Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 28

The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies of Equality: Welfare State Institutions,

Inequality, and Poverty in the Western Countries


Author(s): Walter Korpi and Joakim Palme
Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 63, No. 5 (Oct., 1998), pp. 661-687
Published by: American Sociological Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2657333 .
Accessed: 01/06/2013 19:18

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
American Sociological Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION
AND STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY:
WELFARE STATE INSTITUTIONS, INEQUALITY, AND
POVERTY IN THE WESTERN COUNTRIES*

WalterKorpi Joakim Palme


Swedish Institutefor Social Research Swedish Institutefor Social Research
Debates on how to reduce poverty and inequality have focused on two con-
troversial questions: Should social policies be targeted to low-income groups
or be universal? Should benefits be equalfor all or earnings-related? Tradi-
tional arguments in favor of targeting and flat-rate benefits, focusing on the
distribution of the money actually transferred, neglect three policy-relevant
considerations: (1) The size of redistributive budgets is notfixed but reflects
the structure of welfare state institutions. (2) A trade-off exists between the
degree of low-income targeting and the size of redistributive budgets. (3)
Outcomes of market-based distribution are often more unequal than those of
earnings-related social insurance programs. We argue that social insurance
institutions are of central importance for redistributive outcomes. Using new
data, our comparative analyses of the effects of different institutional types
of welfare states on poverty and inequality indicate that institutional differ-
ences lead to unexpected outcomes and generate the paradox of redistribu-
tion: The more we target benefits at the poor and the more concerned we are
with creating equality via equal public transfers to all, the less likely we are
to reduce poverty and inequality.

Social scientists and social reformers come? These issues are of central importance
have long debated how the welfare state for addressing the question of whether the
and social policies should be designed so as "middle classes" should be included in the
to best reduce poverty and inequality. This welfare state in a way that protects their ac-
debate involves two different issues. One customed living standards. Our purpose in
question concerns whether social policies this paper is to examine the different types of
should be targetedor universal, that is, should social policy programsoperating in capitalist
they be organized for the poor only or should democracies and evaluate their effectiveness
the welfare state include all citizens? In the in reducing inequality and poverty.
context of nontargeted programs, another
question concerns the level of benefits:
BACKGROUND
Should benefits be equal for all, or should
they be related to previous earnings and in- Policymakers and students of social policies
are divided on the issues of targeting versus
*
Direct correspondence to Walter Korpi or
Joakim Palme, Swedish Institute for Social Re- Poverty, Social Welfare and Social Policy in
search, Stockholm University, S-106 91 Canberra in 1996, at the Welfare States at the
Stockholm, Sweden (walter.korpi@sofi.su.se, Crossroads conference in Stockholm in 1997 and
joakim.palme@sofi.su.se). Authors share equal at different seminars. We thank participants in
responsibility for this article. Early versions of these conferences as well as Rune Aberg and
the manuscript were presented at the conferences Johan Fritzell for valuable comments. We also
of the International Sociological Association in thank anonymous ASR referees for their helpful
Bielefeld in 1994, the British Social Policy Asso- comments. This work was supported by the Bank
ciation in Liverpool in 1994, the International of Sweden Tercentenary Foundation, the Social
Sociological Association's Research Committees Science Research Council, and the Council for
for Social Stratification in Stockholm and for Research in the Humanities and Social Sciences.

AmericanSociological Review, 1998, Vol. 63 (October:661-687) 661

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
662 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

universalism and flat-rateversus earnings-re- There is a rough rule of thumb by which we


lated benefit levels. As the following sam- can detect which projects are designed to help
pling of the nature of arguments indicates, the poor and which are not designed to help
their views on these issues have varied over them. This rule of thumb is that if there is a
means-test, i.e., if aid is so arrangedthat it cuts
country and time. Targetingharksback to the off at a reasonably low level, then it is designed
traditions of the Poor Laws, but it continues to help the poor. . . . [T]he switch from a
to play a more or less significant role in all means-tested programto a general aid program
Western countries. In the United States, leg- would, in all probability, hurt the poor. (P. 97)
islation of 1935 introduced nontargeted old-
age pensions and unemploymentinsurance as Evaluating the effects on inequality of uni-
well as what was to become a large means- versal social services in postwar Britain, Le
tested' program,Aid to Families with Depen- Grand (1982) concludes:
dent Children (AFDC). Since World War II, Public expenditure on the social services has
the targeting issue has been prominentin the not achieved equality in any of its interpreta-
United States. Thus, the large programsin the tions. Public expenditure on health care, edu-
War on Poverty initiated in the 1960s were cation, housing and transportsystematically fa-
explicitly directed at the poor (Quadagno vors the better off and thereby contributes to
1994). The basic question for antipoverty inequality in final income. (P. 137)
programswas: "Whatdoes it do to the poor?" Among political scientists, Barry (1990)
(Lampman 1971). Social scientists evaluat- maintains that
ing antipovertyprogramschose as their main ... the Poor Law by its nature brings about a
criterion for program success, the degree of net transfer between classes, whereas the wel-
"targetefficiency," defined as the proportion fare state has no inherent tendency to bring
of programexpendituresgoing exclusively to about such net transfers.... By contrast, a wel-
those below the official poverty line-the fare state characteristically transfers money
greaterthe targeting efficiency, the better the within income strata. (P. 505)
program is evaluated (Barth, Cargano, and Sociologists express similar views. Thus, in
Palmer 1974). Because of the visibility of tar- his famous lectures on "Citizenship and So-
geted social assistance programs like AFDC cial Class," Marshall (1950) compared the
and food stamps in the United States, the tar- equalizing effects of social insurance
geting/universalism question continues to be schemes involving the total population, insur-
central in U.S. social policy debates. In Eu- ance schemes limited to lower income
rope, however, the issue of the earnings-re- groups, and means-tested programs and con-
latedness of universalistic social insurance cluded that "a total scheme is less specifically
benefits has come to the fore. class abating in a purely economic sense than
Referring to the assumed negative effects a limited one, and social insurance is less so
of social benefits on labor supply and sav- than a means-tested service" (p. 55).
ings, economists have typically been cool to- This assumption, that social policies di-
ward universalistic earnings-related social rected at the needy constitute the most effi-
insurance and have regarded programs tar- cient strategy for reducing poverty and in-
geted at the poor as the most efficient way of equality, has been called into question. Brit-
reducing poverty and inequality. For ex- ish historian Tawney (1952) argued that "the
ample, Tullock (1983) writes: strategy of equality" in a society should in-
volve
1 Means-testing implies that the claimant of a . . .the pooling of its surplus resources by
benefit may be disqualified for the benefit if her means of taxation, and the use of the funds thus
or his property or wealth exceeds a certain limit, obtained to make accessible to all, irrespective
or receive the benefit at a reduced rate if the prop- of their income, occupation, or social position,
erty or wealth is small. The property or wealth of the conditions of civilization which, in the ab-
other family members are usually taken into con- sence of such measures, can be enjoyed only
sideration, and, in some cases, the property or by the rich. (P. 130, italics added)
wealth of parents or children not living in the
household is also taken into account. Income-test- Thus, according to Tawney, social policy
ing is a less strict testing of the claimant insofar should not be directed to the poor alone but
as only incomes are taken into consideration. should include all citizens.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 663

In an early critique of the emphasis on tar- cial minorities and children increasingly take
geting in the U.S. policy debate, Korpi a dim view of the effects of targeted policies
(1980a, 1983) contrasted a marginal social (Garfinkel, Hochschild, and McLanahan
policy model with minimumbenefits targeted 1996; Lawson and Wilson 1995). Scholars
at the poor with an institutional model based focusing on gender relations point out how
on universal programs intended to maintain means-tested social programs tend to disad-
normalor accustomed standardsof living. He vantage women (Harrington Meyer 1996;
argued that while a targeted program "may Hobson 1990; O'Connor 1993; Orloff 1993).
have greater redistributive effects per unit of Nevertheless, while support for targeting
money spent than institutional types of pro- has decreased among social scientists, it has
grams,"other factors are likely to make insti- increased among policymakers in Western
tutional programsmore redistributive(Korpi countries. Thus, for example, on the interna-
1980a:304, italics in original). This rather tional scene, institutions such as the Interna-
unexpected outcome was predicted as a con- tional Monetary Fund and the World Bank
sequence of the type of political coalitions have argued that "a comprehensive approach
that different welfare state institutions tend to poverty reduction . . . calls for a program
to generate. Because marginaltypes of social of well-targeted transfers and safety nets"
policy programs are directed primarily at (World Bank 1990:3).
those below the poverty line, there is no ra- The idea that high-income earners should
tional base for a coalition between those be included in the universalistic welfare state
above and those below the poverty line. In via earnings-related benefits also tends to
effect, the poverty line splits the working meet strong resistance from scholars. Ac-
class and tends to generatecoalitions between cording to Goodin and Le Grand (1987), the
better-off workers and the middle class failure of social policies to reduce inequality
against the lower sections of the working lies in the beneficial participation of the
class, something which can result in tax re- nonpoor in the welfare state. If the goal of
volts and backlash against the welfare-state. social policy is limited to the reduction of
In an institutional model of social policy poverty, then universal programs that also
aimed at maintaining accustomed standards benefit the nonpoor are a waste of resources.
of living, however, most households directly If the goal is to reduce inequality between
benefit in some way. Such a model "tends to the poor and the nonpoor,however, their ver-
encourage coalition formation between the dict is even more severe:
working class and the middle class in sup- In egalitarianterms. . . the beneficialinvolve-
port for continued welfare state policies. The mentof the non-poorin the welfarestateis not
poor need not stand alone" (Korpi 1980a: merelywasteful-it is actuallycounterproduc-
305; also see Rosenberry 1982). The hypoth- tive. The more the non-poorbenefit, the less
esis here is that the size of the budget avail- redistributive(or, hence, egalitarian)the im-
able for redistribution is not fixed and that pact of the welfarestate will be. (Goodinand
the institutional structures of welfare states Le Grand1987:215)
are likely to affect the definitions of identity In the same vein, Castles and Mitchell (1992)
and interest among citizens. Thus, an institu- argue that while universalism is likely to lead
tional welfare state model based on a univer- to greater equality than targeting, "earnings-
salistic strategy intended to maintain normal related (or status-related)benefits will clearly
or accustomed standardsof living is likely to have a less equalizing effect, all other things
result in greater redistribution than a mar- being equal, than flat-rate benefits" (p. 4).
ginal one based on targeting. Other social scientists, however, have de-
Since the 1980s, many social scientists in fended earnings-related benefits. In a study
Europe and the United States have become of pensions, Palme (1990) observed that uni-
increasingly critical of the targeting of social versalistic earnings-related pension systems
policies at the poor. Weale (1990) argues that tend to produce less inequality in the distri-
"thereis a series of connections both of prac- bution of final income among the elderly
tice and of principle that link universalistic than do flat-rate systems. He concluded,
forms of provisions to the pursuit of equal- "[Tihere is a paradox here in the sense that
ity" (p. 475). Studies of poverty among ra- comparatively unequal public pensions

