Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 22

The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

The Theory of Tax Evasion:


A Retrospective View

Abstract - The paper gives an overview of some main themes in


the theory of tax evasion, starting from Allingham and Sandmo
(1972). It reviews the comparative statics of the original model of
individual behavior where the tax evasion decision is analogous to
portfolio choice, and its extensions to incorporate socially conscious
behavior, participation in the black labor market and tax evasion by
firms. It also discusses the analysis of tax incidence and the problems
involved in moving from individual to aggregate analysis. Finally,
it reviews the issues that arise in formulating models of optimal
taxation in the presence of tax evasion.

INTRODUCTION

I f someone were to write a full history of taxation, including


both practitioners’ experience and the thinking of theo-
rists, it is probably a good guess that tax evasion would be
part of the picture from the very start. The formal economic
theory of tax evasion, on the other hand, is of considerably
more recent origin and started to develop only a little over
30 years ago. To the best of my knowledge, its beginning can
be dated to 19721 with the publication of the article “Income
Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis” by Michael Allingham
and myself (Allingham and Sandmo, 1972).2 It was followed
by a large number of contributions to the literature which
extended the original model in a number of directions. The
present paper, although not attempting a complete survey
of the literature, reviews the main problems and develop-
ments in the theoretical literature on tax evasion and relates
it to other issues that have traditionally been central in the
Agnar Sandmo theory of public finance.
Department of
1
Economics, Norwegian The paper by Srinivasan (1973), which was written at about the same time,
assumes that the taxpayer is risk neutral, maximizing expected after–tax
School of Economics income, which is a special case of the A–S analysis. On the other hand, he
and Business allows both the regular and the penalty tax schedules to be progressive,
Administration, which is more general than the A–S formulation.
2
N–5045 Bergen, The work on the paper started in the summer of 1971, when the two of us
met in Bergen for an extended (four–week!) summer workshop, organized
Norway
by the International Economic Association. The purpose of the workshop
was to bring together a number of young European economists working in
areas which at the time were at the forefront of interest among theoretical
National Tax Journal economists. Two of these areas were public economics and the economics
Vol. LVIIl, No. 4 of uncertainty, and for those with an interest in both fields, the economics
December 2005 of tax evasion was a perfect topic.

643
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

Recent decades have also seen a number involves costs incurred by the public tax
of attempts to provide empirical estimates authorities3 in assessing tax liabilities,
of the size of the “hidden economy.” reviewing tax returns, pursuing evaders,
Although little of the empirical research, etc. On the other hand, there are the costs
at least to begin with, was based on an that taxpayers carry by spending time to
underlying theoretical structure, there is read up on the tax rules and filling out
no doubt that the empirical work and the their tax return forms. In the case of firms,
policy discussions that followed from it a major cost to them is doing a significant
gave inspiration to further theoretical part of the work of actually collecting the
work, and that theory also gave new taxes for the government in the case of
directions for empirical investigations. indirect taxes, payroll taxes and income
The literature through the 1980s was taxes. If the private costs of tax compliance
very nicely surveyed by Cowell (1990); vary among branches of industry, modes
more recent surveys include Andreoni, of business organization and personal oc-
Erard and Feinstein (1998), Slemrod and cupation, there is every reason to believe
Yitzhaki (2002) and Cowell (2002). that people’s choices will be affected by
In the present paper, I wish to take my these differences in cost. Someone who
point of departure from the 1972 Alling- is about to decide whether to set up his
ham–Sandmo (A–S) article, describe its own business or accept a salaried posi-
basic structure and consider some of its tion in a big company, may let his choice
weaknesses in the light of more recent de- be influenced by the consideration that in
velopments. I then go on to discuss more the former case his costs of tax compliance
normative issues like the implications of —as well as the opportunities for tax eva-
the tax evasion literature for the theory sion and avoidance—are likely to be much
of optimal tax design and the analysis of higher. So the costs of tax compliance on
tax administration. But before going into the part of the taxpayer, which form part
these more analytical parts of the paper, of the economy–wide costs of the tax
it will be useful to start with some more system, are likely to have effects on the
general perspectives on this part of the structure of industry and occupations in a
theory of taxation. country, and in the next round on returns
to investment and gross wages.
The theory of optimal taxation can be
THE COSTS OF TAX ADMINISTRATION
seen as a recipe for minimizing the costs
It is an old insight, going back at least of taxation. The costs on which this lit-
to Adam Smith (1776, Book V, Chapter II) erature focuses are, as already noted, the
that one of the demands that we should efficiency costs of a distorted tax system.
make on a good tax system is that the costs But the more direct costs of administra-
of administration are low. In the modern tion and compliance play little or no
theory of taxation, the costs of the tax sys- role in the analyses, and the theories of
tem have mostly been associated with the tax evasion that will be discussed below
efficiency costs of tax wedges that arise be- alert us to some of the important aspects
cause of the distortions of the competitive of these costs. So far, the potential gains
price mechanism. The more direct costs from using the insights of the tax evasion
of tax collection have, by contrast, practi- literature in the study of optimal taxation
cally been neglected. This is unfortunate have not been fully exploited, although
both from a positive and normative point for some aspects of taxation the evasion
of view. On the one hand, tax collection perspective is obviously highly relevant.

3
In the final instance, of course, all costs of administration must be borne by the consumers.

644
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

This is true, at least to some extent, with switch some hours from work into lei-
respect to the degree of progressivity of sure activities. Am I then engaging in tax
the personal income tax, and even more avoidance? A simplistic definition of tax
so with respect to the interface between avoidance is one that focuses on the law-
personal and company taxation and the makers’ intention and says that avoidance
degree of differentiation of the indirect is a type of action that is an unintended,
tax system. The literature on tax evasion although legal, consequence of tax policy.
should be seen as a way to bring issues By this definition, the price effects should
of tax administration into the focus of the perhaps not be classified as avoidance.
theoretical literature on tax design. However, it is often far from simple to
discover what the intentions of politicians
really are. Official estimates of the revenue
EVASION AND AVOIDANCE
effects of tax changes often assume that
The conceptual distinction between tax bases are constant, which suggests
tax evasion and tax avoidance hinges on that political intentions are formed on
the legality of the taxpayer’s actions. Tax the assumption that price elasticities are
evasion is a violation of the law: When the zero. But when a tax increase leads to a
taxpayer refrains from reporting income reduction of the quantity demanded and
from labor or capital which is in principle supplied and, therefore, to lower revenue
taxable, he engages in an illegal activity than the official estimate, one could then
that makes him liable to administrative classify this as an unintended effect of
or legal action from the authorities. In the tax increase, so that the price effect
evading taxes, he worries about the pos- becomes a kind of avoidance. Clearly,
sibility of his actions being detected. Tax the simplistic definition fails to capture
avoidance, on the other hand, is within the the distinction between tax avoidance as
legal framework of the tax law. It consists a specific type of activity and effects on
in exploiting loopholes in the tax law in demand and supply via relative price ef-
order to reduce one’s tax liability; convert- fects. Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2002) argue
ing labor income into capital income that that avoidance consists in actions that do
is taxed at a lower rate provides one class not change the individual’s consumption
of examples of tax avoidance. In engag- basket (which presumably includes his
ing in tax avoidance, the taxpayer has no consumption of leisure), and that this
reason to worry about possible detection; distinguishes it from real substitution
quite the contrary, it is often imperative responses. This definition focuses on
that he makes a detailed statement about the absence of relative price changes for
his transactions in order to ensure that consumption goods, but it neglects the
he gets the tax reduction that he desires.4 income effects that arise from increases in
If tax avoidance is legal, what is the disposable income. Perhaps the borderline
difference between avoidance and the between tax avoidance and “ordinary”
reaction to high taxes that arises because demand and supply effects must by neces-
of price effects on demand and supply? sity remain somewhat vague.
Suppose a higher tax on air travel makes There would not be much reason to
me travel more by train, or that a higher worry about these distinctions, were it not
marginal tax on labor income makes me for the fact that many people have difficul-
4
As a referee has suggested, it may well be that the provisions of the tax law are so ambiguous that the taxpayer
may be in doubt as to whether his avoidance transactions will be acceptable to the tax collector; if not, they
might in fact be classified as attempted evasion. This may to some extent seem to blur the distinction between
the two cases, although it is hard to imagine that a penalty will be imposed on the basis of transactions that
are truthfully reported.

