Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 30

RICHARD T.

ELY LECTURE

Globalization and Its Challenges

By STANLEY FISCHER*

I stand here with deeply con icting emotions. policy economists of our time. In his policy
I am honored to be delivering this prestigious work he displayed the same rare talent as he had
lecture. I am profoundly sad that Rudi Dorn- in his theoretical work, of being able to extract
busch, who should have delivered the Ely Lec- the essence of a complicated problem and ex-
ture, died in July last year and that I am here in plain it in terms that made it seem simple.
his place. So I would like to start by talking Among his policy papers, the most famous is
about Rudi. the 1994 Brookings paper with Alejandro
Rudi was born and grew up in Krefeld, Ger- Werner that predicted the Mexican peso crisis,
many. He was an undergraduate at the Univer- but that is only one of many applied papers that
sity of Geneva and completed his Ph.D. at the repays rereading.
University of Chicago in 1971, which is where As his policy interests grew, Rudi’s fame
we met. He was a student of Robert Mundell, spread. He was an indefatigable global traveler,
and both the subject matter (the development of speaker, and writer, and a frequent columnist. In
the Mundell-Fleming model) and the elegance his more popular articles, in his columns, and on
and insights of his early work re ected Mun- the podium, his wit and the speed of his mind
dell’s in uence. He taught at the University of made him an exciting and formidable presence.
Rochester and at the University of Chicago be- He was one of the Ž nest debaters and polemi-
fore accepting an offer from MIT in 1975. cists in the profession. He was tough and did not
In 1976, soon after coming to MIT, Rudi shy away from stating his views, often in ways
wrote his most famous and in uential theoreti- that re ected the advice of Keynes: “Words
cal article, “Expectations and Exchange Rate ought to be a little wild for they are the assault
Dynamics.” As Ken Rogoff (2002 p. 1) said in of thoughts on the unthinking.” At various times
his celebratory lecture on the 25th anniversary he was persona non grata to the authorities in a
of its publication, “The ‘overshooting’ paper... number of countries; it did not help that more
marks the birth of modern international often than not he was right.
macroeconomics.” Despite his public persona, Rudi was an
From the late 1970’s, Rudi became increas- excellent conŽ dential policy adviser. When I
ingly interested in policy issues. Within a de- was at the IMF, I often called him to discuss
cade, he had become one of the outstanding a difŽ cult situation. His advice was always
thoughtful, typically nuanced, and frequently
provided insights that no one else had seen—
* Citigroup, 399 Park Avenue, New York, NY 10022- and he was willing to talk as long as it took.
4614 (e-mail: Ž schers@citigroup.com). This is a revised Rudi played a central role in the MIT Eco-
version of the Ely Lecture presented at the American Eco- nomics Department. He was a spectacularly
nomic Association meetings in Washington, DC, on 3 January
2003. The Ely Lecture was originally to have been presented
successful teacher, in the classroom, in super-
by Rudi Dornbusch, who died on 25 July 2002. I am grateful vising theses, and through his textbooks. But he
to Andrew Balls, Olivier Blanchard, Vittorio Corbo, Angus did not spoonfeed the students, sometimes po-
Deaton, Peter Diamond, Jaewoo Lee, Prachi Mishra, Chi sitioning himself in front of an unfortunate stu-
Nguyen, Maurice Obstfeld, Ratna Sahay, Lyn Squire, Larry dent, asking a series of questions until he
Summers, and John Williamson, and to my Citigroup col-
leagues, Lewis Alexander, Eric Darwell, and Dana Peterson, extracted an answer. Nonetheless he won many
for their assistance and advice. Views expressed are those of prizes for teaching. Every outstanding Ameri-
the author and not necessarily of Citigroup. can international macroeconomist who has been

1
2 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

to MIT, among them Jeffrey Frankel, Paul The debate is untidy and ill-deŽ ned, and one
Krugman, Maurice Obstfeld, and Ken Rogoff, could react by saying that it has no place in a
was a Rudi student. And there are outstanding professional setting like this one. But we cannot
Rudi students all over the globe, many of them afford to ignore it, for the views and attitudes
here tonight, many of them professional econ- expressed in it will inevitably affect public pol-
omists, some who became Rudi’s co-author on icy—and the issues are critically important for
a paper, many who became policymakers. In the the future economic growth and well-being of
richly deserved devotion of this legion of stu- all the people of the globe.2
dents to their teacher and friend lies the greatest Here is the message: Globalization, the
compliment to his teaching and mentoring. ongoing process of greater interdependence
I had the good fortune and pleasure of among countries and their citizens, is complex
collaborating with Rudi in the writing of two and multifaceted. Many of the problems that the
textbooks and several articles. Our textbook critics of globalization point to are real. Some of
Macroeconomics, which has sold well over a them relate to economics. Others relate to non-
million copies worldwide, has given me as economic, but no less important, aspects of life.
much satisfaction as anything else I have done And while some of the problems do stem from
in my professional life. And I know Rudi felt the process of global integration, others do not.
the same way. As far as economics is concerned, the big
Rudi was a vital and positive personality, challenge is poverty, and the surest route to
who lit up any group in which he participated. sustained poverty reduction is economic growth.
He was among the most talented of men, and Growth requires good economic policies. The
among the warmest, the most generous, with his evidence strongly supports the conclusion that
time and himself, available for his students and growth requires a policy framework that prom-
his friends whenever they needed him. When inently includes an orientation toward integra-
they called or visited, Rudi would say “Tell tion into the global economy. This places
me everything” and then give them his sympa- obligations on three groups: those who are most
thy, his understanding, and his unsentimental responsible for the operation of the international
advice. economy, primarily the governments of the de-
We will miss Rudi deeply, including tonight, veloped countries; those who determine the in-
for his incisive mind, the brilliance of his in- tellectual climate, which includes this audience
sights, the exuberance of his writing, and his but also government and nongovernment orga-
challenges to conventional thinking—but most nizations and individuals; and the governments
of all, for his friendship and the pleasure of his of the developing countries who bear the major
company. responsibility for economic policy in their
countries.
I. The Globalization Debate Let me start by discussing the historical back-
ground, the protagonists, their views, and the
The debate over globalization is lively, often
passionate, and has sometimes been violent. At
least until recently, it has been intensifying.1 through the use of the Google search engine, and typing
in “anti-globalization” brings up 80,000 links. Type in
globalization and inequality, and there are almost 500,000
1
During the 1970’s the word “globalization” was never references; 700,000 references to globalization and environ-
mentioned in the pages of The New York Times. In the 1980’s ment; almost 200,000 links to globalization and labor
the word cropped up less than once a week; in the Ž rst half standards; 50,000 references to globalization and multina-
of the 1990’s, less than twice a week; and in the latter half tionals; and 70,000 references to globalization and cultural
of the decade, no more than three times a week. In 2000 diversity. A search of globalization and the IMF yields
there were 514 stories in the paper that made reference to 180,000 suggestions.
2
“globalization”; there were 364 stories in 2001, and 393 For a comprehensive review of the economic issues,
references in 2002. Based on stories in The New York Times, see the extremely useful paper by François Bourguignon et
the idea of being “anti-globalization” was not one that al. (2002), which covers many of the issues in this lecture
existed before about 1999. Turning from the newspaper to (see also International Monetary Fund, 1997; World Bank,
the internet, “globalization” brings up 1.6 million links 2002a).
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 3

issues. Economic globalization, the ongoing tries (the more developed and larger developing
process of greater economic interdependence countries) increased, the impossible trinity once
among countries, is re ected in the increasing again asserted itself, and in a series of crises,
amount of cross-border trade in goods and ser- country after country was forced to give up its
vices, the increasing volume of international pegged exchange rate and allow the currency to
Ž nancial  ows, and increasing  ows of labor.  oat.
As is well known to our profession, economic By now, the gross volume of international
globalization thrived in the period before 1914, capital  ows relative to global GDP far exceeds
but was set back by the two World Wars and the the levels reached in the period just before
Great Depression.3 The international Ž nancial 1913, though net  ows of foreign direct invest-
order that was established at the end of World ment have not yet attained the extraordinary
War II sought to restore the volume of world levels of the decade before World War I.5
trade, and by 1973, world trade as a percentage It is generally believed that, with respect to
of world GDP was back to its 1913 level, and it migration and labor  ows, the modern system is
has continued to grow almost every year since.4 less globalized than it was a century ago.6 In
While the founders of the Bretton Woods 1911, nearly 15 percent of the United States
system saw the restoration of trade in goods and population was foreign-born; today that number
services as essential to the recovery of the is probably a bit above 10 percent. Emigration
global economy, they did not have the same rates from Europe, especially Ireland and Italy,
benign view of capital  ows. Nonetheless, cap- were amazing: 14 percent of the Irish popula-
ital  ows among the industrialized countries did tion emigrated in the 1880’s, and over 10 per-
recover during the 1950’s, and intensiŽ ed in the cent of the Italian population emigrated in the
1960’s. Rapidly they became too powerful for Ž rst decade of the 20th century. Jeffrey Wil-
the pegged exchange-rate system to survive, liamson (2002) attributes a signiŽ cant part of
and by 1973, as a result of the impossible trinity the convergence of income levels in the Atlantic
(of a pegged exchange rate, capital mobility, economy in the late 19th and early 20th centu-
and a monetary policy directed at domestic ob- ries to mass migration.7 Whether or not migra-
jectives), the Bretton Woods adjustable-peg tion and labor  ows are greater now than they
system had to give way to  exible exchange
rates among the major countries.
Capital  ows to developing countries grew 5
Some suggest that capital markets remain less inte-
more slowly. In the late 1970’s and early 1980’s grated today than in 1913 (e.g., Maurice Obstfeld and Alan
they consisted mainly of bank loans; by the Taylor, 2003).
6
1990’s they took the form mainly of foreign The note of caution is entered because it is not clear
how much labor  ows between developing countries
direct investment and purchases of marketable
(South–South labor  ows) have changed. These took place
securities. As the volume of international capi- on a large scale before 1913, but they are also very large
tal  ows to and from the emerging market coun- today. Timothy J. Hatton and Williamson (2002 p. 25)
comment “South–South migration is not new. It is just
ignored by economists.” What is clear is that immigration
3
Jeffrey Williamson (2002) classiŽ es the period 1820–  ows to and from industrialized countries are lower now
1914 as the Ž rst great globalization era, and the period since than in the decade before World War I (see Williamson,
World War II as the second. 2002). For example, the annual immigration rate to the
4
Trade as a percentage of world GDP is estimated to United States fell from about 11.6 per 1,000 in 1910 to 0.4
have risen from less than 5 percent in 1800 to a peak of just in 1940 and rose to 4 in the 1990’s. The volume of remit-
over 20 percent at the start of World War I, and then tances provides some evidence on labor-market integration.
collapsed to 5 percent at the end of World War II. Between Remittances from overseas workers make labor services a
1947 and the Ž rst oil shock in 1973, world exports grew at major export for many poor countries. The volume of re-
an average annual rate of 8.8 percent per year. Between mittances increased from an annual average of $22 billion in
1973 and 1990 they grew at an annual rate of 4.4 percent; the 1970’s (measured in 1995 dollars) to $81 billion in the
the growth rate in the 1990’s was 7 percent. As a result, the 1990’s, which is more than the annual volume of aid (Clau-
world’s markets for goods and services are more integrated dia Busch et al., 2002).
7
than ever before, though the pattern is different, with a rise In his work, Jeffrey Williamson frequently uses the
in intra-industry trade, compared with the predominance of convergence of prices, rather than the volume of trade, as an
inter-industry trade in the earlier period of globalization. indicator of the extent of globalization.
4 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

