead of the Dickey–Fuller test.
The Granger causality test is based on the following VAR zt = ψxt +
x̃t + ut , (10)
model:
where d is the maximum order of integration in the variables of

p the model and x̃t = (zt−p−d , . . . , zt−p−1−k ) , the distribution of
zt = µ + Ai zt−i + ut , (3) the Wald statistic based only on the ψ coefficients as defined
i=1 in (8) has an asymptotic χ 2 (p) distribution regardless of the
= ψxt + ut , (4) properties of the cointegrating vectors.
From the perspective of applied research, it is perhaps more
where z t = (v t , yt ) , µ t = (µ 1 , µ 2 ) , u t = (vvt , uyt ) , A i is the important to consider the small sample properties of the test
2 × 2 dimensional matrix of parameters a i.j k (j , k = 1, 2), ψ = statistic. In this vein, Zapata and Rambaldi (1997) conduct a
(µ, A 1 , . . . , A p ) and x t = (1, zt−1 , . . . , zt−p ) . The restrictions Monte Carlo exercise comparing the small sample performance
necessary for agricultural value added (v t ) to be noncausal of of a standard Wald test, the Wald test modified in accordance
GDP (y t ) are that a i.21 = 0, i = 1, . . . , p. 3 These can be ex- with the suggestion of Toda and Yamamoto (1995), and the like-
pressed in the conventional way lihood ratio proposed by Mosconi and Gianini (1992). Broadly
speaking, their results show that all three tests have an empirical
r vec(ψ  ) = 0, (5) size which is close to the nominal size in sample sizes in excess
of a hundred. The power of the three tests is good at all sample
with sizes except for the case of the modified Wald statistic which
is shown to have low power in samples with 25 observations.
r = s1 ⊗ s, (6)
Given the size of the sample used here, this is significant.
and Recent interest in the use of the bootstrap as a method of im-
      proving the small sample performance of tests in a cointegrating
0 0 1 framework stems from the work of Li and Maddala (1997). In
s1 = , s= , s3 = , (7) particular, they consider ways in which dependencies between
1 Ip ⊗ s3 0
the observed variables in the model may be preserved in the
where 0 is a row vector of zeros conformable with the remainder bootstrap sample. These may arise in the type of model under
of s. Because of the presence of stochastic regressors in a VAR, consideration here for two reasons: (1) due to contemporane-
tests of the hypotheses are asymptotic, with the Wald statistic: ous correlation between the elements of the panel and (2) due to
serial correlation within the elements arising, for example due
    
ˆ u r −1 (r vec(ψ̂  )),
λ = (r vec(ψ̂ )) r (XX )−1 ⊗  (8) to misspecification of the number of lags in the Dickey–Fuller
equation. Li and Maddala (1997) also argue that the residuals
being most common, where X = (x1 , . . . , xT ), ψ̂ and 
ˆ u are used in generating the bootstrap sample should be generated
estimates of the parameter vector and covariance matrix of u, using the parameter values assumed under the null hypothesis.
respectively (see Lutkepol, 1993, pp. 64–68). In devising the methods we use here we follow Li and Maddala
The VAR model in (3) can also be rewritten in VECM form (1997) first in using the stationary bootstrap as our method of
resampling, and second, in using a sampling scheme in which
zt = x̃t  + zt−p + ut , (9) the residuals generated under the null hypothesis are resampled
and used to produce pseudo data using the estimates obtained
where x̃t = (1, zt−1 , . . . , zt−p+1 ),  = (µ,  1 , . . . ,  p−1 ) , with the null hypothesis imposed. We use the bootstrap to pro-
µ = (µ1 , µ2 )  i , and  are the 2 × 2 matrices of parame- duce critical values in each of the three major tests applied here:
ters γ i·jk and πj k (j , k = 1, 2). When the series are cointegrated, the Dickey–Fuller test; the Johansen procedure, and the test for
 is of reduced rank and can be decomposed as  = αβ  were noncausality.
α and β are (2 × 1) dimensional matrices. β is known as the
cointegrating vector.
4. Empirical procedure
3 The reverse can be tested using the restrictions a i.12 = 0, i = 1, . . . , p.
Where both sets of restrictions are rejected, causality runs in both directions Each of the series is tested for the presence of a unit root
and feedback is said to exist. by estimating an ADF equation both with and without the
84 R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89

