Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 19

SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSACTIONS:

FOR WHAT KINDS OF PURCHASES DO PEOPLE

MOST OFTEN USE NETWORKS?*

Paul DiMaggio Hugh Louch


Princeton University Princeton University

Why and to what extent do people make significant purchases from people
with whom they have prior noncommercial relationships? Using data from
the economic sociology module of the 1996 General Social Survey, we docu-
ment high levels of within-network exchanges. We argue that transacting with
social contacts is effective because it embeds commercial exchanges in a
web of obligations and holds the seller S network hostage to appropriate role
performance in the economic transaction. It follows that within-network ex-
changes will be more common in risky transactions that are unlikely to be
repeated and in which uncertainty is high. The data support this view. Self-
reports about major purchases are consistent with the expectation that ex-
change frequency reduces the extent of within-network exchanges. Responses
to questions about preferences for in-group exchanges support the argument
that uncertainty about product and performance quality leads people to pre-
fer sellers with whom they have noncommercial ties. Moreover, people pre-
fer to avoid selling to social contacts under the same conditions that lead
buyers to seek such transactions; and people who transact with friends and
relatives report greater satisfaction with the results than do people who
transact with strangers, especially for risk-laden exchanges.

S ociologists and most economists agree


that people use personal networks to
gather information when they contemplate
fault-that market exchange entails imper-
sonal transactions among strangers. Cases in
which consumers buy from or sell to friends
purchasing noncommodity goods and ser- or kin have received little attention. Even as
vices. Yet most of these scholars assume- economic sociologists devote more attention
economists on principle, sociologists by de- to the role of networks and "relational con­
tracting" in labor markets and business-to-
* Direct all correspondence to Paul DiMaggio, business relations (Powell and Smith-Doerr
Sociology Department, 2-N-2 Green Hall, 1994; Uzzi 1997), the social organization of
Princeton University, Princeton NJ 08544 consumer markets has been largely ignored.
(dimaggio@phoenix.princeton.edu). We grate-
fully acknowledge support to NORC for the col- Katz and Lazarsfeld (1955) undertook pio-
lection of these data from the Lilly Endowment neering work on the role of networks in con-
and the Aspen Institute Nonprofit Research Fund sumer decision-making decades ago; but
and support for the analysis from Princeton since then few social scientists have con-
University's Social Sciences and Humanities Fac- ducted empirical research on the influence of
ulty Research Fund. We also thank John Evans social relations on consumption (Biggart
for getting the data up and running; Frank Dob- 1989; Frenzen, Hirsch, and Zerrillo 1994).
bin, Alejandro Portes, Tom Smith, Diane Theoretical work on consumption has fo-
Vaughan, Oliver Williamson, and the ASR Editor cused on the role of social relations in culti-
and reviewers for useful comments; Bruce West- vating demand (e.g., through contagion or
ern for helpful advice on the analyses; and par-
ticipants in the Princeton Sociology Department's bandwagon effects), to the exclusion of the
JOIE Workshop and 1997 American Sociological role of networks in concrete exchanges
Association's Sociology of Markets session for (Becker 199 1; Granovetter and Soong 1986).
useful reactions. Given the progress of economic sociology in

American Sociological Review, 1998, Vol. 63 (October:619-637) 619


AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

recent years, and given the centrality of con- mance (Brown and Reingen 1987; Geertz
sumer behavior to economic life, this omis- 1978; Granovetter 1985; Powell 1990:303).'
sion is surprising. Even when uncertainty is moderate, a ratio-
This study begins to redress this oversight. nal consumer may use networks to identify
We demonstrate that participants in several potential sellers or to assess the performance
kinds of consumer transactions often have of warrantied brand-name goods (e.g., decid-
prior social ties. We develop hypotheses to ing to buy an IBM or a Dell computer).
explain variation across types of transaction By contrast, there is less theoretical war-
in the degree to which people purchase goods rant for anticipating high levels of within-
or services from persons to whom they are network exchange. Indeed, most sociological
connected through nonmarket social rela- work on consumption has focused not on
tions. We test predictions derived from our how people use their social relations to man-
theory with data from a national survey. Fi- age the market, but on how markets restrict
nally, we describe a research agenda that can or enervate social relations (Zelizer 1996).
build on our results to illuminate the role of Studies of commodification almost unani-
social relations in consumer markets. mously depict markets as desocializing. This
perspective has deep roots: "[Tlhe market
and its processes 'knows no personal distinc-
SOCIAL TIES AND CONSUMER tions,"' wrote Weber ([I9221 1946), ". . . it
MARKETS knows nothing of 'honor.' The status order
The conventional neoclassical view of eco- means exactly the reverse" (p. 192).
nomic action as intensely individualistic has Likewise, economic reasoning suggests
been much pilloried by sociologists and re- that within-network exchange should be less
jected as simplistic by many economists common than search embeddedness. First,
(Etzioni 1988). Granovetter (1985) argued search embeddedness is a more available
persuasively that economic transactions are strategy: Most of us know many more people
embedded in social structure: That is. the who have purchased a good or service than
structure of our social relationships, and not we know people who sell it. Second, within-
simply a transaction-specific maximization network exchange is constraining. Consum-
rule, determines our choices of economic ers who prefer to do business with personal
trading partners and how we interact with contacts narrow the field of potential sellers
them. and may trade off price or quality against re-
We treat embeddedness as a variable: The liability. Moreover, transactions with friends
unit of analysis is the economic transaction, (or even with one's friends' friends) impose
and our goal is to understand the conditions reciprocal obligations that are absent when
under which consumers engage in exchanges buyers use networks solely for search.
with persons to whom they are linked by Given all this, it is surprising that people
nonmarket relations. We distinguish two buy and sell goods and services from friends
ways in which social relations may enter into and kin at all. But they do. Identifying and
consumer transactions. Actors may use social explaining the role of networks in consumer
relationships to identify and assess the reli- markets fills a gap in what may be economic
ability of potential transaction partners to sociology's core agenda: exploring the social
whom they have no direct or close indirect organization of different varieties of markets
social ties: We call this search embedded- (White 1981).
ness. Or actors may choose persons with Such research also has important implica-
whom they have preexisting noncommercial tions for work in economics. For example,
ties as transaction partners: We refer to this economists who try to explain anomalous
as within-network exchange. heterogeneity in consumer prices invariably
The distinction is important. Much theory portray economic decision-makers as reason-
predicts high levels of search embeddedness.
Strategic actors use networks to search for Williamson (1991) describes the network "as
the highest quality goods and services at the a nonhierarchical contracting relation in which
lowest price, especially when they are uncer- reputation effects are quickly and accurately com-
tain about product quality or provider perfor- municated" (p. 291).
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSACTIONS 621