were a century ago, we are becoming more improvements in communications and the spread
globalized in this regard too, for migration rates of information were critical to the collapse of
have been rising—and in a potentially impor- the Iron Curtain. People learned what was hap-
tant way, for more migration than in the past pening in other countries and understood that
is from less-developed to more-developed they did not have to live the way they were
countries.8 living, and the Iron Curtain fell.
All this is at an abstract level. In terms of While we need to recognize the importance,
people’s daily lives, globalization means that and possibly the predominance, of the noneco-
the residents of one country are more likely now nomic elements, I shall focus on the economic
than they were 50 years ago to consume the debate. One set of views on economic global-
products of another country, to invest in another ization is summed up by a characteristic passage
country, to earn income from other countries, to from Rudi Dornbusch (2000 p. 91):
talk on the telephone to people in other coun-
tries, to visit other countries, to know that they On the verge of world de ation, Japan
are being affected by economic developments bankrupt and Europe moving at near-
in other countries, and to know about develop- stalling speed only, the emerging markets
ments in other countries. battered and the United States beholding a
Globalization is much more than an eco- glorious bubble—how can this mark the
nomic phenomenon. The technological and end of a great century of prosperity? And
yet, this has been the best century ever,
political changes that drive the process of
never mind the great depression, a mo-
economic globalization have massive noneco- mentary setback from communism and
nomic consequences.9 In the words of Anthony socialism, and two great wars. Mankind
Giddens (2002 p. 10), a leading sociologist: today is far and further ahead of where it
“I would have no hesitation ... in saying that has ever been and there are the seeds of
globalisation, as we are experiencing it, is in innovation from biology to the Internet
many respects not only new, but also revolu- for better and richer lives even beyond
tionary.... Globalisation is political, technologi- our wildest dreams.
cal and cultural, as well as economic.”
The noneconomic aspects are at least as im- This century, and in particular the last
portant in shaping the international debate as are three decades, have witnessed just that as
the economic aspects. Many of those who ob- the nation state has been dismantled in
ject to globalization resent the political and mil- favor of a global economy, state enter-
itary dominance of the United States, and they prise and economic repression give way
resent also the in uence of foreign (predomi- to free enterprise, and breathtaking inno-
vation and greedy capitalism break down
nantly American) culture, as they see it at the government and corporate bureaucracies.
expense of national and local cultures. Anyone who says impossible Ž nds him-
The technological elements matter in practice self interrupted by someone who just did
as well as in the debate. For instance, the events it. The process is far from complete; in-
of 11 September 2001 could not have taken novation and free enterprise spread the
place before the current global era. The com- mindset, the success and the acceptance
munications and transport systems that have of this model to the horror of status quo
accelerated the pace of globalization are also at politicians and the sheer exuberance of all
the disposal of terrorists, money-launderers, and those who are willing to embrace a can-do
international criminals. On the positive side, attitude. If this century taught anything it
is surely this: even daunting setbacks like
depression and war are only momentary
8 tragedies—buying opportunities, if you
The fact that migration often has a brain-drain aspect
raises important issues.
like—in a relentless advance of the stan-
9
The rapid increases in global integration in the second dard of living and the scope for enjoying
half of the 19th century and early 20th century were driven better lives. One of the great economists
by the outbreak of peace in Europe and the invention of the of this century, Joseph Schumpeter—
telegraph, the steamship, and the railroad. Austrian Ž nance minister of the 1920s
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 5

and Harvard professor at the end—wrote other economic issues that feature in the debate
of creative destruction as the dramatic over globalization and its consequences, among
mechanism of economic progress. That them: whether globalization results in unfair
process is at work. labor practices in developing countries—an ar-
gument which is not compelling; whether glob-
A broad range of critics is arrayed on the other alization damages the environment; whether
side. Among them are academics, opinion lead- multinational corporations have become too pow-
ers, individuals and groups who see their inter- erful to the detriment of developing-country citi-
ests being affected by globalization, politicians, zens and governments; whether globalization
NGO’s, and demonstrators—and these categories gives rise to tax competition that undermines
are not mutually exclusive.10 To listen to the the capacity of governments to raise revenues
debate in the terms each side paints the other, and thus to provide necessary services to their
one might think that it is a discussion between citizens; whether intellectual-property protec-
Dr. Pangloss, who believes that all is for the tion is damaging the health of developing-
best in the best of all possible worlds, and those country citizens; and the roles of the World
who believe that the world is going to hell in a Bank and the World Trade Organization. These
handbasket. That is doubly misleading. In the Ž rst are important issues, some of them critical, and
place, many of those who regard themselves as some do not have simple answers. But these
pro-globalization, myself among them, know problems are being seriously analyzed by econ-
that there is far too much misery in the world, omists, for instance by Bourguignon et al.
that there are many wrongs to be righted in the (2002) for the European Commission, by the
global economy, and that it could be made to World Bank (2002a), and others.12
operate much better. And on the other side, One question before turning to the evidence:
many (but not all) of the critics are not against Almost everyone recognizes that the world
globalization. Rather, from NGO’s demonstrat- could be a better place, and that there is much
ing for further debt relief and campaigning for work to be done to improve it. Why then is so
greater access of developing-country exports to much of the debate about whether the world is
industrialized-countrymarkets, to academic critics getting better or worse, rather than about what
questioning current policy views, many are seek- can be done to make it a better place? It is
ing a better and fairer globalization. because the debate is ultimately about policies.
I will discuss Ž ve of the key economic issues The implicit premise is that if the world is going
in the debate:11 to hell, then the policies that have been followed
for the past 50 years are likely to be wrong. And
(i) whether poverty and inequality are in- if the world has been getting better, then the
creasing or decreasing; policies are more likely to be right.13 It is a
(ii) whether integration into the global econ- separate question whether it is globalization that
omy is good for growth; is responsible for what has happened.
(iii) whether the international Ž nancial system The policies in dispute are generally those
is too crisis prone, and capital  ows need that have been recommended by the international
to be banned or regulated; Ž nancial institutions and most industrialized-
(iv) the unfairness of the global trading system, country governments.14 At the broadest level,
and the inadequacy of aid  ows;
(v) the role of the IMF.
12
For references to the literature, see Bourguignon et al.
For want of time, but also for lack of com- (2002); on the trade-related issues, see also Jagdish Bhag-
parative advantage, I will not cover a host of wati (2000).
13
While persuasive, the implicit proposition is not
logically compelling, for policies could be wrong even if
10
For a discussion of the anti-globalization groups and the world is improving, and right even if the world is
their concerns, see Kimberly Ann Elliott et al. (2003). deteriorating.
11 14
See the discussion of the 12 charges against global- In that regard, the present discussion is merely the
ization in the Ž nal chapter of Bourguignon et al. (2002). latest manifestation of a long-running economic policy
6 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

the policy consensus consists of four elements: world situation confronting policymakers, I still
policies to ensure macroeconomic stability; regard these ten elements as a useful shorthand
market-oriented microeconomic policies; inte- description of a major part of a desirable basic
gration into the global economy, particularly on policy orientation.17 And for that reason I shall at
the trade side; and a positive role for govern- least for a while continue to use the term “Wash-
ment in establishing, monitoring, and develop- ington consensus.”
ing the institutional framework of the economy,
providing public goods including especially so- II. The Evidence on Poverty
cial expenditures, and conducting stabilization and Global Inequality
policies.
Beyond these broad headings, detailed policy A. Poverty
recommendations have been spelled out in
many World Bank and IMF publications, for For some time it was accepted that the pro-
instance the World Development Reports of the portion of people living in poverty in the world
World Bank.15 One formulation that has re- has been declining, but their absolute number
ceived much attention and a large share of cal- has been increasing. This refers to the World
umny is the so-called Washington consensus set Bank’s measure of absolute poverty, deŽ ned as
out by John Williamson (1990).16 The ten ele- living on a real income of less than one dollar
ments of the 1990 consensus were (i) Ž scal a day.18 There is no consistent fully reliable set
discipline, (ii) public-expenditure priorities in of data re ecting longer-term developments in
education and health, (iii) tax reform (the tax poverty.19 A useful estimate of post-World War
base should be broad, and marginal tax rates II developments is shown in Figure 1: the global
should be moderate), (iv) positive but moder- poverty rate is estimated to have declined im-
ate market-determined interest rates, (v) a com- pressively from about 55 percent in 1950 to
petitive exchange rate as the “Ž rst essential 23.7 percent in 1992.20 It has continued falling
element of an ‘outward-oriented’ economic pol- since.
icy” (p. 14), (vi) import liberalization, (vii) The data most often used in discussing recent
openness to foreign direct investment (but “lib- poverty developments come from the World
eralization of foreign Ž nancial  ows is not re- Bank and are based on national estimates of
garded as a high priority” [p. 15]), (viii) poverty rates. These estimates are likely to be
privatization (based on “the belief that private subject to signiŽ cant error, as the recent debate
industry is managed more efŽ ciently than state over the Indian poverty data illustrates. Indian
enterprises” [p. 16]), (ix) deregulation, and (x) growth in the 1990’s averaged nearly 6 percent,
protection of property rights. more than 3 percent per capita. Aggregate con-
The Washington consensus is a brand name sumption in the national income accounts rose
that has been so abused as probably to have by 3.2 percent per capita. But household survey
outlived its usefulness. While no short descrip- data, on which India’s poverty estimates are
tion of the economic policy choices that face a
country and of the principles that it should follow 17
I was one of the discussants of the Williamson (1990)
can be adequate to the complexities of the real- paper at the time (my comments are on pp. 25–28) and
mentioned among the missing elements the responsibility of
the government to create an enabling environment for eco-
debate that has at times pitted protectionists against free- nomic activity, the need for directed anti-poverty policies,
traders and those who believe in a greater role for the state and environmental concerns.
18
against those who believe more in markets. Strictly speaking, the $1 per day Ž gure corresponds to
15
See David Lindauer and Lant Pritchett (2002) for an a Penn World Tables Purchasing Power Parity income of
account of changing views of development policy during about $1.08 in 1993 prices (Shaohua Chen and Martin
the post-World War II period. Ravallion, 2001).
16 19
These were not necessarily John Williamson’s views, I am particularly grateful to Angus Deaton for guiding
but rather his attempt to capture the consensus of the time. me through the debate on the poverty data. He bears no
In the article, he expands on the range of views (including responsibility for the views set out in this section.
20
his own, which generally include several qualiŽ cations) These data are from Bourguinon and Christian Mor-
under each heading. risson (2002).
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 7

FIGURE 1. GLOBAL POVERTY RATES: PERCENTAGE OF PEOPLE LIVING ON LESS THAN $1 PER DAY
Source: Bourguignon and Morrisson (2002).

based, showed very little increase in per capita Applying the Bhalla procedure to all coun-
consumption.21 tries also produces rapid declines in global pov-
Based on the sample surveys, poverty de- erty.23 More cautiously, recent World Bank data
clined relatively little in India in the 1990’s. show the global poverty rate declining sharply
Based on the national income accounts, it from 29.6 percent in 1990 to 23.2 percent in
should have declined signiŽ cantly. One way of 1999 (Table 1).24 According to these estimates
combining the data, chosen by Surjit Bhalla (and they are only estimates), the absolute num-
(2002), is to assume that the distribution of ber of the poor declined by 123 million people,
consumption in the sample surveys is correct, or 10 percent, during this period. The number of
but to adjust the mean increase in consumption poor in China alone fell by 150 million. Table
in the sample surveys to equal that in the na- 1 shows that the major decline in the global
tional income accounts. This produces spectac- poverty rate is accounted for by Asia, with the
ular declines in poverty in India during the absolute number of poor in sub-Saharan Africa
1990’s.
The ofŽ cial data also show signiŽ cant, but
smaller, declines in the Indian poverty rate, neither is there any evidence that the pro-market reforms led
from about 40 percent in 1987–1988 to 26 per- to increases in poverty or slowed poverty reduction.
cent in 1999–2000. In checking these data, 23
Bhalla’s (2002) estimates are that poverty was 30
Deaton (2002a) reports, “Much to my surprise, percent in 1987, and only 13 percent in 2000. This would
most of the ofŽ cially claimed reduction in pov- imply that the last decade of the last century was the most
successful in all of history in reducing poverty. Xavier
erty appears to be real.”22 Sala-i-Martin (2002b) shows even larger declines in global
poverty counts over the period 1970–1998, using a similar
methodology. He estimates the $1 per day poverty rate to be
only 5 percent in 1998.
21 24
Angus Deaton (2002a) provides a brief description of Surprisingly, the heading on a table very similar to
the problem. Table 1 (table 1.2, p. 18) in the United Nations Develop-
22
Deaton, whose work is regarded as authoritative, es- ment Program’s (2002) Human Development Report is:
timates the poverty rate for 2000 to be 28 percent; he Ž nds “Worldwide, the number of people living on less than $1 a
that the poverty rate in India declined fairly steadily over the day barely changed in the 1990s.” The table shows that even
past 20–30 years, with no evidence of a pickup following the absolute number of those living on less than $1 a day
the reforms in 1991. But he notes (Deaton, 2002a) that declined by 10 percent in the 1990’s.
8 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

TABLE 1—REGIONAL BREAKDOWN OF POVERTY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Number of people living on $1 per day


less than $1 per day headcount index
(millions) (percent)
Region 1987 1990 1999 1987 1990 1999
East Asia and PaciŽ c, 418 486 279 26.6 30.5 15.6
excluding China 114 110 57 23.9 24.2 10.6
Europe and Central 1 6 24 0.2 1.4 5.1
Asia
Latin American and 64 48 57 15.3 11.0 11.1
the Caribbean
Middle East and 9 5 6 4.3 2.1 2.2
North Africa
South Asia 474 506 488 44.9 45.0 36.6
Sub-Saharan Africa 217 241 315 46.6 47.4 49.0
Total: 1,183 1,292 1,169 28.3 29.6 23.2
Excluding China: 880 917 945 28.5 28.5 25.0

Source: World Bank staff estimates (Global Economic Prospects 2003).