deterministic trend. The number of lags in the ADF equation above. A bootstrap sample {u∗t }, where u∗t = {u∗1t , . . . , u∗Nt }, is
is chosen by testing for serial correlation using the Breusch– produced by resampling the residuals from Eq. (12) in N-tuples
Godfrey statistic (Breusch, 1978; Godfrey, 1978). It is recog- such that each observation in the sample has observations from
nized that this procedure is imperfect and that the ADF test is each cross-sectional unit in the same time period. Equation (12)
sensitive to the number of lags chosen. We therefore use the is then used to produce pseudo data under the null hypothesis
bootstrap procedure that has been outlined to account for the and the test statistic in (1) is computed. Critical values are
fact that errors in the test equation may not be white noise. produced by repeating the procedure.
The procedure adopted in testing for a unit root in the agricul- We test for cointegration using Pedroni’s (1999) procedure
tural value added series of the ith country as follows. 4 First the 7. Thus we estimate the following:
test statistic is obtained as the t-statistic on δ in the following
equation: yit = αi + βi vit + γi t + uit i = 1, . . . , N, (15)

vit = µi + δi vit−1 + γi t + uit . (11) for each series in the panel. The residuals from this regression
are tested for unit roots by estimating the following:
The following equation is then estimated:
ûit = δi ûit−1 + vit , (16)
vit = µi + uit , (12)
and the test statistic is computed as the arithmetic mean of the
where µ is a constant. A bootstrap sample {u∗it | t = 1, . . . , T } is t-statistics on δ i across the cross-sectional units. Critical values
obtained using the stationary bootstrap by drawing u∗i1 randomly are obtained by bootstrapping under the null hypothesis that
from {ûit }, the set of estimated residuals from (12). u∗i2 is then the series are subject to unit roots but not cointegrated. Pseudo
obtained according to the following: data on v it and y it are thus generated in exactly the same way as
  for use in generating critical values for the panel unit root test.
Pr u∗i2 = uij = 1 − ϕ, (13) Critical values are obtained as the centiles of the test statistic
obtained through repeated estimation of Eqs. (15) and (16) using
  the pseudo data.
Pr u∗i2 = uik = ϕ, (14)
The final stage is to test for causality. In the light of the Monte
where j = i + 1 if i < T, j = 1 otherwise and k = j . {µ t } is Carlo results in Zapata and Rambaldi (1997) we choose to ap-
used to produce a pseudo sample {v it } using Eq. (12) with the ply the modified Wald test suggested by Toda and Yamamoto
estimated value of µ. Equation (11) is then estimated and the (1995) by estimating Eq. (10). Our explanation is for the case
test statistic for the pseudo sample is saved. Critical values are in which we test causality from agricultural value added to
obtained by repeating the procedure and computing the centiles GDP. We obtain bootstrap critical values for this test as fol-
of the saved test statistic. lows. First the VECM is estimated under the joint restrictions
Having eliminated the series for which the unit root can be required for Granger noncausality and cointegration. This in
rejected by applying the ADF test to the individual series, we itself entails two steps, the first follows Johansen and Juselius
use the Maddalla and Wu (1999) procedure that is outlined (1990, pp. 199–200) in estimating α and β under the restric-
in Section 3 in order to exploit the increased power of this tions that the rank of  is one and α = (α 1 , 0) . The second
test to confirm the conclusion that the remaining series are step is to estimate  following Mosconi and Gianini (1992, p.
subject to unit roots. The test statistic is estimated by estimating 407). 6 The estimated residuals from the restricted VECM are
Eq. (11) with each series in the panel. The significance levels resampled and used with the estimated parameters to produce
for use in computing the statistic in Eq. (1) are obtained by pseudo data which satisfies the null hypothesis. Critical values
comparing the t-statistic on δ with a sample of 500,000 draws for the test are obtained, by resampling repeatedly and testing
from the distribution of this statistic under the null hypothesis. 5 the null hypothesis using the modified Wald statistic. We use
Maddalla and Wu (1999) note that the Fisher test assumes that a Monte Carlo experiment to assess the use of the bootstrap in
the component test statistics are independent and that this may conducting this test. This is described in Appendix B.
be unrealistic in a panel data setting. We therefore follow their
6Zapata and Rambaldi (1997) note there are errors in the formula given by
suggestion in employing the stationary bootstrap to generate
Mosconi and Gianini (1992). We note that Zapata and Rambaldi (1997) do not
critical values. The procedure used is essentially the same as correct all of the errors and apply the following formula here:
that employed in generating critical values for the ADF test
˜ 1 (s1 s
ˆ = ˜ − s ˜ 1 )−1 s1 V(V
˜ 
(xx )−1 V)V (xx )−1 , (17)
4 We outline the procedure for one of the variables and the alternative hy- where x = (x̃1 , . . . , x̃T ),
potheses of a deterministic trend. The equation used for testing GDP is obvious 
0
while the stationary alternative is tested by omitting the trend in Eq. (11). V= , (18)
5 This sample is produced by repeatedly estimating Eq. (11) using simulated Ip−1 ⊗ s
data generated by a first-order autregressive model that is subject to a unit root. s = (1, 0) , and ˜ and 
˜ are as defined in Mosconi and Gianini (1992).
R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89 85

Table 1 Table 2
Rejections of the null hypothesis of a unit root using ADF test Results of the Maddalla and Wu panel unit root tests

Country Series Statistic 5% bootstrap C.V. Series Alternative hypothesis Statistic 95% bootstrap C.V.

