Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 19

Competition Law in digital

markets in the era of the


Big Data
Final essay of Salvatore Maraventano for the
LL.M. in International Trade Law: Contracts and
Dispute Resolution
1.Introduction...........................................................................................................3
1.Economic structure of digital markets...............................................................3
2.Free goods and Big Data...................................................................................4
2.Competition in digital markets..............................................................................7
1.Value of competition in digital markets.............................................................7
2.Competition and disruptive innovation.............................................................7
3.The debate on “a more technological approach”...............................................8
3.Application of competition law to digital markets..............................................10
1.Relevant market: multi-sided markets and indirect network effect.................10
2.Lock-in, low switching costs and multi-homing.............................................12
4.Big Data and Competition...................................................................................13
1.The importance of data in digital markets.......................................................13
2. Applicability of the essential facility doctrine................................................14
Bibliography...........................................................................................................17
1. Introduction

1. Economic structure of digital markets

Since the beginning of the so-called digital economy, the development of digital
markets has shown unique and peculiar features which make these markets
dramatically different from traditional ones.

The growth of digital markets players is incredibly fast and rapid, companies like
Amazon and Google have witnessed a growth rate that has always been
impossible in traditional markets. The competition game tends to be a winner-
takes-all one, where a player reaching a dominant position is able to enforce its
position and prevent the entrance in the market of other competitors. However,
this monopolization is someway toned down by the fact that in digital markets,
innovation is often disruptive and, thus, monopolistic companies may lose their
revenues for the rise, from one day to another, of a substitutable product or
service.

These features have been deeply analysed by many economists in the view of
reaching a better understanding of the structure of digital markets, which are
constantly getting more importance and relevance in the economy1.

The tendency of digital markets to be highly concentrated is based mainly on one


factor: the network effect.

Before explaining what the network effect is and how it affects the digital markets
structure, it has to be considered that most digital services are offered through
platforms where users do not exclusively interact with the service provider but
also with each other. Since cooperation between users has a great importance in
the digital economy, the utility the users are able to take from a service provider is
related to the number of the users of the platform itself. Thus, the network effect is
the tendency of the users to choose the platform which has many users. In this

1 The most relevant economic models are summerized by Jonathan D. Levin in


‘The Economics of Internet Markets’, NBER Working Paper No. 16852, (2011).
way, digital markets players easily lock-in their users and reduce margin
competition in the market. 2

Due to the network effect and to the high investment required by digital markets,
potential competitors face big barriers to entry. The only possible strategy to
breach the position of a monopolized player in digital markets is to invest a
discouraging amount of resources in marketing. Most of the time, it is simply not
worth.

However, the concentration tendency of digital markets is somehow


counterbalanced by two other factors: the disruptive innovation and the low
switching costs.

Innovation in digital markets is often disruptive, in the sense that new


technologies are able to dethrone big monopolistic players from their position not
attacking it in its market but creating a new innovative one which is able to satisfy
the same demand. An example of how monopolistic players have been just erased
in this way, is what happened to MSN Messenger and MySpace with the arrive of
Facebook. MSN Messenger was an instant messaging service with a strong
position in its market. MySpace had a similar position in the market of personal
blogs. When these two services were at the top of their success, Facebook was
launched, creating a whole new market: the market of social network, where users
could both use instant messaging, blogging and finding each other. A couple of
years later, MSN Messenger and MySpace were almost dead.

On the other hand, very often the monopolistic trend of digital markets is
counterbalanced by the low switching costs. The value users lose when they
switch from a digital service to another is often very low or null. The case of the
search engines is emblematic: a user which is usually using Google for online
searches does not face any switching cost if he start using the Bing search engine.

2. Free goods and Big Data

In the last ten years the number of services and products offered without requiring
the users to pay a fee has grown enormously. This has been made possible by two

2 J. D. Levin ‘The Economics of Internet Markets’, NBER Working Paper No.


16852 (2011), p. 4-8.
main factors: the first is the reduction of the incremental costs due to the changes
in the way of production and distribution of the information, the second is the new
value acquired by personal data for the economy3.