645
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

ties in seeing the difference between tax will pay a penalty rate6 of tax, θ, on the
evasion and avoidance from a moral point evaded amount, so that his net income
of view. The house painter who does a bit in this case is:
of extra work in the black economy vio-
lates the law, while the wealthy investor [2] Z = (1 – t)W + tE – θE = (1 – t)W
who engages a tax lawyer to look for tax
havens does not. However, from a moral –(θ – t)E.
point of view their ways of behavior may
not seem to be all that different. Clearly, It should be pointed out that one obvi-
the borderline between what seems mor- ously unrealistic simplification in this
ally right and wrong does not always model is the assumption that all income is
coincide with the border between what equally unknown to the tax collector. This
is legal and illegal. This should be kept is clearly not the case; in most countries
in mind when considering the theoretical earnings are reported to the tax authorities
literature on tax evasion, where the basic by the employer, so that this part of his
assumption is that the taxpayer wishes to income cannot in fact be underreported
hide his actions from the tax collector. by the employee—unless he acts in col-
lusion with his employer. The analysis
should, therefore, be interpreted as ap-
THE A–S MODEL
plying to that part of his income which
The structure of the Allingham–Sandmo the taxpayer can in fact evade without
(A–S) model is very simple. No account is certainty of detection.
made of the taxpayer’s “real” decisions; The taxpayer’s subjective probability
his labor supply and therefore his gross of detection is p. He chooses the amount
earnings are taken as given, and the same evaded so as to maximize his expected
is true of his income from capital. The utility, which is:
model pictures the taxpayer at the mo-
ment of filling in his income tax return: [3] V = (1 – p)U(Y) + pU(Z).
How much of his income should he report
and how much should he evade? It is assumed that U is increasing and con-
Let W be the gross income of the tax- cave, so that the taxpayer is risk averse.
payer. There is a proportional income The first–order condition for an interior
tax at the rate t.5 The amount evaded, solution is:
i.e. the amount of underreporting, is E,
so that the reported income is W–E. If [4] (1 – p)U’(Y)t – pU’(Z)(θ – t) = 0,
the tax evasion is not detected by the tax
authority, the net income of the taxpayer or
is accordingly:
[5] U’(Z)/U’(Y) = (1 – p)t/p(θ – t).
[1] Y = W – t(W – E) = (1 – t)W + tE.
To see the empirical implications of the
If, however, it is discovered that the tax- model one has to differentiate the first
payer has underreported his income, he order conditions with respect to the exog-

5
Compared with the original A–S formulation, I have introduced some changes in the mathematical notation.
These correspond roughly to the notation used in my later article (Sandmo, 1981). Moreover, I now use the
amount of income evaded, rather than reported, as the decision variable of the taxpayer; this seems a more
natural formulation and leads to more unambiguous results.
6
This terminology has become common usage, although it does not correspond to the more everyday meaning
of ”penalty rate,” which should rather be identified with θ – t.

646
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

enous variables W, t, θ and p. It turns out tion that the penalty is imposed on the
that the signs of the derivatives ∂E/∂θ and amount of income evaded. If, instead, the
∂E/∂p are both unambiguously negative; a fine is imposed on the evaded tax, as in the
higher penalty rate or a higher probability cases of the American and Israeli tax laws,
of detection always tends to discourage there would be no substitution effect and,
tax evasion. Intuitively, this is seen from accordingly, no ambiguity. This is easily
[5] by noting that the right–hand side of seen if we redefine the penalty rate to ap-
the equation can be interpreted as the ply to the evaded tax, so that the penalty
relative price of income in the states of to be paid is θtE with θ > 1. Equation [2]
detection and non–detection, and this de- then becomes:
pends negatively on θ and p. When θ or p
increases, Z increases relative to Y, which [2a] Z = (1 – t)W – (θ – 1)tE.
implies that there must be less evasion.7
It seems reasonable to assume that a The first order condition [5] must then be
higher gross income will increase eva- rewritten as:
sion if one believes that people become
more willing to engage in risky activities [5a] U’(Z)/U’(Y) = (1 – p)/p(θ – 1),
as they get richer. This is also predicted
by the model if one makes the additional so that the relative price of income in the
and common assumption that the mea- two states is now independent of t. There
sure of absolute risk aversion (defined as remains only the income effect, which es-
–U’’(·)/U’(·)) is decreasing. As regards the tablishes a negative relationship between
effect of the regular marginal tax rate, a the tax rate and the amount of evasion.
notable feature of the original A–S model The substitution effect in the A–S model
is that an increase of the tax rate has an occurs because the penalty rate is held
ambiguous effect on tax evasion. There is fixed when the regular tax rate increases,
an income effect which is negative; higher so that the difference between the penalty
taxes make the taxpayer poorer and, there- rate and the regular tax rate goes down,
fore, less willing to take risks. But there is and this increases the incentive to under-
also a substitution effect that works in the report income. In the Yitzhaki reformula-
direction of increased evasion. In fact, the tion, this effect vanishes.
effect of the marginal tax rate on evasion The absence of ambiguity in theoretical
can be written as: models is often considered to be a good
thing, but there is a paradox involved in
[6] ∂E/∂t = –[(W – E)/(1 – t)](∂E/∂W) + S. the Yitzhaki analysis. The ambiguity of
the original A–S analysis is removed, but
Here, S is the substitution effect, which what is left is a result that goes directly
is positive. The first term on the right is against most people’s intuition about
the income effect, and this is negative if the connection between the marginal
evasion increases with gross income. The tax rate and the amount of evasion, and
income and tax effects are derived in the also against much empirical evidence.8
Appendix to the present paper. It seems to be a common belief that high
Yitzhaki (1974) pointed out that this marginal tax rates encourage tax evasion
result depends crucially on the assump- because there is a large gain to be made
7
Christiansen (1980) shows that if the expected gain from tax evasion is held constant, an increase of the penalty
rate combined with a decrease of the probability of detection will always reduce tax evasion.
8
The study by Clotfelter (1983) of tax return data for the United States found a strong positive association be-
tween marginal tax rates and the amount of evasion. For surveys of empirical work in this area see Schneider
and Enste (2000) and Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2002).

