Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 15

bs_bs_banner

doi: 10.1111/apel.12135

Death of linkages in host countries? A firm-level


study on the channels of productivity spillovers in
the Malaysian manufacturing sector

Andrew Jia Yi Kam*

Productivity spillovers from multinational corporations (MNCs) to local


firms have been an area of keen research interest in developing economics.
Claims of positive spillovers in the form of technology transfers have been
questionable, in part because of the many ambiguous conclusions obtained.
The paper argues that the lack of focus in the mechanisms underpinning
spillovers may be one of the reasons for the ambiguity. Using local input–
output linkages as the mechanism for technology transfer, this study exam-
ines the presence and the enabling conditions for spillovers. Accounting
for the variations in firms’ characteristics, the findings show that skills-
oriented MNCs participating in international production networks transmit
horizontal spillovers to local establishments. Vertical spillovers from MNCs
are mostly relevant only to lower-skilled establishments. For skilled and
export-oriented local establishments, technologies learned from producing
for international production networks are more significant than forming
linkages with MNCs in the domestic market.

the impact of spillovers.1 Their argument


Introduction reflects Javorcik’s (2004) claim that ‘researchers
[may] have been looking for FDI spillovers in
Over the years, ‘extravagant’ claims about positive the wrong place’.
spillovers from foreign direct investment (FDI) Previous studies also often overlooked the role
through foreign firms or multinational corpora- of firm characteristics in affecting transmission
tions (MNCs) have been questioned because of channels. For example, MNCs operating in
the paucity of evidence (Rodrick 1999). Re- enclaves2 may hinder productivity spillovers
searchers have provided various explanations to local industries (Kokko 1994; Javorcik 2004;
for this uncertainty. Giroud and Scott-Kennel Jabbour and Mucchielli 2007). MNCs’ decisions
(2006) argued that the use of inappropriate on whether to procure from local firms generally
definitions may have misled conclusions about affect the extent of technology transfers and

* Andrew Jia Yi Kam, Research Fellow, Institute of Malaysian and International Studies, National University of Malaysia,
E-mail: Andrew@ukm.edu.my. The author thanks Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia for providing funding for the research
via GGPM-2014-002. Responsibility for any errors is the author’s alone.

1 ‘Linkages’ are a direct mechanism for spillovers and occur through inter-firm transactions, interactions, and ongoing
relationships; while spillovers occur as a by-product of MNC activity in the host economy.
2 Isolated clusters of MNCs with technologies and scales of operation different from local firms. An example would be MNCs
clustered around free trade zones.

65

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

information sharing in the host economies techniques, and management skills constitute a
(UNCTAD 2000). MNCs would also have an in- form of productivity and technology transfer
centive to withhold their technology in order to ‘spilling over’ from MNCs to local firms/
safeguard their proprietary assets. Knowledge- industries.5 In addition, the terms MNCs and
sharing basically hinges on the strength of foreign firms are also used interchangeably.
supplier–distributor relationships with locals. Section 2 presents the analytical framework
Hence, technology transfers and the impact of and literature reviews on linkages and spillover
spillovers could be more prevalent in a ‘vertical’ channels. Sections 3 and 4 explain the database
setting (Caves 1974; Javorcik 2004; Jabbour and and methodology used. Section 5 presents the
Mucchielli 2007). findings from the estimations, while section 6
The focus on linkages as a spillover channel is concludes the study and examines whether
pertinent to Malaysia because its extensive linkages or policies promoting linkage formation
experience in hosting FDIs since the 1970s. are still relevant.
Linkage-formation plans were embedded in
many Malaysian development strategies. Since
the introduction of the Investment Incentives
Act 1968 and the creation of Free Trade Zones Analytical framework
in the 1970s, policymakers in Malaysia have
put great faith in FDI as one of its early sources
of industrial upgrading. While the country Channels of spillovers
aspires to achieve advanced nation status by
Positive FDI spillovers occur when the presence
the year 2020, industrial upgrading efforts that
of MNCs in the host economy directly or indirectly
spanned more than three decades was ineffective,
increases the productivity growth of local
judging by the current dilemma of being stuck
firms. Although productivity spillovers could
in the ‘middle income trap’.3 This outcome
occur through other channels (for example,
has left policymakers questioning whether its
innovation cooperation or technology licensing),
previous policies have enabled local firms to
this study focuses on the direct/indirect input–
reap productivity gains from the MNCs.
output linkages formed between MNCs and
Thus, instead of making the assumption that
local firms. The a priori assumption is that
foreign presence automatically benefits domestic
MNCs possess technology, management
firms’ productivity, the transmission channels
techniques, and marketing networks that are
of spillovers should be further explored.
superior to those of local firms. The analytical
The paper addresses this issue by asking
framework is explained using Figure 1.
whether linkages facilitate foreign-to-local
productivity spillovers. If so, what are the firm
characteristics that may facilitate the process.4 Indirect or horizontal linkages. Horizontal
Although it is important to address the terminol- linkages measure the impact of foreign presence
ogy differences highlighted by Giroud and in each sector. They could be in the form of a
Scott-Kennel (2006), data limitations have collaborative relationship between firms or an
restricted disentanglement of the terms spill- indirect demonstration effect from MNCs
overs, productivity, and technology transfers. (UNCTAD 2000). The demonstration effect al-
Therefore, this paper uses them interchangeably, lows local firms to improve their productivity
maintaining that positive spillovers from FDI through imitating, learning, adopting, adapting,
such as improvements in technology, marketing and reverse engineering of the management and

3 Unable to remain as a low-cost and high-volume producer, yet unable to move up the value chain and enter high-value
markets for knowledge and innovation-based products and services (Schellekens 2009).
4 This paper extends Khalifah et. al (2015) by identifying the impact of specific establishment characteristics as part of the
push/pull factors for technology transfer, rather than only explaining foreign presence through wage and capital proxies.
5 This is a broad description and it does not account for how the technology is being used. However, the paper is focused on
how the technologies are being transferred. We leave the use of the transferred technologies to further study.

66

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
KAM — CHANNELS OF PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS IN THE MALAYSIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

Figure 1
Analytical framework for channels of spillovers through linkages.

production techniques introduced by the MNCs. local producers use these higher technology
It also includes trained ex-employees of MNCs inputs to produce higher quality goods.
becoming new local players in the industry.