Austria GDP −3.777 −3.061 GDP Trend stationarity 245.779 350.444


Belgium GDP −3.531 −2.733 Ag. val. added Trend stationarity 106.701 207.301
Denmark GDP −2.550 −2.112 GDP Stationarity 81.941 197.623
France GDP −5.671 −3.707 Ag. val. added Stationarity 106.701 125.992
Germany GDP −2.119 −1.729
Greece GDP −4.328 −3.571
Italy GDP −4.846 −2.751
Table 3
Japan GDP −7.591 −3.825
Countries exhibiting bi-directional causality
Mauritania GDP −3.842 −3.390
Mexico GDP −2.392 −2.353 Country Stat GDP  AVA C.V. 95% Stat AVA  GDP C.V. 95%
Norway GDP −2.594 −1.979
Papua New Guinea GDP −2.872 −2.581 Burundi 37.061 21.253 31.478 26.085
Portugal GDP −2.707 −2.478 Fiji 15.511 7.543 50.959 8.294
South Africa GDP −3.061 −2.955 Finland 8.295 6.409 7.517 4.101
Spain GDP −5.079 −3.398 Malawi 12.393 9.588 70.347 7.641
Sweden GDP −2.902 −2.805 Senegal 62.331 32.132 227.172 16.604
Thailand Ag. val. added −1.753 −1.463
Togo GDP −3.176 −2.928
Venezuala Ag. val. added −2.815 −2.276 Table 4
Countries exhibiting causality from GDP to agricultural value added

Country Stat GDP  AVA C.V. 95% Stat AVA  GDP C.V. 95%
Following Gardner, we use data on agricultural value-added
per worker and GDP per capita in constant 1995 US$ from Benin 20.431 9.011 1.937 6.986
World Development Indicators. 7 We exclude countries for Honduras 6.689 4.531 0.283 4.346
Korea, Rep. 15.616 6.802 1.571 5.506
which either series has no observations prior to 1972, which
Peru 8.674 4.526 0.030 4.449
gives 85 countries. The remaining series are of varying lengths
(see Appendix A).

5. Results test statistic obtained is −2.586 compared with a bootstrap crit-


ical value at the 95% level of −1.723 and we therefore conclude
The results of the ADF tests for unit roots in each of the that there is pairwise cointegration between GDP per capita and
individual series for which the null hypothesis of a unit root is agricultural value added in all of the countries remaining in the
rejected are given in Table 1. The full set of results are given panel.
in Appendix C. The ADF test was also carried out omitting Having established that the series cointegrate we proceed to
the term in the deterministic trend in Eq. (11). This leads to a test for Granger causality. The results are given in Tables 3–5.
reduction in the number of rejections. Of the series which reject In each of these Tables, columns 2 and 3 give the test statistic
with the trended model, only Denmark, Spain, and Sweden re- and bootstrapped 5% critical value for the hypothesis that GDP
ject when the trend is omitted. Of the series that fail to reject in is noncausal of agricultural value added and columns 4 and 5
the trended model Brazil (Agricultural Value Added) and China give the statistics and critical values for the noncausality in the
(GDP) reject with the trend omitted. Visual analysis suggests opposite direction. Table 4 shows the countries for which only
that the trended alternative is the most appropriate hypothesis the hypothesis that GDP does not cause agricultural value added
and it is well known that the test lacks power against this al- can be rejected, Table 3 shows the countries for which both
ternative when the trend is omitted from the test equation. We hypotheses can be rejected, and Table 5 shows the countries for
therefore conclude that there is evidence to support the exclu- which only the hypothesis that agricultural value added does not
sion of the countries in Table 1 from further analysis on the cause GDP can be rejected. 8 The striking feature of these results
grounds that they are not integrated. To confirm the conclusion is that for the vast majority of cases, the evidence points to the
that the remaining series are subject to a unit root we apply fact that agricultural value added is causal of GDP. Although
the Maddalla and Wu (1999) panel procedure. The results are this conclusion applies mainly to developing countries, we also
presented in Table 2 and in all cases, the null hypothesis that the note the unexpected presence of five developed countries in
remaining series are subject to a unit root is not rejected regard- Table 5, a point on which we expand in the conclusion.
less of the alternative hypothesis that is used. The next step is to
test for cointegration using the Pedroni (1999) procedure. The
8 Neither hypothesis can be rejected for the countries that do not appear in
7 These data are available online at http://www.worldbank.org/data/. Tables 3, 4, or 5.
86 R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89