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
664 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

might produce the most equal income distri- As the above review indicates, in the late
butions by crowding out even more unequal 1990s Western policymakers are renewing
income sources" (p. 154, italics added), such the old stress on the targeting of social poli-
as private pensions (also see Kangas and cies, and social scientists are disagreeing on
Palme 1993). In Finland, the change from the best strategy for reducing poverty and in-
flat-rate to earnings-relatedpensions reduced equality. While universalism has gradually
inequality and poverty among the elderly be- become accepted in many scholarly quarters
tween 1966 and 1990 (Jantti, Kangas, and outside economics, the earnings-relatedness
Ritakallio 1996). Aberg (1989) shows how of social insurance benefits is still strongly
the distributive profiles of welfare states questioned. Within the countries of the Euro-
combine with their size to generate redistri- pean Union, this questioning has been
bution. Some comparative empirical evi- strengthened by increasing pressures to re-
dence indicates that universalistic welfare duce budget deficits and to reduce the public
states tend to be associated with greater sector. Comparativeanalyses involving coun-
equality and redistribution than do tries with different kinds of welfare state in-
marginalistic welfare states (Fritzell 1991; stitutions are likely to promote our under-
Hicks and Swank 1984; Mitchell 1991; standing of the consequences of different
O'Higgins, Schmaus, and Stephenson 1990; strategies to decrease poverty and inequality.
Ringen 1987, chap. 8; Ringen and Uusitalo In this paper, we carry out a comparative
1991; Uusitalo 1984). analysis of the capacity of what Titmuss
In an innovative and influential study, (1974) refers to as different models of social
Esping-Andersen (1990) appears to take an policy to reduce inequality and poverty in
inconsistent position on the consequences of capitalist democracies. The analysis centers
earnings-related benefits. On one hand, he on the role of the institutional structures of
applaudsthe "social democratic welfare state welfare states in the redistributive process.
regime" (p. 27), which promotes equality on These institutional structures reflect differ-
the highest levels and makes for "universal- ences in the roles played by markets and
ism of middle-class standards"(p. 69). On politics in distributive processes within
the other hand, he takes the difference be- countries and, in Tawney's terms, embody
tween the social insurance benefits of an av- different "strategies of equality." The shape
erage production worker and the maximum of societal institutions is affected by the ac-
legal benefit-an indicator of the degree of tions of different interest groups, but we also
earnings-relatedness-as a main criterion for expect that institutional structures affect the
distinguishing between "socialist" and "con- ways in which citizens come to define their
servative" welfare state regimes. "The ben- interests and preferences (Hechter, Opp, and
efits-differential measure should in principle Wippler 1990; Korpi 1980a, 1980b, 1985;
facilitate a sharpdistinction between 'social- March and Olsen 1989; Pierson 1995; Powell
ist' and 'conservative' cases. In the former, and DiMaggio 1991; Steinmo, Thelen, and
an accent on equality should induce low dif- Longstreth 1992). Thus, welfare state insti-
ferentials; in the latter, the principles of tutions can be viewed as "intervening vari-
maintaining status and hierarchy should re- ables" (Lazarsfeld 1962), on one hand re-
sult in sharp inequalities" (Esping-Andersen flecting causal factors such as actions by
1990:75). Thus, we should expect "the so- coalitions of interest groups, and on the other
cialist-inspired regimes to accentuate benefit hand potentially having feedback effects on
equality, while in the conservative regimes distributive processes via their effects on the
inequalities should be greatest" (p. 69) and formation of interests, preferences and coali-
therefore "the socialist regime ought to ex- tions among citizens. Therefore a fruitful hy-
hibit the lowest level of benefit differentials"
(p. 73).2 M1lter, longtime Minister of Social Affairs in
Social Democratic governments and generally re-
2 It would appear that Esping-Andersen (1990) garded as the founding father of the modern
here reflects the dualist views on earnings-related Swedish welfare state, strongly opposed the in-
social insurance benefits long found in the Nor- troduction of earnings-related benefits in the
dic labor movements. Thus, for example, Gustav Swedish sickness insurance program.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 665

pothesis is that, while the institutions of the quences. Attempts to capture similarities and
welfare state are to an important extent differences by creating typologies of welfare
shaped by different types of interest groups, states have run into familiar problems. By
once institutions are in place they tend to in- specifying ideal types, we hope to crystallize
fluence the long-term development of defi- similarities among countries and to gain a
nitions of interests and coalition formation better understanding of the background to
among citizens. This makes it likely that in- variations among them. However, ideal types
stitutional structureswill have significant ef- will never have a perfect fit with existing re-
fects on redistributive processes and on the alities, and such typologies may obscure the
reduction of inequality and poverty. actual variations among countries. The fruit-
fulness of typologies depends, therefore, on
our ability to construct them using variables
DATA that are of heuristic value for understanding
This analysis is based on two new data sets. the background to and consequences of
One is the Social Citizenship Indicator Pro- variations among ideal types, and on the ex-
gram (SCIP), which contains information on tent to which empirically observed variation
the development of social insurance pro- among types is greater than variation within
grams in 18 OECD countries:Australia,Aus- types.
tria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Typologies of welfare states can serve dif-
France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the ferent purposes and can focus on variables
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Swe- related to causes, institutions, and/or out-
den, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and comes. Esping-Andersen (1990) offers the
the United States.3 The other data set is the most influential attempt to create a welfare
Luxembourg Income Study (LIS), which state typology (also see Korpi 1980b; Mishra
contains micro-data on income distribution 1981; Titmuss 1974). He uses the concept of
in a number of countries.4 These two data welfare state regimes to characterize and de-
sets represent major advances in the oppor- scribe the complex relationships among the
tunity for the comparative study of social state, the labor market, and the family. By
policies and their effects. emphasizing the multidimensional nature of
variation in welfare states, Esping-
Andersen's typology is fruitful and has
A TYPOLOGY OF SOCIAL
stimulated much research. His three clusters
INSURANCE INSTITUTIONS of welfare states regimes are labeled accord-
Welfare state institutions in industrialized ing to the main ideological currents assumed
countries demonstrate differences as well as to underlie them-Conservative, Liberal, and
family resemblances which are likely to be Social Democratic. Because Esping-
of relevance for their redistributive conse- Andersen's primary interest was to describe
the contours of the relationships among
3 These 18 countriesare selectedaccordingto
states, labor markets, and families, his typol-
the principleof most comparablecases (Lijphart ogy is based on a broad set of indicators re-
1975).Theyincludeonly countrieswitha history
of uninterrupted ferring to both outcomes and institutions. 5
political democracyduringthe
post-WorldWarII periodandwith morethan 1 Our interest is primarily analytical-on
millioninhabitants. one hand to study the causal factors affect-
4 The Social Citizenship IndicatorProgram ing the institutional aspects of the welfare
(SCIP)is based at the SwedishInstitutefor So- state and, on the other hand, to examine the
cial Researchat StockholmUniversityand is di-
rectedby thepresentauthors(forpresentations of 5 Esping-Andersen (1990:69-77) uses seven in-
the datafiles, see Korpi1989;Palme 1990). For dicators for his typology: the number of occupa-
a presentationof the LuxembourgIncomeStudy, tionally distinct pension schemes, insurance cov-
see Smeeding,O'Higgins,andRainwater(1990) erage in the population, the difference between
and Buhmannet al. (1988). Analyses are re- average and maximum benefit levels, and the size
strictedto the 11 countriesfor which LIS data of expenditures in terms of the relative size of
wereavailablein 1994andfor whichinformation government employee pensions, means-tested
was detailedenough to enable us to follow the benefits, private sector pensions, and private sec-
variousstepsin the incomeformationprocess. tor health care.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
666 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 1. Ideal-Typical Models of Social Insurance Institutions

Employer-Employee
Bases of Benefit Cooperationin
Model Entitlement Level Principle ProgramGovernance
Targeted Provenneed Minimum No
Voluntarystate-subsidized Membership, Flat-rateor No
contributions earnings-related
Corporatist Occupationalcategory Earnings-related Yes
and laborforce
participation
Basic security Citizenshipor contributions Flat-rate No
Encompassing Citizenshipand Flat-rateand No
labor force participation earnings-related

effects of institutions on the formation of in- nomic categories, old age pensions and sick-
terests, preferences, and identities as well as ness insurance are importantfor all citizens.
on the degree of poverty and inequality in a Because these two programs also have a ma-
society. For these purposes we base our ty- jor economic impact they likely have great
pology of welfare states on their institutional relevance for the formation of interest
characteristics.Institutionalstructuresreflect groups.
the role of conflicts among interest groups, As a basis for our typology, we classify the
for example, regarding the relative roles of institutional structures of old-age pension
markets and politics in distributive pro- and sickness insurance programs according
cesses. Yet, institutional structuresin turnare to three aspects (see Table 1). (1) Relevant
likely to affect outcomes by forming impor- to the issue of targeting versus universalism,
tant frameworks for the definitions of inter- the first aspect refers to the definition of
est and identities among citizens. Thus, they bases of entitlement and involves four quali-
can be expected to affect the formation of tatively different criteria indicating whether
coalitions among citizens that are relevant eligibility is based on need determined via a
for income redistributionand poverty. While means test, on contributions (by the insured
the complex of relationships characterizing or employers) to the financing of the social
welfare state regimes makes it difficult to insurance program, on belonging to a speci-
study change, a typology of institutions fa- fied occupational category, or on citizenship
cilitates the study of change by making it (residence) in the country.7 These four crite-
possible to relate causes and outcomes to in- ria for eligibility to entitlements have been
tervening variables. used in different combinations in different
The major social insurance programs ca- countries. (2) The second aspect concerns the
tering to citizens' most importantneeds dur- underlying principle guiding the determina-
ing the life course constitute a key partof the tion of benefit levels-that is, the extent to
welfare state.6 The institutional structuresof which social insurance benefits should re-
two such programs-old-age pensions and place lost income. The benefit-level principle
sickness cash benefits-are here taken as can be seen as a continuous variable, going
bases for a welfare state typology. These two from means-tested minimum benefits, to flat-
programsrespond to basic features of the hu- rate benefits given equally to everyone, and
man condition-the certainty of aging and to benefits that in different degrees are re-
the risk of illness. Unlike unemployment and lated to previous earnings. (3) The third as-
work-accident insurance, for which the rel- pect is qualitative and refers to theforms for
evant risks differ greatly among socioeco-
7 As a result of immigration, in most countries
6The social services constitute another major an increasing proportion of residents are not citi-
part of the welfare state but cannot be included zens. For convenience, the term "citizens" in-
here. cludes residents as well.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 667

Targeted / \ VoluntaryState Subsidized

4 ~~~~~~~~~Corporatist d

Basic Security Encompassing

Figure 1. Ideal-Typical Models of Social Insurance Institutions


Note: Thefour-sidedfigures representthe social structureof society with high-incomeearnersat the top
and low-income earnersat the bottom. Whiteareas representthe noncoveredpopulation.Horizontal lines
indicate flat-rate benefits. Vertical lines indicate earnings-relatedbenefits. Ellipses in the voluntarystate
subsidized model indicate separateinsuranceprograms.Angled lines in the corporatistmodel indicate in-
suranceprogramsorganizedseparatelyfor differentoccupationalcategories.