Direct linkages. As illustrated in Figure 1, direct Data


linkages are formed between foreign firms and
their local suppliers, customers, or distributors The study uses unpublished 2000–08 data from
within a vertically integrated production network. the Annual Survey of Manufacturing Industries
If it involves a direct relationship between MNCs (ASMI), a survey conducted annually by the
and local suppliers, it is called a backward linkage. Department of Statistics Malaysia (DOS) that fo-
The relationship between MNCs and their prod- cuses only on establishments in the manufactur-
uct distributors/customers is a forward linkage. ing sector. While it contains comprehensive sets
Backward linkages are a relationship in of variables, not all information is accessible to
which MNCs (in downstream industries) the public and is controlled under the Statistics
procure parts, components, materials, and Act 1965 (revised in 1989). Variables from two
services from local suppliers. Spillovers from categories of firms are available: ‘majority local
backward linkages may stem from technology owners’ and ‘majority foreign owners’. Enter-
transfers by the parent MNCs to enhance the prises where the majority of owners are local
output of local establishments. A forward (above 50 per cent) are classified as ‘majority lo-
linkage is a relationship whereby local firms (as cal owned’ (hereafter, local establishments). A
customers) buy intermediate or final products similar classification is applied to ‘foreign estab-
produced by foreign firms. Rodriguez-Clare lishments’. This is not a setback considering that
(1996) argued that inputs supplied by foreign the bulk of foreign affiliates already have major-
firms are specialised inputs that are of higher ity ownership.6 Data prior to 2000 and after 2008
quality than those produced locally. Productivity are omitted because they have different classifi-
spillovers from forward linkages occur when cations, and key information on firm

6 One of the prerequisites for local firms to be eligible for the Industrial Linkages Program is that at least 51 per cent of the
company’s shares is owned by Malaysians. With our data from the DOS matching this prerequisite, we are assured that
linkage creation with MNCs has occurred because by definition these local firms are eligible for the program.

67

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

Table 1
Construction of variables
Value of exports, deflated using the export deflator indicator derived from Bank Negara Malaysia’s annual
Exports report and re-based to the year 2000
Skill Share of skilled workers in total employment. Skilled workers are managers, professionals and executives,
technicians, and associate professionals (DOS 2008)
Sales Sales of goods manufactured/processed/assembled (including duties and taxes) by firms; net of non-
processing re-sales, subsidies, rebates on price, discounts, and allowances on returned goods allowed to the
customers (DOS 2008).
IFN IFN = (MF/Q)*X. IFN is the production fragmentation indicator; MF represents imported intermediate goods;
and Q is gross output (which embeds both domestic and foreign intermediate goods). The share of
intermediate goods in gross output (MF/Q) is used as a weight to represent the share of imported intermediate
goods processed into exported output X
SP Refer to Equations 2 (horizontal), 3 (backward), and (4) (forward linkages)
Gap Differences in TFP between foreign and local firms
Comp Dummy variable where 1 = sales growth of local firms > sales growth of foreign firms (competitive local) and
0 = otherwise (less competitive)
Pol Proxy by year dummy for foreign firms from 2004 to 2008 (assuming the impact of the policy is only evident a
year later)
ICT Industry dummy variable (MSIC 30 and 32)
Scale In this study, the scale or the size of the firms (scale) is proxied by the number of employees per output.

IFN = international fragmentation network, MSIC = Malaysian Standard Industrial Classification, TFP = total factor productivity.

characteristics is unavailable. The study focuses vertical linkages are constructed using the
on the manufacturing sector, defined as Indus- input–output (I/O) tables. A foreign production
tries 15–36 of the Malaysian Standard Industrial component is incorporated to indicate a foreign
Classification (MSIC) 2000. presence in the upstream and downstream
industries (Table 1).

Methodology Horizontal linkages (indirect impact of foreign


presence). Horizontal linkages capture foreign
presence in sector j at time t. The variable shows
Construction of key variables the impact of foreign establishments’ participation
across industries; meaning that it captures the
Productivity growth. To estimate total factor impact on competitors, alliances, or even unre-
productivity growth (TFPG), information on lated establishments. The study re-constructed
capital, labour, and intermediate inputs was ex- Jarvorcik’s (2004) indicator by disregarding the
tracted from the ASMI. TFPG was estimated calculation of ownership shares because all
using the simple growth accounting method.7 foreign establishments in the database have above
50 per cent ownership. Horizontal linkage is there-
Horizontal and vertical linkages. To measures fore represented by the share of foreign output in
horizontal and vertical linkages, the study com- the total output of the sector. The expression in pa-
bines methods from Rasmussen (1956); Ghosh renthesis on the right side of Equation 1 represents
(1958), and Javorcik (2004). The indicators of the foreign presence in the economy:

7 See Kam (2014) for the calculation of skills and capital-adjusted TFPG. The growth accounting method is the method used by
Malaysian officials in estimating productivity. Other methods such as stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) and that of Olley and
Pakes (1996) were considered. SFA is more suitable if firm-level data are available (see Coelli et al. 2005). The latter method
assumes that firms will adjust inputs based on their productivity. It is not used because the database available for this study is
a collective representation of firms.

68

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
KAM — CHANNELS OF PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS IN THE MALAYSIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

 
Foreign Output direct-input coefficient matrix (using the I/O
Horizontaljt ðHozÞ ¼ table). It shows the proportion of i input
Total Output jt
purchased by industry j.
(1) Foreign establishments now play the role of
input suppliers to local final goods producers.
Backward linkages (foreign presence in downstream
The impact of foreign presence is measured net
industries). Backward linkages represent the in-
of exports to ensure only foreign-produced
terconnection of a firm in the sectors from which
intermediates sold in the domestic market are
it purchases inputs. They capture the relation-
included.
ships with domestic suppliers, with MNCs as
The αij and gij coefficients were generated
the customers:
using the 2005 I/O table. The I/O table was
matched with the MSIC 2000.
 
n Foreign output - Imported input
BLj ¼ ∑ gij
i¼1 Total output - Imported input jt Profile of the manufacturing sector
(2) Tables 2 and 3 provide an overview of the
manufacturing sector in Malaysia based on the
where BLi is an indicator of foreign presence in ASMI. Columns 1 and 2 show the output share
downstream industries, with sector i being of local and foreign establishments, respectively,
supplied by sector j. gij is the ijth element of in the manufacturing sector. Foreign establish-
the Ghosh inverse matrix (I-Ā)1 with Ā as the ments are mostly concentrated in the manufacture
direct-output coefficient matrix (using the I/O of office, accounting, and computing machinery
table). It shows the proportion of total output (MSIC 30) and manufacture of radio, television,
of sector i supplied to sector j. n is the number and communication equipment and apparatus
of sectors. (MSIC 32) industries (hereafter, MSIC 30 and
Here, foreign presence (in parenthesis) is MSIC 32 are known as Information and Commu-
calculated net of imported intermediate inputs. nications Technology (ICT)). Foreign firms have
This is to ensure that backward linkages only higher output than local establishments in machin-
involve inputs supplied locally. This method ery and equipment (MSIC 29), textiles (MSIC 17),
shows that the share of an industry’s demand and manufacture of medical, precision, and optical
for an input is weighted by the amount of instruments, watches, and clocks (MSIC 33), and
output produced by foreign establishments in the manufacture of other transport equipment
the host economy. (MSIC 35) industries. Foreign establishments have
the least output contribution in the publishing,
Forward linkages (foreign presence in upstream printing, and reproduction of recorded media
industries). Forward linkages are the intercon- industry (MSIC 22). Local establishments are
nections between input producers from a partic- concentrated more in the resource-based sectors.
ular sector to final-goods sectors. They are On average, the technology gap between for-
defined as a weighted share of output in eign and local establishments has increased
upstream (or supplying) sectors. since 2000. The technology gap is most signifi-
cant in MSIC 33, followed by manufacture of
  furniture (MSIC 36) and manufacture of
n Foreign output - Exports chemicals and chemical products (MSIC 24).
FLj ¼ ∑ αij
i¼1 Total output - Exports jt Local establishments have technological advan-
tages in manufacturing of clothing and apparel
(3)
(MSIC 17 and 18). The technological gaps in
the ICT industries are relatively low. This
where FLj indicates foreign presence in the implies that foreign establishments in ICT indus-
upstream sector. αij is the ijth element of the tries may only be investing in areas with lower
Leontief inverse matrix (I-A)1 with A as the technology requirements. A case study by
69