ing in isolation from their social ties. Indeed, asked "Which of the following best de-
lawyers responding to an empirical survey of scribes your relationship to the person who
legal-service pricing practices were in­ sold you the vehicle at the time of the pur-
structed to assume that they had no social re- chase?" Persons who had purchased cars
lationships with their clients in reporting from used-car or new-car dealerships were
their charges for various services (Cox, asked a similar question about "your rela-
DeSerpa, and Canby 1982). Similarly, work tionship to the salesperson from whom you
on institutional responses to consumer mar- purchased your car or to the owner of the
ket failure rarely takes into account informal auto dealership" and were instructed to an-
social organization (Barzel 1982). Econo- swer on the basis of "your closest relation-
mists who study informal exchange institu- ship." Home-buyers were asked to describe
tions in the less developed world assume that their "relationship to the previous owner of
within-network exchange is a second-best the home you purchased." Those who used
solution and is readily abandoned in econo- realtors were asked to describe their rela-
mies with modern contracting institutions tionship "to the real estate agent with whom
(Landa 1994:xi). Thus documenting empiri- you worked in your purchase of the home or
cally the extent of within-network consumer- to the owner of the real estate agency,"
market exchanges and explaining their inci- again with instructions to answer with refer-
dence has important implications for both ence to the closer relationship of the two.
sociology and economics. For each of these questions, respondents
were asked to choose among the following
responses: "a relative (including in-laws),"
DATA "a friend or acquaintance," "a friend of a
Data come from one of two administrations friend or relative, or a relative of a friend,"
of the General Social Survey (GSS) under- "not a friend, but someone with whom I had
taken in 1996. The GSS is a full-probability, previous business dealings," or "no prior re-
personal interview survey designed to moni- lationship." Respondents also were asked if
tor changes in social characteristics and atti- they were "not too satisfied," "pretty satis-
tudes. It has been conducted almost annually fied," or "extremely satisfied," with their
by the National Opinion Research Center purchase.
since 1972. (As a cost-saving measure, the All respondents were asked if they had
GSS shifted from annual surveys to pairs of purchased legal or home-repair services in
biennial surveys in 1994.) Since the mid- the past 10 years. Those reporting that they
1980s, the GSS has included topical modules had were asked questions similar to those
investigating specific areas in greater depth asked of car and home-buyers about how
than the ongoing core survey permits (Davis they located service providers, any previous
and Smith 1992). relationship to them, and satisfaction with
We use the economic sociology module services received.
administered to all 1,444 people who re- Attitude questions probed the relationship
sponded to one of the two General Social between exchange roles and preferences for
Surveys fielded in 1996. That module asked within-network exchange. One-half of the
respondents to report on specific economic respondents were asked whether they would
transactions and included several relevant at- prefer to sell bedroom furniture, a car, or a
titude questions as well. home to "someone with whom you have had
Split samples of respondents who had some family or social relationship, or to a
purchased cars (in the past five years) or buyer with which you had no prior personal
homes (ever) were asked about their use of contact." Respondents were asked to choose
social ties to locate exchange partners or a position on a five-point scale, with 1 rep-
brokers. They were also asked about any resenting "strong preference for no contact,"
previous relationships to the sellers (previ- 3 indicating "don't care," and 5 indicating
ous owners for car transactions between in- "strong preference for contact." The other
dividuals; and previous owners and. where half of the respondents were asked "Imagine
applicable, realtors in home purchases). that you want to buy each of the following
Purchasers of cars from individuals were items or services. Would you rather buy
622 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 1. Within-Network Exchange, by Type of Transaction: GSS, 1996

Percentages
Number of Friend or Two-step Not Friend1 No
Transaction Casesa Relative Acquaintance Compoundb Prior Dealings Relationship

All car sales 646 7.5 15.9 6.2 8.8 61.6


Any new car 207 2.4 11.1 3.9 9.2 73.4
Any used car 439 9.8 18.2 7.3 8.7 56.0
Used car from 250 15.6 23.2 7.2 6.4 47.6
individual
Used car from dealer 189 2.1 11.6 7.4 11.6 67.2

All home sales: Tie to 3 12 7.7 19.2 7.4 6.1 59.6


owner or realtor
Home sale through 218 0.5 3.7 0.5 3.2 92.1
agent: Tie to owner
Home sale through 218 4.6 16.1 6.9 6.4 66.1
agent: Tie to realtor
Private home sale: 94 14.9 23.4 8.5 2.1 51.1
Tie to owner

Legal services 645 1.4 17.2 6.7 13.5 61.2

Home maintenance 547 3.3 16.8 7.1 11.9 60.9


a N s are less than 1,444 because questions about car and home purchases were asked of split samples, and
because not every respondent had engaged in each transaction.
Two-step compound ties are ties between seller and buyer that pass through a third party to which each
is connected, when there is no direct tie between seller and buyer. Examples include friend of friend, rela-
tive of friend, and so on.

them from a business or service provider HOW COMMON ARE WITHIN-


with whom you had some family or social NETWORK EXCHANGES?
relationship, or from a seller or provider
with whom you had no prior contact?" The Because the 1996 GSS is the first publicly
set of items for buyers included legal and available national survey to ask respondents
home-repair services as well as cars, homes, about their relationships to persons from
and furniture. whom they have purchased goods or ser­
Respondents were asked if they would re- vices, the raw frequencies are of consider-
veal that a car they were selling, although able intrinsic interest. Given limits on net-
currently sound, had "a history of transmis- work size, the opportunity costs of avoiding
sion problems." One-half of the sample was vendors to whom one is not socially tied, and
told that they were selling to a relative, and the problem of reciprocal obligation, we
the other half was told that they were selling would expect within-network exchanges to
to a stranger. All respondents were asked to be relatively uncommon. Yet substantial per-
indicate agreement or disagreement (on a centages of major transactions take place
five-point scale) with two assertions: between friends, relatives, or compound ties
"People usually get a better price for goods (friends of friends, relatives of friends, and
or services when they get them from friends so on) in social and/or kinship networks (see
than when they deal with strangers"; and Table 1).
"When friends buy or sell something to Almost one-half of all used-car purchases
friends, discussing price is usually awkward from individuals (46.0 percent) and home
or puts somebody on the spot." purchases where no agent is used (46.8 per-
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSlACTIONS 623

cent) are transactions between relatives, We conclude that interpersonal relations


friends, or acquaintance^.^ Customers are play a crucial role in many consumption de-
socially linked to service providers in ap- cisions-not only in the search process, but
proximately one in four purchases of legal also in the choice of transaction partners.
services (25.3 percent) and home-mainte- Although we have no baseline against which
nance services (27.2 percent). Even when to compare the results of the General Social
home-buyers use a realtor, 27.6 percent re- Survey, the percentage of purchases .of
port a social or kinship tie to their agent or homes, cars, legal services, and home-main-
the owner of the agency. And 17.4 percent tenance services in which people deal di-
of people who purchase new cars cite simi- rectly with kin, friends, acquaintances, or
lar ties to an owner or employee of the deal- less frequently, two-step compounds of
ership. these relations, strikes us as remarkably
These figures understate embeddedness high.
because they exclude repeat purchases and
other transactions with prior business con-
tacts. When such ties are included, the share TWO TYPES OF WITHIN-NETWORK
of embedded transactions rises to 26.6 per- EXCHANGE
cent for car dealers, 34.0 percent for realtors, Why do people engage in economic ex-
38.8 percent for legal services, and 39.1 per- changes with people they know? We believe
cent for home maintenance. that within-network exchange has two ana-
A surprisingly high percentage of these re- ly tically distinct origins.
lations are direct to kin, friends, or acquain- (1) Persons may choose to transact with
tances, rather than two-step compound ties fellow members of an in-group as a result of
(i.e., relationships mediated by third parties, their participation in systems of generalized
such as relatives of friends). Fewer than 20 reciprocity characterized by a bias toward in-
percent of within-network car and home-pur- group exchange (Bearman 1997). Such a sys-
chase transactions between individuals are tem may have positive functional conse­
based on two-step compound ties, as com- quences, but the choice of transaction part-
pared with direct relations. For other trans- ners in specific instances is influenced by
action types, the figures are between 25 and general dispositions that follow from a his-
29 percent. Kinship ties are most common tory of such participation and by normative
between participants in person-to-person car expectations that group members share.
and home sales, and least common in the Many ethnic enclave economies appear to be
purchase of legal services. systems of this kind (Portes and Stepick
1993).
O u r enumeration of purchases from (2) Individuals may choose to transact
homeowners is complicated by the fact that the with others with whom they are acquainted
question about "relationship to the previous as a result of explicit calculation or tacit
owner" preceded the screening question that strategic understandings, even if normative
might have prevented it from being asked of re- pressures or general dispositions are absent.
spondents who did not purchase homes (with or
without the intercession of realtors) from persons This is most likely to occur in transactions
who owned them at the time of the sale. Conse- that are perceived to entail a high risk that
quently, 19 of 72 respondents who described their the seller will take advantage of informa-
purchase as "other" (i.e., indicating that they did tional or other advantages. Trading with
not use a realtor and did not purchase the house friends or kin reduces risk by embedding
directly from its previous owner or its builder) transactions in sets of continuous, multipur-
gave substantive responses to the "relationships pose relations. From the buyer's perspec-
to the previous owner" question, as did 4 of 61 tive, the seller's willingness to transact with
respondents who reported purchasing a home di- a friend, relative, or compound tie repre-
rectly from its builder. In calculating the percent-
age of embedded purchases for sales by owners
sents a "credible commitment" in which the
and by realtors, we eliminated such respondents seller's reputation and relations to other net-
(i.e., those who reported direct purchases from work members become hostages to the
builders or "others") from samples used to calcu- transaction (Williamson 1996; Yamagishi
late rates of within-network exchanges. and Yamagishi 1994).
AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