governing a social insurance program. This tern-high-income earners are at the top and
aspect receives its significance via its com- low-income earners and the poor are at the
bination with the previous two aspects. Here bottom. Citizens with rights to flat-rate or
we create a dichotomy based on whether rep- minimum benefits are indicated by horizon-
resentatives of employers and employees co- tal lines; citizens with rights to earnings-re-
operate in the governing of a program. lated benefits are indicated by vertical lines.
On the basis of these three aspects of social Note, however, that some social insurance
insurance programs, we delineate five differ- programsthat formally give earnings-related
ent ideal types of institutional structures.In a benefits have relatively low benefit ceilings,
rough chronological order according to their which in practice results in relatively equal
historical appearance in the Western coun- benefits for most part of the insured.
tries, these ideal institutional types are char- In the targeted model eligibility is based
acterized as the targeted, voluntarystate-sub- on a means test, which results in minimum
sidized, corporatist, basic security, and en- or relatively similar benefits (horizontal
compassing models. Figure 1 characterizes lines) to those who fall below a poverty line
the ideal-typical features of these institutional or are defined as needy. Although targeted
structures.The diamond-shapedfigures sym- programs have traditions going back to the
bolize the socioeconomic stratification sys- Poor Laws, the criteria for determining need

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
668 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

can vary considerably in terms of punitive- ing to a specified occupational category.


ness and generosity. During this century, Separate social insurance programswith dif-
many countries relaxed the criteria used for fering entitlements are organized for differ-
means-testing. For example, in Au'straliatar- ent occupations or branches of industry,cre-
geting has gradually come to be focused on ating a segmentation among occupational
excluding top-income earners ratherthan in- categories. Starting with the industrial work-
cluding only the poor. This possibility is in- ing class, over the decades new occupational
dicated by thinner lines above the poverty categories graduallyhave been added and ac-
line. corded separate insurance programs. Ben-
The voluntary state-subsidized model uses efits are clearly earnings-related (vertical
tax money to help mutual-benefit societies lines), but entitlements and rules can differ
and other voluntary organizationsprovide in- significantly among the programs for differ-
surance to protect their members against loss ent occupational categories. In contrast to the
of earnings. Because eligibility for benefits other four institutional types and reflecting
is based on voluntary contributions that give the basic idea of creating sociopolitical com-
membership in the respective schemes, they munities and cooperation among the poten-
have been more important for skilled work- tial antagonists in the labor market,programs
ers and the middle class than for the un- in the corporatist model are governed by
skilled and the poor. Voluntary schemes can elected representatives of employees and
have flat-rate or earnings-related benefits, employers, often with the state present as a
but the latter often approachflat-ratebenefits minor third party. Programsare financed pri-
because of relatively low ceilings for earn- marily via contributions from employers and
ings replacements. employees. Being limited to the economi-
The pioneering social insurance programs cally active population, this model excludes
initiated in Germany by Bismarck in the housewives and others outside the labor
1880s broke with means-testing and volun- force. Typically, an income ceiling for cov-
tarism by introducing programs with com- erage is also introduced, with high-income
pulsory membership that gave specified oc- earners being expected to find private solu-
cupational categories the right to claim ben- tions.
efits when their normal earnings were inter- In the basic security model, eligibility is
rupted for reasons beyond their control. based on contributions or on citizenship
Thus, German social insurance came to fol- (residence). This model comes close to the
low the corporatist model central to Catho- central ideals expressed by Beveridge
lic social teaching and nineteenth-century (1942). One ideal was to have flat-rate ben-
conservative thought (Durkheim [1902] efits or a low ceiling on earnings replace-
1964; Leo XIII [1891] 1943; Messner 1936, ment in order to leave room for high-income
1964; Pius XI [1931] 1943).8 The corporat- groups to protect their standard of living
ist model can be said to create "sociopolitical through private insurance programs.Accord-
communities" within different segments of ing to Beveridge (1942),
the labor force and to induce cooperation be- [T]he first fundamentalprincipleof the social
tween employers and employees within these insuranceschemeis provisionsof a flat rateof
segments. In the corporatistmodel, programs insurancebenefit,irrespectiveof the amountof
are directed at the economically active popu- earnings which have been interrupted.... This
lation. Eligibility for benefits is based on a principlefollows from the recognitionof the
combination of contributionsand on belong- place of voluntaryinsurancein social security.
(P. 121)
8 Here, the term "corporatism" is used in its Another basic idea was to achieve wide or
original meaning of state-induced cooperation be- universal coverage of the relevant population
tween employers and employees within specific categories. Within the basic security model
sectors of industry. In the address of the German
there are two variants with somewhat differ-
emperor to the Reichstag on February 15, 1881
announcing the coming social insurance legisla- ent levels of coverage. In the "citizenship"
tion, the term "korporativeVerbande" (corporat- variant, eligibility is based on citizenship or
ist associations) was used to describe this type of residence (i.e., the idea of "People's Insur-
organizations (Deutsche Reichstag 1881). ance" or universal coverage). In the "insur-

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 669

ance" variant,however, eligibility is acquired ogy, we follow a step-wise decision proce-


through contributions by the insured and/or dure. First we separateout means-tested pro-
employers, entailing less than universal cov- grams. Next we separate out the voluntary
erage. In contrast to the corporatist model, state-subsidized programs. These steps are
however, in the basic security model all in- not problematic, because the relevant quali-
sured are covered by the same program. In tative criteria are established by legislation.
the basic security model, benefit levels have This is also true of the third step, identifying
come to vary to some extent, and although the corporatist model in terms of the exist-
the differences between the "citizenship"and ence of multiple programs directed at sepa-
"insurance"" variants are relatively small, in rate occupations or branches of industry,
some contexts they can be significant. each programgoverned by elected represen-
The encompassing model combines ideas tatives of employers and the insured.9 The
from Bismarck and Beveridge into a new fourth step distinguishes the basic security
pattern. In this model, eligibility is based on and encompassing programs, which are
contributionsand citizenship. Universal pro- based on the degree of earnings-relatedness
grams covering all citizens and giving them of benefits and the program's coverage (see
basic security are combined with earnings- Appendix A for details). In the basic security
related benefits for the economically active programs, earnings-relatedness is absent or
population. This model reduces the demand marginal; in encompassing programs, it is
for private insuranceand has the potential of substantial. In encompassing programs, rel-
encompassing all citizens within the same evant population groups receive universal
program. coverage. In basic security model, however,
"citizenship" programs have universal cov-
erage, while in the "insurance" variant, in
SOCIAL INSURANCE INSTITUTIONS which entitlements are based on contribu-
IN 1985 tions, coverage can be substantially lower.
Can the institutionalmodels described above In 1985, in 14 of our 18 countries sickness
be discerned among the welfare states now insurance and pensions insurance programs
existing in Western countries? We use the had the same institutional structures.In three
SCIP data to classify the institutional struc- of the remaining four countries-the Nether-
tures of old-age pensions and sickness insur- lands, New Zealand, and Switzerland-insti-
ance programs existing in 1985 in our 18 tutional structures differ between program
OECD countries. Here, one must remember areas reflecting processes of change. The
that a typology based on ideal types can fourth country, the United States, lacks a na-
never fit the real world exactly. As a result tional sickness insurance program for the
of a century of efforts by different interest working-age population. In these four coun-
groups to place their stamp on the institu- tries, the organization of pension insurance,
tional structuresof the welfare state, we must in many ways the single most importantpro-
expect to find crossbreeds, not purebreds;al- gram, is used to characterize the country. In
loys, not elements. We also must recognize 1985, the voluntary state-subsidized model is
that the institutional structures of welfare found only in sickness insurance programs
states change over time. Moreover, the ideal- and thus no longer characterizes any of our
typical models refer to single social insur- 18 countries.10 This reflects the fact that al-
ance programsin a particularinsurance area. though some countries introduced voluntary
However, more than one program, and thus state-subsidized pension programs early on,
more than one institutional type, may exist it has proved difficult to organize large-scale
in a given insurance area. Furthermore,in- pension programsin this institutional form.
stitutional forms may differ between the two
program areas. Thus, the clustering of coun- 9 The existence of separate legislated programs
tries must sometimes be based on tendencies for different occupational groups is always com-
and gradations ratherthan on clear-cut crite- bined with earnings-related benefits.
ria close to ideal types. 10In 1985, in three countries unemployment in-
In fitting the institutionalstructuresof pen- surance programs were also organized according
sion and sickness programs into the typol- to the voluntary state-subsidized model.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
670 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

In all of our 18 countries, some social fore to previous earnings, but because of rela-
policy programsare targeted at those defined tively low ceilings for maximum benefits,
as poor.11Australia, however, bases eligibil- their degree of earnings-relatednessis clearly
ity for old-age pensions and sickness insur- lower than it is in the encompassing coun-
ance benefits on means-tests, and thus it is tries (see Appendix A). Reflecting changes
the only country to follow the targeted during past decades, the basic security coun-
model. 12 tries are also more heterogeneous in that the
In 1985, an easily recognizable cluster is institutional structures of sickness insurance
the corporatist one found in five countries of in three of these countries differ from those
continental Europe-Austria, Belgium, of pension insurance: In sickness insurance,
France, Germany, and Italy. Japan also has a the Netherlandsretains the corporatistmodel,
corporatistmodel with separateprogramsfor Switzerland the voluntary state-subsidized
different parts of the labor force as well as model, and New Zealand the targeted model.
for enterprises of different sizes. 13 These six The encompassing model is found in Fin-
countries have corporatist institutions in land, Norway, and Sweden where it devel-
sickness insurance and in pensions. oped from the basic security and the volun-
The basic security model in its two vari- tary state-subsidized forms. In these coun-
ants is found in a relatively heterogeneous tries, encompassing pension programs are
group of eight countries. "Citizenship"pen- based on universal, flat-rate "People's Pen-
sions with universal coverage exist in sions" supplemented with clearly earnings-
Canada, Denmark, the Netherlands, New related programs for the economically active
Zealand, and Switzerland. In Denmark, the population. Sweden initiated the encompass-
Netherlands, and New Zealand, pensions are ing model by replacing its voluntary state-
paid on a flat-rate basis, whereas in Canada subsidized sickness insurance scheme with a
and Switzerland, a limited earnings-related universal earnings-related program in 1955
component is added to flat-ratepensions. The and by supplementing its universal basic se-
"insurance"variant, with eligibility based on curity pensions with an earnings-relatedpen-
contributions and therefore less than univer- sion programfor all economically active per-
sal coverage, is found in Ireland, the United sons in 1959. Norway and Finland introduced
Kingdom, and the United States. In contrast similar reforms in the 1960s and 1970s.
to the corporatist countries, however, these Whereas characterizing countries on the
three countries include all insuredin the same basis of global policy regimes gives an im-
program. In the United Kingdom and the pression of relative stability and permanence,
United States, pensions are to some extent our focus on the structures of social insur-
related to the level of contributionsand there- ance institutions facilitates the study of
change. The institutional structures in 1985
I Thus, for example, according to our classifi-
are only a snapshot in a process of long-term,
cation, in the United States the old-age insurance intermittentchange. These changes are docu-
(Social Security) is a basic security program of mented and analyzed in another context
the "insurance" variant with somewhat less than
(Korpi 1998).
universal coverage and only moderately earnings-
related benefits, but it coexists with targeted pro-
grams such as AFDC and food stamps. INSTITUTIONS, STRATEGIES OF
12 In Australia, the issue of targeting versus
EQUALITY, AND REDISTRIBUTION
universalism has been significant. Regarding old-
age pensions, the targeted category of citizens has The types of social insurance institutions
gradually been expanded. Because the targeted outlined above can be expected to affect re-
model plays an importantrole in social policy de- distributive processes through differences in
bates, and since Australia retains targeting in all the role they accord to markets and to poli-
major social insurance programs, it is worth ana- tics as well as through the direct and indirect
lyzing the consequences of this model (Castles
1985).
ways in which they tend to encourage or dis-
13 During the Meiji Restoration, the Japanese courage the formation of risk pools with
government was influenced by the then new Ger- varying degrees of homogeneity in terms of
man social insurance legislation and attemptedto socioeconomically structureddistribution of
modify it for domestic use. risks and resources. The targeted model ap-