Table 5 to consider the effect of bootstrapping the Granger causality test


Countries exhibiting causality from agricultural value added to GDP and show that it improves the size of the test in short time series
Country Stat 95% Stat 95% in comparison with the use of asymptotic critical values.
GDP  AVA C.V. AVA  GDP C.V. Applying the test to data from “World Development Indica-
Australia 52.089 71.902 53.603 7.917 tors,” we find that in the vast majority of cases causality runs in
Barbados 1.475 11.630 33.520 5.227 one direction from agricultural value added per worker to GDP
Botswana 1.567 6.008 17.193 3.165 per capita, or, in other words, that agriculture is the engine
Burkina Faso 7.307 25.943 36.017 13.017 of growth. This view is consistent with the popular paradigm
Canada 0.190 7.243 13.608 6.134
among agricultural economists that agricultural productivity
Chad 7.438 13.613 98.161 20.286
Dominican Republic 11.983 28.156 1,175.511 7.474 growth is necessary to “get the economy moving” because it
El Salvador 0.959 57.144 389.257 23.668 releases a surplus of food, labor, raw materials, capital, and
The Gambia 0.962 15.657 31.734 13.000 foreign exchange, while simultaneously generating demand for
Ghana 7.015 22.670 210.053 28.523 industrial goods and services. On the other hand, it seems to
Guatemala 0.284 6.130 4.511 4.166
contradict the contention expressed recently by Gardner that
India 5.972 6.420 30.355 6.175
Kenya 14.516 33.420 48.496 37.032 growth in agricultural income is driven primarily by changes
Lesotho 0.438 22.031 52.067 7.752 outside the sector, and most importantly growth of labor de-
Morocco 91.389 96.257 186.939 8.432 mand in the nonfarm economy. This is a comforting result for
Nepal 12.263 8.208 12.458 7.368 agricultural economists because it validates the standard policy
The Netherlands 4.970 17.851 11.744 6.539
recommendations aimed at stimulating growth and develop-
Niger 4.049 22.022 86.901 29.063
Paraguay 0.876 5.467 9.207 3.900 ment through expansion of agriculture. Hence, investments in
Sierra Leone 62.331 5.486 14.895 5.865 agricultural research and the provision of extension services
Singapore 1.839 12.799 18.743 5.497 as well as appropriate price incentives to farmers appear to be
Sri Lanka 2.079 8.103 38.628 5.401 effective and necessary ways of stimulating the other sectors of
Swaziland 0.218 19.932 27.003 10.870
the economy.
Syria 4.277 19.396 162.010 11.939
Trinidad and Tobago 8.387 234.871 1,747.736 10.052 However, while this set of results would have been expected
Tunisia 1.079 13.261 339.002 5.762 by many in the profession as far as developing countries are
UK 13.808 122.774 16,949.25 53.091 concerned, a surprising finding is the evidence in support of
U.S. 1.923 10.833 226.527 7.552 agriculture driving growth in highly developed economies as
Uruguay 0.254 10.645 111.797 5.877
well. Clearly, the relative economic importance of agriculture
Zimbabwe 0.997 10.107 35.888 6.625
in these countries is not high, and in this context it is difficult
to explain why the sector might retain its leading role in the
6. Conclusion growth process. A first possible explanation is that the data
span three decades over which the structural transformation of
This article extends the analysis presented by Gardner in his developed economies proceeded. For instance, the agricultural
2003 Elmhirst lecture on the relationship between agricultural workforce in Canada decreased from 8% of the total in 1970
and general economic growth by rigorously applying modern to barely more than 2% in 2000 (FAOSTAT), hence releasing
time-series econometric methods. After summarizing the ex- an important amount of productive labor from agriculture that
tensive literature on the role of agriculture in the process of contributed to economic growth. The same argument applies to
growth and development, the article has reviewed issues asso- Australia and the Netherlands but does not appear very convinc-
ciated with the application of Granger causality tests to inte- ing for the two countries in Table 5 that are at more advanced
grated data, before applying the tests to establish the direction of levels of their structural transformation (UK, U.S.). A second
causality between GDP and agricultural value added in a panel justification relies on the observation that, for a majority (12)
of developed and developing countries. The estimated VAR of developed countries in our data set, the series are simply not
model, though extremely simple, represents a reduced form of integrated (Table 1), which suggests that there is no long-term
the structural model of Feder (1982) as was first suggested by relationship between agricultural value added per worker and
Gemmell et al. (2000). Our contribution is twofold: first, the GDP per capita. Once that is recognized, the situation of Aus-
empirical application represents the first rigorous attempt 9 to tralia, Canada, the Netherlands, UK, and United States should
test for causality between agricultural and general economic be regarded as the exception rather than the rule. We also note
growth in a cross-country setting; and second, at an economet- that, with the exception of the UK, these five countries have a
ric level, we extend the analysis of Zapata and Rambaldi (1997) clear comparative advantage in agriculture and are major ex-
porters on world agricultural markets. Our results can therefore
9 By rigorous attempt we simply refer to methods that, in the words of Gardner,
be re-interpreted as suggesting that, with the possible exception
address explicitely “the econometric problems of sorting out causal effects from of countries with highly competitive agricultures, the farm sec-
trending time series” Gardner (2003). tor does not drive the growth process in developed countries.
R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89 87

Acknowledgments Appendix A Continued.