To be sure, these two mechanisms are re- bounded rationality and opportunism. Simi-
lated: Systems of generalized reciprocity larly, we view within-network exchange as a
tend to emerge in circumstances that are high governance structure for consumer transac-
in risk (Greif 1994). We distinguish the tions, and we ask under what conditions con-
mechanisms analytically because different sumers are likely to prefer it.
empirical expectations are associated with
each. Because systems of generalized reci-
procity inculcate persistent and transposable The Specificity of Consumer Behavior
dispositions reinforced by collective norms, Consumer markets differ from producer mar-
empirical hypotheses that address this first kets in three relevant respects. These differ-
mechanism posit relatively stable variation ences render unavailable or unsatisfactory
among persons across transactions. By con- the leading solutions (contract and hierarchy)
trast, because calculative rationality is trig- to businesses' transactional dilemmas.
gered by the transaction-specific perception (1) Very expensive consumer purchases
of risk, hypotheses that address the second are infrequent and therefore do not entail on-
mechanism posit relatively stable variation going relationships. Consequently, asset
among types of transaction across persons. specificity (the accumulation of costly rela-
We focus here on variations among differ- tion-specific investments) is rarely a serious
ent kinds of transactions in the prevalence of problem in product markets, rendering hier-
and attitudes toward within-network ex- archy unnecessary. ("Asset specificity" re­
changes. We anticipate that: (1) The em- fers to factors that tend to lock transaction
beddedness of transactions varies with the partners into a relationship by imposing high
type of good or service exchanged as a func- costs or penalties on a party who terminates
tion of the degree and type of uncertainty in the relationship.)
the transaction; and (2) preferences with re- (2) Although human asset specificity is a
gard to within-network exchanges vary by problem in consumer service markets, few
the actor's role in the transaction (as buyer consumers have the resources to purchase
or seller). problematic contractors or interest in doing
We focus on between-transaction variation so. Thus hierarchy is not a viable solution to
rather than between-person variation because service-market dilemmas.
the two kinds of variance are driven by dif- (3) Spot markets are effective in so far as
ferent social processes, require different contracts are not needed or can be written to
forms of explanation, and require different take into account the full range of likely con-
analytic methods. Because this is the first tingencies (Macauley 1963; Williamson
empirical effort of its kind, we prefer to deal 1985). In producer markets, explicit con-
systematically with one aspect of the prob- tracts solve two distinct problems: ambigu-
lem rather than attempt to treat the full range ity (clarifying points that might otherwise
of issues. cause misunderstandings) and bad faith (pro-
viding legal remedies). For most consumers,
litigation is so costly and inconvenient that
EXPLAINING VARIATION IN contracts solve problems of ambiguity but
EMBEDDEDNESS AMONG not of bad faith (Macauley 1985:467-69).
TRANSACTION TYPES Consequently, reliance on contract is a poor
We adapt elements of transaction-cost analy- solution for a consumer who doubts that a
sis-an approach developed to understand seller or service provider is committed to ful-
the make-or-buy decisions of firms-to un­ filling the contract's terms.
derstand why within-network exchanges are
more common in some kinds of consumer
transactions than in others. Williamson Embeddedness as a Response to Risk
(1981, 1985, 1991) has interpreted firms' If imperfections in consumer markets are not
choices of governance structure (contract, addressed adequately by hierarchy or con-
hierarchy, or hybrid forms) as responses to tract, how can consumers minimize the risk
the frequency, uncertainty, and asset speci- that sellers will behave opportunistically?
ficity of transactions under conditions of We propose that the greater the risk that a
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANS ACTIONS

transaction poses to consumers, the more could incur family-wide retaliation). In ei-
likely are consumers to seek out sellers to ther case, the mechanism is the same:
whom they have preexisting social ties. Within-network transactions reduce buyer
Risk refers to the probability that a trans- risk by imposing costs on sellers who take
action's outcome will be substantially infe- advantage of opportunities to exploit advan-
rior to that on which a reasonable consumer tages internal to the exchange. The commer-
would bargain. We view risk as an interac- cial transaction is embedded in a multiplex
tive function of information asymmetry be- network of ongoing interactions, so that the
tween buyer and seller and the probability actor's behavior in the commercial exchange
that a seller will opportunistically take ad- (e.g., selling a used car) influences the way
vantage of such asymmetry. Search em­ in which he or she is treated by many differ-
beddedness addresses information asymme- ent actors across a range of interactions (in-
try by increasing the amount of information cluding noncommercial ones) extending well
that the buyer takes into the purchase about into the future.
the product or service, the identity of poten- What attributes of consumer transactions
tial transaction partners, and the prior per- render risk sufficiently great to justify the
formance of each. Within-network exchange high opportunity costs and reciprocal obliga-
addresses opportunism as well, reducing the tions associated with within-network ex­
risk that the seller will behave opportunisti- changes? First, risk is a function of transac-
cally after the purchase by introducing obli- tion frequency (Williamson 1981). Risk is
gations and sanctions external to the trans- substantial for onetime transactions in which
action. the seller has no economic interest in a fu-
Consider the canonical example of a con- ture relationship with the buyer. This is the
sumer purchasing a used car. According to case when the buyer is unlikely to make a
Akerlof (1970), the risk inherent in this ex- repeat purchase from the seller, and it is es-
change-that the seller can conceal problems pecially the case in what Smith (1990:52-57)
with the vehicle and that some sellers choose refers to as "private-treaty transactions"
to do so--creates an incentive structure that (e.g., the sale of a personal car or home), in
presses all used-car dealers to behave oppor- which the seller has no enduring interest in
tunistically. This occurs because rational establishing or maintaining a commercial
consumers, unable to discriminate between reputation.
honest and dishonest sellers, will assume that Second, the degree of risk is related to un-
all are dishonest and discount the value of certainty about the quality of the product or
the vehicle to take account of potential un- service purchased (Kollock 1994). Two types
observable flaws. The global consequences of uncertainty are relevant: uncertainty about
of this dilemma are well known: Dishonest the quality of a good (product uncertainty),
dealers tend to outcompete honest ones in the and uncertainty about the quality of a seller's
long run and consumers demand legislative future performance (performance uncer­
remedies like lemon laws. Here we are inter- tainty). Of these two, risk related to perfor-
ested in how a consumer approaches a mar- mance uncertainty is more substantial
ket of this kind. (Coleman 1990:90-95; Shelanski and Klein
We suggest that consumers rely on their 1995).
social relations to reduce risk in two ways. In most consumer transactions, the pri-
First, they ask friends and acquaintances mary problem is uncertainty about product
about their experiences in order to locate the quality. Performance uncertainty is limited to
most dependable dealers with the best repu- cases in which the seller retains possession
tations. Second, if possible they may pur- of a good after the purchase agreement and
chase a car from a dealer with whom they therefore can alter its character before deliv-
have an ongoing personal relationship that ery (e.g., removing fixtures from a home or
the dealer may be loath to jeopardize. This replacing a costly~carradio with a cheaper
relationship may be direct (the dealer may be unit). Even in these situations, performance
an old friend who values the friendship for uncertainty may be moderated by the use of
its own sake) or indirect (the dealer may be a detailed contracts, as is customary in home
spouse's relative, for whom shady practice purchases.
AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Performance uncertainty is a more serious panies that rely on repeat business than for
problem in service transactions for three rea- those with whom subsequent transactions are
sons. First, service providers often receive unlikely or temporally distant. Therefore we
advance deposits. Therefore buyers cannot expect consumers to rely more on social re-
dismiss providers lightly, and efforts to re- lations when they buy things that they pur-
solve disputes may entail lengthy delays dur- chase rarely than when they make more fre-
ing which consumers are without vital ser- quent purchases. And, especially, we expect
vices or, in cases of repair or construction, them to rely more on social relations in buy-
cannot use their property. Second, adequate ing from individual sellers than when pur-
performance often relies on the provider's chasing through intermediaries (e.g., real es-
expertise, entails substantial discretion, and tate agents) or from businesses.
thus cannot be specified in a contract. Third,
many service relationships entail significant Hypothesis l a (behavioral version): The
human-asset specificity such that in replac- greater the seller's reliance on commer-
cial reputation and repeat business, the
ing one provider with another (changing at-
torneys in the middle of a case, or contrac- less prevalent are within-network ex-
tors in the midst of a home-remodeling job), changes.
a purchaser risks significant start-up costs We expect within-network exchanges to be
and retribution through withheld information most frequent for car and home purchases
or damage to p r ~ p e r t y . ~ from individuals, who have no interest in
commercial reputation. Because most people
buy homes rarely, especially if they are not
HYPOTHESES geographically mobile, we expect within-
Four general hypotheses follow from these network exchanges to be more common in
arguments, and they yield several specific the selection of realtors than in purchases of
predictions about the effects of transaction legal or home-repair services or of cars from
variables on within-network exchange. dealers.
Hypothesis I b (preference version): The
Hypothesis 1: Effects of Transaction greater the sellers' reliance on commer-
Frequency cial reputation and repeat business, the
Consumers may believe that businesses are less likely are purchasers to prefer to
constrained from taking advantage of infor- deal with network members.
mation asymmetries by their desire for repeat
trade and the related need to maintain posi- We expect buyers' preferences for within-
tive reputations, whereas individuals selling network transactions to be most pronounced
personal possessions are not so constrained. for home purchases, followed by car pur-
Consumers also may expect the degree of a chases or purchases of legal or home-repair
seller's self-restraint to be greater for com- services, and least pronounced for purchases
of furniture, which are likely to be relatively
The degree of risk is also a function of cost,
routine.
of course. When uncertainty is high and cost is
low (e.g., buying a secondhand waffle iron for a Hypothesis 2: Effects of Uncertainty
couple of dollars), people may prefer to accept
risk rather than invest in search. When more Uncertainty stems from the seller's posses-
money is at stake, search costs are more accept- sion of information about product or service
able. We expect actors to use any means, includ- quality that may be withheld from potential
ing networks, to search more intensely for infor- purchasers. Uncertainty is gravest under
mation when the cost of a product or good is high. conditions of asset specificity, when perfor-
But we expect cost to be related to within-network
exchanges only for transactions characterized by
mance quality is unobservable and purchas-
nonrepeatability or uncertainty. We can only ers depend on providers' candor and good
speculate about the influence of cost on transac- will. Because these conditions characterize
tion embeddedness because the GSS did not col- service transactions, we expect within-net-
lect data on purchase prices. work exchanges to be most common in ser-
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSACTIONS 627