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 671

parently involves the lowest degree of politi- the nonpoor, between workers and salaried
cal interferencewith marketdistribution,fol- employees.
lowed by the voluntary subsidized model and The institutions of the corporatist and the
the basic security model. The basic security voluntary state-subsidized models have di-
model establishes a base for market-based rect effects on the segmenting of risk pools.
stratification.The corporatistmodel involves The corporatist model is based on a direct
greater encroachment on market distribution segmentation of risk pools along socioeco-
than does the basic security model, but, be- nomic lines. By creating programs specific
cause of its occupational segmentation and to branches of industry and occupational sta-
its exclusion of the economically nonactive tus, corporatist programs separate citizens
population and top-income earners, it en- into relatively homogeneous risk categories
croaches less than the encompassing model. that are accorded more or less differing con-
In traditionalinsuranceterminology, social ditions, contributions, and benefits. Thus,
insurance involves the creation of risk pools this model brings to the fore the potential
within which risks and resources are shared. lines of socioeconomic cleavages among citi-
In the Westerncountries, economic risks and zens, creates differences in short-term eco-
resources are unequally distributed along nomic interests among occupational catego-
lines that tend to follow socioeconomic ries, and tends to institutionalize these dif-
cleavages. For social insurance, the socio- ferences. Furthermore,the corporatistmodel
economic structuretherefore offers opportu- limits the pooling of risks and resources by
nities to delineate risk pools that are more or excluding the economically nonactive popu-
less homogeneous in terms of risks and re- lation and top-income earners.
sources. We hypothesize that the structures In the voluntary state-subsidized model,
of social insurance institutions can empha- social insurance institutions reflect socioeco-
size differences in risks and resources by in- nomic differences. By organizing relatively
creasing homogeneity within risk pools in homogeneous categories of citizens defined
terms of their socioeconomic composition, or in terms of occupation or domicile and by
they can play down these differences by relying largely on contributionsby members,
pooling resources and sharing risks across voluntary state-subsidized insurance often is
socioeconomically heterogeneous categories. dominated by middle-class groups, while
Social insurance institutions thereby can low-income earners are less well covered.
shape the processes of defining interests and Thus, the voluntary state-subsidized model
identities among citizens, the rational can be expected to discourage coalition for-
choices citizens are likely to make, and the mation between the disadvantaged and the
ways in which they are likely to combine for more fortunate citizens and to generate seg-
collective action.14 Of special interest in this mentation along socioeconomic lines.
context is the extent to which institutional Institutional structuresalso affect coalition
structures discourage or encourage coalition formation and the definition of interests
formation between the poor citizens and bet- among citizens in indirect ways through the
ter-off citizens and between the working various "strategies of equality" they can be
class and the middle class, thus making their seen as embodying. These strategies can be
definitions of interest diverge or converge. defined by their degree of low-income target-
Divergence can be fostered by either institu- ing, (i.e., the extent to which budgets used
tional structures that directly segment risk for redistribution go to those defined as
pools along socioeconomic lines, or indi- poor). The degree of low-income targeting
rectly via redistributive strategies that create varies between institutional types. The tar-
differences of interest between the poor and geted model can be said to follow the Robin
Hood strategy of taking from the rich and
giving to the poor. The flat-rate benefits in
14 Risk groups play a role in the development
the basic security model (as well as those in
of social policies, as stressed by Baldwin (1990),
but not primarily as independent driving forces. many voluntary state-subsidized programs)
Instead, risk groups are created in part by social reflect a simple egalitarian strategy with
insurance institutions, and once formed, act to equal benefits for all, but in relative terms
safeguard their specific interests. giving more to low-income earners than to

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
672 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

the better off. The earnings-related benefits not only themselves but low-income groups
found in the corporatist and encompassing as well (Hirschman 1970).
models follow the biblical Matthewprinciple The debate about the redistributive out-
of giving more, in absolute terms, to the rich comes of welfare state programshas focused
than to the poor, and also, in relative terms, almost exclusively on how to distribute the
having limited low-income targeting. money available for transfer and has largely
By discriminating in favor of the poor, the ignored variations in the size of the redis-
targetedmodel creates a zero-sum conflict of tributive budget (i.e., the total sum available
interests between the poor and the better-off for redistribution).The degree of redistribu-
workers and the middle classes who must tion finally achieved depends on the size of
pay for the benefits of the poor without re- the redistributive budget as well as on the
ceiving any benefits. The targeted model degree of low-income targeting. Without
thus tends to drive a wedge between the specifying the functional form or all other
short-termmaterial interests of the poor and relevant factors, the degree of redistribution
those of the rest of the population, which achieved can be seen as including a multipli-
must rely on private insurance. It gives the cative element-final redistribution is a
better-off categories no rational basis for in- function of degree of low-income targeting x
cluding the poor, and leaves the poor to trust redistributivebudget size.
in the altruism of the more fortunate. The neglect of budget size is all the more
As made explicit by Beveridge (1942), in unfortunate, since, as the discussion above
the basic security model flat-rate benefits are indicates we can expect a trade-off between
intended only to provide a safety net for the the degree of low-income targeting and the
working class, while the middle classes are size of the redistributive budget, such that
expected to safeguard their standardsof liv- the greater the degree of low-income target-
ing through various forms of private insur- ing, the smaller the redistributive budget.
ance. Social insurance systems in the basic This trade-off indicates that it is impossible
security model therefore tend to become a to maximize both the degree of low-income
concern primarilyfor manual workers, while targeting and budget size. In so far as wel-
as in the targeted model, private insurance is fare state institutions contribute to the pool-
likely to loom large for salaried employees ing of risks and resources and to the forma-
and other better-off groups. Therefore, the tion of coalitions that include the middle
basic security model is also likely to sepa- classes as well as the working class and the
rate the interests of high-income strata from poor, they are likely to affect the size of the
those of workers and the poor. redistributive budget.'5 Therefore, encom-
In contrast to voluntary and corporatist passing institutions are expected to generate
programs, the encompassing model includes the broadestbase of supportfor welfare state
all citizens in the same programs. By giving expansion and the largest budget size. How-
basic security to everybody and by offering ever, although corporatist institutions ex-
clearly earnings-related benefits to all eco- clude the economically inactive population
nomically active individuals, in contrast to and segment different occupational catego-
the targeted and basic security models, the ries, because of their earnings-related ben-
encompassing model brings low-income efits they are expected to generate relatively
groups and the better-off citizens into the large budgets. In spite of a high level of cov-
same institutional structures. Because of its erage, the basic security countries with rela-
earnings-related benefits, it is likely to re- tively low benefits are expected to have
duce the demand for private insurance. Thus, smaller budgets than either the corporatist
the encompassing model can be expected to welfare states or the encompassing welfare
have the most favorable outcomes in terms
of the formation of cross-class coalitions that 15 Redistributive budgets are financed through
include manualworkers as well as the middle
taxation with different degrees of progressivity.
classes. By providing sufficiently high ben- Thus, this redistributive formula can also be ap-
efits for high-income groups so as not to plied to the financing side of the redistributive
push them to exit, in encompassing institu- process. We study the combined redistribution
tions the voice of the better-off citizens helps achieved via the tax and transfer systems.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 673

states. The smallest budget is expected in the


institutional types of welfare states and their
targeted welfare state. distributive outcomes in terms of the extent
To test the above hypotheses empirically, of poverty and inequality. We expect poverty
we look first at the overall correlation be- and inequality to be highest in countries with
tween institutional structures and outcomes the targeted and basic security models and
in terms of the degree of inequality and the lowest in countries with the encompassing
level of poverty in the countries for which model, with the corporatist countries falling
relevant data are available. Such a correla- somewhere in between.
tion highlights the need to open the black For 11 of our 18 countries, we are able to
box of causal processes assumed to mediate use micro-surveys on household income in-
cluded in the Luxembourg Income Study
the effects from institutions to redistributive
outcomes. Within the scope of this paper and (LIS).18 Limitations in the LIS-data re-
stricted this part of the analysis to the fol-
with the data now available, it is possible to
take only a partial look into this black box-lowing countries (years for income data are
by following the subsequent stages in the in parentheses): Australia (1985), Canada
causal processes and attempting to verify (1987), Finland (1987), France (1984), Ger-
these different steps. many (Federal Republic) (1984), the Nether-
To the extent that we can verify the work-lands (1987), Norway (1987), Sweden
ing of the hypothesized processes in the sub-(1987), Switzerland (1982), United Kingdom
sequent stages of the redistributive process,(1986), and the United States (1986). Analy-
we can consider our hypotheses to be sup- ses are carried out for the total population,
ported. Accordingly, we will here rely on thethe working-age population (25 to 59 years
combined patternof evidence from different of age), and the elderly (over age 65) (Ap-
pendix A presents a full description of meth-
parts of the redistributiveprocess in evaluat-
ing the supportfor our hypotheses.16 Institu-ods and indicators).
tional structures, however, are only one of For the study of income distribution, the
many factors that affect the distribution of household is generally taken as the income-
income in a country (Hicks and Misra 1993; receiving unit within which members' eco-
Huber, Ragin, and Stephens 1993). Political nomic resources are likely to be pooled,19
traditions, demographic composition, labor but, when using the income distribution to
force participationrates, levels of unemploy-judge economic well-being, individuals
ment, wage setting practices, and industrial should be the units of observation. When
structures are also important.'7 At best we comparing households of different sizes, it is
can hope for a partial agreement between our reasonable to weight family income by the
hypotheses and comparative empirical data. sizes of the family and to account for econo-
As is often the case in comparative research,mies of scale by giving different weights to
we lack good quantitative indicators for the first and "other" family members (Buh-
some relevant variables and will have to use mann et al. 1988). Therefore, the income of
available proxies. each household is divided by an equivalence
scale, and this adjusted disposable income is
then weighted so that each individual gets an
INSTITUTIONS, INEQUALITY, AND
equal count (see Appendix A). Using the so-
POVERTY called standardmodel of income distribution
The causal processes outlined above lead us analysis, disposable income refers to net cash
to expect considerable differences among our income after direct taxes, social security con-
tributions, and public cash transfers (Ringen
16 In view of the relatedness of the hypotheses
18 The LIS data offer great flexibility in terms
concerning different parts of the redistributive
process and the small number of countries for of definitions and in the selection of income units
which information is available, quantitative sta- and variables. Although the accuracy of the data
tistical analyses have been kept to a minimum. is also much better than those in previous stud-
17 Some of these factors can partly be con- ies, some problems of comparability remain.
trolled for by an examination of the change in in- 19It should be noted, however, that within
equality when we move from market income to families we may find gender differences in the
gross and disposable income (cf. below). availability of economic resources.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
674 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 2. Inequality (Gini) and Poverty Rates in Disposable Income by Age and Type of Social Insur-
ance Institution: 11 OECD Countries, ca. 1985

Type of Social Inequality(Gini Coefficient) Poverty Rate (Percentage)a


Insurance Total 25 to 59 65 Total 25 to 59 65
Institution/Country Population Years or Older Population Years or Older
Encompassing
Finland .231 .205 .219 4.1 1.6 3.9
Norway .232 .218 .241 3.5 2.9 2.6
Sweden .215 .194 .182 4.9 2.6 1.4
Corporatist
France .292 .292 .287 8.5 8.0 1.9
Germany .243 .235 .278 5.8 5.3 5.3
Basic Security
Canada .279 .277 .257 10.9 10.9 4.9
Netherlands .252 .254 .220 5.8 3.5 .2
Switzerland .320 .305 .355 7.4 5.8 11.9
United Kingdom .293 .293 .242 13.2 11.0 9.2
United States .333 .327 .355 17.9 17.8 17.5
Targeted
Australia .310 .301 .279 9.1 9.3 5.2

Source:LuxembourgIncome Study.
a Percentagebelow 50 percentof the medianincome.