647
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

from withholding income from the tax col- of any information about W, it might be
lector. This belief is inconsistent with the reasonable to assume p’(W – E) > 0, assum-
Yitzhaki formulation, for there the penalty ing that the agency believes that the rich
increases pari passu with the tax rate. In the tend to evade more. On the other hand,
A–S model, by contrast, there is a positive to assume that the agency is completely
substitution effect on evasion because the ignorant about W may be unrealistic;
net penalty—the difference between the e.g., it could reasonably be expected to
penalty rate and the regular tax rate—goes know the taxpayer’s profession and the
down when the tax rate increases. It normal level of income associated with
is worth noting that this substitution it. Then, for each type of profession, the
effect would be present under the more natural hypothesis would be p’(W – E)
general but weaker assumption that the < 0; as reported income approaches or
penalty rate increases less than propor- exceeds the normal level, the probability
tionately with the tax rate. Perhaps the of detection falls.
theoretical ambiguity in this case is more This is a little ad hoc. A more satisfactory
representative of popular beliefs and approach is to derive a rule from a model
possibly even of actual tax systems. On of policy optimization on the part of the
the other hand, this type of model may agency. This has been done in a number
be too restrictive in its assumptions to be of more recent papers—beginning with
confronted with empirical data on eva- Reinganum and Wilde (1985)—which
sion that also reflect the presence of black have been very carefully surveyed by
market work. This requires an extension Andreoni, Erard and Feinstein (1998).
of the model to include variable labor In this literature it is usually assumed
supply, and this will be discussed in the that the collection agency’s objective is to
seventh section. maximize expected tax revenue, although
this is a rather special assumption as
seen from a welfare economics point of
ENDOGENOUS DETECTION
view; see the discussion in the eleventh
PROBABILITY
section.
The A–S article also considered the case In the case where the tax authority can
where the probability of detection varies commit to an audit rule before taxpayers
with the amount reported,9 so that p = report their incomes, a central result estab-
p(W – E). Under the assumption that p’(W lished by Reinganum and Wilde (1985) is
– E) < 0, it was shown that the predictions that the optimal policy involves a cutoff
of the model concerning the effects of an point whereby all returns reporting an in-
increase in the penalty rate and a positive come below some critical level are audited
shift in the probability of detection func- with probability one, whereas those who
tion continued to hold; a higher penalty report an income higher than this are not
and a higher likelihood of being detected audited at all. This equilibrium rule can
both act as a deterrent to tax evasion. be interpreted as an extreme version of the
The probability function must be taken A–S assumption, although it is based on
to reflect the taxpayer ’s beliefs about the simplification that taxpayers are risk
the policy followed by the tax collection neutral. When a commitment to an audit
agency. How is this belief justified? A–S rule cannot be made, as in Reinganum
discussed both alternatives as to the slope and Wilde (1986), the analysis gets much
of the p(W – E) function. In the absence more complicated and takes the form of

9
Somewhat curiously, a large number of later contributions state rather emphatically that it neglected the
problem.

648
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

a sequential move game with a number to do so. The behavior of these people
of possible equilibria. It is difficult, on can only be explained by the model if one
the basis of these analyses, to arrive at assumes that for them the inequality [7]
reasonably simple and testable conclu- is reversed. Is this reasonable? If, to take
sions about the shape of the probability an illustrative example, the penalty rate
of detection function. Perhaps the main is twice the regular tax rate, [7] implies
value of this type of analysis will be as that the probability of detection, which
a basis for the internal analysis of policy is sufficiently high to deter tax evasion,
design in tax collection agencies. is greater than 0.5. This number is far in
excess of most empirical estimates and
raises the question of whether the model
A CYNICAL VIEW OF TAXPAYER
depicts people as either too rational or too
BEHAVIOR?
cynical compared to what we believe that
In the presentation of the model in the we know about their actual behavior.10
fourth section, it was assumed that the There are several ways to resolve
taxpayer does in fact engage in tax eva- this puzzle. First of all, in practical ap-
sion; the model is one with an interior plications it is important to distinguish
solution in which E > 0. But is it clear that between different types of income that,
the taxpayer will always choose to evade if underreported, are subject to quite dif-
taxes? In other words, is it always optimal ferent probabilities of detection. Ordinary
to move from a state of no evasion (E = 0) wage income is typically reported to the
to one with a positive evasion level? To tax collector by the employer, and an at-
see what the model says about this, we tempt to underreport it by the taxpayer
take the derivative of expected utility at would, therefore, be detected with prob-
E = 0, where Y = Z = (1 – t)W, to obtain ability one; in that case the model predicts
∂V/∂E|E=0 = (1 – p)U’((1 – t)W)t – pU’((1 that there will be no attempt at evasion.
– t)W)(θ – t). Moreover, it is important to realize that the
For some tax evasion to be optimal, it probability that enters condition [7] is the
must be the case that this derivative is taxpayer’s subjective probability, which
positive. It is easily seen that this is the is not necessarily equal to the statistical
case if and only if: frequency with which peoples’ tax returns
are checked. Indeed, empirical studies in-
[7] pθ < t. dicate that people tend to overestimate the
probability of detection, and this could go
For tax evasion to be optimal from the some way towards explaining non–evad-
taxpayer’s point of view, it is a necessary ing behavior. (For an evaluation of these
and sufficient condition that the expected studies see Andreoni, Erard and Feinstein
penalty rate is less than the regular tax (1998, pp. 844–7).)
rate. But this explanation is not entirely con-
This condition presents us with some- vincing. Common sense and everyday ob-
thing of an empirical puzzle. Obviously, servations tell us that people refrain from
we do not know how many people evade tax evasion—as well as from speeding,
taxes, but it is fairly certain that there are shoplifting and polluting the environment
a large number of people who do not, —not only from their estimates of the ex-
even though they have the opportunity pected penalty, but for reasons that have to

10
Frey and Feld (2002) mention this as a major empirical problem with the original A–S analysis. These authors
estimate the probability of detection to be substantially less than one percent on the basis of data for Switzer-
land, 1970–1995.

649
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

do with social and moral considerations.11 leads to less evasion. But because evasion
Allingham and Sandmo (1972) considered decreases, the “conscience tax” B’(E) also
the social stigma that may be attached to goes down, and this diminishes the effect
being caught in evading taxes and showed of the penalty tax. In other words, the
that this leads to a more restrictive condi- stronger extrinsic incentive to truthful
tion for tax evasion to be optimal. Another reporting reduces the intrinsic incentive
alternative is to assume that people have to behave honestly. Some writers have
a bad conscience about evading taxes. A maintained that this type of behavioral
simple representation of this is to let the reaction cannot be explained within the
“disutility” of tax evasion be represented framework of neoclassical economic
in the expected utility function,12 so that theory, but clearly this is not true. The
we can write: present extension of the model does seem
to capture the common notion that explicit
[8] V = (1 – p)U(Y) + pU(Z) – B(E). economic incentives make taxpayers see
it as less imperative to act according
Here it is assumed that B’(E) > 0 and that to moral standards of behavior. On the
B’’(E) > 0. An important insight is that this other hand, one may question whether
extension of the analysis leaves the quali- this is a very meaningful empirical as-
tative nature of the comparative statics sumption. What we can hope to observe
effects for the interior solution case com- is the net effect of the tax increase—and
pletely unaffected. The reason is simple. even that is obviously very difficult. A
First, the budget constraints remain the further empirical decomposition with the
same with this extension. Second, the con- aim of discovering the change of balance
cavity of expected utility, V, in the decision between intrinsic and extrinsic incentives
variable E is also unaffected. These two is fraught with severe difficulties.
facts together mean that the qualitative Expected utility maximization has come
predictions of the model must be the same under increasing criticism in recent years
as before. What changes, however, is the as not being in accordance with observed
condition for positive tax evasion to be behavior in a number of areas, and an-
optimal, which now becomes: other modification of the A–S model
consists in replacing the expected utility
[9] pθ + B’(0)/U’(W(1 – t)) < t. framework with an alternative axiomatic
model of choice under uncertainty. An
This inequality implies that a positive example of this is the work of Bernasconi
expected gain is not sufficient for the tax- (1998), who replaces expected utility with
payer to engage in tax evasion. The nega- a version of the so–called rank–dependent
tive value attached to evasion as such acts expected utility approach. It appears that
as an additional penalty—a “conscience this does not change the comparative
tax”—to deter evasion. statics results for the person who evades
An interesting implication of this for- tax. What it does change is the condition
mulation is that it leads to a less optimistic for some tax evasion to be optimal, which
view of the effectiveness of using penalty becomes more restrictive than in the A–S
taxation as deterrence to tax evasion. In model. In this respect, it is similar to the
the new version of the model it will still variations on the expected utility model
be true that an increase in the penalty rate that consist in introducing social stigma or

11
For further discussion, see McCaffery and Slemrod (2004), who discuss this issue in the wider context of
behavioral public finance.
12
A similar model can be found in Gordon (1989), who assumes that the function B is linear.