vice markets, less common in the sale of Private individuals selling a personal home
physical assets of uncertain quality, and least or car have no such incentive.
common for standardized commodities.
Hypothesis 3: Sellers are less likely than
Hypothesis 2a (behavioral version): The buyers to prefer to transact with people
greater the uncertainty regarding the to whom they are socially linked, and
quality of a good or service (assuming more likely to prefer to transact with
significant cost), the greater the likeli- strangers. The strength of this tendency
hood of within-network exchanges. is a negative function of the trans-
action's frequency and a positive func-
To avoid confounding the effects of uncer-
tion of its uncertainty.
tainty with those of frequency, we restrict
comparisons to individual purchases from We expect buyers to prefer within-network
commercial enterprises and eliminate trans- exchanges more than sellers for all transac-
actions among individuals. We expect that tions (home, cars, and bedroom furniture) in-
people are most likely to use social contacts cluded in our split-sample experiment. We
for service transactions, which involve sub- expect differences between buyers' and sell-
stantial performance uncertainty, followed in ers' preferences to be greatest for home sales,
frequency by purchases characterized by which are less frequent and at least as uncer-
substantial product uncertainty (any home or tain as car purchases, and smallest for furni-
a used-car purchase) and by purchases of ture sales, which are more frequent and en-
warrantied quasi-commodities (new cars). tail less uncertainty than either home or car
transactions.
Hypothesis 2 b (preference version): The
greater the uncertainty regarding the
quality of a product or service, the Hypothesis 4: Within-Network Exchange
greater the consumer's preference for and Satisfaction
transacting with a partner to whom he or
If people purchase products and services
she is socially connected.
from businesses and private persons to whom
We expect people to express stronger prefer- they have social ties in order to reduce the
ences for buying from personal contacts risk of opportunism, then we would expect
when they purchase legal services or home- such people to be more satisfied with the re-
repair services than when they buy cars, sults of those transactions and more success-
homes, or, especially, furniture (a relatively ful in avoiding negative outcomes than those
standardized commodity). who transact with strangers.
Hypothesis 4 : People who transact with
Hypothesis 3: Buyer versus Seller members of their social networks are
Preferences more likely to report high levels of sat-
isfaction and less likely to report low
We have emphasized the value of transact-
satisfaction with the product or service
ing with known exchange partners from the
they receive.
perspective of purchasers. We do so based on
the expectation that networks of shared ties This tendency should be greatest for pur-
reduce risk by imposing external costs on chases of services (because of performance
sellers who behave opportunistically. From uncertainty) and least for purchases of new
the seller's standpoint, such entanglements cars, the most standardized item about which
may make trading with known partners less the satisfaction question was asked.
attractive. This is true of sellers who are in-
clined to behave opportunistically. Ethical
vendors may be torn between wanting to ANALYTIC APPROACH
avoid situations in which honest misunder- We test each hypothesis by examining pairs
standings may have wide ramifications and of transactions to see if differences in behav-
hoping to use social relationships to enlarge ior, preferences, or outcomes conform to our
their client base, a common strategy in some predictions. Although the GSS, which uses a
direct-sales organizations (Biggart 1989). household sample, includes weights for num-
AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

ber of adults in the household, we use un- purchase reports, which were requested of
weighted data because most of the transac- split samples, and in subgroup analyses for
tion types we examine are ordinarily house- which cell sizes were too small to sustain
hold purchase^.^ paired tests), we used simple difference-of-
Whenever data permit, we employ paired group-proportions tests (Agresti and Agresti
t-tests, a type of fixed-effects procedure, to 1979: 169-173). One-tailed significance tests
test the significance of mean differences be- were used to evaluate directional hypotheses.
tween responses of the same individuals to
different questions. Paired t-tests control for
the direct impact of individual-level differ- RESULTS: VARIATION IN
ences in the following way. Let xi equal the EMBEDDEDNESS BY TRANSACTION
value of a binary variable indicating whether TYPE AND ROLE
a respondent who purchased legal services Tests of Hypotheses 1 and 2: Behavioral
bought them from a social tie (= 1) or a Data
stranger (= 0). Let xj equal the value of a bi-
nary variable indicating whether the same re- Table 2 presents results of tests of Hypoth-
spondent purchased a car from a social tie esis 1, which predicts that the incidence of
(= 1) or a stranger (= 0). Imagine that our hy- within-network exchanges will be signifi-
pothesis is that people are more likely to pur- cantly greater for infrequent than for fre-
chase legal services than cars from social quent transactions. The behavioral-report
contacts. A new variable is created by sub- data support the expectation that people are
tracting xj from xi. We then apply the equiva- more likely to transact within networks for
lent of a single-sample t-test to the difference purchases that are unlikely to be repeated,
measure to test the hypothesis that the dif- especially when the seller is a private person
ferences diverge significantly from zero with no interest in a commercial reputation.
(Agresti and Agresti 1979: 184-88).5 Data from the full sample support 7 of 11
The use of paired t-tests is especially ap- pairwise predictions. As predicted, car trans-
propriate for this study given the fact that the actions between individuals entail more
GSS data lack direct measures of the cost, within-network exchanges than do home pur-
frequency and perceived risk of specific chases through realtors, purchases of cars
transactions. The paired t-tests control for from dealers, or purchases of home-mainte-
individual differences associated with these nance services or legal services. Home-pur-
factors (e.g., the tendency of wealthier chase transactions between individuals with-
people to buy more expensive cars and pur- out a realtor's intercession exhibit greater
chase them more often), while permitting us embeddedness than do transactions with
to test directly the hypotheses about differ- realtors or purchases of cars from dealers.
ences between transaction types. And home purchases through realtors (infre-
When the study design did not permit in- quent transactions for most people) are sig-
ternal comparisons of this kind (e.g., in com- nificantly more embedded than are car pur-
parisons between car-purchase and home- chases from dealers.
The four predictions that were not sup-
None of the measures we used was signifi- ported posited more frequent within-network
cantly correlated with the number of adults in the exchanges for home sales (individual-to-in-
household. Therefore our decision not to weight dividual sales and those mediated by
was not consequential. realtors) than for service-market transactions
Using the mean of the differences rather than (legal and home-maintenance). How can we
the raw percentages may render ordinary distri- explain this anomaly?
butional assumptions suspect. To guard against Market behavior reflects not only buyers'
this, we used a bootstrap procedure, taking mul-
preferences for using personal networks, but
tiple samples from the data to determine the ap-
propriate sample mean and to avoid accepting an also the size and composition of the net-
hypothesis on the basis of limited information works that they have available to them. The
(Efron and Tibshirani 1993). The results of the probability of knowing someone in a given
bootstrap tests concurred with those of the ordi- field is a function of the number of people in
nary t-tests in nearly every case. that field and of the size and density of their
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSACTIONS

Table 2. Difference-Test Results for Frequency of Within-Network Exchanges (Hypothesis la, Fre­
quency): GSS 1996

Transaction Transaction

Predicted Predicted

to Entail to Entail
Mean Stable
More Frequent Less Frequent Difference, Residents Only a
Within-Network Within-Network Full
Exchanges Exchanges Sample d.f. Paired d.f. Unpaired d.f.

Car: private sale Car from dealer


Car: private sale Home from realtor
Car: private sale Legal services
Car: private sale Maintenance services
Home: private sale Car from dealer
Home: private sale Home from realtor
Home: private sale Legal services
Home: private sale Maintenance services
Home from realtor Car from dealer
Home from realtor Legal services
Home from realtor Maintenance services
Note: Table entries are mean differences. Numbers in parentheses are degrees of freedom for the signifi-
cance tests.
a Ns for paired tests on subsamples are so small (sample attrition is largely due to split-sample design)
that unpaired (difference-of-mean) tests are also reported.
Because of the split-sample design, paired tests are not possible for these comparisons.
* p < .05 (one-tailed tests)

networks, and these numbers vary widely. Home purchases differ from the other
(There were 57 1,000 lawyers in private prac- transactions in a way that makes the ab-
tice in 1991, 718,000 realtors in 1995, sence of data on network size or availability
899,000 employees of car dealerships in especially salient: The same circumstances
1993, and 2,87 1,000 employees of residen- that cause people to purchase new homes
tial general contractors, plumbers, painters, often attenuate their relevant personal net-
electricians, masons, carpenters and workers works. One can purchase a car anywhere,
in related fields in 1992 [U.S. Bureau of the but one buys a house where one intends to
Census 1996:214, 505, 762, 709]).6 Some live. People who move to a new community
buyers who would prefer to transact with a often purchase houses before developing
friend or relative will not do so because no personal ties to people in that location. Such
suitable transaction partner is available. And movers are probably much less likely to en-
networks are more likely to facilitate some gage in home-purchase transactions with so-
transaction types than others. (At any given cial contacts than are long-term residents
time it is probably easier for most people to because they have fewer contacts with
identify a relative willing to sell them a car whom to transact.
than to find one from whom they can buy a The GSS has no direct measure of recent
home.) mobility, and respondents were not asked
why they purchased a home when they did.
The last figure is approximate, as it includes
But the GSS does identify respondents who
nonresidential workers in trades other than gen- reside in the same community that they lived
eral contractor and excludes many skilled con- in when they were 16 years old. This is an
struction workers who moonlight or otherwise imperfect proxy for the strength of local net-
provide services to homeowners "off the books." works because some respondents identified
630 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 3. Difference-Test Results for Frequency of Within-Network Exchanges (Hypothesis 2a, Un-
certainty): GSS, 1996

Transaction Transaction

Predicted to Entail Predicted to Entail


Mean
More Frequent Less Frequent Difference,
Within-Network
Within-Network Full College Graduates Only a
Exchanges
Exchanges Sample d.f. Paired d.f. Unpaired d.f.

Legal services Used car from dealer


Legal services New car from dealer
Legal services Home from realtor
Maintenance services Used car from dealer
Maintenance services New car from dealer
Maintenance services Home from realtor
Used car from dealer New car from dealer

Home from realtor New car from dealer

Note: Table entries are mean differences. Numbers in parentheses are degrees of freedom for the signifi-
cance tests.
a Ns for paired tests on subsamples are so small (sample attrition is largely due to split-sample design)
that unpaired (difference-of-mean) tests are also reported.
Because of the split-sample design, paired tests are not possible for these comparisons.
* p < .05 (one-tailed tests)

as "movers" by this criterion no doubt re- By contrast, the behavioral data provide
sided in their community for years before meager support for Hypothesis 2, which pre­
purchasing the home to which their re­ dicts that uncertainty about product quality
sponses referred, and some "stayers" may in fosters within-network exchange (Table 3).
fact have returned to their native community As predicted, people are more likely to trans-
after an extended absence. But a poor proxy act with social ties when they buy homes or
is better than none at all. purchase legal services than when they buy
We compared home sales (with and with- new cars. The other six predicted relation-
out realtors) to car purchases from dealers, ships were insignificant, however. The fact
legal-service transactions, and home-mainte- that the uncertainty hypothesis yields a pre-
nance-service purchases for "stable" respon- diction opposite that derived from the fre-
dents: those who still resided in the town quency hypothesis explains the absence of a
they lived in when they were age 16. For this significant difference between service trans-
subsample, which seems likely to have, on actions and home purchases. The failure of
average, comparatively well-developed local home-maintenance and legal-service transac-
networks, Hypothesis l a was supported: tions to involve more within-network ex-
Within-network exchanges remained signifi- changes than used-car purchases is more sur-
cantly more common in direct purchases prising.
from individuals than in those mediated by If ties to attorneys, who are prestigious and
agents. But both kinds of home transactions highly educated professionals, are more
were more likely to entail within-network available to well-educated than to less edu-
exchanges than were transactions for legal cated persons-a reasonable assumption
services, home maintenance, or car pur- given that social networks tend to be homo-
chases from dealer^.^ philous with respect to education (Marsden

' Paired tests fell short of significance for the mean differences were comparable to between-
comparisons between individual home transac- group differences in means, suggesting that fail-
tions (N = 22) and between home sales through ure to reach significance reflected the small cell
realtors and legal-service purchases (N = 35), but frequencies.
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSACTIONS 631

Table 4. Difference-Test Results for Network Preference Data: GSS, 1996

Transaction
Transaction

Predicted to Entail
Predicted to Entail

Greater Preference Less Preference Mean Degrees


for Within-Network
for Within-Network Difference, of
Exchanges
Exchanges Full Sample Freedom
Hypothesis lb: Frequency
Home purchase
Car purchase
Home purchase
Legal services
Home purchase
Maintenance services
Home purchase
Furniture purchase
Car purchase
Furniture purchase
Legal services
Furniture purchase
Maintenance services
Furniture purchase

Hypothesis 2b: Uncertainty


Legal services
Car purchase
Legal services
Home purchase
Legal services
Furniture purchase
Maintenance services
Car purchase
Maintenance services
Home purchase
Maintenance services
Furniture purchase
Home purchase
Furniture purchase
Car purchase
Furniture purchase
* p < .05 (one-tailed tests)