Country Ag. val. added GDP
The authors are grateful to the two anonymous referees for
their helpful comments. All remaining errors are the responsi- Mexico 1965 1960
Morocco 1965 1960
bility of the authors.
Nepal 1965 1960
The Netherlands 1971 1960
Appendix A: Dates of first observations Nicaragua 1965 1960
Niger 1961 1960
Table A.1
Nigeria 1961 1960
Country Ag. val. added GDP Norway 1971 1960
Pakistan 1961 1960
Algeria 1961 1960 Papua New Guinea 1961 1960
Argentina 1965 1960 Paraguay 1962 1960
Australia 1971 1960 Peru 1961 1960
Austria 1971 1960 Philippines 1961 1960
Bangladesh 1961 1960 Portugal 1971 1960
Barbados 1966 1960 Rwanda 1965 1960
Belgium 1970 1960 Senegal 1961 1960
Belize 1970 1960 Sierra Leone 1964 1960
Benin 1970 1960 Singapore 1961 1960
Botswana 1961 1960 South Africa 1961 1960
Brazil 1965 1960 Spain 1971 1960
Burkino Faso 1970 1960 Sri Lanka 1961 1960
Burundi 1965 1960 Swaziland 1971 1970
Cameroon 1965 1960 Sweden 1970 1960
Canada 1971 1965 Syria 1965 1960
Central African Republic 1965 1960 Thailand 1961 1960
Chad 1967 1960 Togo 1965 1960
Chile 1961 1968 Trinidad and Tobago 1966 1960
China 1961 1960 Tunisia 1965 1961
Colombia 1965 1960 Turkey 1968 1968
Democratic Republic of Congo 1968 1960 United Kingdom 1971 1960
Republic of Congo 1961 1960 United States 1971 1960
Costa Rica 1961 1960 Uruguay 1961 1960
Cote d’Ivoire 1961 1960 Venezuela 1961 1960
Denmark 1966 1960 Zambia 1965 1960
Dominican Republic 1965 1960 Zimbabwe 1969 1960
Egypt 1965 1960
El Salvador 1961 1960
Fiji 1965 1960
Finland 1961 1960
Appendix B: Monte Carlo experiment
France 1971 1960
The Gambia 1966 1966 In order to assess the extent to which the bootstrap improves
Germany 1971 1971 the performance of the noncausality test we repeat Zapata and
Ghana 1965 1960 Rambaldi’s (1997) Monte Carlo experiment with their DGP(3).
Greece 1961 1960
Guatemala 1965 1960
We carry out 5,000 Monte Carlo trials and for each trial we
Guinea-Bissau 1970 1970 generate critical values using a bootstrap sample of 1,000 ob-
Guyana 1961 1960 servations. The probability ϕ used in the bootstrap (see Eqs.
Honduras 1961 1960 (13) and (14)) is 0.1. Table B.1 presents the results of the trial
India 1961 1960 along with the results reported by Zapata and Rambaldi (1997)
Indonesia 1961 1960
Italy 1970 1960
for comparison. Results are reported with the order of the esti-
Jamaica 1961 1960 mated VAR ( p, see Eq. (3)) equal to the true order, p = 2 with
Japan 1961 1960 cases where it is over-fitted ( p = 3) and under-fitted ( p = 1).
Kenya 1964 1960 In all cases, the nominal size of the tests is 0.05. The results
Korea 1961 1960 show that the use of the bootstrap gives an improvement in size
Lesotho 1970 1960
Madagascar 1970 1960
over the use of asymptotic critical values at the expense of the
Malawi 1967 1960 power of the test. The power of the bootstrap test is reasonable
Malaysia 1970 1960 with a sample size of 40 provided the correct number of lags are
Mali 1967 1967 used in the estimation. The consequences of underestimating
Mauritania 1961 1960 the number of lags are more severe than overestimation. Un-
Continued derestimation results in a severe reduction in the power of the
88 R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89

Table B.1 Appendix C Continued.