650
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

a bad conscience. This suggests, as indi- same time it seems clearly unrealistic. It is
cated above, that the comparative statics unreasonable to believe that the taxpayer
results of the A–S model may be rather has not thought about the possibility of
insensitive to changes in assumptions evading taxes before he sits down to fill
about the taxpayer’s objective function. A out his income tax return. More prob-
bigger challenge to the model is to intro- ably, he has thought about this before
duce a larger choice set for the taxpayer, making decisions about the allocation of
e.g., by studying the interaction between his work and leisure hours or about the
tax evasion and labor supply. composition of his investment portfolio.
When people are asked about possible It is especially the connection between tax
justifications for engaging in tax evasion, evasion and labor supply that has caught
a common answer is that they are being the interest of economists working in this
treated unfairly by the tax system. This area. This is in many ways natural, since
response could easily be regarded just public attention to the hidden economy
as an attempt at moral defense of one’s has focused on this problem, presumably
own self–interested behavior, but some because, in spite of its name, it is far from
attempts have been made to offer theoreti- hidden from the majority of people, many
cal explanations for it, and to explore its of whom have personal experience with
empirical implications. Thus, Bordignon the black labor market, either as sellers or
(1993) assumes that the taxpayers are buyers of labor services.
motivated by considerations of fairness Once we link the amount of tax eva-
with respect to the services that the gov- sion with the earnings from black market
ernment provides in exchange for their tax work, it is clear that we can no longer take
payments as well as the tax structure and the view of the A–S model that decisions
the prevalence of evasion by other taxpay- about tax evasion can be postponed to
ers. Alternatively, Barth, Cappelen and the moment of filling out the income tax
Ognedal (2005), observing that the income return. Instead, such decisions are closely
tax does not distinguish between people related to labor market choices, so that the
who earn a given income by working tax evasion decision should be studied in
long hours at low wages or short hours at the context of a model of labor supply. In
high wages, assume that the former group the fourth–section model, utility depend-
consider themselves unfairly treated and, ed only on income, which, in a one–period
therefore, justified in evading taxes. This world, is equivalent to consumption. The
type of approach is particularly interest- first extension of the model must be to
ing in that it sees tax evasion as basically allow for the labor–leisure choice, so that
a social phenomenon, which cannot be we rewrite the basic utility function as
understood just by considering the in- U(C, L), where C is consumption and L
centives of a single individual; one also is leisure. The utility function is assumed
has to consider the interaction between to have the usual convex indifference
taxpayers in a social setting. curves and also to be concave in C, so
that the taxpayer is risk averse towards
variations in his consumption level.
TAX EVASION AND BLACK MARKET
Let us now interpret Y and Z of equations
WORK
[1] and [2] as the levels of consumption
The A–S model looks at the tax evasion in the two states of non–detection and
decision in isolation from other types of detection. Expected utility can then be
economic choices. This may be an advan- written as:
tage because it leads to clear and reason-
ably unambiguous hypotheses, but at the [10] V = (1 – p)U(Y, L) + pU(Z, L).
651
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

But the constraints also differ from the derive from the model and contrast them
previous formulation and can, in fact, be with the results from the original A–S
formulated in several different ways. The model.
one that is closest in spirit to the identi- The present model is a mixture of the
fication of tax evasion with black market standard textbook model of labor supply
work starts with a time constraint that lets and the A–S tax evasion model. In general,
total time available consist of three parts— we must expect the composite model to
regular market hours, black market hours yield less clear–cut results than the partial
and leisure; this can be written as: models, while at the same time alerting
us to connections that are less obvious in
[11] H + h + L = T. a more partial view. Some of the results
from the partial models turn out to carry
Gross income is then: over to a more general setting. Thus, the
effects of changes in the penalty rate and
[12] W = w0H + w1h, the probability of detection turn out, on
reasonable assumptions,13 to have the
where w0 is the wage rate in the regular same signs as they have in the A–S model;
labor market and w1 is the wage paid for an increased penalty rate as well as an in-
black market work. The final step of the creased risk of detection both tend to deter
extension is to identify black market earn- tax evasion. Moreover, the compensated
ings with the amount of income evaded, effect on regular labor supply of a change
so that: in the marginal tax rate is negative, just as
in the standard model. Does a high mar-
[13] E = w1h. ginal tax rate encourage black market la-
bor? Here it becomes even clearer than in
Consumption in the two states of non– the A–S model that the theoretical answer
detection and detection can then be writ- must necessarily be ambiguous. Even if
ten as: we neglect the income effects, a reduction
of hours in the regular market must be
[14] Y = (1 – t)w0H + w1h, and accompanied by increased hours either in
black market labor or in leisure, but the
[15] Z = (1 – t)w0H + (1 – θ)w1h. model cannot predict how the increased
hours will be divided between the two
Note that we take the two wage rates as types of activity. The marginal tax rate ef-
exogenously given; we return to the ques- fects on evasion and black market activity
tion of tax incidence below. remain indeterminate in the sense that no
Maximizing expected utility [10] subject clear empirical hypothesis emerges from
to the budget constraints [14] and [15] the theoretical model.14
and the time constraint [11] leads to first A different type of model was for-
order conditions that can be subjected to mulated by Pestieau and Possen (1991),
comparative statics analysis. I will not go who studied the connection between
into the details of this, which easily gets tax evasion and occupational choice.
quite complicated. Instead I will simply Individuals can choose between being
summarize a few insights that one can wage–earners, who have no opportuni-

13
This is based on the results in Sandmo (1981, especially pp. 269–75), although the interpretations are not spelled
out in detail there.
14
A similar conclusion was reached by Pencavel (1979) on the basis of a model with the special assumption of
additive preferences but with a more general income tax schedule. See also Baldry (1979).

652
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

ties for tax evasion, and entrepreneurs, regular labor market? These are questions
who do. The stricter the enforcement of that so far have received little attention in
the tax law becomes, the smaller becomes the theoretical literature.
the fraction of the population that chooses In an otherwise competitive setting, it is
to become entrepreneurs. A rather differ- natural to think about the incidence effects
ent perspective on this issue is in Kolm of the hidden economy in the following
and Larsen (2004), where only manual manner: When firms and consumers hire
workers are assumed to have access to black market labor, it must be because it is
the black labor market. In their model, cheaper; gross wages must be lower than
stricter measures against the black labor in the regular economy. Moreover, when
market lead more manual workers to get individuals supply labor to the black
an education. These may appear to be economy, it must be because it pays them
rather different stories about tax evasion to do so; net wages must be higher than
and occupational choice, but how differ- in the regular economy. Consequently, we
ent they are obviously depends on how should expect the private gains from tax
one identifies real–life occupations with evasion to be divided between employ-
theoretical concepts like “entrepreneurs” ers and workers, and the more precise
and “manual workers.” The general mes- nature of this division must depend on
sage is clearly that a stricter enforcement the demand and supply elasticities, just
policy may affect tax compliance via the as in the standard theory of tax incidence.
incentives to choose occupations where However, in this context the elasticities
the opportunities to evade taxes or engage do not simply reflect preferences and
in black market activities are fewer. productivity; if the two parts of the market
produce the same goods and use the same
technology, the risk aspects of the situa-
INCIDENCE EFFECTS OF THE
tion will be crucial in the determination
HIDDEN ECONOMY
of incidence.
Theoretical analyses of tax evasion in As an example of the special features
the context of black market work focus of incidence analysis relating to the hid-
on the labor supply decision. But there den economy, consider the proposition
can be no activity in the “hidden” labor familiar from the standard analysis that
market unless there is also a demand for the real incidence of taxes is independent
labor there. The demand for labor comes of the formal incidence. This implies that
partly from other consumers who are a shift of the tax on labor from income to
interested in the short–term employment payroll taxation, provided that the tax
of someone to paint their house or repair bases are the same, should not have any
their car, and partly from firms that wish effect on wages and employment. Taking
to exploit the advantages of hiring labor at account of tax evasion changes this result.
“net of tax” wage rates.15 Taking account Since the probability of detection may be
of both the supply and demand side of the different for workers and employers, a
market for black labor raises the problem change of the tax base—i.e., of the formal
of tax incidence. What are the effects of incidence of the tax—may lead to a dif-
the income tax rate, the penalty rate and ferent balance between regular and black
the probability of detection on wages in labor markets with implications for gross
the black labor market and how do these wages and the level of employment. A
effects spread to wage formation in the related point is that the incidence also

15
These net of tax wage rates may reflect both the fact that the workers are not reporting their earnings and that
the firm does not report their employment, thus evading the payroll tax.