(and also in the transition economies) rising risen in all regions in the last 25 years, and
signiŽ cantly. infant mortality has declined signiŽ cantly. Life
Between them, China and India account for expectancy has risen in most regions. However,
38 percent of the world’s population. In 1990 under the impact of the HIV/AIDS pandemic,
they accounted for 60 percent of the world’s it has begun to decline in sub-Saharan Africa,
poor. It is therefore hardly surprising that the with particularly large and tragic impact in
global poverty rate fell sharply in a decade in Botswana, Zimbabwe, South Africa, and
which China grew at more than 9 percent and Kenya.27
India at 6 percent. It may be argued that what The Human Development Report presents a
happened in China and India is atypical. That is Human Development Index (HDI), which is
true if the unit is the country, but not if the unit based on three equally weighted factors, life
is the individual.25 Further, there can be little expectancy, education, and (the logarithm of) a
doubt that, in both India and China, the growth purchasing-power-parity estimate of per capita
policy during the period was pro-globalization, GDP.28 Figure 3 shows changes in the HDI over
pro-entry into the global economy. Of course, the past 20 years. Note in particular that the
not every detail of policy in either country fol- HDI is inherently an index of relative perfor-
lowed the Washington consensus, but both mance, so that the improvements in all regions
countries grew faster after opening up.26 represent a convergence of this more general
Beyond the data on per capita income, most measure of economic and social progress across
social indicators have also shown considerable regions.
improvement in the postwar period and more In addition, as the 2002 Human Development
recently. As Figure 2 (taken from the United Report shows, democracy has been spreading,
Nations Development Program’s [2002] Human including in the developing world. By one clas-
Development Report) shows, adult literacy has

27
Life expectancy is estimated by applying current age-
25
The sharp differences in poverty rates among Indian speciŽ c mortality rates; it thus is not the life expectancy of
states and among Chinese provinces should also contain an individual born today, for which it would be necessary to
policy-relevant information. forecast mortality.
26 28
However, Deaton (2002b) Ž nds no acceleration in the All measures are taken relative to the highest level
rate of poverty reduction following India’s policy reforms in attained within the sample, so the index is bounded above
1991. by 1.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 9

FIGURE 2. ALTERNATIVE INDICATORS OF HUMAN DEVELOPMENT


Notes: Regions are abbreviated as follows: LHD, low human development; SSA, sub-Saharan Africa; AS, Arab states; SA,
south Asia; EA, east Asia and the PaciŽ c; LA, Latin America and the Caribbean; CEE, central and eastern Europe and CIS;
OECD, high-income OECD.
Source: United Nations Development Program’s (2002) Human Development Report.

siŽ cation, the number of authoritarian regimes The discussion of trends in global poverty is
declined from 67 to 26 between 1985 and 2000 a signiŽ cant part of the globalization debate.
(hardly surprising given the transition in the But it does not directly address the globalization
former Soviet bloc and the changes in Latin issue, of whether whatever has been happening
America) while the number of nations catego- is caused by increasing integration into the global
rized as “most democratic” rose from 44 to 82 economy. That question will be addressed when I
(United Nations Development Program, 2002 discuss the impact of openness on growth.
[Ž g. 1.1]).
Thus there is considerable evidence that on B. Inequality
average conditions have been improving in the
developing countries. That is to say, the world is While a global Rawlsian perspective would
not going to hell in a handbasket. But that is lead to a focus on poverty reduction, we need to
emphatically not to say that everyone in the focus also on inequality, not only because for
developing countries is doing better. In partic- many great inequality is undesirable per se, but
ular, conditions in most of sub-Saharan Africa, also because growing inequality may have pow-
where per capita growth has been negative in erful political consequences. For instance, in the
nearly half the countries in the last quarter cen- Ž rst era of globalization, changes in the income
tury, have been deteriorating, and Latin Amer- distribution that affected real wages and the
ica has not done well in the last decade. returns to land and capital led to pressure to
10 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

inequality among country average incomes


would eventually decline—but that could take a
very long time. The weight of the evidence
appears now to have moved away from the
initial conclusion of conditional convergence
toward the twin-peaks view, that there is a con-
vergence club among the high-income OECD
countries, while lower-income countries are
converging to a lower income level (Danny T.
Quah, 1996).
Developments in inequality within countries
may be politically more important than changes
in inequality among countries. There was a rise
FIGURE 3. RECENT TRENDS IN THE HUMAN DEVELOPMENT in inequality in the United States and the United
INDEX (HDI), SHOWING G LOBAL DISPARITIES Kingdom from the start of the 1980’s until well
Notes: Regions are abbreviated as follows: SA, South Asia; into the last decade. Inequality during that pe-
SSA, sub-Saharan Africa; AS, Arab States; DC, all devel- riod did not increase markedly in continental
oping countries; EA, east Asia and the PaciŽ c; LA, Latin Europe, probably due to labor-market regula-
America and the Caribbean; CEE, central and eastern Eu-
rope and CIS; OECD, high-income OECD. tions, social welfare programs, and tax sys-
Source: United Nations Development Program’s Human tems.30 Reviewing the literature, Lawrence F.
Development Report ofŽ ce calculations based on indicator Katz and David H. Autor (1999) concluded that
table 2. trade explains at most 20 percent of the rise in
inequality in the United States and that skill-
limit economic integration (Jeffrey Williamson, biased technological change explains 80 percent
2002). That could happen again, as globaliza- of the rise.31 There are also instances of increas-
tion creates losers as well as winners in the short ing inequality within some poor countries, in-
run.29 cluding China and India, even though incomes
Inequality among national average incomes have increased at both the top and the bottom of
appears to have been increasing for at least 400 the scale. In the transition economies of the
years, since before the rapid increases in eco- former Soviet bloc, inequality increased sharply
nomic integration that took place in the 19th in the 1990’s.
century (Jeffrey Williamson, 2002). However, Beyond the inequalities among national av-
this long-term rise in inequality among national erage incomes, and within countries, stands the
average incomes seems to have slowed during concept of the distribution of global income
the past 20 years (see Bourguignon and Morris- among all the world’s people, of which there
son, 2002; Sala-i-Martin, 2002a, b). are now several estimates (e.g., Bhalla, 2002;
The convergence debate in macroeconomics Bourguignon and Morrisson, 2002; Milanovic,
was based on purchasing-power-parity esti- 2002a; Sala-i-Martin, 2002). These are all based
mates of national average incomes. As is well on data on the distribution of income within
known, and as Figure 4 illustrates, the raw data nations, and some method (typically using pur-
on country average incomes show divergence, chasing power estimates) for comparing income
not convergence. The early results, for instance levels across countries. Figure 5 shows why
those of Robert J. Barro (1997), supported con- such an estimate might Ž nd inequality declining
ditional convergence. Provided the conditioning
variables do not change in an offsetting direc-
tion, conditional convergence implies that the 30
They may well instead have produced higher
unemployment.
31
Kenneth Scheve and Matthew Slaughter (2001) em-
phasize what they call the “skills-preferences cleavage” on
29
See Branko Milanovic (2002b) for a forceful state- globalization among the American public, in which views
ment of the view that current trends are likely to produce a on globalization are signiŽ cantly affected by the skill level
backlash unless globalization as we know it is tamed. of poll respondents.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 11

FIGURE 4. AVERAGE ANNUAL GROWTH (1980–2000) ON INITIAL LEVEL


OF R EAL GDP PER CAPITA

Note: The data are values for real GDP in U.S. dollars per equivalent adult.
Source: Penn World Tables, version 6.1 (available online: http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ ).

among nations: it is the graphic representation  ected in the HDI, presents a more encouraging
of a population-weighted convergence diagram, picture of the changing fortunes of the poorest,
in which the dominance of China and India but the HIV-AIDS epidemic is taking a sad toll
drives the relationship. Bourguignon and Mor- on longevity in Africa.
risson (2002) conclude that the inequality of Income-distribution developments are more
global income worsened from the start of the mixed. There has been a growing divergence
19th century until the end of World War II “and among national average incomes. Inequality has
after that seems to have stabilized or to have risen within many countries; but it is likely that
grown more slowly.”32 inequality among the world’s citizens declined
Where does that leave us on both poverty and during the last decades of the 20th century.
the global distribution of income? Poverty rates However, we should not take too much comfort
have been declining, especially in Asia. So very from that, for as Sala-i-Martin (2002a) points
likely has the absolute number of those living at out, “Unless Africa starts growing in the near
below one dollar a day. Increasingly, global future, ... income inequalities will start rising
poverty is being concentrated in Africa. At the again.”
same time, poverty rates have not declined
much in Latin America in recent decades. Tak- III. The Policy Issues
ing account of other social indicators, as re-
A. Trade and Growth

32 Trade policy has long been central to eco-


However, Milanovic (2002a) Ž nds that global income
inequality increased between 1988 and 1993, in part be- nomic policy choices. In the early post-World
cause of growing gaps between rural and urban incomes in War II period, the theory of import-substituting
China. By contrast, Bhalla (2002) shows world inequality in industrialization (ISI) dominated among devel-
2002 at its lowest level in the post-World War II period, a oping countries, and its implementation for
result of the much greater reductions in global poverty in the
1990’s that his methodology produces. Similarly, Sala-i-
some time seemed to produce positive results.
Martin (2002a) Ž nds massive decreases in global inequality Then, as time went by, it was observed both that
at the individual level between 1980 and 1998. countries that had pursued export promotion
12 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

FIGURE 5. AVERAGE ANNUAL GROWTH (1980–2000) ON INITIAL LEVEL OF REAL GDP PER
CAPITA (AS IN FIG. 4, BUT WITH AREA PROPORTIONAL TO POPULATION IN 1980)
Note: The data are values for real GDP in U.S. dollars per equivalent adult.
Source: Penn World Tables, version 6.1 (available online: http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ ).

strategies were more successful than those that (1995) which concludes that, ceteris paribus,
had focused on keeping imports out and that the open countries grow 2 percent per annum more
returns to ISI seemed to be diminishing. rapidly than closed countries, has received par-
Early case studies of trade liberalization were ticular attention. A closely related literature ex-
conducted in the 1970’s and 1980’s under the amines the mechanisms through which openness
auspices of the OECD, the National Bureau of contributes to growth, particularly through its
Economic Research (NBER), and later the impact on productivity, where the availability of
World Bank.33 These by and large supported the imported inputs plays a role.36
case for export promotion policies, that is, for The regression studies have been comprehen-
integration into the global economy. Subse- sively reexamined and criticized by Francisco
quently a host of cross-sectional regression Rodriguez and Dani Rodrik (2001), who argue
studies were undertaken,34 most of them show- that the results are not robust, the measures of
ing that greater openness is associated either with openness used in the studies neither clearly ex-
higher levels of income or more rapid growth.35 ogenous nor consistent across studies, and the
The study by Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner econometrics  awed.37 Nonetheless, the case
studies that show trade liberalization as an es-
sential element in policy reforms that led to
33
The NBER studies are summarized in Bhagwati growth, the bulk of the empirical evidence, and
(1978) and Anne Krueger (1978); the World Bank studies
are summarized in Michael Michaely et al. (1991).
the fact that the most spectacular growth stories
34
T. N. Srinivasan and Bhagwati (1999) criticize the all involve rapid increases in both exports and
regression approach in arguing for the superiority of the imports (frequently after speciŽ c policy deci-
case-study method. I have used both methods on different
occasions and regard each as having important weaknesses
36
(see also Krueger, 1983). The literature on openness and growth is well sum-
35
Examples include David Dollar (1992), Dan Ben- marized by Bourguignon et al. (2002 pp. 37–39) and by
David (1993), Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner (1995), Andrew Berg and Krueger (2003).
37
Sebastian Edwards (1998), Jeffrey Frankel and David Ro- Warner’s (2001) draft response to the Rodriguez-
mer (1999), and Dollar and Aart Kraay (2001a, b). Robert Rodrik critique strongly disputes several of these criticisms,
E. Hall and Charles Jones (1999) include both openness (the including the suggestion that the black-market premium is
Sachs-Warner index) and a measure of good governance, not a useful indicator of trade distortions, and reafŽ rms the
which is highly correlated with the openness indicator. Sachs-Warner conclusions.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 13