If the first factor, the reduction of the incremental cost, does not imply a radical
change in the traditional market paradigms since it is a common and well known
tendency of the innovation on the production processes, the value acquired by
personal data is something completely new requiring a deep analysis.

Personal data are, today, a key feature of digital markets since it is through
personal data that market players are able to monetize their businesses. Personal
data gathered by digital companies are used and re-used for so many purposes
(including personalization of services, targeted marketing, etc.) that data are now
considered as the currency of the digital age.

The importance acquired by data lead to an incredibly fast improvement of the


technologies allowing the elaboration and the storage of such data. Such
technologies and the possibilities open by it are usually referred to with the term
“Big Data”, which is always more frequently addressed as a key feature for the
success of a broad range of activities, from business to public administration4.

Today, processing and storing Big Data represent a way bigger added value
compared to what was processing and storing data few years ago. It is not only
possible to store and process bigger volume of data, but also to analyse them
through forecast models and algorithms, making it the most powerful tool of
information5.

This huge amount of data, the “Big Data”, are gathered by digital services
providers. Google, which is the biggest player in digital markets, is able to easily
hold its dominant position due to the incredible amount of data it is able to gather
and then, eventually, reuse or resell.

3 M. S. Gal and D. L. Rubinfeld, ‘The Hidden Costs of Free Goods: Implications


for Antitrust Enforcement’, NYU Law& Economics Research Paper Series
Working Paper NO. 14-44 (2015).
4 J. M. Cavanillas, E. Curry, W. Wahlster, ‘New horizon for a Data-Driven
Economy’, Springer (2016), p. 3.
5 Monopolies Commission of Germany, 'Competition policy: The challenge of
digital market', Special Report no 68 (2015).
It is self evident that this new relevance of Big Data is able to influence the digital
markets structure and the way the competitors interact with each other. Thus,
digital markets, which were already very different in terms of competition and
market structure from traditional ones, became now, with the Big Data starting to
invade all field of business, even more peculiar from a competition point of view.
2. Competition in digital markets

1. Value of competition in digital markets

The goals and the foundations of competition law have always been disputed. If
competition has always been felt like a value to preserve in liberal market
economies, the reason of such protection has been subject to debate. European
competition law is traditionally oriented towards consumer protection and the
promotion of market integration between EU members. However, much criticism
has been brought to the methods of assessment of EU competition law violation
by the European Commission. Such criticism have been widely underlined in a
book edited by Schimdtchen, Albert and Voigt6, which opened a deep debate on
the tools used in competitive proceedings assessment by the European
competition authority. Such debate pushed the European Commission to follow a
more strictly economic approach and be more careful about economic efficiencies,
similarly to what the US Federal Trade Commission (FTC) has always done.

2. Competition and disruptive innovation

The growing importance of digital markets takes now a new challenge to


European competition policy. As reported in the Introduction, economic structure
of digital markets is different from the structure of traditional markets for which
the rules of competition law have been tailored for.

Whereas the monopolization of a market is not a violation per se, still the
presence of a monopoly is considered to be a negative feature of a market. Such
negative qualification, based on the economic approach adopted by competition
authorities, seems to ignore the possibilities of innovation in dynamics market
such as the digital ones7.

Digital markets are subject to rapid and, sometimes, disruptive innovation. If


traditional, even though rapid, innovation is to be considered the one which

6 D. Schimdtchen, M. Albert, S. Voigt, ‘The More Economic Approach to


European Competition Law’, Mohr Siebeck (2007).
7 R. Podszun; S. Kreifels, 'Digital platforms and competition law', EuCML 33,
(2016).
reduces incremental costs due to technological in a regular and predictable
manner, disruptive innovation is defined as “breakthroughs that bring radical
changes which were unforeseen by the market and occur irregularly”, often
destroying completely market shares of incumbent firms or creating a completely
new market8.

An example of this kind of disruptive innovation is the one regarding the way
Facebook dethroned the incumbent of MSN and Myspace, which were incumbent
in their own markets, through the creation of a completely new service and, thus,
a completely new market.