653
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

depends on the legal responsibility for does not vary with income. There is em-
truthful reporting; does this rest only on pirical evidence to indicate that evasion
the seller of black market labor, or does the is higher from income from independent
buyer also carry some share of it? business than for wage income, and it
In order to understand the demand for may also be the case that high–income
labor in the hidden economy, there is also people spend more resources on efforts to
a need to understand the risks faced by conceal their true income. If this is true,
the employer. Firms that operate in the the presence of tax evasion could change
labor market of the hidden economy on a a proportional statutory income tax into
regular commercial basis violate the law a regressive one or reduce the effective
and run the risk of legal sanctions. Private degree of progression.16
consumers who employ black labor may
realize that they have less security of
EVASION BY FIRMS
contract than in the regular market, and
this risk comes in addition to whatever The formal models surveyed so far all
risks they run of sanctions imposed by concern evasion by individual taxpayers,
the tax authorities. In a more general while the role of firms has been very much
incidence analysis, these considerations in the background. I have briefly noted the
should be integrated with the analysis possible role of firms in the black labor
above. A more general analysis should market, but firms could also have a more
also go beyond the labor market and independent role in tax evasion activities
study the effects of the black economy as evaders of indirect taxes for which they
on relative prices of goods and services: act as tax collectors for the government.
Does competition between the two sectors This role was first studied in a theoreti-
drive down the prices of services that are cal framework by Marrelli (1984), who
typically produced in the black economy? extended the A–S model to the case of
Kesselman (1989) studies such problems a risk–averse firm and established com-
in a two–sector general equilibrium model parative statics results similar in nature to
in the Harberger tradition and finds that those of the A–S model.17
relative price effects tend to modify the ef- Marrelli explicitly studied the case of an
fects on evasion of changes in the marginal ad valorem tax which was not seen in the
tax rate on income. context of the value–added system. The
Another area of great importance con- value–added system has a self–policing
cerns the effects of evasion on the personal property in that buyers of intermediate
income distribution. The A–S model sug- goods have opposing interests to the sell-
gests that evasion increases with gross ers, and this reduces the scope for indirect
income, while the effect on the fraction of tax evasion. The main problem with indi-
income evaded depends on relative risk rect tax evasion may, therefore, be at the
aversion (Allingham and Sandmo, 1972, final stage of production, i.e., at the sale
p. 329); e.g., if relative risk aversion is con- of final goods and services to consumers.
stant, the fraction of income evaded will It is also of potential importance for areas
be constant. However, this result assumes like environmental taxes, where taxes on
that the perceived probability of detection emissions may be evaded by the polluter;

16
E.g., in the model of Persson and Wissén (1984), which is a direct extension of the A–S model, there is a linear
progressive tax system; in spite of this, taxation may become regressive when evasion is taken into account.
Slemrod (1998) argues that the reduced progressivity that followed from the American tax reforms of the 1980s
led to more income being reported by high–income taxpayers.
17
Marrelli and Martina (1988) is a further extension of the results to an oligopolistic market with strategic
interaction between firms.

654
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

for details and references to the earlier and the penalty function. It is interesting
literature on this, see Sandmo (2002). to note that a similar result holds if the
There is one result in the theory of firm firm is risk averse and maximizes the
evasion of indirect taxes that is particularly expected utility of profit instead of just
interesting and concerns the separability expected profit. In that case, condition
of production and evasion decisions. This [17] still holds; it remains optimal for the
can be illustrated in a simple model of a firm to set marginal cost, inclusive of tax,
competitive firm, which produces a single equal to the consumer price. Risk aver-
output in the amount x, sells it at a tax– sion only modifies condition [18], making
inclusive price Q and pays a specific tax τ the risk–averse firm evade less than its
per unit of output. It reports sales of x – e, risk–neutral counterpart for any given
where e is the amount of underreporting. level of output.
If discovered, the firm has to pay a fine Firms may not only evade the payment
θ(e) on the amount evaded such that θ’(e) of indirect taxes; they may also evade cor-
> τ (the marginal fine must be greater than porate income taxes, and this is possibly
the tax), and θ’’(e) > 0, so that the marginal of even greater practical significance. This
fine is increasing. Assuming that the firm problem has been examined in recent pa-
is risk neutral, expected profit is: pers by Chen and Chu (2002) and Crocker
and Slemrod (2003). These authors point
[16] επ = (1 – p)[Qx – c(x) – τ(x – e)] out that the theoretical framework of
the A–S model is likely to be inadequate
+ p[Qx – c(x) – τ(x – e) – θ(e)], in this context, since the separation of
ownership and control is essential for un-
where c(x) is the cost function and p as derstanding corporate tax evasion. They,
before, is the probability of detection. Tak- therefore, explicitly model the tax evasion
ing the derivatives of expected profit with decision in the context of the contractual
respect to x and e, the first order conditions relationship between the shareholders
for this problem can be written as: and the manager of the corporation. An
interesting result that emerges from the
[17] Q = c’(x) + τ, and analysis is that the effect of policies to
control evasion may depend crucially
[18] pθ’(e) = τ. on who is penalized—the corporation or
the manager. This type of result has no
The interesting feature of the firm’s counterpart in the previous literature and
optimum is that the output decision is indicates that this may be a promising new
independent of the probability of detec- area of research.
tion and the penalty function; equation
[17] determines output, while [18] deter-
FROM THE INDIVIDUAL TO THE
mines the amount of underreporting. An
AGGREGATE: TAX EVASION IN A
implication of this is that if the tax rate
SOCIAL CONTEXT
τ has been set with the aim of achieving
some specific policy objective, e.g., to Most of the theoretical literature on
achieve some reduction of the consump- tax evasion considers the decisions of a
tion of a good with negative external single individual, and empirical predic-
effects, the optimal tax rate is unaffected tions about the extent of tax evasion take
by the opportunities for evasion. The tax their points of departure from hypotheses
rate should be used to achieve the right derived from the comparative statics of
consumer price, while evasion should be the model of the individual taxpayer.
controlled by the probability of detection A more careful analysis would take the
655
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

aggregation problem more seriously and Another mechanism that could lead
base predictions on a model of many to similar results comes from the social
taxpayers, differing both with respect to conscience effect described in the sixth
their income and evasion opportunities. section. There is a disutility involved
But even such a model might not take in evading taxes, but it might be small-
adequate account of tax evasion as a er if it is perceived that many others
social phenomenon. There is empirical evade taxes also. If individual i’s per-
evidence to indicate that the amount of ception of the evasion of others were
tax evasion and black market behavior to increase, e.g., as a result of increased
differ substantially between countries,18 attention to these matters in the media,
and it is far from obvious that the differ- he might decide to evade more, which
ences can be satisfactorily explained by could again trigger more evasion by
tax and penalty parameters. Cowell (1990, others. The same is true of the social
ch. 6) considers a number of alternative stigma effect of the original A–S model;
explanations of tax evasion as a social the stigma attached to being caught for
phenomenon, requiring a theory of social tax evasion is less if this is a common
interaction. I will illustrate by considering occurrence.
two channels through which tax evasion This sketch of an analysis has elements
behavior might spread in a population of in common with Andvig and Moene’s
taxpayers. (1990) study of corruption. The main
In the A–S model with an endogenous point of their model is that it is individu-
probability of detection, it is assumed that ally more costly to be honest when cor-
the probability of detection increases with ruption is common. Similarly, it may be
the amount that one evades. But how does less risky to evade taxes when evasion
the taxpayer form his views about this is widespread. At a more general level,
probability? One source of information the analysis is related to that of Schelling
about the probability is the taxpayer’s own (1978), who studies externality models
observations of other taxpayers; he may with multiple equilibria in which small
have observed neighbors or colleagues changes in parameter values may lead to
who work in the black economy and ap- large changes in the equilibrium values of
parently get away with it. This means that the endogenous variables.
we could write the taxpayer’s subjective
probability of detection as a function both
ISSUES OF OPTIMAL TAXATION
of his own evasion and of his perceived
amounts of evasion by others. Suppose The two main elements in a model of
now that his perception of the amount optimal taxation are the social welfare
evaded by others increases. His subjec- function and the government budget
tive probability of detection falls, and he, constraint. The optimal taxation prob-
therefore, decides to evade more. Others lem is posed as that of choosing a set
now perceive that he evades more and, of tax instruments that maximize social
therefore, evade more themselves. It is welfare subject to a government budget
not difficult to see that this kind of social constraint. The budget constraint often
process could involve multiple market takes the simple form of requiring a given
equilibria, either with high or low evasion, tax revenue; more generally, tax revenue
with only small differences in the tax and should be equal to government expendi-
penalty incentives. ture on goods and services, which could