1988)-then supply factors may distort our risk by making the seller's relations with
results for legal-service purchases. To ex- mutual associates a hostage to his or her per-
plore this possibility, we ran separate com- formance in the transaction.
parisons between legal-service purchases and
ised-car, home, andnew-car transactions for
respondents with college degrees. College Tests of Hypotheses 1 and 2: Preference
graduates were significantly more likely to Data
report transacting with kin, friends, acquain- The preference data supplement the behav-
tances, or compound ties when they pur- ioral indicators in four ways. First, they per-
chased legal services than when they bought mit us to ignore the peculiarities of particu-
new cars or used cars from dealers. lar transactions and tap people's preferences
To summarize, analyses of behavioral re- based on their schematic expectkions-the
ports lend strong support to the frequency images they carry in their heads-for differ­
hypothesis and very weak support to the un- ent types of transaction. Second, unlike be-
certainty hypothesis. All 11 predictions of havioral reports, preferences should not be
the frequency hypothesis are supported once influenced directly by variation in network
a crude proxy for the availability of ties to size and composition. Third, in addition to
homeowners and realtors (residential stabil- cars, legal services, home-maintenance ser­
ity) is introduced into the analyses. Only 3 vices, and homes, respondents were asked
of 8 predictions of the uncertainty hypothesis about purchases of bedroom furniture, ex-
are supported, 1 only after introducing a panding the range of variation with a pur-
proxy for tie availability (college education). chase relatively low in uncertainty and high
These results suggest that purchases of goods in frequency. Fourth, because all questions
and services from persons with whom one were asked of one-half of the sample (the
shares social ties is a strategy for reducing other half was asked to imagine themselves
632 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 5. Percentages of Respondents Preferring Within-Network Exchanges versus Exchanges with


Strangers by Transaction Type and Role: GSS, 1996
Prefers Exchange with Stranger Prefers Within-Network Exchange
As Buyer As Seller As Buyer As Seller
Transaction % S 8 S Difference 8 N 9 S Difference
Bedroom furniture 19.2 (694) 20.2 (718) 1.O 27.5 (694) 17.0 (718) 10.5:
Car 20.6 (694) 31.0 (720) 10.4' 49.7 (694) 18.5 (720) 31.2:
Home 17.2 (697) 25.7 (717) 8.5' 45.5 (697) 19.2 (717) 26.3'
Legal services 16.2 (693) NA - 60.9 (693) NA -
Home maintenance 12.0 (700) NA - 62.6 (700) NA -
Note: Ns are less than 1,444 because buyer and seller roles were addressed in split samples. Respondents
were given a card and asked to place themselves on a continuum from 1 ("strong preference no contact") to
5 ("strong preference contact"), with the mid-point (3) labeled "don't care." Those choosing 1 or 2 are
included under "prefers exchange with stranger" above; those choosing 4 or 5 are included under "prefers
within-network exchange." (The percentage choosing 3 is the complement to the percentages reported above
for each transaction typelrole combination.)
* p < .05 (one-tailed tests for significance of difference between percentages of buyers and sellers)

in the "seller" role), all hypotheses can be support the uncertainty hypothesis. Across
evaluated with mean difference tests, thus the board, then, the more uncertain the trans-
controlling for the effects of all the indi- action and the greater the degree of perfor-
vidual differences that shape preferences for mance uncertainty, the more people prefer
in-group exchanges as opposed to imper- transaction partners with whom they have a
sonal exchanges. social tie.
In contrast to the behavioral data. mean-
difference tests using the preference data
provide only modest support for predictions Tests of Hypothesis 3: Buyer Role versus
of the frequency hypothesis (Table 4). Four Seller Role
of seven predictions are supported, but these Split samples were asked to assume the roles
are all comparisons between furniture pur- of buyers or sellers of bedroom furniture, a
chases and other transactions. In each case, car, or a home. Hypothesis 3 was tested by
as predicted, respondents report a less strong comparing the percentage of buyers and sell-
preference for transacting with kin or friends ers who expressed a preference for transact-
when purchasing furniture than when buying ing with social ties or strangers. The predic-
cars, homes, or services. The other predic- tion that buyers are more likely than sellers
tions-that respondents' preferences for to prefer dealing with friends or kin was sup-
within-network transaction partners would ported for all three transaction types (Table
be stronger for home purchases than for car, 5 ) . The prediction that sellers prefer to trans-
legal-service, or home-maintenance transac- act with strangers was supported for the two
tions-received no support. transaction types (cars and homes) that en-
In striking contrast to the behavioral evi- tail substantial uncertainty but not for the
dence, the preference data provide strong sale of furniture, a result consistent with our
support for the uncertainty hypothesis: All theoretical framework.
eight predicted differences reach statistical Is it realistic to expect friends and rela-
significance. Comparisons of home pur- tives to behave less opportunistically than
chases to legal-service and home-mainte- strangers? Respondents were presented with
nance-service transactions are of special in- a scenario in which they were selling a car
terest because the frequency and uncertainty that was in good repair but had had trans-
hypotheses lead to contradictory expecta- mission problems. They were asked whether
tions. Whereas the behavioral data support they would disclose that history to a poten-
the frequency hypothesis, the preference data tial purchaser. One-half of a split sample
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSACTIONS 633

Table 6. Buyer Satisfaction with Transaction by Presence of Tie to Seller: GSS, 1996

Percentage "Not So Satisfied" Percentage "Extremely Satisfied"


Degrees of
Transaction Freedom No Tie Tie Difference No Tie Tie Difference

Used Cars 182 15.3 5.0 10.3* 43.1 55.0 11.9*


New Cars 203 4.7 8.3 3.6 59.2 50.0 9.2
Home 317 4.7 1.6 3.1* 43.5 61.0 17.5*
Legal services 64 1 17.3 11.8 5.5* 36.2 55.3 19.1*
Home maintenance 527 13.3 4.7 8.6* 27.6 36.9 9.3'
Note: Car transactions include only purchases from dealers, as the GSS did not ask about satisfaction
with purchases from individuals.
* p < .05 (one-tailed tests for significance of difference between percentages of buyers with and percent-
ages without ties to sellers)

was told that the purchaser was a stranger Tests of Hypothesis 4: Satisfaction

and the other half was told that the buyer


was a relative. When the purchaser was a We have demonstrated that people believe
stranger, 27 percent reported that they that friends or relatives will give them better
would probably not or definitely not men- terms in economic exchanges than will
tion the transmission problems, compared to strangers, that people act as if they believe
14 percent if the purchaser was a relative. that they will do better as consumers in risky
Although the difference is statistically sig- exchanges if buyer-seller roles are embedded
nificant, it is not large, and most respon- in noncommercial social relations, and that
dents in both situations said they would their preferences for exchange are consistent
probably or definitely disclose the problem. with this view. Moreover, evidence from the
Some respondents no doubt gravitated to the split-sample experiments confirms these re-
socially desirable response. Unless those sults.
selling to a stranger exaggerated less than In light of these findings, we expect that
those selling to a relative, however, the dif- embedding transactions in social relation-
ference i s nontrivial from the standpoint of ships leads to more positive outcomes, as re-
buyers, who can reduce the risk of this flected in respondent reports of satisfaction
rather mild type of opportunistic behavior with goods and services. This expectation re-
by nearly 50 percent by keeping such trans- ceives strong support (Table 6). Home pur-
actions within the family. chasers with ties to home sellers or realtors
These patterns reflect a widespread per- are significantly more likely to report that
ception that persons in one's social network they are "extremely satisfied," and are less
are constrained to treat one more generously likely to say that they are "not so satisfied"
and honorably than are strangers. Of GSS with their purchases, than are those who
respondents, 56 percent agreed and only 27 transacted with strangers. Purchasers of
percent disagreed that people "usually get a home-maintenance services are significantly
better price" from friends than from strang- more likely to express great satisfaction, and
ers. Similarly, a survey of Seattle residents are significantly less likely to express dissat-
revealed high levels of agreement with isfaction, if their service provider was a net-
statements that people one knows well are work member. The same is true for purchas-
more trustworthy than are strangers and are ers of legal services: 55.3 percent of within-
more likely to provide help in time of need. network transactors but just 36.2 percent of
Moreover, most of the Seattlites agreed that out-of-network transactors were "extremely
"I would feel more comfortable buying [a satisfied" with the services they received;
used car] from a salesperson whom a friend and people who had social ties to their law-
has introduced me to" rather than from a yers were significantly less likely than
stranger (Yamagishi and Yamagishi 1994: people who did not to say they were "not so
154-55). satisfied" with the results. The hypothesis
AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