sions have been made to open up) should per- has been fastest where economic growth has
suade us that openness to the global economy been fastest (in developing Asia) and slowest
is a necessary, though not sufŽ cient, condition where growth performance has been worst (in
for sustained growth.38 To quote Dani Rodrik Africa).
(2001 p. 23), “No country has developed suc- Nor, despite the early results of Simon
cessfully by turning its back on international Kuznets, does there appear to be any inevitable
trade and long-term capital  ows.” association between growth and inequality;
To say that is not to say that immediate full rather, it depends on the details of the policies,
trade liberalization is necessarily the best policy including distributional policies, that accompany
for a country, nor that opening to trade is suf- the growth strategy.41 In two related studies,
Ž cient for growth, nor that the accompanying Dollar and Kraay (2001a, b) conclude, based on
policy framework is irrelevant.39 Indeed the data from 92 countries, that on average the
accompanying framework is essential. It is to say, income of the lowest Ž fth of the income distri-
however, that countries that want to grow should bution rises one-for-one with aggregate income,
as a key part of their policy framework orient and that this same relationship holds for growth
themselves toward integration into the global that is induced by trade liberalization.
trading system, to take advantage of the avail- To say that, on average, growth or opening to
ability both of much larger global than domes- trade does not adversely affect the incomes
tic markets, and of more sophisticated capital-, of the poor is not to say that the impact of
intermediate-, and consumer-good imports.40 policy changes on income distribution should
be ignored when any particular policy change is
B. Growth, Poverty, and Inequality being considered. The opening of trade is de-
signed to affect domestic relative prices and
Here I can be brief. Logic dictates that there most likely will affect the distribution of income
is no way of lifting the populations of poor in each case.42 If these effects are judged to be
countries out of poverty (say, on the scale that adverse, transitional compensatory measures
has been achieved in East Asia) without sus- and gradual liberalization may help mitigate
tained growth. Globally, the decline in poverty them (see Scheve and Slaughter, 2001 pp. 94 –
96). It is also the case that a small economy
38 tends to be more vulnerable to  uctuations in
Rodrik (2001 p. 23) does not disagree with this con-
clusion, emphasizing rather the speed of adjustment and the the terms of trade when it is open than when it
need for accompanying policies: “The trick in the successful is closed, and that the poor may be the most
cases has been to combine the opportunities offered by vulnerable in this regard.43
world markets with a domestic investment and institution-
building strategy to stimulate the animal spirits of domestic
C. Capital-Account Liberalization
entrepreneurs. Almost all of the outstanding cases—East
Asia, China, India since the early 1980s—involve partial
and gradual opening up to imports and foreign investment.” There is far more controversy about capital-
39
Berg and Krueger (2003 p. 39) state, “Openness has account liberalization as part of a growth
important positive spillovers on other aspects of reform, so strategy than there is about current-account lib-
the correlation of trade with other pro-reform policies
speaks to the advantages of making openness a primary part
eralization. That is not surprising, for as the
of the reform package.” This relates to an emerging litera-
ture (e.g., Dollar and Kraay, 2002; William Easterly and
41
Ross Levine, 2002) that argues either that the growth effects Barro (1999) states that the Kuznets curve does
of openness and the institutional structure of the economy emerge as a clear empirical regularity but does not explain
are difŽ cult to distinguish, or that institutions are more most of the variations of inequality across countries or over
important. I Ž nd the Berg-Krueger argument on this point time.
42
persuasive. Mattias Lundberg and Lyn Squire (1999) Ž nd that growth
40
Nancy Birdsall (2002) argues that openness does not is more sensitive than inequality to policy interventions.
43
work well for the poorest countries, because of their greater There is no general prescription for what these policies
dependence on primary exports and because of their greater should be; they need to be designed taking the circum-
vulnerability to external shocks. It is nonetheless difŽ cult to stances of the country into account; for instance, in the
see how a small economy could hope to reach a high level Indonesian crisis of 1997–1998, subsidizing the price of rice
of income without integrating into the global economy. was a key pro-poor policy.
14 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

Asian crisis drove home, a country with an open atic in this case, for as Hali Edison et al. (2002b)
capital account is more vulnerable to external note, successful economies are generally open
shocks than one that is closed to external capital economies.
 ows. The relationship between capital-account lib-
In considering capital-account liberalization, eralization and growth is likely to be inherently
I assume that countries will and should at some weaker than that between current account liber-
stage in the course of their development want to alization and growth, since it is more dependent
liberalize the capital account and integrate into on the sequencing of reforms, and the presence
global capital markets. This view is based in of preconditions (e.g., a strong macroeconomic
part on the fact that the most advanced econo- framework) than is the current-account liberal-
mies all have open capital accounts; it is also ization relationship. An interesting Ž nding in
based on the conclusion that the potential ben- this regard is that of Carlos Arteta et al. (2001),
eŽ ts of well-phased and well-sequenced inte- who conclude that capital-account openness has
gration into the global capital markets (and this a positive impact on growth contingent on the
includes the beneŽ ts obtained by allowing for- absence of a large black-market premium—
eign competition in the Ž nancial sector) out- which is a good idicator of the absence of mac-
weigh the costs.44,45 roeconomic imbalances.
With regard to empirical evidence on the At present most developing countries main-
beneŽ ts of capital-account liberalization, I tain capital controls. Experience suggests they
believe we are roughly now where we were should only be removed gradually, at a time
in the 1980’s on current-account liberaliza- when the exchange rate is not under pressure,47
tion—that some evidence is coming in, but and as the necessary infrastructure (in the form
that it is at this stage weak and disputed.46 The of strong domestic Ž nancial institutions, a
direction of causation is particularly problem- sound macroeconomic framework, a market-
based monetary policy, the underpinnings of an
effective foreign-exchange market, and the in-
44
The argument is developed at greater length in Fischer formation base necessary for the markets to
(1998). The point has been much disputed, including by operate efŽ ciently) is put in place.48 For most
Bhagwati (1998).
45
countries, it would be desirable to begin allow-
It is also based on the views that in practice capital ing some  exibility of exchange rates as the
controls are often discriminatory, a standing invitation to
corruption, and grow progressively less effective over time. controls are eased, unless the country intends to
46
Rodrik (1998) presents a critical view of capital- move to a hard peg—and after Argentina, that
account liberalization. A set of papers presented at a May does not look advisable, unless there is a clearly
2002 World Bank conference “Financial Globalization: deŽ ned terminal condition.49 Prudential controls
A Blessing or a Curse?” (available online: http://www.
worldbank.org/research/conferences/Ž nancial_globalization.
htm ) on balance pointed to small positive impacts of Ž nan-
47
cial liberalization on growth (see e.g., Geert Bekaert et al. The removal of controls on out ows sometimes re-
(2002), Anusha Chari and Peter B. Henry (2002), Arturo sults in a capital in ow, a result of foreigners or domestic
Galindo et al. (2002), Pierre Gourinchas and Olivier Jeanne residents bringing capital into the country in light of the
(2002), and Carmen Reinhart and Ioannis Tokatlidis (2002). greater assurance it can be removed when desired.
48
Hali Edison et al. (2002a) review the literature on the Some countries have attempted to impose controls on
relationship between growth and capital-account liberaliza- out ows once a foreign-exchange crisis is already under
tion. They Ž nd that capital-account liberalization spurs way. This use of controls has generally been ineffective (see
growth signiŽ cantly in a middle-income range of countries, Akira Ariyoshi et al., 2000 pp. 18 –29; Edwards, 1999 pp.
but not for rich or poor countries. However, in a study of 57 68 –71). It has also to be considered that the imposition of
countries, using a wide array of measures of international controls for this purpose in a crisis is likely to have a
Ž nancial integration and an assortment of statistical meth- longer-term effect on the country’s access to international
ods, Edison et al. (2002b) are unable to establish a relation- capital. For the record, I should note here that there is very
ship between greater international Ž nancial integration and little information about such use of controls in the Malay-
faster economic growth. They do identify indirect effects, sian case of 1998, for the controls were imposed when
by Ž nding a signiŽ cant impact from capital-account liber- exchange rates in the region were at their most depreciated,
alization on investment and Ž nancial development; these and as capital  ows in all the crisis countries were reversing.
49
two channels are estimated to increase growth by 0.5 per- For instance, that the country plans to join the Euro-
cent per year or more. pean Monetary Union and give up its currency.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 15

that have a similar effect to some capital con- country is trying to reduce in ation using an
trols, for instance, limits on the open foreign- exchange-rate anchor and, for anti-in ationary
exchange positions that domestic institutions purposes, needs interest rates higher than
can take, should also be put in place as direct those implied by the sum of the foreign inter-
controls are removed.50 est rate and the expected rate of currency
Any country using capital controls builds up depreciation. A tax on capital in ows can
an information system on capital  ows. It may help maintain a wedge between the two inter-
be useful to maintain an information base for est rates. In addition, by taxing short-term
some time even after the removal of controls, as capital in ows more than longer-term in-
in the Brazilian case, for such information can  ows, capital-in ow controls can also in prin-
be useful in managing a crisis. ciple in uence the composition of in ows.
Several countries, among them Singapore, Evidence from the Chilean experience
the three Asian crisis countries, and Malaysia implies that controls were for some time
have taken steps to limit the offshore use of successful in allowing some monetary-policy
their currencies. In principle this makes it pos- independence, and also in shifting the
sible to break the link between onshore and composition of capital in ows toward the
offshore interest rates, particularly by restrict- long end. Empirical evidence presented by
ing the convertibility of the currency for non- José De Gregorio et al. (2000) suggests
residents—who need access to the domestic that the Chilean controls lost their effective-
banking system to complete their transactions ness after 1998. They have recently been
(see Shogo Ishii et al., 2001).51 Ishii et al. removed.
(2001) conclude that such restrictions have been Thus, controls can be used to help limit cap-
more successful the more comprehensive they ital out ows and maintain a pegged exchange
have been, and that they could provide the au- rate, given domestic policies consistent with
thorities with a breathing space in which to maintenance of the exchange rate. However,
implement policy changes.52 But as with other such controls tend to lose their effectiveness and
capital controls, their effectiveness tends to efŽ ciency over time. Capital-in ow controls
erode over time. Further, the longer the mea- may for a time be useful in enabling a country
sures are implemented, and the stronger they to run an independent monetary policy when the
are, the higher the associated costs in terms of exchange rate is softly pegged and may in u-
the efŽ ciency of the Ž nancial system are likely ence the composition of capital in ows, but
to be. their long-term effectiveness to those ends is
Excessive indebtedness of domestic Ž nan- doubtful.
cial and nonŽ nancial institutions arises not
from capital out ows, but from in ows, es- D. Instability in the Global Financial System
pecially short-term in ows. Market-based
capital-in ow controls, Chilean style, could The series of emerging-market Ž nancial cri-
be helpful for a country seeking to avoid the ses from Mexico in 1994 to Asia to Russia,
difŽ culties posed for domestic policy by cap- Brazil, Turkey, Argentina, and Brazil again, has
ital in ows. This typically occurs when a been at the center of the globalization debate.
The crises hit some countries that had at times
been described as model reformers, and others
50
Morris Goldstein (2002) recommends a “managed (in Asia) that had been growing very fast. The
 oating plus” regime, where the plus consists of measures to
discourage currency mismatching by domestic institutions.
crises took a heavy toll on almost all of the
51
This paper describes three different mechanisms that crisis countries, as well as on other countries
are used to limit offshore currency trading. affected by the contagion.53 Figure 6 shows the
52
Singapore has been gradually dismantling these con- behavior of output in the crises.
trols. Jaewoo Lee (2001) concludes that the Singapore con-
trols were successful in large part because the underlying
macroeconomic imbalances were very small and therefore
did not provide signiŽ cant incentives to circumvent the
53
controls. In this section I draw heavily on Fischer (2001, 2002).
16 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

FIGURE 6. REAL GDP GROWTH


Source: International Monetary Fund (World Economic Outlook).