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
Table 2
2(a)Market characteristics of the Malaysian manufacturing sector

Technology gap Intermediate input sources (Local firms) (4) Intermediate input sources (Foreign firms) (5)
(TFPForeign—
Local output Foreign output
Total output (1) Total output (2) TFPLocal) (3) Import Local Import Local Import Local Import Local
Year
Industry 2000 2008 2000 2008 2000 2008 2000 2000 2008 2008 2000 2000 2008 2008
15 0.79 0.82 0.21 0.18 0.25 0.29 11.2 62.5 5.3 51.1 10.7 50.7 13.5 39.7
16 0.74 0.88 0.26 0.12 0.40 0.89 27.5 20.0 4.3 35.1 46.7 11.7 17.6 48.2
17 0.37 0.39 0.63 0.61 0.36 0.27 28.4 25.5 18.7 24.7 32.0 19.3 17.6 31.3
18 0.70 0.78 0.30 0.22 0.40 0.45 26.6 27.4 13.5 23.4 38.3 21.8 29.2 9.9
19 0.62 0.63 0.38 0.37 0.14 0.29 6.9 49.4 9.6 40.4 33.7 26.6 22.5 15.8
20 0.85 0.88 0.15 0.12 0.10 0.15 2.0 57.0 1.8 43.0 7.7 50.0 3.0 36.8
21 0.84 0.74 0.16 0.26 0.18 0.32 16.6 38.2 10.0 36.4 30.4 28.6 16.4 24.5
22 0.90 0.88 0.10 0.12 0.40 0.23 10.8 34.5 11.1 31.7 30.0 12.3 20.3 22.5
23 0.74 0.81 0.26 0.19 0.07 0.21 15.5 48.5 0.1 28.6 31.6 59.6 21.5 13.6
24 0.50 0.61 0.50 0.39 0.20 0.34 10.5 35.9 16.5 21.4 29.8 36.0 20.3 24.0

70
25 0.71 0.70 0.29 0.30 0.28 0.22 10.5 45.0 10.8 39.0 17.9 30.2 17.1 30.1
26 0.74 0.76 0.26 0.24 0.16 0.20 7.2 29.8 3.6 31.5 19.7 10.7 12.1 17.0
27 0.73 0.79 0.27 0.21 0.02 0.42 23.4 46.3 21.6 34.5 43.1 25.4 43.4 13.5
28 0.66 0.77 0.34 0.23 0.11 0.32 13.5 47.5 8.2 37.4 40.3 19.9 22.5 21.8
29 0.34 0.48 0.66 0.52 0.01 0.25 12.6 46.2 16.6 38.9 27.0 32.9 21.1 36.7
30 0.12 0.07 0.88 0.93 0.05 0.13 40.2 37.7 38.2 31.4 45.1 37.4 48.2 16.8
31 0.47 0.54 0.53 0.46 0.13 0.15 29.5 39.6 26.9 37.8 36.2 24.6 37.9 23.9
32 0.23 0.23 0.77 0.77 0.16 0.41 34.2 34.1 38.2 17.5 47.7 27.7 44.5 15.3
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

33 0.17 0.25 0.83 0.75 0.03 0.75 17.8 42.2 53.2 12.6 41.2 25.2 37.1 19.8
34 0.92 0.81 0.08 0.19 0.50 0.01 29.1 46.0 18.0 47.3 39.4 20.9 40.3 19.9
35 0.82 0.69 0.18 0.31 0.40 0.13 20.8 25.0 16.2 27.3 40.7 7.4 17.2 21.9
36 0.74 0.86 0.26 0.14 0.31 0.50 9.7 48.9 11.2 47.9 19.0 34.9 18.3 31.7
Average 0.62 0.65 0.38 0.35 0.04 0.06 18.4 40.3 16.1 33.6 32.2 27.9 24.6 24.3
Median 0.72 0.75 0.28 0.25 0.11 0.18 16.0 40.9 12.4 34.8 32.9 26.0 20.7 22.2

Note: Refer to Appendix 6.1 for industrial codes. Source: Author’s calculation from ASMI 2000–08, I/O 2000 and I/O 2005.
TFP = total factor productivity, ASMI = Annual Survey of Manufacturing Industries.

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
Table 3
2(b)Market characteristics of the Malaysian manufacturing sector (continued)
IFN* (6) Share of skilled workers (7)
Local Foreign Local Foreign
Local Foreign Local Foreign firms firms firms firms
Total 2000 2000 2008 2008 2000 2000 2008 2008
15 1.8 5.1 2.2 9.7 15.2 22.5 14.0 26.6 Manufacture of food products and beverages
16 0.6 33.0 0.1 7.5 7.9 45.6 10.8 26.6 Manufacture of tobacco products
17 7.6 26.9 3.5 3.4 16.2 16.6 14.0 28.0 Manufacture of textiles
18 11.9 21.9 5.3 13.3 8.0 10.3 6.2 11.0 Manufacture of wearing apparel; dressing and dyeing of fur
19 0.9 21.6 1.3 3.1 11.0 4.6 9.9 18.5 Tanning and dressing of leather; manufacture of luggage, handbags,

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


saddlery, harness, and footwear
20 1.1 5.2 0.9 2.1 8.6 7.1 9.2 8.7 Manufacture of wood and products of wood and cork, except
furniture; manufacture of articles of straw and plaiting materials
21 2.5 12.7 0.7 3.5 16.8 16.7 17.4 22.6 Manufacture of paper and paper products
22 0.4 18.5 0.3 2.0 17.9 12.8 23.2 17.0 Publishing, printing, and reproduction of recorded media
23 5.0 4.5 0.1 3.1 30.6 48.8 81.0 17.2 Manufacture of Coke, refined petroleum products, and nuclear fuel
24 2.7 11.6 3.1 8.8 26.7 36.1 29.3 34.4 Manufacture of chemicals and chemical products
25 3.3 11.1 3.5 9.0 13.9 14.7 16.0 16.4 Manufacture of rubber and plastic products

71
26 1.5 6.2 0.3 3.2 18.8 14.9 17.1 26.8 Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products
27 4.5 19.3 3.0 14.5 19.3 25.5 23.5 23.3 Manufacture of Basic Metals
28 2.0 23.2 1.4 15.4 16.5 17.3 15.6 24.0 Manufacture of fabricated metal products, except machinery and
equipment
29 1.4 17.1 4.4 9.1 18.7 21.6 20.7 21.6 Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c.