was confirmed as well in the "market for sumer markets are intensely social and indi-
lemons" (Akerlof 1970): Of people who cates that the social organization of con­
bought used cars from dealers, 15.3 percent sumer markets deserves scholarly attention.
without ties but only 5.0 percent with ties Specifically, we demonstrate that insights
describe themselves as "not so satisfied." from the economics of organization
The pattern of results is also consistent (Williamson 1985) are of substantial value in
with our theoretical framework in that the explaining the extent to which different
hypothesis was rejected only for new-car kinds of ties are embedded in social rela-
purchases, the transaction with the lowest tions. The data provide strong support for the
risk in terms of frequency and uncertainty. view that individual consumers use social
And it was most strongly supported for ser- networks in much the same way as firms use
vice transactions, which are characterized by hierarchy: as alternative governance struc-
risk-bearing performance uncertainty. More- tures for transactions for which impersonal
over, embedding relationships in social ties market relations provide inadequate protec-
appears particularly useful for reducing tion against opportunistic behavior. In this
downside risk, lessening dissatisfaction by view, the greater the risk in a transaction-
approximately one-third in legal-service that is, the greater the advantages that infor-
transactions, by two-thirds in home pur- mation asymmetry and asset specificity be-
chases and used-car sales, and by almost stow on sellers and the greater the seller's
three-quarters for home-maintenance ser­ inclination to exploit those advantages-the
vices. greater the likelihood that buyers will prefer
dealing with people to whom they have so-
cial ties outside the transaction itself. Trans-
Why Would Anyone Not Prefer to Buy acting with social contacts is effective be-
from a Friend? cause it embeds commercial exchanges in a
Some insight into this paradox is provided by web of multiplex relations that extend over
responses to two other GSS items. Although space and time, in effect holding the seller's
5 6 percent of respondents agreed that network hostage to appropriate role perfor-
"people usually get a better price for goods mance in the economic exchange.
or services when they get them from friends Respondents' reports about their purchases
than when they deal with strangers," 23 per- of homes, cars, legal services, and home-
cent disagreed and another 21 percent were maintenance services are consistent with the
uncertain. And 73 percent agreed that when view that the greater the frequency of a trans-
friends buy or sell something to friends, "dis- action (and therefore the greater the extent
cussing price is usually awkward or puts to which market incentives can control op-
somebody on the spot." Both social discom- portunism), the less common are within-net-
fort and uncertainty as to outcome may lead work exchanges. Responses to questions
some people to avoid transactions with about preferences for in-group exchanges
friends, even when they stand to benefit. support the argument that product and per-
formance uncertainty (i.e., information
asymmetries favoring sellers) lead people to
DISCUSSION prefer to buy products and services from pro-
This is the first study of social ties between viders to whom they are socially connected.
buyers and sellers that is based on a national These central results are fortified by a
sample. It demonstrates that economic wide range of supporting evidence. People
sociology's view of markets as "socially em- believe that their friends give them better
bedded" (Granovetter 1985) is applicable to terms of trade than do strangers; and they are
consumer markets. The prevalence of preex- more inclined to withhold product informa-
isting social relationships between consum- tion from strangers than from family mem-
ers and the people who sell them cars or bers. Sellers prefer to avoid selling to social
homes, staff the real-estate agencies or car contacts under the same conditions that lead
dealerships they patronize, provide them buyers to seek such transactions. People who
with legal services, and repair their homes have purchased goods and services from
confirms sociology's expectation that con- friends and relatives report greater satisfac-
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANS

tion and less dissatisfaction with the results A second factor concerns the structure of
than do people who engaged in commercial the questions: A respondent asked to imag-
transactions with strangers, and the differ- ine purchasing a home or car is likely to vi-
ences were greatest for transactions with the sualize an attractive good, and the actual pro-
greatest uncertainty. This accumulation of cess of exchange may remain in the back-
evidence suggests that our theoretical frame- ground. By contrast, a question evoking a le-
work possesses quite general applicability. gal-service or home-maintenance transaction
We also raised some questions that we necessarily entails a representation of the
could not resolve. One such question con- service providers themselves and may prime
cerns the contrast between the behavioral the respondent's perception of risk in a more
data's support for the frequency hypothesis realistic manner.
and the preference data's support for the un- A more important limitation of the analy-
certainty hypothesis. To be sure, this contrast sis is that it explains variation across trans-
is less anomalous than it appears, as the two actions and does not address variation across
views index complementary processes within persons-which, we argue, requires a differ-
one theoretical framework, not alternative ent theoretical framework and different ana-
explanatory models. Moreover, the behav- lytic methods. Many people buy homes and
ioral results were strongest for private sales, used cars from strangers, or hire attorneys or
which were not addressed by the preference electricians who are not recommended by
questions to sellers. Presumably, if the pref- their kin, friends, or acquaintances. Such de-
erence questions had asked respondents viations from apparent rationality are not just
about purchases from individuals rather than second-best solutions adopted by people with
businesses, the behavioral and preference re- impoverished social networks: Roughly 15 to
sults would have been more similar. 20 percent of each of the GSS subsamples
Even so, the strong tendency of respon- express preferences for buying from strang-
dents taking the purchaser role to prefer to ers and selling to friends, respectively-pref-
work with attorneys and home-maintenance erences that are plainly irrational in terms of
contractors to whom they have noneconomic logic set out above. To explore such indi-
ties is striking and is inconsistent with the vidual differences requires a theoretical
behavioral reports. These results cannot be framework that focuses less on how indi-
attributed to differing availability of ties, for viduals apply standardized principles of ra-
private-practice lawyers and home-mainte- tional action and more on variation among
nance workers are, respectively, the scarcest persons in their understandings of incentives
and most numerous of our occupational and risks (Dobbin 1994). The strategic fac-
groups. tors to which we call attention constitute
The inconsistency between preferences only one of two mechanisms that influence
and behavior probably reflects two factors. the extent of within-network exchange. The
The first has to do with the temporal dimen- other, variation in the extent to which people
sions of consumer choice. Many people hire participate in systems of generalized reci-
lawyers when they are in trouble or obtain procity, is not relevant to differences among
home-maintenance services when something transaction types but may be highly pertinent
is broken, and therefore they cannot control to explaining variation among persons.
the timing of their purchase. By contrast, we The GSS module is a uniquely valuable
suspect that in many car or home sales be- but imperfect resource for scholars interested
tween friends or relatives, the buyer's de- in these questions. An ideal data set would
mand for the good is stimulated by his or her include direct measures of key variables not
knowledge of its availability. Even for sales included in the GSS data: price, exchange
of used cars through dealers or homes frequency, perceived risk, and network size
through realtors, personal contacts may pro- and composition. Data on sets of transaction
vide inside information about a particularly types that vary more in uncertainty, asset
attractive deal to a buyer who is not actively specificity, and cost would be valuable, as
"in the market." Purchasers of services rarely would designs (perhaps using factorial meth-
have the luxury of waiting for a known pro- ods) that systematically manipulate transac-
vider to come to them. tion attributes.
AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Further research on the relationship be- Our results provide a useful beginning to
tween within-network exchange and formal this agenda. They should at least convince
institutions would also be desirable (Zucker readers that the phenomenon of within-net-
1986). In the GSS data, realtors seem to be work exchange is substantively important
functional alternatives to within-network ex- and theoretically engaging, and that it de-
changes. How might behavior respond to serves a larger share of economic sociolo-
variation in state "lemon laws" or real-estate gists' attention than it has received to date.
market regulations?
Finally, interpreting the GSS data some- Paul DiMaggio is Professor of Sociology and
Chair of the Sociology Department at Princeton
times required heroic assumptions about the University, and Research Coordinator of
way in which respondents perceived the Princeton's Center for Arts and Cultural Policy
world. Because little research has been un- Studies. Current research interests include iden-
dertaken on consumer markets, systematic tifying the social location of homines economici,
interviewing and ethnographic research emerging changes in the structure of firms, so­
would provide valuable input into theory de- cial division in the U.S. as revealed in both so-
velopment and research design. cial and cultural attitudes and in public conflicts
Understanding the role of social ties in con- over the arts and media, and the relationship be-
sumer relations can provide insight into other tween trends in cultural participation and
changes in family structure and gender roles.
social-scientific questions. Zelizer (1994,
chap. 3) has analyzed the ways that ex- Hugh Louch is a graduate student at Princeton
changes of monetary gifts define and build University and a research associate at the Citi-
relationships. Certain ostensibly commercial zens' Housing and Planning Council in New York
transactions probably operate the same way. City. He is currently studying land-use policy in
New York.
Once we understand the conditions under
which people engage in commercial transac-
REFERENCES
tions with their friends, we can begin to un-
derstand more fully the way that markets con- Agresti, Alan and Barbara Agresti. 1979. Statisti­
tribute to, as well as erode, social solidarity. cal Methods for the Social Sciences. San Fran-
Economists have been puzzled by the de- cisco, CA: Dellen.
gree of price heterogeneity in markets for Akerlof, George A. 1970. "The Market for 'Lem-
ons': Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market
consumer goods and services (Becker 1991). Mechanism." Quarterly Journal of Economics
Research on the role of social networks sug- 84:488-500.
gests that some price variation may reflect Barzel, Yoram. 1982. "Measurement Cost and the
not only interpersonal variation in the pos- Organization of Markets." Journal of k w and
session of information, but also heterogene- Economics 25:27-48.
ity across transactions in buyer-seller rela- Bearman, Peter. 1997. "Generalized Exchange."
tionships. Presumably, under conditions that American Journal of Sociology 102: 1383-
have yet to be specified, apparent deviations 1415.
from equilibrium prices may represent either Becker, Gary S. 1991. "A Note on Restaurant
Pricing and Other Examples of Social Influ-
quasi-insurance costs to buyers, investments
ences on Price." Journal of Political Economy
in long-term relationships by either party, or 99:1109-16.
other moves in systems of dyadic or general- Biggart, Nicole. 1989. Charismatic Capitalism:
ized reciprocity. Direct Selling Organizations in America. Chi­
Economists also have sought to understand cago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
institutions such as warranties and consumer Brown, Jacqueline Johnson and Peter H. Reingen.
protection laws as responses to market im- 1987. "Social Ties and Word-of-Mouth Refer-
perfections (Furubotn and Richter 1997:226- ral Behavior." Journal of Consumer Research
27). Recognizing within-network exchange 14:350-62.
Coleman, James. 1990. Fou~dationsof Social
as an alternative governance structure for
Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
consumer relationships may alter conclusions Press.
about the costs and benefits of institutional Cox, Steven R., Allan C. DeSerpa, and William
responses and suggest additional reasons for C. Canby, Jr. 1982. "Consumer Information
variation in the practices of sellers serving and the Pricing of Legal Services." Journal of
different market segments or client bases. Industrial Economics 30:305- 18
SOCIALLY EMBEDDED CONSUMER TRANSACTIONS 637