1987; see Whiteford 1993 for a critique). the distribution of disposable household in-
There are strong arguments for viewing come in the 11 countries for which full data
needs and welfare in relative terms (i.e., an on the income formation process are avail-
individual's welfare is to some extent deter- able. We find considerable differences in in-
mined by her or his position relative to oth- come inequality and the extent of poverty
ers [Goodin 1990]). Therefore, we use the among countries using different institutional
traditional Gini coefficient to describe the models. For the total population, the work-
overall degree of income inequality. We also ing-age population, and the elderly, the low-
look at those with the lowest incomes. As is est income inequality is found in the three
well-known, the measurementof poverty in- encompassing countries-Finland, Norway,
volves a number of problems and consider- and Sweden. Among the basic security coun-
able arbitrariness (Kangas and Ritakallio tries, variation in Gini coefficients is rela-
1995). Thus, among the elderly, for example, tively large-the Netherlands has a relatively
we find a clustering of persons around in- low coefficient and the United States has the
come levels provided by minimum pensions. highest coefficient. The highest income in-
This clustering makes the indicator of cross- equality figures occur in the basic security
national differences in poverty highly sensi- and targetedmodels, especially in the United
tive to the choice of the poverty line (Palme States, Switzerland,Australia, and the United
1998). Here we define poverty rates for each Kingdom. The two corporatist countries,
country as the percentage of the population France and Germany, occupy intermediate
below 50 percent of the median income. positions.
Table 2 indicates the overall relevance of A similar pattern emerges for poverty
our institutional welfare states typology for rates. With a few exceptions, the lowest pov-
income equality and poverty. It presents the erty rates are found among countries in the
results from LIS-based analyses that describe encompassing category. Again, the variation

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 675

in poverty rates among the basic security Table 3. Social Benefit Expenditures as a Per-
countries is high. The Netherlands again re- centage of GDP, by Type of Social In-
sembles the encompassing countries, and the surance Institution: 18 OECD Coun-
tries, 1985
United States has the highest poverty rate.
With its targeted model, Australia also has Percentage of GDP for:
comparatively high poverty rates. Again, the
Type of Social Total Expenditures
two corporatist countries, France and Ger- Insurance Total minus
many, occupy intermediate positions. These Institution/ Benefit Unemployment
results thus give considerable supportfor our Country Expenditures Insurance Benefits
hypothesis about the overall role of welfare
Encompassing
state institutions in the distributive processes
of the Western countries. Finland 21.3 20.8
Norway 28.0 27.3
Sweden 29.5 28.8
BUDGETS, TARGETING, AND
Average 26.3 25.6
REDISTRIBUTION
As indicated above, we expect to find the Corporatist
largest redistributive budgets in the encom- Austria 24.3 23.5
passing countries, followed in descending Belgium 26.4 22.5
order by corporatist, basic security, and tar- France 27.3 24.5
geted categories of countries. As the best Germany 23.3 21.8
available proxy for the size of redistributive Italy 20.5 19.7
budgets in our 18 countries, we use Interna- Japan 11.1 10.7
tional LabourOffice (ILO) data on social ex- Average 22.5 20.5
penditures, which include expenditures for
cash transfersas well as for noncash benefits Basic Security
(InternationalLabourOffice 1992).20 Expen- Canada 15.6 12.3
ditures refer to 1985. At that time, unemploy- Denmark 27.5 24.3
ment levels varied greatly among the OECD Ireland 21.8 18.2
countries: The percentage of GDP spent on Netherlands 28.2 24.9
unemployment benefits ranged from .7 per- New Zealand 14.6 14.0
cent in Norway to about 3.5 percent in Bel- Switzerland 13.5 13.2
gium, Denmark, and Ireland. The direct cost United Kingdom 19.4 17.6
of income maintenance for the unemployed United States 12.0 11.6
depends in part on benefit replacement lev- Average 19.1 17.0
els, but in practice reflects primarilythe level
of unemployment (Kangas and Palme Targeted
199 lb). Table 3 presents total benefit expen- Australia 9.9 8.6
ditures as well as total benefit expenditures Source: International Labour Office (1992).
minus expenditures for the unemployed as a
percentage of GDP.
The results in Table 3 confirm the expected have total expenditure levels approximating
general rank-orderamong institutional types those in the encompassing group. After ex-
and budget size. However, some countries in cluding expenditures for unemployment ben-
the basic security and corporatist categories efits, two of the three encompassing coun-
tries, Sweden and Norway, have the highest
20 The costs of social security in these data expenditure levels. Finland, however, still
cover nine branches of social security, related to has relatively low levels, which may partly
medical care and benefits with respect to sick- reflect its relatively young population (also
ness, unemployment, old-age, employment in-
see text below for a discussion on problems
jury, family, maternity, invalidity, and survivors.
In contrast to the OECD definition of social ex- of comparability). With the exception of Ja-
penditures, the ILO definition does not include pan, expenditure levels are relatively high in
the cost of education, which is less relevant in the corporatist countries. In the basic secu-
this context. rity countries, the average is lower, but here

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
676 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

55

50 * Sweden

* Netherlands
45
* Germany
U
eU
.? 40- - United
E France Kingdom
.
* Norway
'a 35 -
E) * Finland *Canada
E
? 30- *m Australia

* United States
25
2 Switzerland

20

15 l
5 10 15 20 25
Relative Size of Redistributive Budgetb

Figure 2. Relative Size of the Redistributive Budget and Income Redistribution: 11 OECD Countries
Source: LuxembourgIncome Study.
a Income redistribution
equals the reductionin the Gini coefficient from marketincome to disposable
income expressedas a percentageof the Gini for marketincome.
b Relative size of the redistribution
budgetequals transferincome as a percentageof gross income.

again we find relatively wide variation. Aus- the degree of income redistributionachieved
tralia, with its targeted social insurance pro- through the tax and transfer systems. The
grams, has the lowest expenditure levels. correlation between these two variables is
Do size of the redistributive budget and strong (r = .92). The lowest level of redistri-
degree of low-income targeting reduce in- bution is found in two basic security coun-
come inequality? To control for variations in tries-Switzerland and the United States-as
market income inequality among countries, well as in the targetedmodel Australia; these
we examine income redistribution in terms three countries also have the smallest welfare
of the relative reduction in Gini coefficients states. The Netherlandsand Sweden have the
when we move from market income to dis- largest redistributive budgets, and they also
posable income (i.e., after taxes and trans- have the highest redistributive effects. The
fers; for definitions of terms see Appendix two corporatist countries, France and Ger-
A). We present results for the total popula- many, have fairly large transfer budgets and
tion (results are similar for the working-age also show relatively large reductions in Gini
population, ages 25 to 59). Redistributive coefficients.
budget size in a country is measured as the We run into problems, however, of lack of
size of transfers as a percentage of gross in- comparability between different data sets-
come (defined as post-transfer but pre-tax problems that are all too familiar to com-
income). parative social scientists. Thus, in terms of
Figure 2 presents the bivariate plot of the the LIS data, Finland with its encompassing
relative size of the redistributive budget by institutions appears among countries with

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 677

55 -

50-- Sweden
* Netherlands
45 -
EGermany
co EUnited Kingdom
.? 40-
.0 U France
n35 -U* Norway
M
N~~~~~~~Finland
E *Canada
0
?30 - * Australia

*United States
25
ESwitzerland

20

15
-40 -30 -20 -10 0 10 20
Index of Targeting of Transfer Incomeb

Figure 3. Index of Targeting of Transfer Income and Income Redistribution: 11 OECD Countries
Source:LuxembourgIncome Study.
a Income redistributionequals the
reductionin the Gini coefficient from marketincome to disposable
income expressedas a percentageof the Gini for marketincome.
b Negative values indicate low-income
targetingfor transferincome; positive values indicate the target-
ing of transferincome to residentswho are economically better-off.

small transfer budgets. This largely reflects rate but less redistribution than Norway.
the fact that the Finnish earnings-related Contrary to expectations based on the ILO
pension schemes are inappropriatelytreated data, in the LIS data the United Kingdom
as private programs in the LIS data. Al- has the same transfer size as Sweden and
though the Finnish pension programs are the Netherlands, probably reflecting the
administered by private insurance compa- high levels of unemployment.
nies, they were created and are financed To assess the degree of low-income tar-
through legislation and should thus be re- geting, we use an index of the degree of tar-
garded as public programs. In the LIS data, geting of transfers. This index takes on
Norway, despite its encompassing institu- negative values when transfers are targeted
tions, also appears as an average welfare at individuals with low gross incomes, and
spender. This partly reflects Norway's high takes on positive values when transfers are
pension age (67 years) and partly the use of concentrated on those with higher gross in-
legislated employer wage-continuation in comes. Values around zero indicate, in dis-
sickness and work accident insurance that, tributive terms, neutral outcomes. Figure 3
in the LIS data, is defined as market in- indicates, as our hypotheses predict, that the
come.21 Canada has an intermediate transfer lower the degree of targeting at low-income
groups (i.e., the higher the value indicated
21 Also, Germany has wage-continuation peri- by the index), the greater the redistribution.
ods in sickness and work accident insurance. The correlation between the index of trans-