The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
30 23.7 37.7 13.6 23.8 15.3 18.0 25.5 32.4 Manufacture of office, accounting, and computing machinery
31 10.8 24.4 4.4 16.7 14.7 18.7 17.7 20.0 Manufacture of electrical machinery and apparatus n.e.c.
32 24.0 39.8 15.1 25.7 17.4 21.2 27.8 28.6 Manufacture of radio, television and communication equipment,
and apparatus
33 6.3 27.5 24.4 15.4 18.1 21.0 20.0 19.0 Manufacture of medical, precision and optical instruments, watches,
and clocks
34 5.6 14.0 0.3 7.4 17.2 15.9 21.7 22.3 Manufacture of motor vehicles, trailers, and semi-trailers
35 1.1 35.6 1.4 5.4 22.0 15.7 22.9 39.3 Manufacture of other transport equipment
36 3.5 14.4 3.3 10.6 11.0 10.9 11.0 15.1 Manufacture of furniture; manufacturing n.e.c.
Average 5.6 19.6 4.2 10.9 16.4 19.8 20.7 22.7
Median 3.0 18.9 2.6 9.1 16.7 17.0 17.6 22.4
KAM — CHANNELS OF PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS IN THE MALAYSIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

Note:
*The indicator for international fragmentation network (IFN) is constructed based on the equation in Appendix 6.2. It is basically the imported input content of exported output.
Source: Author’s calculation from ASMI 2000–08, I/O 2000 and I/O 2005.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

Driffield and Noor (1999) showed that MNCs corporations (GLCs) in steel, petrol, and automo-
only employ older technologies in order to foster tive industries (MSIC 23, 27, and 34) have the
input linkages with domestic suppliers. This is resources to compete with MNCs in employing
common when MNCs mainly focus on labour- skilled engineers, scientists, and managers. In
intensive assembly, and low value-added ICT industries, the share of skilled labour to total
production of parts and components. employment is only marginally higher for foreign
Columns 4 and 5 in Table 2 compare the establishments. This is consistent with the data in
different sources of input procurement (as a Column 3 that shows technology gaps between
share of total output) by foreign and local estab- foreign and local establishments in ICT are low.
lishments. On average, local establishments use
more local intermediate inputs than foreign Variable specification and model structure
establishments, while foreign establishments
have higher imported input content in their The model to estimate the impact of foreign
production. This implies relatively weak back- presence and establishment characteristics on
ward linkages. It is not surprising that foreign the productivity growth of local establishments
and local establishments in ICT industries are consists of five elements:
highly dependent on foreign sourcing because
of the outward-oriented nature of this industry. TFPG= ƒ{Establishments’ characteristics
The decline in the average share of domestic (FC), spillover channels (SP), inter-
input procurement suggests a weakening in action between establishments’
backward linkage formation with local estab- characteristics and spillover chan-
lishments since 2000. nels (FC*Sp), comparative effect
There are also foreign establishments that (DE), and indirect effect (IE)}
have switched their preferences from imported Where:
inputs to locally made inputs. This switch
suggests local establishments have entered FCown Export intensity (Exp) or skilled-
foreign establishments’ production networks. orientation (Skill) or sales intensity
Foreign establishments in industries such as (proxy for output) (Sale) or IFN par-
tobacco (MSIC 16) and MSIC 35 have reduced ticipation (IFN)
their dependence on foreign inputs, while SP Horizontal (Hoz), backward (BL),
deepening backward linkages with local estab- and forward (FL) channels. Foreign
lishments. Column 6 shows that both local and presence in upstream and down-
foreign establishments in ICT are integrated into stream industries. Positive coeffi-
international fragmentation networks (IFNs).8 cient of these variables shows the
Although the shares of their involvement de- channel of spillovers.
creased from 2000 to 2008, this industry is still FCown*SP Interaction terms identifying the
very dependent on foreign demand and sourc- impact of Sale, Exp, Skill, and IFN-
ing. Foreign establishments may retain doubts oriented establishments in different
on the quality of local production (Leslie 1993). SP channels on TFPG. Positive signs
Column 7 shows that foreign establishments in the interaction variables show the
in the manufacture of chemicals and chemical channels and firm characteristics
products (MSIC 24) hire more skilled workers that facilitates productivity spill-
than local establishments. MNCs often offer overs from foreign to local establish-
higher wages and better benefits to retain ments.
human capital in an effort to prevent skills CE Impact of TFPG gaps between for-
mobility and knowledge leakage to competitors. eign and local establishments (Gap).
However, protected, government-linked Proxy for establishments’ absorptive

8 International production fragmentation is defined similarly to vertical specialisation (Hummels et al. 2001), a situation where
imported intermediate parts and components are used to produce goods for export.

72

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
KAM — CHANNELS OF PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS IN THE MALAYSIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