Comparison of size (S) and power (P) of the modified Wald test with asymptotic
(A) and bootstrap (B) critical values for Zapata and Rambaldi’s model 3, Country Ag. val. added GDP
nominal size 0.05 Stat. C.V. Stat. C.V.
Repetitions 25 30 40 50 75 100 200 400 Fiji −4.702 −5.859 −1.880 −3.967
p = 1 S A 0.146 – – 0.087 – 0.062 0.054 0.048 Finland −3.071 −3.531 −1.682 −2.876
B 0.030 0.029 0.027 0.026 0.032 0.028 0.027 0.030 France −3.260 −4.799 −2.502 −2.865
The Gambia −1.526 −3.243 −1.721 −3.497
P A 0.477 – – 0.835 – 0.988 1.000 1.000
Germany −3.084 −5.634 −1.753 −3.277
B 0.030 0.025 0.022 0.024 0.023 0.031 0.149 0.616
Ghana −2.041 −3.232 −0.590 −3.297
p = 2 S A 0.229 – – 0.108 – 0.070 0.052 0.051 Greece −2.946 −6.063 −2.757 −2.984
B 0.030 0.032 0.037 0.043 0.043 0.054 0.050 0.050 Guatemala −1.753 −3.022 −1.469 −3.194
P A 0.645 – – 0.937 – 0.998 1.000 1.000 Guinea-Bissau −2.238 −4.178 −3.254 −4.489
B 0.141 0.258 0.481 0.693 0.937 0.987 1.000 0.999 Guyana −2.662 −5.193 −1.351 −3.018
Honduras −2.456 −3.502 −1.529 −3.148
p = 3 S A 0.344 – – 0.140 – 0.078 0.064 0.043
India −4.217 −5.601 1.915 −2.229
B 0.028 0.039 0.046 0.046 0.048 0.047 0.047 0.050
Indonesia −1.016 −3.387 −0.171 −2.676
P A 0.727 – – 0.930 – 0.999 1.000 1.000 Italy −2.455 −3.687 −4.846 −2.751
B 0.082 0.114 0.155 0.179 0.284 0.416 0.895 1.000 Jamaica −1.689 −2.887 −1.982 −2.412
Japan −2.175 −4.134 −7.591 −3.825
Kenya −1.724 −3.933 −1.842 −2.920
test and underrejection of the null hypothesis. Overestimation Korea, Republic −2.086 −4.411 −0.192 −1.768
Lesotho −3.768 −4.527 −1.255 −1.917
has only a small impact on the size of the test relative to the Madagascar −2.269 −4.247 0.084 −2.177
correctly parameterized model, and there is also some reduction Malawi −2.656 −4.621 −2.115 −2.874
in power. Malaysia −1.657 −4.186 −0.755 −1.758
Mali −3.316 −3.631 −1.647 −2.471
Appendix C: Results of ADF tests Mauritania −2.320 −4.325 −3.842 −3.390
Mexico −2.986 −4.854 −2.392 −2.353
Table C.1 Morocco −5.270 −6.475 −0.940 −1.851
Nepal −2.319 −4.132 0.753 −2.504
Country Ag. val. added GDP The Netherlands −3.179 −3.735 −2.172 −2.446
Stat. C.V. Stat. C.V. Nicaragua −1.224 −3.294 −0.108 −2.464
Niger −1.939 −4.720 −0.556 −2.460
Algeria −2.754 −4.682 −1.817 −4.104 Nigeria −1.589 −3.089 −1.865 −2.915
Argentina −2.279 −3.499 −1.711 −2.971 Norway −2.301 −4.160 −2.594 −1.979
Australia −4.900 −5.660 −2.187 −3.372 Pakistan −2.079 −3.996 −2.040 −2.098
Austria −1.823 −3.949 −1.048 −3.465 Papua New Guinea −2.756 −3.750 −2.872 −2.581
Bangladesh −1.432 −4.065 −0.783 −3.596 Paraguay −1.114 −3.298 −2.178 −3.442
Barbados −2.958 −3.805 −2.227 −2.895 Peru −1.413 −3.738 −2.295 −2.432
Belgium −0.957 −3.548 −1.785 −3.313 Philippines −2.383 −3.973 −1.888 −2.297
Belize −2.487 −5.109 −1.782 −2.696 Portugal −2.706 −3.714 −2.707 −2.478
Benin −3.112 −4.227 −1.788 −3.195 Rwanda −3.201 −5.051 −2.107 −3.241
Botswana −0.953 −2.512 0.165 −2.762 Senegal −5.282 −5.723 −2.386 −3.353
Brazil −6.018 −5.620 −0.645 −3.337 Sierra Leone −0.684 −2.962 0.551 −2.653
Burkina Faso −3.620 −6.327 −3.663 −5.204 Singapore −1.458 −4.065 −2.253 −2.879
Burundi −1.960 −3.966 −0.680 −4.010 South Africa −3.720 −5.367 −3.061 −2.955
Cameroon −1.709 −3.626 −0.965 −3.066 Spain −3.338 −4.508 −5.079 −3.398
Canada −3.031 −3.099 −2.174 −3.034 Sri Lanka −2.560 −4.330 1.034 −2.253
Central African Republic 0.051 −2.950 −1.968 −3.662 Swaziland −3.430 −4.282 −1.820 −2.321
Chad −3.413 −6.233 −1.970 −3.726 Sweden −2.493 −4.093 −2.902 −2.805
Chile −2.648 −3.882 −1.109 −2.991 Syrian Arab Republic −3.791 −5.383 −1.705 −2.571
China −2.489 −3.830 −4.526 −3.093 Thailand −3.301 −6.140 −0.651 −2.102
Colombia −1.521 −3.488 0.404 −2.629 Togo −2.983 −4.261 −2.858 −3.280
Democratic Republic of Congo −2.240 −3.782 −0.939 −3.246 Trinidad and Tobago −1.891 −5.678 −1.610 −3.364
Republic of Congo −3.039 −4.228 −0.650 −2.651 Tunisia −3.087 −4.015 −1.763 −3.332
Costa Rica −1.569 −3.152 −1.375 −3.047 Turkey −3.447 −6.096 −2.755 −3.988
Cote d’Ivoire −2.296 −4.321 −2.032 −2.769 United Kingdom −1.301 −3.721 −2.433 −3.499
Denmark −3.857 −4.768 −3.375 −3.288 United States −2.100 −4.179 −2.751 −3.471
Dominican Republic −3.003 −5.411 −1.717 −3.262 Uruguay −4.598 −4.743 −1.779 −2.684
Egypt. −2.731 −3.464 −1.165 −2.822 Venezuela, RB −1.976 −3.034 −2.187 −3.506
El Salvador −2.727 −4.497 −1.343 −3.697 Zambia −5.112 −6.544 −2.391 −3.732
Zimbabwe −3.420 −5.268 −1.005 −3.054
Continued
R. Tiffin, X. Irz / Agricultural Economics 35 (2006) 79–89 89