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
678 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

fer targeting and income redistribution in INCOME INEQUALITY AMONG THE


the transfer system is positive although rela- ELDERLY
tively low (r = .45). The transfer systems in
Sweden and the Netherlands, which have In the analysis of the effects of the social in-
little or no targeting to low-income groups, surance institutions on inequality and pov-
bring about the largest redistribution. erty, the elderly provide an interesting test
France, with the largest positive value on case. The economic situation of the elderly
the index of targeting, achieves a medium is determinedby their previous economic ac-
level of redistribution.In contrast, although tivities as well as by public transfers. Thus,
Australia targets much more of its transfers their situation reflects the cumulative effects
at the less well-off than does any other of forces operating in markets and in poli-
country, with the exception of Switzerland tics, but public transfers play a greater role
and the United States, it achieves less redis- in their income than they do for the working
tribution than any of them. Several coun- population. The goal of eradicating poverty
tries with low to intermediate levels of tar- and achieving relatively low income inequal-
geting achieve very different degrees of re- ity probably commands more support with
distribution. respect to the elderly than it does with regard
The correlation between the index of tar- to economically active citizens. Many fear
geting of transfersand the size of transfersis that "earnings-relatedsystems may . . . per-
positive, although relatively low (r = .49). petuate existing income inequalities over the
This correlation indicates that, as expected, life cycle" (Mitchell, Harding, and Gruen
there tends to be a trade-off between the de- 1994:324).
gree of low-income targeting and the size of Because of the relationship between old-
budgets made available for transfers. Thus, age benefits and previous income, public
the more that countries target benefits to pensions probably exhibit the highest degree
low-income categories, the smaller their re- of inequality in the encompassing and cor-
distributive budgets. poratist countries, and the lowest degree of
It could be argued that in countries with inequality in the basic security countries. In
basic security programs, meager social in- the targeted model, however, transfers are
surance payments are compensated for by directed primarily at low-income categories.
more generous income-tested or means- LIS data allow us to study the consequences
tested benefits. Nevertheless, we find a of these differences in public pensions on in-
positive, although relatively weak, correla- equality among the elderly in nine countries
tion (r = .48) between our index of targeting during the mid-1980s.23Thus, in terms of the
of transfer income via social insurance pro- index of targeting of transfer income, the
grams and the relative size of income-tested highest positive values (i.e. the highest de-
or means-tested social assistance program gree of inequality) occur for public pensions
benefits in a country.22Thus, countries in in the three encompassing countries-Fin-
which social insurance programs target ben- land, Sweden, and Norway-as well as in
efits to low-income categories not only have corporatist Germany, all countries with rela-
relatively small redistributive social insur- tively high maximum pensions (see Figure
ance budgets, but they also have restricted 4). In the basic security countries-the
general means-tested programs. Countries United States, the Netherlands, the United
with large welfare states, like the Nordic Kingdom, and Canada-public pensions are
countries, not only have high transfer rates relatively neutral in terms of distribution. In
via social insurance programs but also gain the targeted country, Australia, however, the
legitimacy for increased spending on in- negative value of the index of targeting indi-
come-tested benefits outside the social in-
surance programs.
23 Figure 4 is constructed from the LIS data,
22 Totalexpenditures on means-tested and in- except for Finland and Sweden, where we had to
come-tested programs as percent of GDP are reanalyze the original national data sets in order
taken from the International Labour Office to get a proper division between public and pri-
(1992). vate pensions (see Kangas and Palme 1993).

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 679

.40
L Indexof Targeting
.35 IncomeInequality(Gini)

.30

.25

.20

* .15 1

.10

.05

.05

-.10

Figure 4. Index of Targeting of Public Pensions and Income Inequality (Gini) in Gross Income among
the Elderly: Nine OECD Countries
Sources: LuxembourgIncome Study;Kangasand Palme (1993).

cates that public pensions go primarily to among the elderly, second only to the United
low-income earners.24 States. Countries with relatively flat-rate
Public pensions are only one of the factors pensions-the Netherlands, the United King-
determining total income inequality among dom, and Canada-also have higher inequal-
the elderly. When we look at inequality in ity in total income among the elderly than do
total gross income among the elderly (in- the earnings-relatedcountries.
cluding private and occupational pensions as How can we account for these rather sur-
well as income from savings and earnings), prising results? One factor generating differ-
the picture is largely reversed. The lowest in- ences in income inequality between various
equality in total gross income occurs in the social insurance models is the relative roles
four countries with the most unequal public played by public and private transfer sys-
pensions-Finland, Sweden, Germany, and tems. Social insurance institutions affect the
Norway. In contrast,Australia, with pensions public/private insurance mix in a country.
targeted at low-income groups, has much Economically better-off citizens are more
higher inequality in total gross income likely to acquire private pension insurance
than are low-income earners. Thus, the de-
24 In the 1970s, the degree of income targeting
mand for private pension insurance depends
in Australian social programs decreased, reach- partly on the maximum benefit levels of the
ing a low in 1977-1978. Since then, targeting has public systems, which determine whether the
gradually increased. By 1985, the income test for middle classes and high-income earners are
the old-age pension had been reintroduced(SCIP- given earnings-related pensions or are
data). pushed toward private pension programs.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
680 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

2.2

2.0 l u * Switzerland
CL Australia
O * mCanada
0
'O 1.8-
m
cm * United States
= 1.6

0L 1.4.- * Denmark
co
(L1.4
e Germany
c1.2 -.z Netherlands
r0 * United Kingdom

DL 1.0
0
France
m* .Japan
.8
(L
m Belgium
o mNorway * Sweden
0 .6 mIreland

c
CL
. .4
~ ~ Zealand
~*New ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~*
Austria
mFinland
.2
mItaly

0 I I I
20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200
Maximum Public Pension
as Percentage of an Average Production Worker's Wage

Figure 5. Maximum Public Pensions and Private Pension Expenditures: 18 OECD Countries, ca. 1980
(1990); KangasandPalme(199la).
Sources: Social CitizenshipIndicatorProgram(SCIP),Esping-Andersen

The encompassing institutional countries, Palme 1991a). From the SCIP data, we take
which provide clearly earnings-related ben- information for 1980 on the level of net
efits for all citizens, are expected to generate maximum public pensions for a single per-
the lowest level of private insurance. In con- son, expressed as a percentage of average net
trast, the targeted or basic security countries earnings (after taxes and social security con-
are likely to have high levels of private in- tributions) among production workers. Fig-
surance because high-income earners in ure 5 portrays a negative moderate correla-
these countries must rely on private channels tion (-.53) between maximum pension lev-
for income security. The demand for private els and the relative size of private pension
insurance should be lower in the corporatist expenditures. On average, private pension
model because of its earnings-related ben- expenditures as a percentage of GDP are low
efits for those insured. However, because of in the encompassing countries (Finland, Nor-
income ceilings for coverage and sizable cat- way, and Sweden), followed closely by the
egories of noncovered citizens, we expect corporatist group, while the basic security
private insurance to play a larger role in the countries and the targeted country have
corporatist model than in the encompassing higher expenditure levels.25 Thus, the high-
model.
These hypotheses are tested using esti- 25 The earnings-related system in Norway had
mates of the size of private pension expendi- not fully matured for those retiring in 1980, but
tures relative to GDP available for 1980 future retirees could expect higher maximum pen-
(Esping-Andersen 1990:84; Kangas and sions, something contributing to small private

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 681

est private pension expenditures are found in expenditure is relatively strongly correlated
Australia, the targetedcountry,and in the ba- with inequality in total gross income for the
sic security countries-Switzerland, Canada, elderly (rank correlation = .83). These data
the United States, Denmark,the Netherlands, are thus congruent with the hypothesis that
and the United Kingdom-in which maxi- when public pensions provide high-income
mum public pensions represent less than 60 earners with income security, they crowd out
percent of an average production worker's private pensions and other sources of income
wage. Ireland and New Zealand, which have that are likely to be even more unequal than
basic security institutions, are outliers with public pensions. The final outcome is that
low private pension expenditures in spite of earnings-related universal public pensions
low maximum public pensions.26 The high- tend to generate less gross income inequality
est maximum pensions (representing 120 to among the elderly than do targeted or basic
180 percent of an average production security pensions.
worker's wage) are found in the three corpo-
ratist countries-Austria, Italy, and Ger-
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION
many-and in Finland, an encompassing
country.Except for Germany,these countries The social insurance models outlined here
also have the lowest private pension expen- developed over a century of conflicts among
ditures. The exception of Germany is partly different interest groups concerning the dis-
related to the fact that the corporatist Ger- tribution of people's worldly goods. These
man public pension system for salaried em- models are associated with different strate-
ployees traditionallyexcluded the very high- gies of equality and different roles for mar-
income earners, who had to turn to private kets and politics in distributive processes,
pensions.27In addition, economically nonac- and they can have different consequences for
tive persons in Germany, primarily women, income distribution and poverty among citi-
were excluded from compulsory insurance. zens. We find that by providing high-income
These results indicate that the institutional earners with earnings-related benefits, en-
structure of public pension systems, prima- compassing social insurance institutions can
rily the extent to which they include and pro- reduce inequality and poverty more effi-
vide income security for high-income earn- ciently than can flat-rate or targetedbenefits.
ers, is important for the relative size of pri- This finding may surprise many scholars and
vate pension programs. In the encompassing policymakers. The traditional arguments fa-
countries and the corporatist countries, the voring low-income targeting and flat-rate
relatively high maximum public pensions benefits have focused on the distribution of
tend to reduce the demand for private pen- money actually transferred and overlook
sions. In the basic security and targeted three basic circumstances. (1) The size of re-
countries, however, better-off citizens must distributive budgets is not necessarily fixed
rely on private pensions to attain income se- but tends to depend on the type of welfare
curity. Among the nine countries for which state institutions that exist in a country. (2)
data are available, the size of private pension There tends to be a trade-off between the ex-
tent of low-income targeting and the size of
pensions. In Sweden, relatively large private oc- redistributivebudgets. (3) And because large
cupational pension systems existed prior to the categories of citizens cannot or are not will-
establishment of earnings-related pensions, and ing to acquire private earnings-relatedinsur-
because the ceiling in this system is only moder- ance and because of the socioeconomic se-
ately high, these systems have been retained. lection processes operating, the outcomes of
26 The Irish case may partly reflect the impor- market-dominated distribution tend to be
tance of agriculture in this country. In New more unequal than the distribution found in
Zealand, private savings for old age in the form earnings-related social insurance programs.
of homeownership is encouraged (Davidson
1994).
Recognition of these factors helps us under-
27 The ceiling for coverage of pensions was
stand what we call the paradox of redistribu-
abolished in Germanyin 1967, making it formally tion: The more we target benefits at the poor
possible for all salaried employees to join the only and the more concerned we are with
public program. creating equality via equal public transfers