capacity (A. Kokko 1994) and com- establishments have the potential to add value
petition (Comp). to the learning curve of local suppliers/
IE Policy and ICT-dummy (Pol and producers. However, local establishments with
ICT), Scale and Demand. a higher share of skilled workers (SkillL) have
better capacities to imitate, adapt, and even
Subscript own represents the types of estab- innovate on the technologies from the MNCs.
lishments in the analysis: local (L) or foreign (F) Hence, here the relationship between linkages,
establishments. T represents the combined establishment skills, and spillovers is
database of F and L. ambiguous.
There are four establishment characteristics Productivity spillovers are also driven by
(FCown) and three channels of FDI spillovers sudden increases in demand generated by FDIs
(SP) of interest in this study. These channels of (Javorcik 2004; Jabbour and Mucchielli 2007).
technology spillovers (horizontal, backward, Local establishments will increase productivity
and forward linkages) are explained in in profitable markets where MNCs enter. To con-
section 2. This study adds to the literature by in- trol for shifts in market demand, this study uses
cluding interaction terms between spillover establishment sales (Sale) as a proxy (Harabi
channels and firm characteristics (FC*SP). The a 1992). Growth in sales also represents the estab-
priori understanding is that the foreign establish- lishments’ output growth, which can be loosely
ments in upstream/downstream industries argued in the context of Verdoorn’s Law.9 The
have an impact on the productivity of local es- indicator also enables the study to examine
tablishments based on the characteristics of both whether foreign (local) high-performing and
kinds of establishments. market-competitive establishments are dissemi-
Export-intensive foreign establishments (ExpF) nating (absorbing) technology.
may have lesser interactions with local estab- Previous studies argued that local sourcing
lishments because they generally operate in by foreign establishments will increase the
enclaves such as export processing zones possibilities for spillovers compared with
(EPZs). MNCs located in EPZs may not form foreign establishments that rely solely on foreign
linkages with local establishments because the inputs (Driffield and Noor 1999). However, with
duties exemptions on imported inputs are more the increasing access to the IFNs, internal link-
attractive. Their counterpart, export-intensive ages with the domestic economy may be con-
local establishments (ExpL), is exposed to inter- fined to a small basket of local inputs. Foreign
national production standards and therefore establishments that are integrated into global
has higher absorptive capacities. Unless domestic production networks (IFNF) have greater access
vertical linkages are formed with the MNCs in the to foreign inputs. Therefore, interactions with
country, these local establishments may not rely the local economy are much less and hence
on them as the main source of technology. There- minimise the potential for spillovers. The IFNs
fore, horizontal linkages may also create spillovers also provide opportunities for local establish-
as ExpL have the capacity to learn by exporting. ments (IFNL) to form external linkages with other
As shown in Table 3, foreign establishments global MNCs. Hence, domestic vertical linkages
with higher numbers of skilled workers (SkillF) with foreign establishments are also unnecessary,
are in high-tech and knowledge-based indus- thus invoking the phrase ‘death of linkages’.
tries. Compared with labour-intensive and One uncontrolled element in this study is the
assembly oriented industries, high-tech foreign level of import protection. Import protection

9 According to this law, faster growth of output (in this context, sales) increases productivity because of increasing returns. The
impact of sales on TFPG is therefore expected to be positive.
10 Since 1992 tariff reduction has been on-going through AFTA’s Common Effective Preferential Tariff (CEPT) scheme.
Integration with the regional/global economic system has been on going (being a signatory of the WTO Information
Technology Agreement since 1994; becoming a member of the WTO in 1995; being a member of the ASEAN-China FTA since
2005; and a member of the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement 2015).

73

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

distorts resource allocation of MNCs and Model 1: Spillovers from linkages with different
impedes productivity improvements (Truong types of foreign establishments.
et al. 2015). However, in Malaysia, efforts to
remove import protection have long been in TFPGL;it ¼ α þ α1 lnFCF;it ðþÞ þ β1 Hoz þ β2 BL (6)
place.10 Despite some industries being more ðþ=Þ ðþ=Þ

protected than others, Table 2 shows that, on av- þβ3 FL þ θ1 Hoz*lnFCF;it þ θ2 BL*lnFCF;it
erage, foreign establishments have a higher share ðþ=Þ
ðþ=Þ ðþ=Þ

of imported inputs than locally made inputs. This þθ3 FL*lnFCF;it þ γ1 Gapit þ γ2 Compit
implies that, in general, import protection is not ðþ=Þ ðþ=Þ ðþ=Þ

overly restrictive for foreign establishments in þϕ 1 Scale þ ϕ 2 Polt þ ϕ 3 ICT t þ εit


Malaysia. The IFN indicator thus controls for ðþÞ ðþÞ

the impact of import restrictions as they may af- where subscripts i and t represent establish-
fect the operations of a production network. ments and year.
Comparative effects (CE) are variables that Model 1 tests the impact of the MNCs’
affect TFPG because of differences in competi- presence and their characteristics on the TFPG
tive advantages between foreign and local estab- of local establishments. The model aims to
lishments. The first indicator is the difference in identify the types of foreign establishments that
technology gaps (Gap) between foreign and local affect local TFPG and through which channels
establishments. Significant technological differ- spillovers will most likely occur. The interaction
ences imply weak domestic absorptive capaci- indicators explain the impact of linkages with
ties, which impede technological transfers the MNCs, conditional on their characteristics.
(Kokko 1994). The second CE is market competi- For example, Hoz*lnExpF represents the
tion11 (Comp). Previous studies suggest that local horizontal impact of foreign export-oriented
competition will force foreign establishments establishments on local TFPG. BL*lnExpF
into bringing in newer technologies to protect measures the impact of export-oriented foreign
market share. However, this variable may not establishments in downstream sectors on local
be relevant in a highly open economy where establishments, while FL*lnExpF measures the
competition stems from international rather impact of export-oriented foreign establish-
than domestic markets. ments in upstream sectors on local firms.
Indirect effects (IE) are the indirect factors
affecting TFPG in the presence of MNCs. For Model 2: Local establishments and linkages
example, investment liberalisation policies
implemented by the Malaysian Industrial TFPGL;it ¼ α þ α1 lnFCL;it ðþÞ þ β1 Hoz (7)
Development Authority (MIDA) in 2003 aimed ðþ=Þ

to attract foreign investors into the manufacturing


þβ2 BL þ β3 FL þ θ1 Hoz*lnFCL;it
sector. This policy indirectly created more ðþ=Þ ðþ=Þ
ðþ=Þ

opportunities for foreign-to-local spillovers. The þθ2 BL*lnFCL;it þ θ3 FL*lnFCL;it


model also controls for the Malaysian ICT sector ðþ=Þ ðþ=Þ

because of the heavy concentration of foreign þγ1 Gapit þ γ2 Compit þ ϕ 1 Scale þ ϕ 2 Polt
presence in the industry. Finally, by definition, ðþ=Þ ðþ=Þ ðþÞ

TFPG is an indicator of residual, where an þϕ 3 ICT t þ εit


increase in output due to economies of scale ðþÞ

may artificially increase TFPG values. Therefore,


economies of scale are being controlled as well. where subscripts i and t represent industry
Two model specifications were proposed: (collective establishments) and year.

11 The commonly used Herfindhal index or the CR4 index is not used here because firm-level data (market share of firms) is not
available in the ASMI. The alternative used here is to proxy competition with intra-industry sales growth between foreign and
local firms. Local firms in the same industry with higher sales growth than foreign firms are considered more competitive than
foreign firms. A positive value may also indicate a change in the technology used due to market competitive pressures.
Therefore, a caveat is that the indicator used is unable to ascertain the dynamics of technology utilization.