The proximate cause of most of the crises the only country that kept growing through its
was the reversal of large-scale short-term capi- external crises.
tal  ows. In every case except Brazil in 2001– Although hedge funds received a large share
2002, the crisis affected a country with a more of the blame for the reversals, and were proba-
or less formally pegged exchange rate, which bly predominant in determining the timing of
gave way, usually at the beginning of the crisis. some of the crises,54 the reversals were more
In every case except in Brazil, the crisis hit a general and not conŽ ned to short-term funding.
country with a weak Ž nancial system—though Neither were they conŽ ned to the actions of
the Russian Ž nancial system was very small at foreigners; not surprisingly, in most of the cri-
the time of the crisis, and the Argentinian bank- ses domestic residents and corporations played
ing system had been strong a year before the a prominent part in the capital- ow reversals.
crisis but was severely weakened by measures What can be done to reduce the volatility of
imposed on it in attempts to preserve the cur- capital  ows to emerging-market countries?
rency peg. The Ž rst response would be for countries to shut
Capital- ow volatility during the crises was themselves off from international capital  ows.
massive. For the extreme cases, between 1996 It bears emphasis that despite the crises, and
and 1998, private capital in ows to Indonesia the arguments of many critics of globalization,
declined by 16.5 percent of GDP, while the almost no country has taken this route; the
turnaround for Turkey between 2000 and 2001
was 13.6 percent of GDP. Among the crisis
countries shown in Figure 6, the smallest rever- 54
Following the Asian crisis, an IMF study concluded
sal in private capital  ows was in Brazil, where that a wide range of Ž nancial institutions, including banks,
the decline was by 3.1 percent of GDP between had engaged in the same behavior as the hedge funds (see
2001 and 2002. This helps explain why Brazil is Barry Eichengreen and Don Mathieson, 1998).
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 17

revealed preference of the emerging-market During the 1980’s Latin American debt cri-
countries is to stay involved with the interna- sis, the Federal Reserve System and the IMF
tional Ž nancial system.55 worked closely with the principal creditors, the
However, as previously noted, some coun- banks, and the debtor countries to put together
tries have taken measures to limit the offshore Ž nancing packages. As the 1990’s crises un-
use of their currencies, thus securing more folded, there were many who argued that the
monetary-policy  exibility. In addition, I should authorities should act similarly and seek to co-
note that capital- ow reversals would not have ordinate the creditors. In effect, the argument is
been so large had the in ows been smaller that there is a bad equilibrium in which all the
to begin with. The introduction of a  exible lenders seek to withdraw funds and only worsen
exchange-rate system has generally sharply re- the crisis in doing so, and a good equilibrium in
duced short-term capital in ows and is thus a which the creditors stay in and thereby help
major part of the solution to the problem of mitigate the crisis. In such situations, in coor-
excessive capital- ow volatility. For transi- dinating the creditors the authorities can be seen
tional periods, the use of Chilean-style capital- as resolving a collective-action problem that the
in ow controls and more detailed reporting creditors acting individually cannot solve.
requirements can also help moderate in ows. This approach was successful in the South
The question also arises of whether policy Korean crisis at the end of 1997 and in early
measures to mitigate the volatility of capital 1998. Nonetheless, great care needs to be taken
 ows to emerging-market countries can be in seeking to coordinate the creditors. It would
taken by the authorities in the major capital be destabilizing if the creditors were coordi-
markets from which the funds  ow. Many, nated in every crisis, for they would have a
including the authorities in some Asian coun- greater incentive to rush for the exits at the mere
tries, have argued for more transparency by hint of a crisis.58 In addition, it is much more
the hedge funds and other market partici- difŽ cult for the authorities to justify coordinat-
pants.56 However it has not been possible to ing the creditors when there is a signiŽ cant risk
reach a consensus on greater disclosure of that those who have been persuaded to stay
position-taking by Ž nancial institutions par- in will nonetheless suffer losses. That is why
ticipating in emerging markets. Although it is industrial-country regulators have been less
doubtful that a different consensus will enthusiastic about creditor coordination in re-
emerge any time soon, this issue should re- cent years than they were in the 1980s: there is
main on the agenda—and in the meantime, it a con ict between their regulatory role and their
remains open to emerging-market authorities pressuring the banks to maintain portfolio posi-
to build better information systems about cap- tions against their will.
ital  ows in their countries. The recent experience suggests a differenti-
Also prominent on the agenda is private- ated approach to creditor coordination. Some-
sector involvement in the resolution of crises. times a formal approach may be necessary, as in
Let me brie y take up two issues: the extent to Korea at Christmas in 1997; at other times, as in
which the ofŽ cial sector should seek to coordi- the case of Brazil in March 1999, when the
nate the actions of the private sector when a commercial banks voluntarily agreed to main-
crisis appears imminent, and the recent IMF tain their lines of credit, less formal discussions
proposal for a sovereign debt-restructuring could serve better; when Ž nancing needs are
mechanism.57 small, or when an IMF package seems adequate

58
This possibility was very much in the minds of those
55
Even Malaysia, which imposed capital controls in contemplating coordinated action during the crises of the
1998, removed most of them within 1–2 years. 1990’s: we believed that the more often we sought to
56
For more detailed proposals, see Wendy Dobson and coordinate the creditors, the more likely it was that the crisis
Gary Hufbauer (2001). would spread even further than it did, and that in the limit
57
For a more comprehensive analysis, see Fischer the entire system could seize up, and we would have been
(2002). back in the 1930’s.
18 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

to reverse out ows, there may be no need to market debtors will too easily use legal provi-
approach the creditors; and in extreme and in- sions to restructure debts, spreads will rise, and
frequent cases, an involuntary restructuring of capital  ows to those countries will decline.
the debt may be necessary. That is why policymakers from emerging-
It is striking that, when governments face the market countries generally oppose proposals
decision on whether to seek to impose a stand- to make it easier for them to restructure their
still and/or restructure their debts in a nonvol- payments, be it through collective-action
untary way, they are generally willing to go clauses or the creation of a sovereign bank-
very far to avoid a default. Why? The reasons ruptcy procedure.
are: (i) that a debt restructuring will almost Based on their behavior during the last de-
certainly involve a restructuring of the domestic cade, I believe it unlikely that emerging-market
Ž nancial system, where Ž nancial institutions economic ofŽ cials will be encouraged to default
(including banks and pension funds) hold gov- by the presence of an SDRM, though some of
ernment bonds as important parts of their them fear that it would change the balance of
portfolios; (ii) that there may be serious inter- forces within the country, encouraging populist
ruptions to the payments mechanism and to forces that often favor repudiating debts.
trade credit;59 and (iii) that it is impossible to Rather, an SDRM would be more likely to
know when domestic and foreign conŽ dence in affect the behavior of the IMF and the ofŽ cial
the government’s ability to meet its promises sector, which could become too quick to urge
will be restored, and for how long the country restructurings as an alternative to IMF lending.
will be punished by the markets for having There is a balance to be struck, and it is impor-
defaulted. Rightly or wrongly, probably rightly, tant for the effective operation of the interna-
debtor governments see the costs of a debt de- tional system that the IMF not step back from
fault as extremely large—and much larger than providing Ž nancing to countries facing a liquid-
the critics of IMF loans typically imply.60 ity crisis.
A key problem is that we have no accepted The SDRM proposal has already achieved
framework in which a country in extremis can success in leading the private sector to sup-
impose a payments suspension or standstill port the inclusion of collective active clauses
pending agreement with its creditors to support (CAC’s) in bond contracts. It is certainly desir-
the restoration of viability—which takes us to able that the IMF continue its important work
Anne Krueger’s proposal for a Sovereign Debt on the mechanism. But we should recognize
Restructuring Mechanism (SDRM), a legal that at best it will take years to change the legal
mechanism to approve payments standstills by framework, and that it is quite possible that it
sovereign nations, and for the restructuring and, will not in the end be possible to persuade the
if necessary, writing down of sovereign debts.61 U.S. Congress on this issue. In any case, I
The costs of resorting to such measures have believe the Executive Board of the IMF should
to be high if the international Ž nancial system is continue seeking to spell out more precisely a
to work well. If creditors believe that emerging- set of procedures for how it will act in the event
it concludes that a country has an unsustainable
level of debt. This would help formalize the
59
The experience of Argentina so far in its current crisis approach that has already been developed on an
suggests that creditor legal action following a default may ad hoc basis in response to some of the recent
be less disruptive than many, including me, had anticipated. crises. At the very least, it would provide more
60
It is the judgment of how far to go to help a country
that seeks to avoid a default, and of what probability of
clarity on the question for debtors and creditors
success to require, that lies behind the controversies over alike, which would be a good in itself.
recent IMF support for Turkey, its decision to support Let me turn next to what the emerging-
Argentina in August 2001, and not to provide further sup- market countries can do to reduce their vulner-
port in December 2001. ability. The crises of the last decade can be seen
61
National bankruptcy laws should apply to private-
sector debtors who cannot make payments; if debtors can as the manifestation of the impossible trinity in
pay in local currency, the stay could permit a delay in the emerging markets, 25 years after the Bretton
converting these payments into foreign currency. Woods system succumbed to the same forces.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 19

The adoption of  exible exchange-rate systems policies when in recession but that the IMF does
by most emerging-market countries is by far not recommend a similar course for emerging-
the most important emerging-market crisis- market countries in crisis. If a country in crisis
prevention measure taken in response.62 In has a strong Ž scal position and has no problem
choosing a new nominal anchor to replace the borrowing, then it can indeed run a more ex-
exchange rate, most countries have (wisely, I pansionary Ž scal policy.64 But many emerging-
believe) opted for in ation-targeting. market countries that enter IMF programs are in
However, exchange-rate  exibility is not suf- a debt crisis, in which they cannot borrow from
Ž cient to prevent crises, for a country may the market, and high interest rates are adding
nonetheless get into trouble because of market to adverse debt dynamics. The country cannot
doubts about its ability to service its debt. This increase market borrowing in these circum-
is the main cause of the 2002 crisis in Brazil. stances,65 and the international Ž nancial institu-
Even with a  exible exchange rate, excessive tions (IFI’s) do not usually have enough
indebtedness of either the public or the private resources to more than offset the contractions
sector, and weaknesses in the Ž nancial sector, imposed by the markets. Thus, Ž scal policy has
make a country more vulnerable to both internal to be tightened if the country is to avoid a
and external shocks. default—as virtually every country in crisis des-
Hence, countries wishing to operate in the perately wants to do.
international capital markets need both to As to monetary policy, if the country has few
strengthen their Ž nancial systems and to ensure debts denominated in foreign currency, and in-
that their Ž scal policies are sustainable. Fiscal  ation is low, then it can cut interest rates and
sustainability requires not only that the debt to allow the currency to depreciate. If, however, its
GDP ratio will stabilize if things go well, but currency is plunging, then a rise in interest rates
also that the debt will be sustainable (possibly is more likely than an interest-rate cut to slow or
with the assistance of policy adjustments and stop the collapse.66
the IMF) if the economy is hit by shocks. As already discussed, in adapting themselves
Fiscal-sustainability criteria for emerging-market to living in the international Ž nancial system,
countries have not yet been deŽ ned. However, it countries need also to be cautious about when
is likely that the Maastricht 60-percent debt-to- and how they liberalize capital-account transac-
GDP threshold ratio is too high for countries tions. Other measures include greater transpar-
subject to much larger interest-rate and other ency about both data and the intentions of the
external shocks than are the industrialized government, and the adoption of international
countries.63
In criticizing IMF-supported programs, it is 64
As noted in Jack Boorman et al. (2000), the initial
often remarked that industrialized countries can
programs supported by the IMF in Asia, where government
cut interest rates and run expansionary Ž scal indebtedness was generally low, tightened Ž scal policy
excessively, though policy was relaxed within a short
time. Policy was tightened because it was believed this
62
By a  exible exchange-rate system I do not mean a would strengthen market conŽ dence, and would serve as a
purely  oating rate, but rather a system in which the au- down-payment on the expected costs of Ž nancial-sector
thorities may intervene to affect the rate but are not per- restructuring.
65
ceived as trying to defend a particular rate or narrow range Mindful of the difŽ culties caused by tightening Ž scal
of rates. policy in a recession, the IMF in late 2000 agreed with
63
Several economists have pointed to what they call the Argentina on a small Ž scal expansion, as a contribution to
original sin of emerging-market borrowers, that they are recovery. Political economy is complicated: we were told by
unable to borrow internationally in their own currencies. As some Argentines at the time that this was a mistake, not
Eichengreen and Ricardo Hausmann (2002) explain, had because Keynes was wrong, but because the government
Brazil been borrowing in its own currency, investor uncer- would use the extra room given by the IMF support to
tainty that caused the real to plummet would mainly have increase the deŽ cit by more than the agreed amount. They
led to more competitive Brazilian exports, rather than a turned out to be right.
66
large increase in debt-servicing costs. I see no simple solu- However, at some point, further increases in the in-
tion to the original-sin problem, beyond establishing a terest rate become counterproductive, because they make
record that encourages creditors to accept the risks of lend- debt dynamics worse and weaken the Ž nancial conditions of
ing in emerging-market currencies. both Ž nancial and nonŽ nancial corporations.
20 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