References Lewis, W., 1954. Economic development with un-limited supplies of labour.
The Manchester School 22, 139–191.
Adelman, I., 1995. Beyond export-led growth, Institutions and Development Li, H., Maddala, G., 1997. Bootstrapping cointegrating regressions. J. Econo-
Strategies: Selected Essays of Irma Adelman. Edwar Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. metrics 80, 297–318.
290–302. Lucas, R., 1998. The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future. University of
Breusch, T., 1978. Testing for autocorrelation in linear dynamic models. Aust. Chicago, Chicago.
Econ. Papers 17, 334–355. Lutkepohl, H., Reimers, H., 1992. Granger-causality in cointegrated VAR pro-
Butzer, R., Larson, D. F., 2002. Intersectoral migration in Venezuela. Econ. cesses. Econ. Lett. 40, 263–268.
Development and Cultural Change, pp. 227–248. Lutkepol, H., 1993. Introduction to Modern Time Series Analysis. Springer
Echevarria, C., 1997. Changes in the sectoral composition associated with Verlag, Berlin.
economic growth. Int. Econ. Rev. 38(2), 431–452. Maddalla, G., Wu, S., 1999. A comparative study of unit root tests with panel
Estudillo, J., Otsuka, K., 1999. Green Revolution, human capital, and off-farm data and a new simple test. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. (Special Issue), 631–
employment: changing sources of income among farm households in central 652.
luzon, 1966–1994. Economic Development and Cultural Change 47, 497– Martin, M., Warr, P., 1993. Explaining the relative decline of agriculture: a
523. supply-side analysis for Indonesia. The World Bank Research Observer
Feder, G., 1982. On exports and economic growth, journal of development 7(3), 381–401.
economics. J. Dev. Econ. 12, 50–73. Martin, W., Warr, P., 1992. The declining economic importance of agriculture: a
Gallor, O., Weill, D., 1999. From malthusian stagnation to modern growth. Am. supply-side analysis for Thailand. Working Paper in Trade and Development
Econ. Rev. 89(2), 150–154. 92/1. Australian University, Research School of Pacific Studies, Canberra.
Gardner, B., 2000. Economic growth and low income agriculture. Am. J. Agric. Matsuyama, K., 1992. Agricultural productivity, comparative advantage and
Econ. 82, 1059–1074. economic growth. J. Econ. Theory 58(2), 317.
Gardner, B., 2003. Causes of Rural Economic Development. Document Trans- Mosconi, R., Gianini, C., 1992. Non-causality in cointegrated systems: rep-
fer Technologies. Durban, South Africa. resentation estimation and testing. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. 54, 399–
Gemmell, N., Lloyd, T., Mathew, M., 2000. Agricultural growth and inter- 417.
sectoral linkages in a developing economy. J. Agric. Econ. 51(3), 353– Mundlak, Y., Larson, D., Butzer, R., 2004. Agriculture dynamics in Thailand,
370. Indonesia and the Philippines. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 48(1), 95–
Ghatak, S., Ingersent, K., 1984. Agriculture and Economic Development. 126.
Wheatsheaf Harvester Press, Brighton, UK. Murphy, K., Schleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1989. Income distribution, market size
Godfrey, L., 1978. Testing against general autoregressive and moving average and industrialization. Q. J. Econ. 104(3), 537–564.
models when the regressors include lagged dependent variables. Economet- Pedroni, P., 1999. Critical values for cointegration tests in hetergeneous panels
rica 46, 1293–1302. with multiple regressors. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. (Special Issue), 653–670.
Gollin, D., Parente, S., Rogerson, R., 2002. The role of agriculture in develop- Piñeres, A. D., 1999. Externalities in the agricultural export sector and economic