Another more recent example is the case of Spotify. Spotify is a software allowing
free on demand streaming of a big catalogue of music9. Spotify libraries includes
almost all main stream music, including new exit. Prior to the enter of Spotify in
the market, Apple’s Itunes, a digital platform distributing music for paid
download, was the leader in the market. Itunes it is now struggling to survive in
the market and, for this reason, Apple is now trying to slow down Spotify using its
power on side markets where Apple is dominant10.

Even though the disruptivness of the Spotify case is not based on a technological
improvements only, but mostly on a new revolutionary business model which
smartly leveraged on the poor situation of the mainstream music industry, it
clearly show how players in dominant positions may be subject to a fast and rapid
reduction of market share to the final disappear from the market. Thus in these
markets typical inefficiencies caused by monopolies are reduced.

3. The debate on “a more technological approach”

Such deep differences between digital markets and traditional ones, expecially
when it comes to assessing competition and its effects, led some academics to
open a debate about a new approach that should be used when applying

8 Competition Committee of the Directorate for financial and enterprise affairs of


the OECD, 'Hearing on disruptive innovation', DAF/COMP(2015)3, p. 2.
9 https://www.spotify.com/ (last access: 29/12/2016).
10 The competition between Apple and Spotify is proven by many recent
declarations coming from both sides. One and for all: (last access: 29/12/2016).
competition law to digital markets. Professor Rupprecth Podszun opened such
debate with a paper11 discussing the idea that competition authorities should find a
new approach as they did as a result of the debate regarding a more economic
approach. According to the thesis of Prof. Podszun, five core strategic points
should inform competition enforcement to adapt it to technological developments
and to the factual reality of digital markets12, namely:

1) Innovation should be put at the center of the analysis and each behaviour
on the markets should be assessed with innovation as first parameter.

2) The new economic phenomenon of digital markets should not be


compared and assessed in analogy with traditional economic phenomenon
but requires new concepts and a new terminology.

3) It should be recognized that competition law is not neutral.

4) The role of consumers should be reviewed since their position is not as


passive as it has always been.

5) The role of regulation should be reviewed in the light of the fact that
trends of digital markets are hardly foreseeable.

11 R. Pdozsun, ‘The More Technological Approach: Competition Law in the


Digital Economy’ in G. Surblitè (Ed.), 'Competition on the Internet', Springer
(2015).
12 R. Pdozsun, ‘The More Technological Approach: Competition Law in the
Digital Economy’ in G. Surblitè (Ed.), 'Competition on the Internet', Springer
(2015), p. 108.
3. Application of competition law to digital markets

1. Relevant market: multi-sided markets and indirect network effect

The first challenge of the application of competition law to digital markets is the
definition of the relevant market. The major issue comes up from the fact that
digital economy is mainly based on platforms acting as intermediaries between
different categories of users. If we take, for example, the Google search engine, it
is clear that it is a platform operating in a market which has more sides: one is the
side of the users of the search engine service and the other one is the market of the
advertisers.

Thus, digital markets are usually multi-sided markets, but tools so far developed
to define the relevant market for competition law purposes are not completely
efficient to include in such analysis the effect of the interplay between the
different sides of the market13.

The price on one side of the market cannot be set without affecting deeply the
supply and demand on another side of the market. For such reason, market power
on one side does not unilaterally means a dominant position, since an arbitrary
raise of the prices might lead to a reduction of the prices on the other side of the
market, nullifying the benefits for the incumbent14.

Whereas in one-sided market is the direct network effect having impact on the
competition process, in multi-sided markets network effects are defined as
indirect. Direct network effect, as explained in the introduction of this essay,
refers to the phenomenon according to which a service becomes more attractive as
the number of users of that service grows. Indirect network effect refers, on the
other hand, to the phenomenon according to which the number of users of one
side of a multi-sided market makes another side more attractive.