changes, the world trading system will remain


unfairly tilted against the developing countries.
Figure 8 shows the results of a World Bank
model simulation, which examines the long-
term impact of full trade liberalization.67 The
dynamic gains calculation assumes that open-
ness affects productivity. With or without this
effect, the gains are impressive and are greater
relatively and even absolutely for the develop-
ing countries than for the industrialized coun-
tries. Nearly half the beneŽ ts for the developing
countries come from the liberalization of agri-
cultural trade.
One other result bears emphasis. A consistent
FIGURE 7. TRADE PROTECTION IN INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES Ž nding of such studies is that at least half the
Note: The Ž gure shows tariffs on merchandise imported by
gains for the developing countries derive from
high-income countries (as percentages) in 1995. greater intra-developing-country trade, that is,
Source: Global Economic Prospects 2003 (Ch. 6). South–South trade. In other words, the devel-
oping countries would beneŽ t not only from the
industrialized countries opening up to their ex-
codes and standards with regard to the Ž nancial ports, but also from opening up their markets to
system, Ž scal- and monetary-policy transpar- each other.
ency, accounting standards, corporate gover- Of the many measures that could be taken
nance, and so forth. to make the international system work better
and more fairly, removing the bias against
E. The International Trading System developing-country exports and further South–
South trade liberalization would be among the
Reductions in tariffs and the growth in trade most effective.
in the past half century have been greater among
the OECD countries than between industrial- F. Aid
ized and developing countries. In particular, as
is well known, agricultural protection in the Over the period 1990–2000, the percentage
European Union, the United States, and Japan of their GDP given as aid by industrialized
discriminates against those goods in which country governments fell from 0.33 percent to
many developing countries are relatively most 0.22 percent.68 The total amount of aid is about
efŽ cient, and limitations on textiles exports $60 billion, and donor governments are com-
(which are due to be removed in 2005) have a mitted to seeking to raise aid’s share of their
similar effect. Figure 7 illustrates this trade pro- GDP by 2015. The share of 0.7 percent is a
tection of manufacturing and agriculture in norm, but only Scandinavian countries and the
high-income countries. Netherlands come close to meeting this ratio
The international trading system is biased (and they all exceed it).69 For the developing
against developing countries. In the wake of countries as a whole, net private capital  ows
September 11, the Doha Round of trade nego- far exceed aid. But for the group of the 44
tiations was inaugurated and named “the devel- least-developed countries (32 of them in Af-
opment round.” It remains to be seen whether
agricultural subsidization and protection in the
industrialized countries will be lifted, and 67
These results are presented in Global Economic Pros-
whether antidumping regulations and other non- pects 2003 (Ch. 6).
68
Net grants by NGOs added another 0.03 percent of
tariff barriers will be eased. To be sure, reduc- donor GDP to the total in each year.
ing agricultural protection is politically difŽ cult 69
In 2002, Luxembourg gave 0.71 percent of its GDP in
in the industrialized countries, but absent such aid.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 21

FIGURE 8. LONG-TERM IMPACT OF FULL TRADE LIBERALIZATION


Notes: The Ž gure shows that developing countries could reap income gains of more than $500 billion from full trade
liberalization, which implies up to a 5-percent boost in incomes. The left-hand panel shows additional income in 2015, in
terms of 1997 dollars, compared with the baseline. The right-hand panel shows the income boost as a percentage of baseline
income in 2015. Static gains refer to the results holding productivity constant. Dynamic gains allow productivity to respond
to sector-speciŽ c export-to-output ratios.
Source: World Bank model simulations.

rica), foreign aid (at 7.6 percent of GDP) is within a country.72 The millennium challenge
three times larger than private  ows.70 approach set out by the United States, in which
The 0.7-percent norm has been in existence countries will have to compete for extra aid, is
for decades, while aid has continued to fall. an interesting and potentially important experi-
Underlying the rationale for the decline has ment. In terms of focus within countries, there is
been growing skepticism about the effective- an increased emphasis on health and education
ness of aid, abetted by the continuing emphasis spending. Greater reliance on NGOs to deliver
by those in the development business on re- aid is another— but the proliferation of NGOs
maining problems rather than achievements. has also fostered aid dependence.
Corruption in some of the recipient govern- The new (as of 2000) approach of the IMF
ments has also severely reduced public support and the World Bank, in which countries are
for aid. In addition, the way the aid process has supposed to take the lead in preparing poverty-
worked has created an aid dependence in some reduction strategy plans, in cooperation with
of the poorest countries that has inhibited their their aid partners, could help deal with the prob-
taking action to solve their own problems.71 lem of aid dependence, but the evidence on the
Among the new approaches now being im- success of the new approach is not yet in. This
plemented is greater selectivity, both among approach re ects the evidence that economic
countries and in the focus of the aid effort programs are more likely to succeed when they
are owned by those implementing them—which
is to say that the government regards the pro-
70 gram as its own rather than an imposition of the
There are several small and very poor countries that
receive more than 20 percent of GDP in aid. Data are aid-givers, and the government has public sup-
available in the Human Development Report, based on port for the program.
Development Assistance Committee reports (United Na-
tions Development Program, 2002).
71
There is also a selection bias in the evaluation of aid.
The countries that used aid most successfully at earlier
72
stages, including, for example, Korea and Taiwan no longer See World Bank (2002b) for recommendations (in-
count in the evaluation of aid. cluding greater selectivity) for making aid more effective.
22 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

One problem inherent in approaches that pe- secretive organization, with no real accountabil-
nalize governments for bad behavior, and that ity. In the past the Fund may well have been too
makes aid such a difŽ cult area, is that when aid secretive for the good of its member countries
to a country with a bad government is cut off, or its own good. But there has been a sea change
most of those who suffer are private citizens, in the Fund’s transparency, and the charge of
who are already suffering from poor govern- secrecy is no longer valid.
ment. Hence humanitarian aid generally does As to accountability, Fund management is
and should continue even in cases, like Zimba- accountable to the shareholders, the member
bwe, where the humanitarian crisis is caused by governments, who are represented in the Exec-
the actions of the government. Jeffrey Sachs utive Board. The Board discusses and votes on
and others (see World Health Organization, all loans and all Fund policies. The largest
2001) have also made a powerful case that the shareholders have individual representatives;
very poorest countries should receive large other countries are grouped into constituencies,
amounts of aid, to enable them to improve with one Executive Director representing all the
health, education, and infrastructure, as part of countries in the group. Voting is weighted by
an effort to jump-start development. the number of shares of the country or countries
As countries develop, private capital  ows the Executive Director represents.
augment and then replace aid. But private cap- These shares, the quotas, are proportional to
ital barely  ows to the poorest countries, and the amount the country has to contribute to the
solutions to the plight of those living in the very Fund. Thus the largest contributors have the larg-
poorest countries, which have a population of est share of the vote, which means the United
about 650 million, will require major external States, with over 17 percent of the contribu-
assistance. It is hard to believe that a successful tions, has far and away the biggest share of the
attack can be made on global poverty with con- vote. The quotas not only determine the coun-
tinually declining  ows of aid—though some of try’s share of the total vote, but they are also a
the new approaches should make that aid more norm for the amount a country can borrow from
effective than it has been in the past. the Fund.75
The member governments, through their Ex-
G. Reform of the IMF ecutive Directors (and sometimes directly, in
discussions with the management) play an ac-
As a result of the crises of the last decade, tive role in Fund decision-making.76 Because the
and its own internal dynamics, the IMF has laid management needs Board support for its pro-
out an agenda of reform.73 The agenda includes posals, it consults with Board members well
more focused conditionality, with an emphasis before an issue reaches them for formal discus-
on macroeconomic policies and those structural sion. Although the management rarely loses
measures essential to macroeconomic stability, votes in the Board, this is mainly because it
and greater efforts to ensure country ownership does its homework and does not take issues on
of programs. The Fund is also seeking to im- which it expects to lose to the Board.
prove its surveillance, as part of an overall I regard the accountability of the Fund’s man-
effort to help prevent crises. agement to its member governments, and the
Rather than discuss Fund reform in detail,74 I weighted voting, as both fundamental and ap-
want to concentrate on one issue that has re- propriate. It has been suggested that the Fund
ceived a great deal of attention in recent discus- management should be more independent,
sions about the IMF, that of its accountability. along central-bank lines. But this misunder-
The charge is often made that the Fund is a stands the nature of Fund lending activities,

73 75
See for instance the speech of the then new Managing For example, borrowing in excess of 300 percent of
Director at the Annual Meeting in Prague in September quota is regarded as “exceptional access.”
76
2000, available online: http://www.imf.org/external/am/ The Board of the Fund is generally viewed as more
2000/speeches/PR03E.pdf . involved in Fund decision-making than the Board of the
74
That is done in Fischer (2001). World Bank in Bank decisions.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 23

which inevitably have a political element to to the formalization of the role of NGOs and
them—and on which, the governments who are civil society in the Poverty Reduction Strategy
funding the loans should ultimately decide. In Papers, arguing that as democratically elected
negotiating programs, I took great comfort from governments, it is for them to represent their
the management’s accountability to the Board, country and the views of its citizens.
for without the legitimacy provided by the need In brief, the Fund is and should be account-
for backing by member governments, it was able to the governments that are its members. It
not clear what authority a bureaucrat like my- should be as open and as transparent as possible
self would have had for undertaking such about its activities, and it has moved a long way
negotiations. in that direction in the last decade. It should be
As to the weighted voting, the Fund is com- as open as possible to discussions with members
mitting the resources of its member govern- of civil society constructively interested in the
ments when it lends money, and I believe those issues it deals with. But its decision-making
who provide more of the resources should have processes should remain inter-governmental,
a bigger say. The one-country, one-vote alter- with the primary responsibility for re ecting the
native would put the borrowers in charge of views of civil society on each issue and in each
lending decisions, which is not a good principle program being taken by member governments.
on which to run a Ž nancial institution. However,
the present quotas are not optimal, for there are IV. The Challenges
countries whose actual quota is far from repre-
sentative of their role in the global economy. The overall challenge to economic globaliza-
It has also been suggested that the Fund staff tion is to make the global system deliver eco-
and management should be more accountable to nomic growth more consistently and more
the citizens of the countries receiving loans. equitably, as the best way to further reduce
Increasingly, Fund staff has tried to ensure that global poverty and inequality. The speciŽ c chal-
the citizens of the recipient country are well lenges to globalization are both region- and
informed about the details of loans, and it en- subject-speciŽ c.
courages the borrowing government to publish Global growth is determined mainly by the
the relevant documents. Many of them do so, performance of the industrial countries.77 After
and all should do so. Ultimately though, Fund the current adjustments are done, the United
loans are to member governments, and it is the States and, less certainly, Europe should be able
governments that make the decisions and that to resume growth at rates in the range of 2– 4
should be accountable to their citizens. percent. The prospects for Japan are more dif-
It has also been suggested that the Fund Ž cult: with decisive action to deal with its weak
should consult more with outside academics banking sector and associated corporate-sector
and experts. In the normal course of business, problems, Japan can return to modest but posi-
the Fund does from time to time hold organized tive growth; without such action Japan is likely
meetings with outside experts on speciŽ c issues, to continue its present dismal performance, with
regions, and countries. There is less time for a chance of a crisis ever present. The choice is
formal consultative meetings when a program is Japan’s, for the nature of the problem and the
being negotiated. But as negotiations proceed, choice are well understood.
the staff and management do consult informally Attitudes to globalization in the industrial-
with academic and other experts whose judg- ized countries will be key to the future of the
ment and discretion they trust. global economy. Hence, governments in those
Many others would like to be heard and take countries need to stand up and support the right
part in the discussion as the Fund thinks through
and negotiates its programs. To the extent time 77
allows, the Fund should be open to those dis- The IMF calculates global growth by weighting coun-
try growth rates by purchasing-power-parity estimates of
cussions. But not everyone who wants to be GDP, which leads to a higher growth number by enhancing
heard has a legitimate role in the process. Some of the role of the developing countries (including China and
the borrowing countries have objected strongly India) in the estimate.
24 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