18
For a recent survey and further references, see Schneider and Klinglmair (2004).

656
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

also be subject to optimization within the implied that tax revenue will be uncertain
same model.19 also. An apparent solution to this prob-
To extend the usual analysis of optimal lem is to write the government’s budget
taxation to take account of tax evasion constraint in terms of expected values,
raises some problems for both of these but this is inconsistent with a general
elements. As regards the social welfare equilibrium formulation. If ex post it turns
function, the problem arises with respect out that revenue is less than expenditure,
to the principle of consumer sovereignty then the deficit must be financed in some
or the Pareto principle. We usually take it way, e.g., by tax increases or public bor-
for granted that the social welfare func- rowing. But then those methods of finance
tion should be increasing in individual should have been part of the optimization
utilities. Now suppose that there occurs problem from the start.
an exogenous “improvement”—from the The essence of models of optimal
point of view of the tax evader—in the taxation is to clarify the respective roles
opportunities to evade taxes, so that the of equity and efficiency considerations in
probability of detection falls. The imme- the design of tax systems. A framework
diate effect of this is to raise the expected in which the equity–efficiency tradeoff
utility of all tax evaders. Should this count becomes particularly transparent is that
as a welfare improvement? It is obviously of choosing an optimal linear income tax,
realistic to assume that increases in the as in Sandmo (1981). The model has two
expected utility of the tax evaders will be groups of taxpayers: the evaders (or, more
accompanied by decreases in utility on the accurately, the potential evaders) and the
part of the non–evaders; in this particular non–evaders. The non–evaders’ behavior
example, the non–evaders might, e.g., is modelled as in the standard textbook
have to pay more taxes. But the basic issue analysis of labor supply, while the evad-
remains the same: When aggregating wel- ers are described by the sixth–section
fare gains and losses across individuals, model.20 The social welfare function is
should the gains from evasion count on a the utilitarian weighted sum of utilities,
par with the gains from other economic where the weights can be varied to give
activities? Some thought will have to be more or less importance to the utility of
given to this problem before one formu- the evaders. The problem related to the
lates a model of optimal taxation with government budget constraint is solved
tax evasion. by assuming that the evaders’ subjective
The problem with regard to the gov- probability of detection is equal to the
ernment budget constraint is of a more actual frequency of audit—an empirically
technical nature and lies in the fact that dubious but analytically useful simplifica-
the standard formulation consists in as- tion. There is assumed to be an exogenous
suming that tax revenue should be equal revenue requirement and, in addition, the
to public expenditure. If taxpayers try government needs resources to cover the
to evade taxes and their evasion is only administrative costs of the tax system,
discovered with some probability, it is which in this context is simply equal to

19
An early contribution in this area is Kolm (1973), who wrote of the A–S analysis, ”...this is hardly public
economics; in fact, it is very private.” Extending the analysis to take account of the utility of public goods,
Kolm studied the government’s optimal choice of deterrence instruments subject to a government budget
constraint.
20
Cremer and Gahvari (1994) have an alternative formulation of the model in which they assume that taxpay-
ers can spend resources on lowering the probability of detection, and this is reflected in their formula for the
optimal tax rate.

657
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

the costs of discovering tax evasion. For- pushes labor from the more–distorted to
mally, the model can be written as follows. the less–distorted sector may represent
Choose the parameters of a linear income an efficiency gain to the economy. From
tax, the penalty rate and the probability of one point of view, this makes economic
detection that maximize the social welfare sense. However, it also raises some
function: questions about the fundamental assump-
tions of a model that turns “antisocial”
[19] W = NnγnVn + NeγeVe, behavior into a social gain. These are to
be found in the social welfare function,
where N n and N e are the numbers of but it is not easy to see which alterna-
non–evaders and evaders, Vn and Ve are tive assumptions would lead to more
their expected utilities, and γ n and γ e are palatable conclusions. Slemrod and Yit-
the social welfare weights. The maximiza- zhaki (2002), commenting on a similar
tion is subject to the government budget discussion by Cowell (1990), conclude
constraint, which is: that “in our opinion no convincing alter-
native that provides reasonable policy
[20] R = R0 + φ(p)Ne. prescriptions has yet been presented”
(p. 1447).
Here R is revenue as a function of the How high should the penalties be?
policy instruments, R0 is the fixed rev- One possible answer to this is that the
enue requirement, and the last term is penalty rate and the frequency of audits
administrative cost as a function of the should be chosen so as to maximize tax
frequency of audits (which again is equal revenue. In the present model this pre-
to the probability of detection). scription turns out to be correct only for
What are the types of questions that the special case of γ e = 0. This is the case
this model can answer? Perhaps the most where no weight is given to the evaders’
immediate question would be whether utility, and the optimal tax problem is to
the optimal marginal tax rate is lower choose that policy which maximizes the
because of tax evasion. Implicitly at least, utility of the non–evaders. This case is
this is often maintained in policy discus- clearly not without interest. If you believe
sions when it is claimed that a higher tax that it is the rich who evade taxes, you
rate encourages evasion. Here we already might take the Rawlsian view that anti–
know from the model of the individual evasion policy should aim to maximize
taxpayer that theory does not offer a the utility of the poor non–evaders. 22
clear prediction, but even if one believes The non–evaders’ interest in deterring
that a high marginal tax rate encourages evasion lies in the net revenue to be had
evasion, the optimum tax analysis does from the penalties; the higher this is, the
not yield a clear conclusion in favor of a lower will the regular income tax be. But
lower tax rate.21 The clue to understand- in a more general analysis, where the
ing this ambiguity is the insight that the evaders’ utility is taken into account, the
black labor market is less distorted than conclusions must be modified to lower
the regular one, and a tax increase that both the penalty rate and the frequency

21
Cremer and Gahvari (1994) show that the optimum marginal tax rate is lower with tax evasion, provided
that the social welfare function displays inequality aversion, but the result depends on their assumption that
the individual utility function is quasi–linear in consumption, so that taxpayers are risk neutral. See also the
analysis of this issue in Schroyen (1997).
22
Alternatively, one might conceivably take the view that only the welfare of the honest should count in the
social welfare function.