74

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
KAM — CHANNELS OF PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS IN THE MALAYSIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

Model 2 tests the impact of foreign presence


on local establishments with differentiated Results
characteristics. This model focuses on the
values of θ1, θ2, and θ3 in identifying the
types of local establishments that have experi- Model 1: Spillovers from linkages with
enced the most profound changes in their pro- different types of foreign establishments
ductivity growth when MNCs are present. The
explanations for the interaction terms mirror Model 1 examines the impact of foreign estab-
those in Model 1 with the impact now based lishments with different characteristics on the
on local establishments’ characteristics. For productivity growth of local firms. In Table 4,
example, BL*lnExpL represents the impact of all indicators of foreign characteristics (without
foreign presence in downstream industries on interaction terms) are insignificant. This result
the local export-oriented establishments’ pro- was expected because the FCF variables have
ductivity growth. excluded linkage/spillover effects (SP = 0) from
The lin-log model is used to reduce the local establishments. However, using the center-
variation (or stabilise the variances) for a ing method (results with the ‘(b)’ label),
better fit of the model. Each FC enters the Equations (2b), (3b), and (4b) suggest that
model separately to prevent multicollinearity skilled, sales and IFN-oriented foreign establish-
problems. The standard Hausman test is first ments on average have a positive impact on the
applied in examining whether unique errors productivity growth of local establishments;
are correlated with the regressors. The with skills-oriented foreign establishments regis-
Breusch–Pagan Lagrange multiplier (LM) test tering the largest impact.13
is used to determine whether random effects On backward linkages, export-oriented
estimation is preferred over pooled estima- foreign establishments (Equations (1) and (1b))
tion methods. The estimation is undertaken have the most profound impact on local
using heteroskedasticity-robust standard establishments, followed by skill-intensive
errors. The Levin–Lu-Chu stationarity test is establishments, and, as expected, the impact of
also deployed (with ‘demean’ for scale to IFN-oriented establishments is the least. By
mitigate cross-sectional dependence, because construction, the IFN variable assumes establish-
the size of establishments may also affect ments to have high procurement of foreign inputs
linkages). (meaning low local input procurement). There-
Finally, in analysing the interaction terms, fore, linkage formation with locals is less and
the paper uses the data ‘centring’ method spillovers are not evident. Market-driven foreign
(Aiken and West 1991). ‘Centring’ involves establishments with high sales also form
subtracting their mean value from the inde- backward linkages with local establishments in
pendent variables and re-estimated again so order to utilise local resources and minimise
that the analysis is undertaken ‘on average’.12 production costs.
The benefits of estimating the centred model Productivity spillovers from skill-oriented
is that the t-statistics and the level of statistical foreign establishments (the interaction term)
significance have taken account of the overall are stronger through the horizontal channel
joint effect. even though skill-oriented foreign establishments

12 For example, the impact of FC on TFPG is as follows: ∂TFPG/∂FC = α1 + θ1Hoz + θ2BL + θ3FL where the impact of FC is
subjected to the channels of foreign spillovers (conditional effect). Without centring, α1 is the impact of FC on TFPG when
all three channels of spillovers are equal to zero. With centring, α1 is the impact of FC when all three channels of
spillovers are equal to their mean values. It is similar to putting mean values of Hoz, BL and FL into the partial derivative
expression above.
13 A caveat to this finding is that different industries may exhibit different outcomes. For example, Khalifah et al. (2015) found
negative spillovers in E&E industries, in part due to the lack of demand from foreign firms for locally supplied intermediate
goods.

75

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

0.223 (0.68)
0.178 (0.47)
0.233 (0.38)

0.996** (2.74)
also transfer technology to local firms through

0.102 (0.56)
0.340** (4.95)
0.213** (3.49)
0.0474 (0.04)

0.398** (2.62)

0.0503 (1.37)

0.263* (2.35)
0.168 (1.51)
backward linkages. Horizontal indirect linkages
tfpg
4(b)

180
such as through demonstration effects are evi-
dent in shared training programs in facilities such
as the Penang Skills and Development Center.
0.00301 (0.03)

5.402** (2.71)
1.502 (0.55)
0.233 (0.38)

0.996** (2.74)
0.102 (0.56)
0.340** (4.95)

3.082 (0.34)

0.398** (2.62)

0.0503 (1.37)

0.263* (2.35)
0.168 (1.51)
Also, in-house training centres of skill-oriented
tfpg

MNCs facilitated horizontal spillovers as many


(4)

180
ex-MNC-trained local employees set up local es-

Corrections added on 24 June 2016, after first online publication: the missing columns for Equations: 3-4(b) and IFN have now been added in Table 4.
tablishments such as Unisem, Carsem, and
Globtronics in the same industry (Best and
lnscale
lnIFN
H
B
F
H*IFN
B*IFN
F*IFN

N
ict
tgap

comp
pol
IFN

Rasiah 2003). This is contrary to the findings of


Khalifah et al. (2015), while augmenting the spill-
0.627 + (1.92)
0.500 (0.45)
0.307 (0.86)

0.235 (0.35)
Impact of foreign presence and foreign firms’ characteristics on local firms’ TFPG

0.000580 (0.00)
0.389** (4.65)
0.233** (3.10)

0.0993 (0.26)

0.657** (3.29)

0.0321 (0.91)

0.243* (2.15)
0.0660 (0.56)

over literature whereby accounting for workers’


skills (instead of only wages or capital) may pro-
tfpg
3(b)

180

vide better evidence of productivity spillovers in


the Malaysian manufacturing sector.
Another important observation is the ab-
0.0773 (0.73)

10.31** (3.28)

0.235 (0.35)

0.627 + (1.92)
0.000580 (0.00)
0.389** (4.65)

3.080 (0.28)

0.0904 (0.03)

0.657** (3.29)

0.0321 (0.91)

0.243* (2.15)
0.0660 (0.56)

sence of spillovers through forward linkages in


tfpg
(3)

180

all the four characteristics of interest. This may


be due to MNC’s production of specialised in-
puts being mostly not tailor-made for domestic
Sales (sal)

producers. Apart from being more expensive


F*sal
H
B
F
H*sal

N
B*sal

ict
lnscale
lnsale

tgap

comp
pol

(Khalifah et al. 2015), these specialised parts


are likely to be exported to international mar-
Table 4

kets. In addition, there are also restrictions (such


3.939** (3.06)
5.252** (3.61)

0.0362 (0.10)
0.845** (4.05)
0.577* (2.46)

2.255** (2.62)
0.688 (1.43)
2.821** (2.90)
0.717 + (1.80)

0.0639 + (1.96)

0.179 (1.64)
0.393 (1.06)

as import duties) on local consumption because


TFPG = total factor productivity growth, IFN = international fragmentation network.
tfpg
2(b)

180

Malaysian law states that procuring inputs from


MNCs located in free trade zones is akin to
importing. Therefore, the presence of technol-
0.113 (0.49)
27.23** (3.73)
3.334 (1.06)

3.939** (3.06)

ogy spillovers from MNCs in upstream indus-


0.0362 (0.10)
0.845** (4.05)

0.406 (0.17)
2.821** (2.90)
0.717 + (1.80)

0.0639 + (1.96)

0.179 (1.64)
0.393 (1.06)

tries may not be captured in the model.