Some digital markets are subject only to direct network effect, some others only to
indirect one and others to both of them. Google search engine, for example, is

13 R. Podszun; S. Kreifels, 'Digital platforms and competition law', EuCML 33,


(2016), p. 2.
14 H. A. Shelanski, ‘Innovation, Information and Competition Policy for the
Internet’. University of Pennsylvania Law review, Vol. 1663 (2013), p. 73-74.
only subject to indirect network effect on a unilateral direction: the attractiveness
of the market of advertisers is strictly related to the number of users on the other
side of the market, the one of the users of the search engines. However, the
attractiveness of the search engine is not related nor to the number of advertiser in
their side of the market – and, thus, the indirect network effect is unilateral – nor
to the number of the users of the search engines.

The market of the social network like Facebook, on the other hand, is subject to
both direct and indirect network effects.

Indirect network effect play a consistent role on price formation, giving often rise
to price asymmetries15. When indirect network effect occur prices are differently
set for the different sides of the market, giving the operators the possibility to
charge heavily the market side which is less sensitive to price fluctuation, with the
result that one side of the market will be subsidized by another side16.

Due to these mechanism, in digital markets has became always more and more
common to deliver free goods and service in one side of multi-sided markets. The
delivery of free good makes even harder to use standard tools of competition law
enforcement. For example, the so called SSNIP – Small but significant non
transitory increase in price - test to define the relevant market, cannot be applied
since the price of the goods and services is zero17. Moreover, if some more recent
decision regarding a Google case recognized the existence of a search engine
market18, a previous decision of a US Court simply disregarded this recognition
due to the lack of financial consideration19.

15 E. G. A. Weyl, ‘A price theory of multi-sided platforms’, The American


Economic Review (2010), pp. 1642-1672.
16 Monopolies Commission of Germany, 'Competition policy: The challenge of
digital market', Special Report no 68 (2015), p. 19-20.
17 R. Podszun; S. Kreifels, 'Digital platforms and competition law', EuCML 33,
(2016), p. 2.
18 Commission, 25.4.2013 <http://europa.eu/rapid/pressrelease_MEMO13-
383_en.htm>.
19 KinderStart.com v Google, 2007 WL 831806 (N D Cal.).
2. Lock-in, low switching costs and multi-homing

The aforementioned mechanism of the direct and indirect network effect may
lock-in users and, thus, represent an important obstacle for competition. However,
according to a traditional approach, the lock-in effect generated as such are
counterbalanced since in digital markets switching costs are usually very low or
zero and users have the possibility of multi-homing 20. The switching costs are the
costs that a user have to pay to switch from a service or a product offered by a
company to the service or a product offered by a competitor. The higher are the
switching costs the more the competition process is hindered. Multi-homing is the
possibility for the user to use, in the same moment, different and in competition
services or product to satisfy the same demand.

If it is true that monetary switching costs are often low or zero, still has been
noted that there are sometimes switching costs that are not strictly monetary and
that have to be taken into consideration in a competitive analysis. Even though
users do not face any monetary costs for switching, they are yet subject to brand
effect and user adaptation21. User habituation is especially relevant when the
quality of the service provided cannot easily evaluated. For example, in the online
searches engine market the kind of service provided is not easy to evaluate and
users usually use a specific online search engine based on its trustworthiness.
Thus, even though the monetary switching costs are equal to zero, users will tend
not to switch to other service since they are adapted and trust a specific service
provider. For these reasons, according to some author user habituation has to be
considered between non-monetary switching costs in a competition assessment 22

20 A.V. Lerner, ‘The Role of “Big Data” in Online Platform Competition’,


Compass Lexecon, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?
abstract_id=2482780.
21 R. Pollock, ‘Is Google the next Microsoft: Competition, Welfare and
Regulation’, Online Search Review of Network Economics, Vol.9 iss. 4 article 4
(2010). p. 16.
22 E. Harris, ‘The Role of Switching Costs in Antitrust Analysis: A comparison of
Microsft and Google’, 15 Yale Journal of Law and Technology 169 (2013), p. 197
4. Big Data and Competition

1. The importance of data in digital markets

As already exposed in the introduction, the importance of data for the digital
economy has recently grown enormously, so much that data can be today be
addressed as the new currency of the digital age. Whereas the definition of data is
self-evident, the definition of the term “Big Data” is somehow unclear and not
precise. Nonetheless, this buzzword is crucial for economy and deserves the
attention of the scholars.