658
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

of audit from their revenue–maximizing This discussion of the optimal taxation


levels.23 problem has solely been concerned with
There is also an issue of horizontal income tax evasion. The optimal indirect
equity involved here. Suppose that you tax problem has been studied by Cremer
believe that people with income from and Gahvari (1993), who show how the
independent business are more likely to Ramsey conditions have to be modified
evade income, so you identify them with when the extent of tax evasion differs
the evaders of the model, in contrast to across commodities. Under some condi-
the non–evading wage earners. One rea- tions, they show that the optimal statu-
son for not trying to extract a maximum tory rate will be higher for commodities
of tax revenue from the former group is subject to evasion; however, the optimal
that by so doing you might come to inflict effective (or expected) rate is lower for
heavy punishment on a small subgroup of such commodities.
people for violations of the tax law com-
mitted by a much larger group. This might
CONCLUDING REMARKS: LESSONS
have some positive incentive effects, but
FOR POLICY AND FURTHER
if one has inequality aversion, it is also
RESEARCH
a policy with rather unattractive equity
characteristics.24 One should obviously be careful about
This framework of analysis is based drawing policy conclusions from the
on two simplifying assumptions: first theoretical literature in an area where our
that the tax system is linear and second empirical knowledge is by necessity so
that the probability of detection is the uncertain. Let me, nevertheless, hazard
same for all taxpayers. A more general some tentative conclusions.
set of assumptions is to allow for non– The first is based on the theoretical in-
linear taxation and a probability of sight that the probability of detection (the
detection that depends on reported frequency of audits) and the penalty for
income, and this approach has been evasion are policy substitutes. If one wish-
taken by, among others, Chander and es to achieve a given degree of deterrence,
Wilde (1998) and Marhuenda and this may be achieved by high probabilities
Ortuño–Ortín (1997). An interesting and low penalties or by low probabilities
insight that emerges from these papers and high penalties. The concern for low
is that there is a tradeoff between induc- costs of tax administration leads one to
ing truthful reporting and achieving favor the second alternative; this was
progressive taxation; in order to achieve Becker’s (1968) argument in his analysis
truthful reporting, the optimal tax sched- of the economics of crime. However, such
ule must be regressive. This can be seen a policy might lead to unacceptable high
as an extension of the results in the classic penalties for a few for violations commit-
Mirrlees (1971) study of optimal income ted by many, a horizontal equity argument
taxation. neglected by Becker.25 A counterargument

23
Penalties could also be set above their revenue–maximizing level, with unfortunate consequences for social
efficiency, as pointed out by Adam Smith in Book V, Part II, of the Wealth of Nations: “...by the forfeitures and
other penalties which those unfortunate individuals incur who attempt unsuccessfully to evade the tax, it
may frequently ruin them, and thereby put an end to the benefit which the community might have received
from the employment of their capitals” (Smith 1776; 1976, p. 826).
24
The equity aspects of tax enforcement have been analyzed in more depth by Boadway and Sato (2000).
25
An additional complication is that some violations of the law may be committed by ignorance and mistakes,
a point made by Stern (1978) in a general evaluation of the Becker model.

659
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

might be that one could then just set pen- such effects could be of considerable
alties so high that nobody would evade importance.
taxes. But for penalties to be socially ac- One perspective on tax evasion and the
ceptable, they probably must be set so that hidden economy that merits more atten-
in the eyes of the general public, they “fit tion is that of positive political economy.
the crime.” In this regard, the optimum The normative public economics approach
tax analysis of the eleventh section may of deriving optimal policies to control tax
be a bit simplistic in assuming that the evasion is clearly relevant and important,
optimal penalty can be set independently but it is also of major interest to achieve
of the regular tax rate. a better understanding of the political
Is the existence of tax evasion an argu- and economic forces that determine the
ment for a lower marginal tax rate? We policies that we actually observe. It is,
have seen that the optimal tax analysis e.g., not obvious that the low degree of
does not offer any clear conclusion on enforcement of the tax law in some sec-
this point, and my own inclination is to tors or countries is entirely due to cost
say that, at least as long as tax evasion is considerations; it may also be because the
not an overwhelming social problem, the electorate is actually against attempts to
choice of the marginal tax rate should be achieve a higher rate of compliance. The
governed by the more standard efficiency reasons underlying such resistance may
and equity concerns. The penalty and be several, reflecting both judgements of
audit rate are instruments better targeted the overall fairness of the tax system and
on the decision to evade taxes. people’s self–interest in a lax enforcement
The tax evasion decision may depend policy, either as sellers or buyers of black
on the individual taxpayer ’s percep- market services. This is clearly a promis-
tions of the behavior of others. The more ing field for further research.
widespread evasion is, the more socially
acceptable it may become, and the lower
Acknowledgments
is the subjective probability of it being de-
tected. This is a good reason for trying to This paper was prepared for the Nor-
control evasion; relaxing policy measures dic Workshop on Tax Policy and Public
in this area may unleash mechanisms Economics in Helsinki, November 2004,
that lead to a much lower level of tax while an earlier version was presented at
compliance. the Research Forum on Taxation in Rosen-
What are the main issues that still await dal, Norway, June 2003. I am indebted to
theoretical clarification? Taking a broad Joel Slemrod for helpful comments on
view of the literature, one is struck by the original version, and to the referees of
the theoretical focus on the evasion of this Journal for a number of constructive
labor earnings. While empirical evidence suggestions.
seems to indicate rather strongly that
non–compliance is of greater quantitative
REFERENCES
importance in income from capital and
independent business, this has not so far Allingham, Michael G., and Agnar Sandmo.
left a strong mark on theory in the area. “Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analy-
A related point is that the theory has paid sis.” Journal of Public Economics 1 No. 3/4
little attention to the general equilibrium (November, 1972): 323–38.
effects on relative prices of consumer Andreoni, James, Brian Erard, and Jonathan
goods and the implications for the struc- Feinstein.
ture of industry, although in countries “Tax Compliance.” Journal of Economic Litera-
where the underground economy is large, ture 36 No. 2 (June, 1998): 818–60.
660
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

Andvig, Jens C., and Karl O. Moene. Cowell, Frank A.


“How Corruption May Corrupt.” Journal of Cheating the Government. Cambridge, MA:
Economic Behavior and Organization 13 No. 1 MIT Press, 1990.
(January, 1990): 63–76. Cowell, Frank A.
Arrow, Kenneth J. “Sticks and Carrots.” London School of
Essays in the Theory of Risk–Bearing. Amster- Economics. Mimeo, 2002.
dam: North–Holland, 1974. Cremer, Helmuth, and Firouz Gahvari.
Baldry, Jonathan C. “Tax Evasion and Optimal Commodity
“Tax Evasion and Labor Supply.” Economics Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 50 No.
Letters 3 No. 1 (1979): 53–6. 2 (February, 1993): 261–75.
Barth, Erling, Alexander W. Cappelen, and Cremer, Helmuth, and Firouz Gahvari.
Tone Ognedal. “Tax Evasion, Concealment and the Optimal
“Fair Tax Evasion.” Department of Econom- Linear Income Tax.” Scandinavian Journal of
ics, University of Oslo. Mimeo, 2005. Economics 96 No. 2 (1994): 219–39.
Becker, Gary S. Crocker, Keith J., and Joel Slemrod.
“Crime and Punishment: An Economic Ap- “Corporate Tax Evasion with Agency Costs.”
proach.” Journal of Political Economy 76 No. University of Michigan Business School.
2 (March–April, 1968): 169–217. Mimeo, 2003.
Bernasconi, Michele. Frey, Bruno, and Lars P. Feld.
“Tax Evasion and Orders of Risk Aversion.” “Deterrence and Morale in Taxation: An
Journal of Public Economics 67 No. 1 (January, Empirical Analysis.” Working Paper No.
1998): 123–34. 760. Munich: CESifo, 2002.
Boadway, Robin, and Motohiro Sato. Gordon, James, P. F.
“The Optimality of Punishing Only the Inno- “Individual Morality and Reputation
cent: The Case of Tax Evasion.” International Costs as Deterrence to Tax Evasion.” Euro-
Tax and Public Finance 7 No. 6 (December, pean Economic Review 33 No. 4 (April, 1989):
2000): 641–64. 797–805.
Bordignon, Massimo. Kesselman, Jonathan R.
“A Fairness Approach to Income Tax Eva- “Income Tax Evasion: An Intersectoral
sion.” Journal of Public Economics 52 No. 3 Analysis.” Journal of Public Economics 38 No.
(October, 1993): 345–62. 2 (March, 1989): 137–82.
Chander, Parkash, and Louis L. Wilde. Kolm, Ann–Sofie, and Birthe Larsen.
“A General Characterization of Optimal In- “Does Tax Evasion Affect Unemployment
come Tax Enforcement.” Review of Economic and Educational Choice?” Institute for
Studies 65 No. 1 (January, 1998): 165–83. Labor Market Policy Evaluation. Working
Chen, Kong–Ping, and C. Y. Cyrus Chu. Paper No. 4. Uppsala: Uppsala University,
“Internal Control vs. External Manipulation: 2004.
A Model of Corporate Income Tax Evasion.” Kolm, Serge–Christophe.
Institute for Social Sciences and Philosophy, “A Note on Optimum Tax Evasion.” Journal
Academia Sinica, Taipei. Mimeo, 2002. of Public Economics 2 No. 3 (July, 1973):
Christiansen, Vidar. 265–70.
“Two Comments on Tax Evasion.” Journal Marhuenda, Francisco, and Ignacio
of Public Economics 13 No. 3 (June, 1980): Ortuño–Ortín.
389–401. “Tax Enforcement Problems.” Scandinavian
Clotfelter, Charles T. Journal of Economics 99 No. 1 (1997): 61–72.
“Tax Evasion and Tax Rates: An Analysis Marrelli, Massimo.
of Individual Returns.” Review of Econom- “On Indirect Tax Evasion.” Journal of Public
ics and Statistics 65 No. 3 (August, 1983): Economics 25 No. 1/2 (November, 1984):
363–73. 181–96.
661
NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