ment. Am. Econ. Rev. 92(2), 160–164. growth: a developing country perspective. Agric. Econ. 21, 257–267.
Griffin, K., 1979. The Political Economy of Agrarian Change. MacMillan, Schiff, M., Valdez, A., 1992. The Plundering of Agriculture in Developing
London. Countries. World Bank.
Hansen, G., Prescott, E., 2002. From Malthus to Solow. Am. Econ. Rev. 92(4), Schiff, M., Valdez, A., 1998. Agriculture and the macroeconomy. In: Gardner,
1205–1217. B., Rausser, G. (Eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Elsevier
Hwa, E., 1988. The contribution of agriculture to economic growth: some Science, Amsterdam.
empirical evidence, world development. World Dev. 16(11), 1329–1339. Schultz, T., 1964. Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Yale University Press,
Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y., 1997. Testing for Unit Roots in Heteroge- New Haven.
neous Panels. University of Cambridge, Cambridge. Sims, C., Stock, J., Watson, M., 1990. Inference in linear time series models
Irz, X., Roe, T., 2000. Can the world feed itself? Some insights from growth with some unit roots. Econometrica 58, 113–144.
theory. Agrekon 39(4), 513–528. Steger, T., 2000. Economic growth with subsistence consumption. J. Dev. Econ.
Johansen, S., Juselius, K., 1990. Maximum likelihood inference on cointegra- 62, 343–361.
tion with applications to the demand for money. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. Stern, N., 1996. Growth theories, old and new, and the role of agriculture in
52, 169–210. economic development. FAO Economic and Social Development Paper 136,
Johnston, B., Mellor, J., 1961. The role of agriculture in economic development. FAO.
Am. Econ. Rev. 51, 566–593. Thirtle, C., Piesse, J., Lin, L., 2003. Th impact of research led productivity
Kanwar, S., 2000. Does the dog wag the tail or the tail the dog? Cointegration growth on poverty in Africa, Asia and Latin America. World Dev. 31(12),
of Indian agriculture with nonagriculture. J. Policy Modelling 22(5), 533– 1959–1975.
556. Toda, H., Phillips, P., 1993. Vector autoregressions and causality. Econometrica
Kogel, T., Prskawetz, A., 2001. Agricultural productivity growth and escape 61, 1367–1393.
from the Malthusian trap. J. Econ. Growth 6, 337–357. Toda, H., Yamamoto, T., 1995. Statistical inference in vector autoregressions
Koo, W., Jinding, L., 1992. An intersectoral perspective on the relationship with possibly integrated processes. J. Econometrics 66, 225–250.
between the agricultural and industrial sectors in Chinese economic devel- Ventura, J., 1997. Growth and interdependence. Q. J. Econ. 112(1), 57–84.
opment. In: Bellamy, M., Greenshields, B. (Eds.), Issues in Agricultural Wichman, T., 1995. Food consumption and growth in a two sector economy.
Development—Sustainability and Cooperation. Dartmouth, Aldershot. Working Paper, Technical University Berlin.
Kuznets, S., 1964. Economic growth and the contribution of agriculture. In: World Bank, 1982a. Accelerated Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: An
Eicher, C., Witt, L. (Eds.), Agriculture in Economic Development. McGraw- Agenda for Action. World Bank.
Hill, New York. World Bank, 1982b. World Development Report 1982. World Bank.
Levin, A., Lin, C., Chu, C., 2002. Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and Zapata, H., Rambaldi, A., 1997. Monte carlo evidence on cointegration and
finite sample properties. J. Econometrics 108, 1–24. causation. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. 59, 285–298.

Вам также может понравиться