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
682 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

to all, the less likely we are to reduce pov- Contrary to many scholars' expectations,
erty and inequality. earnings-related benefits appear to be a con-
The'LIS and SCIP data sets have enabled dition for, rather than a hindrance to, the re-
us to test hypotheses on causal processes duction of inequality. Because of their low
among welfare state institutions, redistribu- ceilings for earnings replacement, targeted
tive processes, and distributive outcomes. programsand basic security programsstimu-
Yet, in view of the difficulties involved in late program exit among the middle classes
carrying out comparative research in these and increase the demand for private insur-
areas, some of our results are primarily sug- ance. From the point of view of equality, the
gestive of future research. Our analyses in- problem with the corporatist model is not
dicate that the institutions of the welfare that benefits are earnings-related. The main
state are of key importance in producing the difference between the corporatist and the
paradox of redistribution. These institutions encompassing models is that by organizing
affect the relative roles of markets and poli- the economically active citizens into occupa-
tics in distributive processes and the types tionally segmented social insurance pro-
of coalitions formed among interest groups. grams, the corporatist model highlights so-
The effects on poverty and inequality ap- cioeconomic distinctions among different
pear to be largest in countries with encom- categories of citizens and creates divergent
passing institutions and lowest in the basic interests among these categories. In contrast,
security countries. The Australian experi- encompassing institutions pool the risks and
ence indicates that targeting-excluding the resources of all citizens and thus create con-
better-off citizens-is not highly effective in verging definitions of interest.
reducing poverty and inequality. The corpo- The encompassing model requires high
ratist countries occupy an intermediate posi- taxes and generates large social security
tion. In all categories of countries, however, transfers, often described as unnecessary
additional factors that could not be consid- "churning." This has generated concern
ered here are also relevant, such as the rela- among social scientists and policymakers
tive strength of political parties and eco- who fear that universalistic earnings-related
nomic factors affecting the distribution of welfare state programs will be unsustainable
market incomes. In some countries, such as because of the economic inefficiencies, bud-
the United States where racial cleavages are get deficits, and the tax revolts they are ex-
correlated with income, institutional demar- pected to generate. Thus, neoclassical eco-
cations may be reinforced by racial ones nomic theory assumes that through "tax
(Quadagno 1994). wedges," high taxes create serious distor-
We view institutions as intervening vari- tions in marketmechanisms, reduce work in-
ables that reflect conflicts of interest among centives, and thereby reduce economic effi-
different interest groups and affect the defi- ciency and growth. Careful empirical analy-
nitions of interests and coalition formation ses, however, indicate no major negative ef-
among citizens, which in turn have conse- fects on the labor supply (Atkinson and
quences for the size of budgets available for Mogensen 1993). In Sweden, the prototype
redistribution and the final degree of redis- of the encompassing welfare state, it has not
tribution achieved. The empirical testing of been possible empirically to demonstrate
the macro-microlinks among institutions and slowdowns of economic growth that can be
the formation of interests and coalitions pro- attributed to the welfare state (Dowrick
vides a major challenge to social scientists, 1996; Korpi 1996).
but comparative micro-data currently are By providing earnings-relatedbenefits and
lacking. Of indirect relevance in this context non-means-tested benefits, the encompassing
is the fact that in the countries with encom- model generates incentives to work and also
passing institutions, surveys have shown that avoids poverty traps. Furthermore,if citizens
universal and encompassing programs re- find that they get significant benefits in re-
ceive considerably more support among citi- turn for their taxes, their take-home pay is
zens than do means-tested or income-tested no longer the only basis for work incentives.
programs (Forma 1996; Kangas 1995; If tax payments are seen as providing indi-
Kangas and Palme 1993; Svallfors 1996). vidual benefits and the free-rider problem

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 683

can be overcome, the effects of tax wedges of Matthew than to the practices in Sher-
will tend to decrease. Such factors make it wood Forest.
difficult to find empirical supportfor the hy-
pothesis of neoclassical economics that taxes Walter Korpi is Professor at the Swedish Insti-
have serious negative effects on efficiency. tute for Social Research, Stockholm University.
What can be demonstrated, however, is the His research interests include distributive con-
superior capacity of the encompassing wel- flict, political sociology, social movements and
political economy. He has published comparative
fare state to reduce inequality and poverty. It work on these issues in this and other journals.
would require much "churning" to transfer He has recently published books on unemploy-
some of the surplus cream in the capitalist ment and on economic growth in Sweden.
democracies to their poor citizens. Many fear
Joakim Palme is Senior Researcher at the Swed-
that although universalistic earnings-related
ish Institutefor Social Research. His research fo-
programs are popular, citizens will balk at cuses on the development of welfare institutions
the tax levels required to sustain them and at among the advanced industrial nations, and the
the budget deficits they may generate. Em- causes and consequences of this development. He
pirical evidence, however, does not support has written on pension rights, the public-private
such arguments.28 mix of welfare provisions, and on health and so-
In the Western countries, the emphasis on cial insurance. He has recently directed a study
targetinghas been increasing in recent years. on "Welfare State in Crisis" for the Council of
If the goal is to reduce poverty and inequal- Europe.
ity, this is an unfortunate development.
Lawson and Wilson (1995), reflecting on the Appendix A. Methods and Indicators
War on Poverty in the United States, argue
that policies to support the poor "should be- The distinction between basic security programs
gin with a new public rhetoric that does two and encompassingprogramsis based on the degrees
things: focuses on the problems that afflict of earnings-relatednessand coverage. Because of
not only the poor, but the working and the difference between short-term and long-term
middle classes as well; and emphasizes inte- forms of income replacementwhen determiningthe
degree of earnings-relatedness,we use different in-
grative programsthat promote the social and dicators for pension programs and sickness pro-
economic improvement of all groups in soci- grams.In both cases, however, the critical factor is
ety, not just the truly disadvantagedsegments whetherthe maximumbenefits in the legislatedpro-
of the population" (p. 706). Our analyses grams give higher provisions than the benefits of
here support this recommendation. average productionworkers and hence include the
To paraphrasean old saying, if we attempt middle classes within the frameworkof the statu-
tory system.
to fight the war on poverty through target- In the pension area, we have used the net maxi-
efficient benefits concentrated on the poor, mum pension to measurethe degree of earnings-re-
we may win some battles, but we will prob- latedness. Maximumpension relates the net maxi-
ably lose the war. Universalism is not mum pension to the net wage of an averageproduc-
enough, however. To be effective, universal- tion worker.In the eight basic securitycountries,the
ism must be combined with a strategy of maximumpension equals the pension for an average
production worker, except in Switzerland and the
equality that comes closer to the preaching United Kingdom, where the maximumpension re-
places 52 percentand 61 percentof an averagepro-
28 For the period 1980-1990, the average defi- duction worker's wage, respectively (less than 10
cit in general government financial balances was percentagepoints higher than the replacementrate
4.8 percent in our corporatist countries, 4.2 per- of an average productionworker's pension). In the
cent in the basic security countries, and 1.1 per- encompassing countries, the maximum pension in
relationto the average productionworker's wage is
cent in Australia, the targeted country. Among
76 percent in Norway and 101 percent Sweden
our three encompassing countries, however, only (more than 10 percentagepoints higher than the re-
Sweden had a deficit (1.1 percent), while Finland placement rate of an average productionworker's
and Norway ran surpluses, giving an average sur- pension). For Finland, which has no formal maxi-
plus of 2.3 percent in the encompassing countries. mum pension (ceiling), we use the pension level of
For the countries and years for which we have in- a person with earnings three times the level of an
come data in the LIS data set, there is zero corre- average productionworker.In basic security coun-
lation between budget position and size of redis- tries of the "insurance"variant,pensioncoverage(as
tributive budgets. a percentageof the populationaged 15 to 64 years)

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
684 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

in Ireland, the United Kingdom, and the United The equivalencescale used here gives a weight of
States is 52 percent,59 percent, and 67 percent,re- 1.0 to the first adult, .7 to the second adultand .5 to
spectively. In the other basic security countriesand each additionalperson,regardlessof age. This scale
in the encompassingcountries, pension coverage is has been used by the OECDand is a "middle-of-the-
universal. road" choice compared to other alternatives. The
For sickness insurance,the indicatorof earnings choice of scale is especially importantwhen differ-
relatednessis the relationshipbetween gross maxi- ent kinds of householdsare compared(e.g., families
mumlegislated benefit and the gross wage of an av- with childrenarecomparedwith otherfamilies). The
erage productionworker.In 1985, in the eight basic choice of scale is less crucial when similar house-
security countries, the maximum sickness benefit hold categories are compared(e.g., the elderly, see
equals the sickness benefit for an average produc- Buhmannet al. 1988).
tion workers,while in the encompassingcountries, To control for variationsin marketincome ine-
maximum benefits are more than 10 percentage quality, we examine income redistributionin terms
points higherthanthe sickness benefit of an average of the relative reductionin income inequalitywhen
productionworker.In termsof coverage in the labor we move from marketincome to disposable income
force, the "insurance"variantof the basic security (i.e., income aftertaxes andtransfers).Thus,follow-
programshas a 73 percent coverage in Ireland,80 ing Kakwani(1986), we define:
percent in the United Kingdom, and 89 percent in Incomeredistribution
=
Canada.In the other basic security countriesand in
the three encompassing countries, sickness insur- Gini Market income - Gini Disposable income
ance coverage is universal. GiniMarket income
In analyses based on the Luxembourg Income
Study (LIS) on inequality and poverty in different Redistributivebudget size is expressed as the size
populationcategories, our purpose was to examine (percentage)of transfersrelative to the meansize of
populationsabove and below normal pension age. gross income (post-transferbut pre-taxincome). To
Because the pension age differs among nations and indicate the way in which benefits are distributed
is associatedwith differentdegrees of flexibility, to among citizens with differing incomes, we use an
improvecomparabilitywe have defined the elderly index of targeting of transfer income. To compute
as those age 65 or older (except for Norway, where this index we rankedincome units accordingto the
the age limit is set at 67, the normalpension age). In size of gross income and then distributedtransfers
defining the working-agepopulation,we wanted to along this continuum. This index is equivalent to
exclude studentsand young people living with their what Fields (1979) has labeled the "factorGini co-
parents.Hence, we defined the working-agegroup efficient" and what Kakwani(1986) has called the
as those between 25 and 59 years of age. In orderto "index of concentration."It takes a value of -1.0 if
improve comparability,in the analysis of the total the poorest person gets all the transferincome, 0 if
populationwe have excluded households headedby everybody gets an equal amount, and +1.0 if the
persons under20 years of age (e.g., in Swedish in- richest person gets all the transferincome. The in-
come statistics, all persons above age 18 are mis- dexes thatappearin the figures have been multiplied
leadinglydefined as separatehouseholds). by 100.

REFERENCES
Aberg, Rune. 1989. "Distributive Mechanisms of sin Institute for Research on Poverty.
the Welfare State-A Formal Analysis and an Beveridge, William. 1942. Social Insurance and
EmpiricalApplication."European Sociological Allied Services. London: HMSO.
Review 5:167-82. Buhmann, Brigitte, Lee Rainwater, Gunther
Atkinson, Anthony B. and GunnarV. Mogensen. Schmaus, and Timothy S. Smeeding. 1988.
1993. Welfare and Work Incentives. A North "Equivalence Scales, Well-Being, Inequality
European Perspective. Oxford, England: and Poverty: Sensitivity Estimates across Ten
Clarendon. Countries using the Luxembourg Income Study
Baldwin, Peter. 1990. The Politics of Social Soli- (LIS) Database." The Review of Income and
darity. Class Bases of the European Welfare Wealth 34:115-42.
State 1875-1975. Cambridge, England: Cam- Castles, Francis G. 1985. The WorkingClass and
bridge University Press. Welfare in Australia and New Zealand. Lon-
Barry, Brian. 1990. "The Welfare State versus the don, England: Allen and Unwin.
Relief of Poverty." Pp. 73-103 in Needs and Castles, Francis G. and Deborah Mitchell. 1992.
Welfare, edited by A. Ware and R. E. Goodin. "Identifying Welfare State Regimes: The Links
London, England: Sage. between Politics, Instruments, and Outcomes."
Barth, Michael C., George J. Cargano, and John Governance 5:1-26.
L. Palmer. 1974. Toward an Effective Income Davidson, Alexander. 1994. A Home of One's
Support System: Problems, Prospects, and Own. Housing Policy in Sweden and New
Choices. Madison, WI: University of Wiscon- Zealandfrom the 1840s to the 1990s. Uppsala,