Tfpg
(2)

180

Model 2: Impact of local establishments’


characteristics
Skill (skil)

F*skil
lnskil
H
B
F
H*skil
lnscale

B*skil

N
ict
tgap

comp
pol

Results from the second model (Table 5) analyse


local firms’ absorption of technology/produc-
2.702 (1.03)

0.0332 (0.06)
0.454 (0.39)

2.150* (2.23)

tivity spillovers from foreign establishments.


0.377 (1.38)
1.043+ (1.79)
0.327 (1.32)

1.473 (0.80)

0.720 + (1.77)

0.0533 (0.89)

0.214+ (1.77)
0.589 + (1.84)

The specification of Equation 6 suggested that


Tfpg
1(b)

180

local skill-intensive (lnskil) establishments have


**p values < 0.01, *p < 0.05, +p < 0.10.

sufficient ability to improve productivity


growth without forming local linkages with
0.133 (0.47)

8.871 + (1.73)
5.459 (1.31)
0.454 (0.39)

2.150* (2.23)
0.377 (1.38)
1.043+ (1.79)

3.819 (0.23)

0.720 + (1.77)

0.0533 (0.89)

0.214+ (1.77)
0.589 + (1.84)

foreign affiliates. On the contrary, the negative


tfpg
(1)

180

coefficient signs from the interaction terms in


the results for Equations 6 and (6b) indicate
linkage formation with foreign establishments
Techgap (tgap)
Horizontal (H)

may only be relevant for local establishments


Backward (B)
Exports (ex)

competition
Policy (pol)
Forward(F)

that have lesser skills requirements. Low-skilled


Equations:
lnscale

local producers usually require lesser start-up


H*ex
Lnex

B*ex
F*ex

capital, hence the low initial technological base.


ict
N

76

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
KAM — CHANNELS OF PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS IN THE MALAYSIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

0.356 (1.62)

0.282* (2.17)

0.162 (0.58)
0.137 (-1.00)
Therefore, even if MNCs bring in lower or dated

0.307** (4.86)
0.0632 + (1.73)
0.756 (1.00)
0.190 (0.68)

0.0420 (1.39)
1.500** (3.25)

0.0924 (0.83)
0.227* (2.00)
TFPG
technologies (by MNC’s standards), linkage
8(b)

180
formation with foreign establishments has a
significant impact on the TFPG of low-skilled
17.10** (3.31) local producers.

0.137 (1.00)
0.282* (2.17)

0.162 (0.58)
0.0420 (1.39)
0.307** (4.86)
0.0748 (0.95)

2.996* (2.15)
1.815 (1.14)

1.500** (3.25)

0.0924 (0.83)
0.227* (2.00)
Equations (5b) and (8b) show that export and

Corrections added on 24 June 2016, after first online publication: the missing columns for Equations: 5-6(b), Skill and Sales have now been added in Table 5.
TFPG

(8)

180
IFN-oriented local establishments are able to in-
crease productivity even without forming link-
ages with foreign establishments. However, the
F*IFN
lnIFN
H

N
B

H*IFN
B*IFN

tgap
lnscale

ict
pol
comp
impact on local export-oriented establishments
IFN

is much stronger if backward and forward link-


ages are formed with foreign establishments.
0.578 + (1.94)
3.501* (1.99)

0.0804 (0.12)
2.646** (3.13)

0.00163 (0.04)

0.458 (0.67)
0.905** (3.72)

0.643* (2.50)
1.676** (3.18)
1.194 (1.42)

0.305* (2.56)
0.889* (2.13)

Backward linkages are significant because


TFPG

7(b)

180

export-intensive local establishments are more


Impact of foreign presence on local firms’ characteristics and local TFPG

competitive in nature and have sufficient ab-


sorptive capacity to learn management tech-
1.386** (3.94)

25.28** (3.00)
10.25* (2.24)
2.646** (3.13)

0.00163 (0.04)

0.458 (0.67)

niques and production technologies from their


0.905** (3.72)

38.31** (2.69)

0.643* (2.50)
1.676** (3.18)

0.305* (2.56)
0.889* (2.13)

foreign partners. The impact of foreign presence


TFPG

(7)

180

is most prevalent for export-oriented local firms


and least for IFN-oriented local firms.
Equations 7 and (7b) show that local estab-
Sales (sal)

lishments with high sales growth (lnsal) have


lnscale
lnsale
H
B

H*sal
F

B*sal
F*sal

N
tgap

ict
comp
pol

negative productivity regardless of the linkages


with foreign establishments. This can be
Table 5

0.108 (0.78)

0.493 + (1.75)
0.158 (0.45)
0.00442 (0.14)

explained by the mechanics of growth account-


0.196 (0.32)
0.175 (0.67)

1.061 (1.00)

0.0567 (0.24)
0.268** (4.10)
0.124* (2.08)

0.191 + (1.66)
0.0811 (0.72)

ing. If sales is a proxy for output and increases


TFPG

6(b)

180

TFPG = total factor productivity growth, IFN = international fragmentation network.

with a reduction in its residual (TFPG), it means


capital and labour has to increase to offset the
decline in the residual. This implies sales growth
8.835 (0.98)

0.493 + (1.75)
0.158 (0.45)
0.00442 (0.14)
0.319* (2.46)

0.0567 (0.24)
4.372 + (1.82)
0.268** (4.10)

1.238 (0.42)
1.061 (1.00)

0.191 + (1.66)
0.0811 (0.72)

is more input-driven and less productivity-


TFPG

driven, which is more commonly the case in


(6)

180

Malaysian manufacturing sector (Tham 1997;


Kam 2013). Hence, local establishments with
high sales growth may not necessarily allocate
Skill (skil)

tgap

ict
lnskil
H
B
lnscale

comp

N
F
H*skil
B*skil
F*skil

pol

the revenues from sales into technology-


intensive and R&D activities.
Even in the absence of internal vertical link-
2.467 + (1.69)

3.011** (3.69)

0.00340 (0.09)

1.216 (1.64)
3.241 (1.16)
0.717* (2.41)
1.112** (4.83)

0.137 (0.21)

2.066** (4.17)

0.271* (2.28)
0.356+ (1.87)

0.193 (0.49)

ages, external linkages formed through IFNs


TFPG

5(b)

have allowed local establishments to improve


180

**p values < 0.01, *p < 0.05, +p < 0.10.

their productivity through horizontal channels


(for example, learning effects and imitation
effects). Equation (8) suggests that being
0.141 (0.64)