It is a shared truth that future of business lies in the big data. For this reason,
business studies are focusing more than other field of studies on the topic of big
data. A company willing to enter in a digital market, today, is not competitive if
does not have a strong strategy on data.

In business, information has always been crucial. However, before the arrival of
digital technology, the possibility of gather, store and process information
regarding consumers was limited. Thus, obtaining a competitive advantage
through information was not easy and required a strong investment. As the
technology kept improving and service and product became always more and
more digitalized, the possibility to gather, store and process data got increasingly
cheaper.

The type of data which has the greatest impact on market structure and
competition is personal data. Personal data is collected in three main ways 23: by
voluntary disclosure, by observing users behaviour or by inferring new
information from already existing data.

Personal data, in the framework as set above, can be considered as a crucial asset
for digital market players. The relevance of data can be observed from three
different point of view related to three different functions that data can have:24

23 French Autoritè de la Concurrence and German Bundeskartellamt


‘Competition Law and Data’ (2016), p. 6-7
24 H. A. Shelanski, ‘Innovation, Information and Competition Policy for the
Internet’. University of Pennsylvania Law review, Vol. 1663 (2013), p. 78-82
a) Data as an input of production: companies use data to customize services for
different categories of users according to their habits and preferences. A new
frontier of such customization is price discrimination: companies are increasingly
able to evaluate the willingness to pay of every user and, according to this, they
establish a link between the price a user will pay and his willingness to pay.

b) Data as strategic asset. Data is always retained by companies as a strategic asset


hindering other competitors from entering into the market. This point led some
author to push the hypothesis that some data may be considered as an essential
facility and, thus, be subject to the so called essential facility doctrine (see
paragraph 2 below).

c) Data commodities. Data is also collected, stored and then eventually exchanged
as a commodity. Many players of traditionally non-digital markets are interested
in the data collected by digital companies. These operations are regulated by
privacy law, to which the scholars are giving more and more attention. Terms and
limits of data reuse is currently on debate in the light of the new privacy rules
adopted by UE. On the competition law side, the debate is open on whether there
may be an interplay between privacy law and competition law itself. This debate
will be reported in a following paragraph.

2. Applicability of the essential facility doctrine


Due to the amount of data and information owned by digital companies and now
online, the European Parliament defined online search engines like Google the
“information gatekeeper” of our time25. This crucial position of Google led some
scholar to speculate over the possibility that the access to search engine listings
may be considered as an essential facility and be, thus, subject to the essential
facility doctrine26. According to such doctrine of the Court of Justice of the
European Union, a firm in dominant position should allow access to certain

25 European Parliament, ‘Motion for a Resolution to wind up the debate on the


statement by the Commission pursuant to Rule 123(2) of the Rules of Procedure
on supporting consumer rights in the digital single market’ (2014/2973(RSP)),
para. 10.
26 B.P. Paal, ‘Internet search engines and antitrust law’ Journal of Intellectual
Property Law and Practice, vol. 11 no. 4 (2016), p. 301-303.
information, products, services, networks or other facilities which prevent
competition in an upstream or downstream market when three conditions occur:

1) The refusal to grant access must be likely to prevent competition

2) The refusal must not be justifiable on the basis of objective reasons

3) There must be no available replacement for the essential facilities27.

Recurring these conditions, the essential facilities doctrine may be applied to


cases regarding Google. Nonetheless, it seems that the actual legal framework and
the potential possibility, even though only theoretical, to replicate the internet
infrastructure of Google prevent this application28.