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 685

Sweden: Department of Government, Uppsala Women's Economic Dependence and the Wel-
University. fare State." Acta Sociologica 33:235-50.
Deutsche Reichstag. 1881. Stenographische Huber, Evelyn, Charles Ragin, and John D.
Berichte uber die Verhandlungen des Stephens. 1993. "Social Democracy, Christian
Deutschen Reichstages, IV. Legislaturperiode, Democracy, Constitutional Structure, and the
Vierte Session. (Stenographic Reports on the Welfare State." American Journal of Sociology
Proceedings of the German Diet, IV. Legisla- 99:711-49.
tive Period, Fourth Session.) Microfische. International Labour Office. 1992. The Cost of
Dowrick, Steve. 1996. "Swedish Economic Per- Social Security 1984-1986. Geneva, Switzer-
formance and Swedish Economic Debate: A land: InternationalLabour Office.
View from Outside." The Economic Journal Jdntti, Markus, Olli Kangas, and Veli-Matti
106:1772-1800. Ritakallio. 1996. "From Marginalism to Insti-
Durkheim, Emile. [1902] 1964. The Division of tutionalism: Distributional Consequences of
Labor in Society. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. the Transformationof the Finnish Pension Re-
Esping-Andersen, Gosta. 1990. The Three Worlds gime." Review of Income and Wealth 42:473-
of Welfare Capitalism. Cambridge, England: 91.
Polity Press. Kakwani, Nanak. 1986. Analyzing Redistribution
Fields, Gary S. 1979. "Decomposing LDC-In- Politics. Oxford, England: Oxford University
equality." OxfordEconomic Papers 31 :437-61. Press.
Forma, Pauli. 1996. "The Politics of Interest Me- Kangas, Olli. 1995. "Attitudes to Means-Tested
diation. The Case of Universalistic Social Social Benefits in Finland." Acta Sociologica
Policy in Finland." Research Report, Depart- 38:299-310.
ment of Social Policy, University of Turku, Kangas, Olli and Joakim Palme. 1991a. "The
Finland. Public-Private Mix in Pension Provision." In-
Fritzell, Johan. 1991. "The Gap between Market ternational Journal of Sociology 20:78-116.
Rewards and Economic Well-Being in Modern . 1991b. "Social Rights, StructuralNeeds
Societies." European Sociological Review and Social Expenditures." Paper presented at
7:19-33. International Sociological Association's Re-
Garfinkel, Irwin, Jennifer L. Hoschschild, and search Committee 19 Workshop, August 29-
Sara S. McLanahan. 1996. Social Policies for September 1, Vouranta, Helsinki, Finland.
Children. Washington, DC: Brookings Institu- . 1993 "Eroding Statism? Labour Market
tion. Benefits and the Challenges to the Scandina-
Goodin, Robert E. 1990. "Relative Needs." Pp. vian Welfare States." Pp. 3-24 in Scandinavian
12-33 in Needs and Welfare, edited by A. Welfare Trends, edited by E. J. Hansen, S.
Ware and R. E. Goodin. London, England: Ringen, H. Uusitalo, and R. Erikson. Armonk,
Sage. NJ: M. E. Sharpe.
Goodin, Robert E. and Julian LeGrand. 1987. Not Kangas, Olli and Veli-Matti Ritakallio. 1995.
Only the Poor. London, England: Allen and "Different Methods-Different Results? Ap-
Unwin. proaches to Multidimensional Poverty."
Harrington Meyer, Madonna. 1996. "Making Themes 5. Helsinki, Finland: National Re-
Claims as Workers or Wives: The Distribution search and Development Center for Welfare
of Social Security Benefits." American Socio- and Health.
logical Review 61:449-65. Korpi, Walter. 1980a. "Approaches to the Study
Hechter, Michael, Karl-Dieter Opp, and Reinhard of Poverty in the United States. Critical Notes
Wippler. 1990. Social Institutions. Their Emer- from a European Perspective." Pp. 287-314 in
gence, Maintenance and Effects. New York: Poverty and Public Policy, edited by V. T.
Aldine de Gruyter. Covello. Boston, MA: Schenkman.
Hicks, Alexander and Joya Misra. 1993. "Politi- . 1980b. "Social Policy and Distributional
cal Resources and the Growth of Welfare in Conflict in the Capitalist Democracies: A Pre-
Affluent Capitalist Democracies 1960-1982." liminary Comparative Framework." West Eu-
American Journal of Sociology 99:668-7 10. ropean Politics 3:296-316.
Hicks, Alexander and Duane H. Swank. 1984. . 1983. The Democratic Class Struggle.
"GovernmentalRedistribution in Rich Capital- London, England: Routledge.
ist Democracies." Policy Studies Journal 13: . 1985. "Power Resources vs. Action and
265-8. Conflict: On Causal and Intentional Explana-
Hirschman, Albert 0. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loy- tion in the Study of Power." Sociological
alty. Responses to Decline in Firms, Organiza- Theory 3:31-45.
tions, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard . 1989. "Power, Politics and State Au-
University Press. tonomy in the Development of Social Citizen-
Hobson, Barbara. 1990. "No Exit, No Voice: ship: Social Rights During Sickness in 18

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
686 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

OECD-Countries since 1930." American So- fare State Regimes." British Journal of Sociol-
ciological Review 54:309-28. ogy 44:501-18.
. 1996. "Eurosclerosis and the Sclerosis of O'Higgins, Michael, Gunther Schmaus, and
Objectivity: On the Role of Values among Eco- Geoffrey Stephenson. 1990 "Income Distribu-
nomic Policy Experts." The Economic Journal tion and Redistribution: A Micro Data Analy-
106:1727-46. sis for Seven Countries." Pp. 20-56 in Poverty,
. 1998. "Rational Choice, Power and Pref- Inequality and Income Distribution in Com-
erence in Institutional Analysis: A Compara- parative Perspective, edited by T. M.
tive Study of the Emergence and Change of Smeeding, M. O'Higgins, and L. Rainwater.
Welfare State Institutions in 18 OECD Coun- New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
tries." Paper presented at the annual meeting of Orloff, Ann. 1993. "Genderand the Social Rights
the American Sociological Association, August in Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of
21-25, San Francisco, CA. Gender Relations and Welfare States." Ameri-
Lampman, Robert J. 1971. "What Does It Do to can Sociological Review 58:303-28.
the Poor? A New Test for National Policy." Palme, Joakim. 1990. Pension Rights in Welfare
The Public Interest 34:66-82. Capitalism. Dissertation Series No. 14, Swed-
Lawson, Roger and William J. Wilson. 1995. ish Institute for Social Research, Stockholm
"Poverty, Social Rights, and the Quality of University, Stockholm, Sweden.
Citizenship." Pp. 693-714 in Poverty, Inequal- . 1998. "The Welfare State and Equality:
ity, and the Future of Social Policy, edited by Pensions, Poverty and Income Inequality
K. McFate, R. Lawson, and W. J. Wilson. New among the Elderly in Western Countries." Pa-
York: Russel Sage. per presented at the annual meeting of the
Lazarsfeld, Paul F. 1962. "Interpretationof Sta- American Sociological Association, August
tistical Relations as a Research Operation."Pp. 21-25, San Francisco, CA.
115-25 in The Language of Social Research, Pierson, Paul. 1995. Dismantling the Welfare
edited by P. F. Lazarsfeld and M. Rosenberg. State? Reagan, Thatcher and the Politics of
Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Retrenchment. Cambridge, England: Cam-
Le Grand, Julian. 1982. The Strategy of Equality. bridge University Press.
Redistribution and the Social Services. Lon- Pius XI. [1931] 1943. Quadragesimo Anno. Pa-
don, England: George Allen and Unwin. pal encyclical. Vatican City.
Leo XIII. [1891] 1943. Rerum Novarum. Papal Powell, Walter W. and Paul J. DiMaggio. 1991.
encyclical. Vatican City. The New Institutionalism in Organizational
Lijphart, Arendt. 1975. "The Comparable-Cases Analysis. Chicago, IL: Chicago University
Strategy in Comparative Research." Compara- Press.
tive Political Studies 8:158-77. Quadagno, Jill S. 1994. The Color of Welfare.
March, James and Johan P. Olsen. 1989. Redis- How Racism Undermined the War on Poverty.
covering Institutions. New York: Free Press. New York: Oxford University Press.
Marshall, T. H. 1950. Citizenship and Social Ringen, Stein. 1987. The Possibility of Politics.
Class. Cambridge, England: Cambridge Uni- Oxford, England: Clarendon Press.
versity Press. Ringen, Stein and Hannu Uusitalo. 1991. "In-
Messner, Johannes. 1936. Die Berufstdndige come Distribution in the Nordic Welfare
Ordnung (The Corporatist Order). Innsbruck, States." Pp. 69-91 in Comparing Welfare
Austria: Verlagsanstalt Tyrolia. States and Labour Markets, edited by J. E.
. 1964. Die Soziale Frage in Blickfeld der Kolberg. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.
Irrwege von Gestern, die Sozialkdmpfe von Rosenberry, Sara A. 1982. "Social Insurance,
Heute, die Weltentscheidungen von Morgen Distributive Criteria and the Welfare Backlash:
(The Social Question in Perspective of the A Comparative Analysis." British Journal of
Strayings of Yesterday, Social Battles of To- Political Science 12:421-27.
day, and World Settlements of Tomorrow). Smeeding, Timothy, Michael O'Higgins, and Lee
Innsbruck, Austria: Tyrolia Verlag. Rainwater, eds. 1990. Poverty, Inequality and
Mishra, Ramesh. 1981. Society and Social Policy. Income Distribution in Comparative Perspec-
Theories and Practice of Welfare. London, En- tive: The Luxembourg Income Study. New
gland: MacMillan. York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Mitchell, Deborah. 1991. Income Transfers in Steinmo, Sven, Kathleen Thelen, and Frank
Ten Welfare States. Aldershot: Avebury. Longstreth. 1992. Structuring Politics. Histori-
Mitchell, Deborah, Ann Harding, and Fred Gruen. cal Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis.
1994. "Targeting Welfare." The Economic Cambridge, England: Cambridge University
Record 70:315-40. Press.
O'Connor, Julia. 1993. "Gender, Class, and Citi- Svallfors, Stefan. 1996. Vdlfdrdsstatens moral-
zenship in the Comparative Analysis of Wel- iska ekonomi. Vdlfdrdsopinionen in 90-talets

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE PARADOX OF REDISTRIBUTION STRATEGIES OF EQUALITY 687

Sverige (The Moral Economy of the Welfare biological Review 1:163-76.


State. Social Policy Attitudes in Sweden of the Weale, Albert. 1990. "Equality, Social Solidarity
1990s). Umea',Sweden: Borea. and the Welfare State." Ethics 100:473-88.
Tawney, R. H. 1952. Equality. London, England: Whiteford, Peter. 1993. "The Concept of Income
George Allen and Unwin. in InternationalComparative Research." Paper
Titmuss, Richard. 1974. Social Policy. London, presented at the Conference on Comparative
England: George Allen and Unwin. Research on Welfare States in Transition, In-
Tullock, Gordon. 1983. Economics of Income Re- ternational Sociological Association's Re-
distribution. Amsterdam,Netherlands:Kluwer- search Committee 19, September 9-12, Uni-
Nijhoff. versity of Oxford, Oxford, England.
Uusitalo, Hannu. 1984. "Redistribution and World Bank. 1990. World Development Report.
Equality in the Welfare State." European So- New York: Oxford University Press.

This content downloaded from 148.206.159.132 on Sat, 1 Jun 2013 19:18:13 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Вам также может понравиться