31.38** (3.90)
4.838 (1.49)
3.011** (3.69)

0.00340 (0.09)

1.216 (1.64)
45.39** (3.32)
1.112** (4.83)

2.066** (4.17)
0.356 + (1.87)

0.271* (2.28)
0.193 (0.49)

integrated into the IFN enabled them to source


TFPG

(5)

180

cheaper and higher quality inputs from abroad,


hence assigning internal linkages to a lesser role
in productivity growth. Local establishments
Techgap (tgap)
Horizontal (H)

producing for IFNs are also more competitive


Backward (B)
Forward (F)
Exports (ex)

competition
Policy (pol)

and capable in constantly revising their produc-


Equations:
lnscale

tion techniques to match the needs of the


H*ex
B*ex
F*ex
lnex

network.
ict
N

77

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

In summary, local establishments generally ing for IFNs having the least impact. The
absorb technology from foreign establishments negative sign on the skills coefficient suggests
through horizontal linkages. Therefore, are do- that local linkages formed with MNCs are more
mestic linkages dead? With the proliferation of relevant for less-skilled industries. Firms in host
trade agreements in the region, the focus of local nations should take advantage of the interna-
establishments on forging internal linkages is tional market through IFNs to reduce over-
becoming less important than the international dependency on MNCs for technology transfers.
linkage-creation process. Hence, local establish- As the results suggest, only export-oriented
ments need to increase exporting activities and and market-driven local firms have absorbed
skill-oriented investments and seek new market spillovers from foreign affiliates through vertical
opportunities in order to fully reap the benefits linkages.
of FDI. Existing policies that isolate the domestic
economy from foreign firms and encourage
enclave operations (for example, EPZs) should
be reviewed and restructured to promote
Conclusions and policy implications training and collaboration with local firms.
Support in the form of promoting local
The notion that all foreign firms will automati- suppliers and incentives for MNCs to develop
cally contribute to productivity upgrading of local content should also be welcomed.
local firms is misleading. The findings indicate However, the concept of competition-based
that foreign firms that are export-oriented, assistance should be employed in order to
skill-intensive, and market-driven have different foster a competitive cluster of local firms that
magnitudes of impact on local TFPG through are able to harness the opportunities made
backward linkages—with foreign firms produc- available through the IFNs.

References
Aiken, L. and West, S., 1991. Multiple Regression: testing Harabi, N. M., 1992 ‘Determinants of technical change:
and interpreting interactions, Sage Publications, Inc., empirical evidence from Switzerland’. Empirica, 19
Newbury Park London, New Delhi. (2), 221–44.
Best, M. and Rasiah, R., 2003. Malaysian Electronics at Hummels, D., Ishii, J., and Yi, K. M. 2001‘ The
the Crossroads, United Nations Industrial Develop- nature and growth of vertical specialization in
ment Organization (UNIDO), Vienna. world trade’. Journal of International Economics,
Caves, R.E., 1974. ‘Multinational firms, competition, 54(1), 75–96.
and productivity in host-country markets’, Jabbour, L. and Mucchielli, J.L., 2007. ‘Technology
Economica, 41(162): 176–93. transfer through vertical linkages: the case of the
Coelli, T., Rao, P., O’Donnell, C. and Battese, G., 2005. Spanish manufacturing industry’, Journal of Applied
An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analy- Economics, 10(1): 115–36.
sis, Springer, New York. Javorcik, B. S., 2004‘ Does foreign direct investment
DOS, 2008 Annual survey of manufacturing industries increase the productivity of domestic firms? In
—multiple years 2000 to 2008. search of spillovers through backward linkages’.
Driffield, N. and Noor, A.H., 1999. ‘Foreign direct in- American Economic Review, 94(3), 605–27.
vestment and local input linkages in Malaysia’, Kam, A. J.-Y., 2013,‘ International production net-
Transnational Corporations, 8(3): 1–23. works and host country productivity: evidence
Ghosh, A., 1958. ‘Input–output approach in an alloca- from Malaysia’. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature,
tion system’, Economica, 25(97): 58–64. 27: 127–146. doi: 10.1111/apel.12006.
Giroud, A., and Scott-Kennel, J., 2006 Foreign- Kam, A. J.-Y., 2014‘ Revisiting the productivity growth
local linkages in international business: a re- and spillovers debate: the case of Malaysian
view and extension of the literature. Working manufacturing sector’, Journal of the Asia Pacific
Paper Series No. 06/06 Bradford University School Economy, 19:4, 656–681, doi: 10.1080/13547860.
of Management. 2014.934529

78

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
KAM — CHANNELS OF PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS IN THE MALAYSIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

Khalifah, N.A., Mohd Salleh, S. and Adam, R., 2015. No. 24, Overseas Development Council, John Hop-
‘FDI productivity spillovers and the technology kins University Press: Washington DC.
gap in Malaysia’s electrical and electronic Rodriguez-Clare, A., 1996. ‘Multinationals, Linkages,
industries’, Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 29: and Economic Development’, American Economic
142–160. doi: 10.1111/apel.12094. Review, 86(4): 852–72.
Kokko, A., 1994. ‘Technology, market caharacteristics Schellekens, P., 2009. Malaysia Economic Monitor: reposi-
and spillovers’, Journal of Development Economics: tioning for growth, International Bank for Recon-
279–93. struction and Development / The World Bank,
Leslie, O.B., 1993. ‘Malaysian manufacturing sector Thailand.
linkages’, in K.S. Jomo (ed.), Industrialising Malay- Tham, S.Y., 1997. ‘Determinants of productivity
sia: policy performance and prospect, Routledge, growth in the Malaysian manufacturing sector’,
New York. ASEAN Economic Bulletin: 333–42.
OECD, 2009 OECD investment policy perspectives Truong, T.N.T., Jongwanich, J. and Ramstetter, E.D.,
2008: OECD. 2015. ‘Productivity spillovers from foreign multi-
Olley, G.S. and Pakes, A., 1996. ‘The dynamics of pro- nationals and trade protection: firm-level analysis
ductivity in the telecommunications equipment of Vietnamese manufacturing’, Asian-Pacific Eco-
industry’, Econometrica, 64(6): 1263–97. nomic Literature, 29: 30–46. doi: 10.1111/apel.12117.
Rasmussen, P.N., 1956. Studies in Intersectorial UNCTAD, 2000. Enhancing Competitiveness on SMEs
Relations, North Holland, Amsterdam. Through Linkages: background paper prepared by the
Rodrik, D., 1999. The New Global Economy and Develop- UNCTAD secretariat, UNCTAD, United Nations,
ing Countries: Making Openness Work. Policy Essay, Geneva.

79

© 2016 Crawford School of Public Policy,


The Australian National University and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd

Вам также может понравиться