The hypothesis of the application of the essential facility doctrine to data, even
though has never occurred in any case, is becoming always more likely due to the
growing importance of data for digital markets. According to this trend, thus, it is
likely that personal data will fall into the definition of the Court. This is
demonstrated by the recent decision of the European Commission on the
Microsoft/Linkedin merger. One of the reason that made the Commission clear the
merger was that “[…] access to the full LinkedIn database is not essential to
compete on the market.”29. The attention paid by the commission on the database
of Linkedin show that the watchdog of the European Competition Law
investigated the possibility that database of Linkedin may be an essential facility
for its competitors.

3. The interplay between Data protection law and Competition law

A highly discussed topic in the framework of competition law in data-driven


markets is whether role, if any, data protection law has in competition assessment.
Some authors argued that the growing importance of data for digital markets is
opening the possibility that violation of data protection law and privacy of users
may constitutes an abuse of dominant position and, thus, privacy law and

27 European Court of Justice, Case C-7/97 Bronner [1998] ECR I-07791


ECLI:EU:1998:569, n. 18 para. 4.
28 B.P. Paal, ‘Internet search engines and antitrust law’ Journal of Intellectual
Property Law and Practice, vol. 11 no. 4 (2016), p. 301-303.
29 European Commission, Microsoft/Linkedin Merger, IP/16/4284 (2016).
competition law may overlap30. However, competition authorities have so far
excluded an interplay as such, always stating that privacy law and competition
law are to be assessed separately, serving different purposes.

This clear cut position emerged both in USA and in Europe with respect to the
Facebook/Whatsapp merger. The US FTC cleared the transaction excluding that
privacy concern were relevant for a competitive assessment and sending a letter to
the Bureau of Consumer Protection, which the FTC considered to be the only
authority with jurisdiction on privacy issues 31. On the other side of the Atlantic,
the European Commission cleared the transaction on the same basis, stating that:
“Any privacy-related concerns flowing from the increased concentration of data
within the control of Facebook as a result of the Transaction do not fall within the
scope of the EU competition law rules but within the scope of the EU data
protection rules."32

Even though the distinction between the scope of privacy law and the one of
competition law has been made clear by competition authorities, still data
protection and privacy has a role on competition proceeding as important element
of non-price competition33.

30 A. Gebicka, A. Heinemann, ‘Social Media and Competition Law’, 37 World


Competition 149, p. 165
31 Letter from J. L. Rich, Dir., Bureau of Consumer Protection, Fed. Trade
Comm’n, to Erin Egan, Chief Privacy Officer, Facebook, Inc. & Anne Hoge, Gen.
Counsel, WhatsApp Inc. (Apr. 10, 2014), availabe at:
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_statements/297701/140410fac
ebookwhatapp ltr.pdf.
32 European Commission, Case COMP/M.7217, Facebook/WhatsApp, Comm’n
Decision, ¶ 191 (Mar. 20, 2014).
33 N. Schepp, A. Wambach, ‘On Big Data and Its Relevance for Market Power
Assessment’, Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, vol. 7 no. 2
(2016), p. 124.
Bibliography