policies, help their own people deal with the of poor has been rising rapidly. There have been
adverse consequences of economic change, and success stories in Africa, including for a long
deliver on their promises on trade, aid, and the time Botswana and Uganda, but success has
strengthening of the international economic been fragile. The economic future of southern
system. Africa will be determined by developments in
In Asia, where South Korea has already led South Africa, whose economic policies during the
the way, China and India are well launched on past eight years have been very good, but where
the path to sustainable growth, and it is reason- the HIV/AIDS problem and events in Zimbabwe
able to expect growth to continue to spread have cast multi-dimensional shadows.
through the region—though we should not for- Some countries in Africa are beset by prob-
get that some countries in Asia are among the lems of governance, which are exacerbated by
world’s poorest. Nor should we forget that In- poverty, wars for control over mineral wealth,
dia’s growth could accelerate if it intensiŽ es its and in some cases ethnic fragmentation. The
macroeconomic stabilization and reform efforts. problems of Africa can only yield to a combi-
Most of the former Soviet-bloc transition econ- nation of domestic political and economic re-
omies, most importantly Russia, have turned the form and outside assistance. The creation of the
corner from decline to growth, which is likely to NEPAD, the New Partnership for African De-
continue if policies stay on track. velopment, is an encouraging sign of African
Latin America made a promising start toward determination to take the lead in solving their
sustained growth in the Ž rst half of the last own problems. But a great deal of further work
decade. But then there were major crises in the needs to be done to make NEPAD succeed.
three biggest economies in the region: Mexico, In turning next to the national and global
Brazil, and Argentina. South America’s eco- policy challenges, I shall be summarizing much
nomic prospects are tied to the fortunes of Bra- of the material presented to this point.
zil, which faces a difŽ cult but manageable
economic situation. If the new government suc- A. Implementing the Right Policies
ceeds while maintaining both macroeconomic
stability (and this is an issue on which it has The outward-oriented policies described in
insisted) and deepening its links with the rest of the 1990 Washington consensus remain an im-
the world, while at the same time increasing portant component of the right approach to eco-
social spending, that would help solidify the nomic policy.78 That policy approach needs to
ongoing transformation of the economic policy be enhanced by: Ž rst, a greater emphasis on
approach in Latin America. The stakes are very social justice, to be implemented through health
high, but the answers in terms of the right and education spending, social safety nets
general orientation of policy seem clear. Suc- adapted to the economic structure of the coun-
cessful negotiation of a free-trade area of the try, and infrastructure spending; second, greater
Americas would help secure the economic gains attention to developing the institutions of effec-
that the region is close to achieving. tive economic governance, including efŽ cient
There is relatively little poverty in the Middle judicial systems, civil service, the tax system,
East. But the countries of the region, the oil- and other elements in the enabling environment
producers included, face formidable economic for private-sector activity; third, more attention
development challenges, many of them a result to crisis-prooŽ ng the economy, especially by
of the pressure of rapid population growth. strengthening the Ž nancial system, and macro-
Whether governments can meet those chal- economic policies; and fourth, labor-market re-
lenges, and the associated challenge of democ- form to allow a greater proportion of the
ratization, will affect not only the economies of workforce to enter the formal labor market.
the Middle East, but also peace in the Middle
East and the rest of the world.
The challenge of development is most pro- 78
I am grateful to John Williamson for discussion and
found in sub-Saharan Africa, which has by far for allowing me to draw on a draft paper on the policy
the highest poverty rate, and where the number lessons of the last decade (Williamson, 2002).
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 25

B. Delivering on Trade and Aid in the global economy, for good (in helping
produce convergence of income levels among
The industrialized countries need to deliver countries if it is the unskilled who migrate) or ill
on their part of the bargain that tells developing (because of possible brain-drain effects). This is
countries that they should integrate into the an area where national economic, social, and
global economy. In particular, that means liber- cultural preferences are bound to take a front
alizing agricultural trade and ending the mas- seat. But it is also an area where greater clarity
sive subsidies to agriculture that impair the is needed on the economic effects of alternative
exports of so many developing countries. It policies, and where, eventually, more public
means also making a success of the Doha de- policy attention will be focused (see e.g.,
velopment round. At the same time, the devel- George Borjas et al., 1997; Barry Chiswick and
oping countries can achieve major gains by Timothy Hatton, 2003).80
opening up trade to each other.
The aid process needs to be made more ef- E. Improving Governance
fective through greater selectivity among coun-
tries and sectors within countries and through It was often said during the mid-1990’s that
countries taking greater ownership of the pro- “we cannot want reform more than the Russians
cess. But at the same time it is hard to see the do.” The same applies everywhere. Ordinary
problems of the poorest countries being solved people everywhere want to improve their lives.
without signiŽ cant increases in aid. But corrupt governments do not necessarily re-
spond to those desires. That is why the trend to
C. Making the International Financial System democracy is so important. It is also why global
Less Crisis-Prone term limits are a good idea, even though I have
no idea of how to enforce them—but I have
The shift to  exible exchange rates 30 years seen no government improve after ten years in
ago, and the strengthening of macroeconomic ofŽ ce.
policy frameworks since, which has removed While countries are primarily responsible for
the in ation problem, have helped prevent for- their own fates, outsiders from both the public
eign exchange crises among the industrialized and private sectors can help in uence the
countries.79 But the system is still disturbingly outcome, by promoting democracy, by eco-
crisis-prone for the emerging-market countries. nomic investing, and by supporting good
Measures are being implemented to make the projects in social sectors. Through their actions
system more stable for the emerging-market they can also help Ž ght corruption in develop-
countries. The most important of these is the ing countries.
shift to exchange-rate  exibility—but crises
can erupt for other reasons, particularly market V. Concluding Comments
fears of an unstable debt dynamics, and the
strengthening of domestic policies and institu- In thinking about the globalization debate,
tions is essential. and considering that the proponents of global-
ization recognize the need to deal with most of
D. Dealing with Migration the problems to which the critics point, I am
sometimes tempted to conclude that the debate
Migration of labor and temporary labor  ows is mainly a matter of temperament—between
are playing an increasing role in the global those who see the glass as half full versus those
economy. They are a potentially powerful force who see it as half empty; those who see the
doughnut and those who see the hole; or those
79
In fact, exchange rates among the industrialized coun-
tries moved in bipolar fashion, with members of EMU
80
pegging in the hardest possible way by eliminating their Bhagwati (2003) points to the importance of migration
own currencies, and all other exchange rates becoming and suggests the establishment of a World Migration Orga-
 exible. nization to coordinate international policy on these issues.
26 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

on the inside who are in a position to in uence internationalisation of which was nearly
policy directly and those who, for whatever complete in practice.
reason, are outside critics. But then I re ect that
the debate will affect economic policies in both Some argue that globalization is driven by
industrialized and developing countries, and I technology, and that it represents an unstoppa-
realize again its critical importance for the eco- ble force. Perhaps—in the long run. But we
nomic future. economists know that the forces of globaliza-
In developing that argument, I will quote two tion were stopped and reversed for nearly a third
of the greatest Englishmen of the last century. (the worst third) of the last century. As the
The Ž rst is John Maynard Keynes, the young words of Keynes remind us, we cannot take it
Keynes who in 1919 (pp. 9 –10) said: for granted that the world will continue down
the road of globalization, greater prosperity,
What an extraordinary episode in the eco- and greater democracy. That may be an aston-
nomic progress of man that age was ishing thing to say at the end of a century that
which came to an end in August witnessed the Ž rst sustained competition be-
1914! ... The inhabitant of London could tween two clearly deŽ ned economic and politi-
order by telephone, sipping his morning cal systems, and in which the pro-democracy,
tea in bed, the various products of the pro-market, pro-globalization system won that
whole earth, in such quantity as he might contest decisively. Nonetheless that system is
see Ž t, and reasonably expect their early
under attack.
delivery upon his doorstep; he could at
the same moment and by the same means The attack is about much more than econom-
adventure his wealth in the natural re- ics, and it could well be that the issues we have
sources and new enterprises of any quar- discussed tonight are not the decisive ones.
ter of the world, and share, without Rather, political, cultural and religious forces
exertion or even trouble, in their prospec- could play the dominant role in shaping the
tive fruits and advantages; or he could future of globalization. As concerned and well-
decide to couple the security of his for- informed citizens we can participate in and try
tunes with the good faith of the townspeo- to shape the broader debate.
ple of any substantial municipality in any But we have special obligations as profes-
continent that fancy or information might
recommend. He could secure forthwith, if sional economists participating in the debate
he wished it, cheap and comfortable over economic globalization:
means of transit to any country or climate
without passport or other formality ... . (i) to maintain our professional standards;
(ii) not to be afraid to take on big untidy is-
This paean of praise would place Keynes safely sues, but to do so objectively, element by
among the extreme globalizers. But then comes element;
his warning: (iii) to keep trying to Ž nd solutions to real
world problems; and
But, most important of all, he regarded (iv) from time to time—to stand up and be
this state of affairs as normal, certain, and counted on the issues.
permanent, except in the direction of fur-
ther improvement, and any deviation from The world and the economic system we live
it as aberrant, scandalous, and avoidable. in are highly imperfect. There is much that
The projects and politics of militarism needs to be done to make them work better. But
and imperialism, of racial and cultural as we do that, we should maintain a perspective
rivalries, of monopolies, restrictions, and
that re ects what Winston Churchill said of
exclusion, which were to play the ser-
pent to this paradise, were little more democracy:81 The pro-market pro-globalization
than the amusements of his daily news-
paper, and appeared to exercise almost
no in uence at all on the ordinary 81
“Democracy is the worst form of government, except
course of social and economic life, the for all the others that have been tried.”
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 27

approach is the worst economic policy, except Birdsall, Nancy. “A Stormy Day on an Open
for all the others that have been tried. Field: Asymmetry and Convergence in the
Global Economy,” in David Gruen, Terry
REFERENCES O’Brien, and Jeremy Lawson, eds., Glo-
balisation, living standards and inequality.
Ariyoshi, Akira; Habermeier, Karl; Laurens, Ber- Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia and Aus-
nard; Otker-Robé, Inci; Canales-Kriljenko, tralian Treasury, 2002.
Jorge Iván and Kirilenko, Andrei. “Capital Boorman, Jack; Lane, Timothy; Schulze-Ghattas,
Controls: Country Experiences with their Use Marianne; Bulir, Ales; Ghosh, A. R.; Hamann,
and Liberalization.” International Monetary Javier; Mourmouras, Alex and Phillips, Steven.
Fund (Washington, DC) Occasional Paper “Managing Financial Crises: The Experience
No. 190, 2000. in East Asia.” Carnegie-Rochester Confer-
Arteta, Carlos; Eichengreen, Barry and Wyplosz, ence Series on Public Policy, December
Charles. “When Does Capital Account Liber- 2000, (53), pp. 1– 67.
alization Help More Than It Hurts?” National Borjas, George; Freeman, Richard and Katz,
Bureau of Economic Research (Cambridge, Lawrence. “How Much Do Immigration and
MA) Working Paper No. 8414, 2001. Trade Affect Labor Market Outcomes?”
Barro, Robert J. Determinants of economic Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
growth: A cross-country empirical study. 1997, (1), pp. 1– 67.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1997. Bourguignon, François and Morrisson, Christian.
. “Inequality, Growth, and Investment.” “Inequality among World Citizens: 1820–
National Bureau of Economic Research (Cam- 1992.” American Economic Review, Septem-
bridge, MA) Working Paper No. 7038, 1999. ber 2002, 92(4), pp. 727–44.
Bekaert, Geert; Harvey, Campbell R. and Lund- Bourguignon, François; et al. “Making Sense
blad, Christian. “Does Financial Liberaliza- of Globalization: A Guide to the Economic
tion Spur Growth?” Unpublished manuscript Issues.” Centre for Economic Policy Re-
presented at the World Bank conference search (London, U.K.) Policy Paper No. 8,
“Financial Globalization: A Blessing or a 2002.
Curse?” Washington, DC, 30 –31 May 2002. Busch, Claudia; Kuckulenz, Anja and Le Man-
Ben-David, Dan. “Equalizing Exchange: Trade chec, Marie-Helene. “Worker Remittances and
Liberalization and Income Convergence.” Capital Flows.” Kiel Working Paper No.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1130, Kiel Institute for World Economics,
1993, 108(3), pp. 653–79. Kiel, Germany, 2002.
Berg, Andrew and Krueger, Anne. “Trade Chari, Anusha and Henry, Peter B. “Capital
Growth and Poverty.” IMF Working Paper Account Liberalization: Allocative EfŽ -
03/30, International Monetary Fund, Wash- ciency or Animal Spirits.” Unpublished
ington, DC, March 2003. manuscript presented at the World Bank
Bhagwati, Jagdish. Foreign trade regimes and conference “Financial Globalization: A
economic development: Anatomy and conse- Blessing or a Curse?” Washington, DC,
quences of exchange control regimes. Cam- 30 –31 May 2002.
bridge, MA: Ballinger, 1978. Chen, Shaohua and Ravallion, Martin. “How Did
. “The Capital Myth.” Foreign Affairs, the World’s Poorest Fare in the 1990s?” Re-
May/June 1998, 77(3), pp. 7–12. view of Income and Wealth, September 2001,
. The wind of the hundred days. Cam- 47(3), pp. 283–300.
bridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000. Chiswick, Barry and Hatton, Timothy. “Interna-
. “Borders Beyond Control.” Foreign tional Migration and Integration of Labor
Affairs, January/February 2003, 82(1), pp. Markets,” in Michael D. Bordo, Alan M.
98 –104. Taylor, and Jeffrey Williamson, eds., Glob-
Bhalla, Surjit. Imagine there’s no country. alization in historical perspective. Chicago:
Washington, DC: Institute for International University of Chicago Press, 2003 (forth-
Economics, 2002. coming).
28 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