Marrelli, Massimo, and Riccardo Martina. Schneider, Friedrich, and Dominik H. Enste.
“Tax Evasion and Strategic Behavior of the “Shadow Economies: Size, Causes, and Con-
Firms.” Journal of Public Economics 37 No. 1 sequences.” Journal of Economic Literature 38
(October, 1988): 55–69. No. 1 (March, 2000): 77–114.
McCaffery, Edward J., and Joel Slemrod. Schneider, Friedrich, and Robert Klinglmair.
“Toward an Agenda for Behavioral Public “Shadow Economies Around the World:
Finance.” CLEO Research Paper Series. Los What Do We Know?” Working Paper No.
Angeles: University of Southern California 1167. Munich: CESifo, 2004.
Law School, 2004. Schroyen, Fred.
Mirrlees, James A. “Pareto Efficient Income Taxation Under
“An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Costly Monitoring.” Journal of Public Eco-
Income Taxation.” Review of Economic Studies nomics 65 No. 3 (September, 1997): 343–66.
38 No. 2 (April, 1971): 175–208. Slemrod, Joel.
Pencavel, John H. “How Costly Is a Large, Redistributive Pub-
“A Note on Income Tax Evasion, Labor Sup- lic Sector?” Swedish Economic Policy Review 5
ply, and Nonlinear Tax Schedules.” Journal No. 1 (Spring, 1998): 87–105.
of Public Economics 12 No. 1 (August, 1979): Slemrod, Joel, and Shlomo Yitzhaki.
115–24. “Tax Avoidance, Evasion and Administra-
Persson, Mats, and Pehr Wissén. tion.” In Handbook of Public Economics,
“Redistributional Aspects of Tax Evasion.” Volume 3, edited by Alan J. Auerbach and
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 86 No. 2 Martin Feldstein, 1423–70. Amsterdam:
(1984): 131–49. Elsevier Science, 2002.
Pestieau, Pierre, and Uri M. Possen. Smith, Adam.
“Tax Evasion and Occupational Choice.” An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Journal of Public Economics 45 No. 1 (June, Wealth of Nations. London: Strahan and
1991): 107–25. Cadell, 1776. Glasgow Bicentenary Edition,
Reinganum, Jennifer F., and Louis L. Wilde. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976.
“Income Tax Compliance in a Principal– Srinivasan, T. N.
Agent Framework.” Journal of Public Econom- “Tax Evasion: A Model.” Journal of Public Eco-
ics 26 No. 1 (February, 1985): 1–18. nomics 2 No. 4 (November, 1973): 339–46.
Reinganum, Jennifer F., and Louis L. Wilde. Stern, Nicholas.
“Equilibrium Verification and Reporting “On the Economic Theory of Policy Towards
Policies in a Model of Tax Compliance.” Crime.” In Economic Models of Criminal Be-
International Economic Review 27 No. 3 (Oc- havior, edited by John M. Heineke, 123–52.
tober, 1986): 739–60. Amsterdam: North–Holland, 1978.
Sandmo, Agnar. Yitzhaki, Shlomo.
“Income Tax Evasion, Labor Supply, and “A Note on ‘Income Tax Evasion: A Theoreti-
the Equity–Efficiency Tradeoff.” Journal of cal Analysis.’ ” Journal of Public Economics 3
Public Economics 16 No. 3 (December, 1981): No. 2 (May, 1974): 201–2.
265–88.
Sandmo, Agnar.
“Efficient Environmental Policy with Im- APPENDIX
perfect Compliance.” Environmental and This appendix derives the expressions for
Resource Economics 23 No. 1 (September, the income effect on tax evasion and the tax
2002): 85–103. rate derivative in equation [6].
Schelling, Thomas. Starting from the first–order condition [4], we
Micromotives and Macrobehavior. New York: note that the second–order derivative has to be
Norton, 1978. negative for a maximum. This implies that:

662
The Theory of Tax Evasion: A Retrospective View

[A1] (1 – p)U’’(Y)t2 + pU’’(Z)(θ – t)2 = D < 0. so that ∂E/∂W > 0, proving the assertion in
the text.
Now differentiate the first–order condition The expression [6] for the tax rate effect is
with respect to W: derived by differentiating equation [4] with
respect to t. We then obtain:
[A2] (1 – p)U’’(Y)[(1 – t) + t(∂E/∂W)]t
[A6] (1 – p(U’(Y) + pU’(Z) + (1 – p)U’’(Y)[–W
– pU’’(Z)[(1 – t) – (θ – t)(∂E/∂W)]
+ E + t(∂E/∂t)]t – pU’’(Z)[–W + E
(θ – t) = 0.
–(θ – t)(∂E/∂t)](θ – t) = 0.
Collecting terms and inserting D as defined
by [A1], we can rewrite this expression as: Inserting the expression for D and collecting
terms, we have that:
[A3] D(∂E/∂W) = –(1 – p)U’’(Y)(1 – t)t

+ pU’’(Z)(1 – t)(θ – t). [A7] ∂E/∂t = (1/D)(W – E)[(1 – p)U’’(Y)t

–pU’’(Z)(θ – t)] – (1/D)[(1 – p)U’(Y)


Define the coefficient of absolute risk aver-
sion, RA, as the negative of the ratio of the + pU’(Z)].
second and first derivative of the utility func-
tion; for the properties of this coefficient as We now substitute in the first term on
a measure of risk aversion, see Arrow (1974, the left for the expression for ∂E/∂W in [A3].
Essay 3). Thus, we have that: Defining:

[A4] RA(Y) = –U’’(Y)/U’(Y) and [A8] S = –(1/D)[(1 – p)U’(Y) + pU’(Z)],

RA(Z) = –U’’(Z)/U’(Z). we then get:

Using this definition and the equality of the


[A9] ∂E/∂t = –[(W – E)/(1 – t)](∂E/∂W) + S,
two terms in [4], we can rewrite [A3] as:

which is equation [6] in the main text.


[A5] ∂E/∂W = (1/D)(1 – p)U’(Y)(1 – t)t[RA(Y)
The expressions for the effects of increas-
– RA(Z)]. es in θ and p can be derived by using the
same procedure as above; this is left as an
Decreasing absolute risk aversion implies exercise.
that the expression in brackets is negative,

663

Вам также может понравиться