J. M. Cavanillas, E. Curry, W. Wahlster, ‘New horizon for a Data-Driven


Economy’, Springer (2016)
Competition Committee of the Directorate for financial and enterprise affairs of
the OECD, 'The digital economy', DAF/COMP(2012)22
Competition Committee of the Directorate for financial and enterprise affairs of
the OECD, 'Hearing on disruptive innovation', DAF/COMP(2015)3
B. Custers; Helena Ursˇicˇ, 'Big data and data reuse: a taxonomy of data reuse for
balancing big data benefits and personal data protection', International Data
Privacy Law Vol. 6, No. 1 (2016)
European Commission, Case COMP/M.7217, Facebook/WhatsApp, Comm’n
Decision, ¶ 191 (Mar. 20, 2014).
European Court of Justice, Case C-7/97 Bronner [1998] ECR I-07791
ECLI:EU:1998:569, n. 18 para. 4.
European Parliament, ‘Motion for a Resolution to wind up the debate on the
statement by the Commission pursuant to Rule 123(2) of the Rules of Procedure
on supporting consumer rights in the digital single market’ (2014/2973(RSP))
French Autoritè de la Concurrence and German Bundeskartellamt ‘Competition
Law and Data’ (2016)
M. S. Gal and D. L. Rubinfeld, ‘The Hidden Costs of Free Goods: Implications
for Antitrust Enforcement’, NYU Law& Economics Research Paper Series
Working Paper NO. 14-44 (2015)
A. Gebicka, A. Heinemann, ‘Social Media and Competition Law’, 37 World
Competition 149, p. 165
J. Haucap; U. Heimeshoff, 'Google, Facebook, Amazon, eBay: Is the Internet
driving competition or market monopolization?', Int Econ Econ Policy 11 (2014)
J. Hederstro¨m; L. Peeperkorn, 'Vertical Restraints in On-line Sales: Comments on
Some Recent Developments', Journal of European Competition Law & Practice
Vol. 7, No. 1 (2016)
E. Harris, ‘The Role of Switching Costs in Antitrust Analysis: A comparison of
Microsft and Google’, 15 Yale Journal of Law and Technology 169 (2013)
S.P. King, 'Sharing Economy: What Challenges for Competition Law?', Journal of
European Competition Law & Practice Vol. 6, No. 10 (2015)
A. V. Lerner, ‘The Role of 'Big Data' in Online Platform Competition’, available
online at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2482780
Jonathan D. Levin “The Economics of Internet Markets”, NBER Working Paper
No. 16852, (2011).
Monopolies Commission of Germany, 'Competition policy: The challenge of
digital market', Special Report no 68 (2015)
R. Nazzini, 'Google and the (Ever-stretching) Boundaries of Article 102 TFUE',
Journal of European Competition Law & Practice Vol. 6, No. 5 (2015)
N. Newmant, 'Search, Antitrust, and the Economics of the Control of User Data',
Yale Journal of Regulation Vol. 31.2 (2014)
B.P. Paal, ‘Internet search engines and antitrust law’ Journal of Intellectual
Property Law and Practice, vol. 11 no. 4 (2016)
R. Podszun; S. Kreifels, 'Digital platforms and competition law', EuCML 33,
(2016)
R. Pollock, ‘Is Google the next Microsoft: Competition, Welfare and Regulation’,
Online Search Review of Network Economics, Vol.9 iss. 4 article 4 (2010)
Neil M. Richards; Jonathan H. King , 'Three paradoxes of Big Data', 66 Stan. L.
Rev. Online 41 (2013)
Letter from J. L. Rich, Dir., Bureau of Consumer Protection, Fed. Trade Comm’n,
to Erin Egan, Chief Privacy Officer, Facebook, Inc. & Anne Hoge, Gen. Counsel,
WhatsApp Inc. (Apr. 10, 2014), availabe at:
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_statements/297701/140410fac
ebookwhatapp ltr.pdf.
N. P. Schepp; A. Wambach, 'On Big Data and Its Relevance for Market Power
Assessment', Journal of European Competition Law & Practice Vol. 7, No. 2
(2016)
D. Schimdtchen, M. Albert, S. Voigt, ‘The More Economic Approach to European
Competition Law’, Mohr Siebeck (2007).
H. A. Shelanski, ‘Innovation, Information and Competition Policy for the
Internet’. University of Pennsylvania Law review, Vol. 1663 (2013)
M. E. Stucke; A. P. Grunes, 'No Mistake About It: The Important Role of Antitrust
in the Era of Big Data' - Research paper #269, Legal studies research paper series
of the University of Tennesse (2015)
G. Surblitè, 'Competition Law at the Crossroads in the Digital Economy: is it all
about Google?', EuCML 170 (2015)
G. Surblitè (Ed.), 'Competition on the Internet', Springer (2015)
Omer Tene; J. Polonetsky, 'Big Data for All: Privacy and User Control in the Age
of Analytics', 11 Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property
239 (2013)
E. G. A. Weyl, ‘A price theory of multi-sided platforms’, The American Economic
Review (2010)

Вам также может понравиться