Deaton, Angus. “Is World Poverty Falling?” Fi- tary Fund (Washington, DC) Working Paper
nance and Development, June 2002a, 39(2), No. 02/145, 2002b.
pp. 4 –7. Edwards, Sebastian. “Openness, Trade Liberal-
. “When Numbers Don’t Tell the Full ization, and Growth in Developing Coun-
Story about Poverty in India and the World.” tries.” Journal of Economic Literature,
IMF Survey, 8 July 2002b, pp. 215–17. September 1998, 31(3), pp. 1358–93.
De Gregorio, José; Edwards, Sebastian and . “How Effective Are Capital Con-
Valdés, Rodrigo. “Controls on Capital In- trols?” National Bureau of Economic Re-
 ows: Do They Work?” Journal of Develop- search (Cambridge, MA) Working Paper No.
ment Economics, October 2000, 63(1), pp. 7413, 1999.
59 – 83. Eichengreen, Barry and Mathieson, Don. “Hedge
Dobson, Wendy and Hufbauer, Gary. World cap- Funds and Financial Market Dynamics.” In-
ital markets: A challenge to the G-10. Wash- ternational Monetary Fund (Washington,
ington, DC: Institute for International DC) Occasional Paper No. 166, 1998.
Economics, 2001. Eichengreen, Barry and Hausmann, Ricardo.
Dollar, David. “Outward-Oriented Developing “An International Solution to Financial Fra-
Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: gility.” Financial Times, 21 November 2002.
Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976– 85.” Eco- Elliott, Kimberly Ann; Kar, Debayani and Rich-
nomic Development and Cultural Change, ardson, J. David. “Assessing Globalization’s
April 1992, 40(3), pp. 523–44. Critics: Talkers Are No Good Doers,” in
Dollar, David and Kraay, Aart. “Growth Is Good Robert Baldwin and L. Alan Winters, eds.,
for the Poor.” Unpublished manuscript, Challenges to globalization. Chicago: Univer-
World Bank, Washington, DC, 2001a. sity of Chicago Press, 2003 (forthcoming).
. “Trade, Growth and Poverty.” Unpub- Fischer, Stanley. “Capital-Account Liberaliza-
lished manuscript, World Bank, Washington, tion and the Role of the IMF,” in Stanley
DC, 2001b. Fischer et al., Should the IMF pursue capital-
. “Institutions, Trade, and Growth.” Un- account convertibility? Essays in Inter-
published manuscript, World Bank, Wash- national Finance No. 207, Princeton, NJ:
ington, DC, 2002. Princeton University Department of Econom-
Dornbusch, Rudi. “A Century of Unrivaled ics, 1998, pp. 1–10.
Prosperity,” in Ian Vasquez, ed., Global for- . The international Ž nancial system:
tune. Washington, DC: Cato Institute, 2000, Crises and reform, The Robbins Lectures,
pp. 91–111. London, U.K.: London School of Economics,
Dornbusch, Rudi and Werner, Alejandro. “Mex- 2001 (forthcoming).
ico: Stabilization, Reform and No Growth.” . “Financial Crises and Reform of the
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, International Financial System.” National
1994, (1), pp. 253–97. Bureau of Economic Research (Cambridge,
Easterly, William and Levine, Ross. “Tropics, MA) Working Paper No. 9297, 2002;
Germs, and Crops: How Endowments Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv (forthcoming).
In uence Economic Development.” Na- Frankel, Jeffrey and Romer, David. “Does Trade
tional Bureau of Economic Research, 9106, Cause Growth?” American Economic Re-
2002. view, June 1999, 89(3), pp. 379 –99.
Edison, Hali; Klein, Michael; Ricci, Luca A. and Galindo, Arturo; Micco, Alejandro and Ordoñez,
Slok, Torsten M. “Capital Account Liberaliza- Guillermo. “Financial Liberalization and
tion and Economic Performance: Survey and Growth: Empirical Evidence.” Unpublished
Synthesis.” International Monetary Fund manuscript presented at the World Bank Con-
(Washington, DC) Working Paper No. 02/ ference “Financial Globalization: A Blessing or
120, 2002a. a Curse?” Washington, DC, 30–31 May 2002.
Edison, Hali; Levine, Ross; Ricci, Luca and Slok, Giddens, Anthony. Runaway world: How glob-
Torsten. “International Financial Integration alisation is reshaping our lives. London,
and Economic Growth.” International Mone- U.K.: ProŽ le Books, 2002.
VOL. 93 NO. 2 RICHARD T. ELY LECTURE 29

Global economic prospects 2003. Washington, Report 01/177, International Monetary Fund,
DC: World Bank, 2002. Washington, DC, 2001, pp. 33– 40.
Goldstein, Morris. Managed  oating plus, Pol- Lindauer, David and Pritchett, Lant. “What’s the
icy Analyses in International Economics No. Big Idea? The Third Generation of Policies
66. Washington, DC: Institute for Interna- for Economic Growth.” Economia, Fall 2002,
tional Economics, 2002. 3(1), pp. 1–28.
Gourinchas, Pierre and Jeanne, Olivier. “On the Lundberg, Mattias and Squire, Lyn. “The Si-
BeneŽ ts of Capital Account Liberalization multaneous Evolution of Growth and In-
for Emerging Economies.” Unpublished equality.” Unpublished manuscript, World
manuscript presented at the World Bank con- Bank, Washington, DC, 1999.
ference “Financial Globalization: A Blessing Michaely, Michael; Papageorgiou, Dmitri and
or a Curse?” Washington, DC, 30 –31 May Choksi, Armeane, eds. Liberalizing foreign
2002. trade: Lessons of experience in the develop-
Hall, Robert E. and Jones, Charles. “Why Do ing world. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell, 1991.
Some Countries Produce So Much More Milanovic, Branko. “True World Income Distri-
Output per Worker than Others?” Quar- bution, 1988 and 1993: First Calculation
terly Journal of Economics, February 1999, Based on Household Surveys Alone.” Eco-
114(1), pp. 83–116. nomic Journal, January 2002a, 112(1), pp.
Hatton, Timothy J. and Williamson, Jeffrey G. 51–92.
“What Fundamentals Drive World Migra- . “The Two Faces of Globalization:
tion?” National Bureau of Economic Re- Against Globalization as We Know It.” Un-
search (Cambridge, MA) Working Paper No. published manuscript (second draft), World
9159, September 2002. Bank, Washington, DC, May 2002b.
International Monetary Fund. World economic Obstfeld, Maurice and Taylor, Alan. “Globaliza-
outlook:Globalizationopportunitiesand chal- tion and Capital Markets,” in Michael D.
lenges. Washington, DC: International Mon- Bordo, Alan M. Taylor, and Jeffrey William-
etary Fund, May 1997. son, eds., Globalization in historical perspec-
Ishii, Shogo; Otker-Robe, Inci and Cui, Li. tive. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
“Measures to Limit the Offshore Uses of 2003 (forthcoming).
Currencies—Pros and Cons,” International Quah, Danny T. “Twin Peaks: Growth and
Monetary Fund (Washington, DC) Work- Convergence in Models of Distribution Dy-
ing Paper No. 01/43, 2001. namics.” Economic Journal, July 1996,
Katz, Lawrence F. and Autor, David H. “Changes 106(437), pp. 1045–55.
in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequal- Reinhart, Carmen and Tokatlidis, Ioannis. “Be-
ity,” in Orley Ashtenfelter and David Card, fore and After Financial Liberalization.” Un-
eds., Handbook of labor economics, Vol. 3A. published manuscript presented at the World
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1999, pp. 1463– Bank conference “Financial Globalization:
1555. A Blessing or a Curse?” Washington, DC,
Keynes, John Maynard. The economic conse- 30 –31 May 2002.
quences of the peace. London, U.K.: Macmil- Rodriguez, Francisco and Rodrik, Dani. “Trade
lan, 1919. Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s
Krueger, Anne. Foreign trade regimes and eco- Guide to the Evidence,” in Ben S. Bernanke
nomic development: Liberalization attempts and Kenneth Rogoff, eds., NBER macroeco-
and consequences. Cambridge, MA: Ball- nomics annual 2000. Cambridge, MA: MIT
inger, 1978. Press, 2001, pp. 261–325.
. “The Effects of Trade Strategies on Rodrik, Dani. “Who Needs Capital-Account Con-
Growth.” Finance and Development, June vertibility?” in Stanley Fischer et al., Should the
1983, 20(2), pp. 6 – 8. IMF pursue capital-account convertibility?
Lee, Jaewoo. “Evolution of the Policy on Non- Princeton Essays in International Finance No.
internationalization of the Singapore Dollar,” 207. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University De-
in Singapore: Selected issues, IMF Country partment of Economics, 1998, pp. 55–65.
30 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003

. “The Global Governance of Trade as if development report. New York: Oxford Uni-
Development Really Mattered.” Unpublished versity Press, 2002.
manuscript, United Nations Development Warner, Andrew. “Once More into the Breach:
Programme, New York, 2001. Economic Growth and Global Integration.”
Rogoff, Kenneth. “Dornbusch’s Overshooting Mimeo, Harvard Institute for International
Model after 25 Years.” IMF Staff Papers, Development, Cambridge, MA, October 2001.
Special Issue 2002, 49, pp. 1–35. Williamson, Jeffrey. “Winners and Losers
Sachs, Jeffrey and Warner, Andrew. “Economic over Two Centuries of Globalization.” National
Reform and the Process of Global Integra- Bureau of Economic Research (Cambridge,
tion.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activ- MA) Working Paper No. 9161, 2002.
ity, 1995, (1), pp. 1–95. Williamson, John. “What Washington Means by
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. “The Disturbing ‘Rise’ of Policy Reform,” in John Williamson, ed.,
Global Income Inequality.” National Bureau Latin American adjustment: How much has
of Economic Research (Cambridge, MA) happened? Washington, DC: Institute for In-
Working Paper No. 8904, April 2002a. ternational Economics, 1990.
. “The World Distribution of Income.” . “An Agenda for Policy Reform.”
National Bureau of Economic Research Mimeo, Institute for International Econo-
(Cambridge, MA) Working Paper No. 8933, mies, Washington, DC, December 2002.
May 2002b. World Bank. Globalization, growth, and pov-
Scheve, Kenneth and Slaughter, Matthew. Glob- erty. World Bank Policy Research Report.
alization and the perceptions of American Washington, DC: World Bank, 2002a.
workers. Washington, DC: Institute for Inter- . A case for aid. Washington, DC:
national Economics, 2001. World Bank, 2002b.
Srinivasan, T. N. and Bhagwati, Jagdish. “Outward- . World development report. New York:
Orientation and Development: Are Revisionists Oxford University Press, various years.
Right?” Economic Growth Center Discussion World Health Organization. Investing in
Paper No. 806, Yale University, 1999. health for economic development, Report
[Available online: http://www.library.yale. of the Commission on Macroeconomics
edu/socsci/egcdis2.html .] and Health. Geneva, Switzerland: World
United Nations Development Program. Human Health Organization, 2001.

Вам также может понравиться