Davis, James A. and Tom W. Smith. 1992. The keley, CA: University of California Press.
NORC General Social Survey: A User's Guide. Powell, Walter W. 1990. "Neither Market nor Hi-
Newbury Park, CA: Sage. erarchy: Network Forms of Organization." Re­
Dobbin, Frank. 1994. "Cultural Models of Orga- search on Organizational Behavior 12:295­
nization: The Social Construction of Rational 336.
Organizing Principles." Pp. 117-42 in The So- Powell, Walter W. and Laurel Smith-Doerr. 1994.
ciology of Culture: Emerging Theoretical Per- "Networks and Economic Life." Pp. 368-425
spectives, edited by D. Crane. Cambridge, En- in Handbook of Economic Sociology, edited by
gland: Blackwell. N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg. Princeton, NJ:
Efron, Bradley and Robert J. Tibshirani. 1993. An Princeton University Press and Russell Sage
Introduction to the Bootstrap. New York: Foundation.
Chapman and Hall. Shelanski, Howard A. and Peter G. Klein. 1995.
Etzioni, Amitai. 1988. The Moral Dimension: To- "Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Eco-
wards a New Economics. New York: Free nomics: A Review and Assessment." Journal of
Press. Law, Economics, and Organization 1 1:335-61.
Frenzen, Jonathan K., Paul M. Hirsch, and Philip Smith, Charles W. 1990. Auctions: The Social
C. Zerrillo. 1994. "Consumption, Preferences, Construction of Value. Berkeley, CA: Univer-
and Changing Lifestyles." Pp. 403-25 in The sity of California Press.
Handbook of Economic Sociology, edited by N. U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1996. U.S. Statistical
J. Smelser and R. Swedberg. Princeton, NJ: Abstracts, 1996. 116th ed. Washington, DC:
Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Government Printing Office.
Foundation. Uzzi, Brian. 1997. "Social Structure and Compe-
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Rudolf Richter. 1997. In­ tition in Interfirm Networks: The Paradox of
stitutions and Economic Theory: The Contribu- Embeddedness." Administrative Science Quar-
tion of the New Institutional Economics. Ann terly 42:35-67.
Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Weber, Max. [I9221 1946. "Class Status and
Geertz, Clifford. 1978. "The Bazaar Economy: Party." Pp. 180-95 in From Max Weber: Es-
Information and Search in Peasant Marketing," says in Sociology, edited by H. H. Gerth and
American Economic Review 68:28-32. C. W. Mills. Reprint, New York: Oxford Uni-
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. "Economic Action and versity Press.
Social Structure: The Problem of Embedded- White, Harrison C. 1981. "Where Do Market
ness." American Journal of Sociology 91:481­ Come From?" American Journal of Sociology
501. 87517-47.
Granovetter, Mark and Roland Soong. 1986. Williamson, Oliver E. 1981. "The Economics of
"Threshold Models of Interpersonal Effects in Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach."
Consumer Demand," Journal of Economic Be- American Journal of Sociology 87: 548-77.
havior and Organization 7:48 1-5 10. . 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capi-
Greif, A v ~ e r .1994. "Cultural Beliefs and the Or- talism. New York: Free Press.
ganization of Society." Journal of Political . 199 1. "Comparative Economic Organiza-
Economy 102:9 12-50. tion: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alter-
Katz, Elihu and Paul F. Lazarsfeld. 1955. Per­ natives." Administrative Science Quarterly
sonal Influence. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. 36:269-96.
Kollock, Peter. 1994. "The Emergence of Ex- . 1996. "Credible Commitments: Using
change Structures: An Experimental Study of Hostages to Support Exchange." Pp. 120-44 in
Uncertainty, Commitment and Trust." Ameri­ The Mechanisms of Governance. New York:
can Journal of Sociology 100:3 13-45. Oxford University Press.
Landa, Janet Tai. 1994. Trust, Ethnicity, and Yamagishi, Toshio and Midori Yamagishi. 1994.
Identity: Beyond the New Institutional Eco­ "Trust and Commitment in the United States
nomics of Ethnic Trading Networks, Contract and Japan." Motivation and Emotion 18: 129-
Law, and Gift Exchange. Ann Arbor, MI: Uni- 66.
versity of Michigan Press. Zelizer, Viviana A. 1994. The Social Meaning of
Macauley, Stewart. 1963. "Non-Contractual Re- Money. New York: Basic Books.
lations in Business: A Preliminary Study." . 1996. "Payments and Social Ties." Socio­
American Sociological Review 28:55-67. logical Forum 11:48 1-95.
. 1985. "An Empirical View of Contract." Zucker, Lynne G . 1986. "The Production of
Wisconsin Law Review 3:465-82. Trust: Institutional Sources of Economic Struc-
Marsden, Peter. 1988. "Homogeneity in Confid- ture, 1840-1920." Pp. 53-1 11 in Research in
ing Relations." Social Networks 9: 100-25. Organizational Behavior, edited by B. Staw
Portes, Alejandro and Alex Stepick. 1993. City on and L. L. Cummings. Greenwich, CT: JAI
the Edge: The Transformation of Miami. Ber­ Press.

Вам также может понравиться