Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 7

Science of the Total Environment 408 (2010) 4396–4402

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Science of the Total Environment


j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w. e l s ev i e r. c o m / l o c a t e / s c i t o t e n v

Economic feasibility study for wastewater treatment: A cost–benefit analysis


María Molinos-Senante a,⁎, Francesc Hernández-Sancho a, Ramón Sala-Garrido b
a
Department of Applied Economics II, Faculty of Economics, University of Valencia, Campus dels Tarongers, 46022 Valencia, Spain
b
Department of Mathematics for Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Valencia, Campus dels Tarongers, 46022 Valencia, Spain

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Water resource management should be made from a multidisciplinary perspective. In this sense, economic
Received 30 March 2010 research into the design and implementation of policies for the efficient management of water resources has
Received in revised form 21 June 2010 been emphasized by the European Water Framework Directive (WFD). Cost–benefit analysis (CBA) is one of
Accepted 3 July 2010
the more widely accepted economic instruments since it is a rational and systematic decision-making
Available online 29 July 2010
support tool. Moreover, the wastewater treatment process has significant associated environmental benefits.
However, these benefits are often left uncalculated because they have no market value. In this paper, using
Keywords:
Cost–benefit analysis
the concept of shadow price, a quantification of the environmental benefits derived from wastewater
Economic feasibility treatment is made. Once the environmental benefits are estimated and the economic costs of the treatment
Environmental benefits processes are known, a CBA is made for each of the wastewater treatment plants (WWTPs) under study. In
Shadow prices this way, a useful economic feasibility indicator is obtained for WWTP operation.
Wastewater treatment © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction water bodies implies disproportionate costs. In this sense, all of the
benefits, including those which have a nature of ‘non-market’, i.e.,
As environmental quality and sustainable use of natural resources those whose value is not determined by the market, but have a high
have been recognized as a real social need, authorities have tried to value because they uniquely contribute to improving people welfare,
find the most appropriate tools for environmental protection. In most and costs must be integrated into a CBA as a decision support tool.
industrialized countries, the so-called direct regulation instruments Historically, the application of CBA in the evaluation of projects has
have been traditionally applied. Yet, this type of instrument has been amended in the function of the objectives of the development
generally failed to achieve a high level of environmental protection policies. There are three stages:
and there have been high costs for all of society (Zhang & Wen, 2008).
As a result, a number of authors (Gayer & Horowitz, 2006; Wissel & 1) Traditional approach: a clear economic approach that aims to
Watzold, 2010; Song et al., 2010; among others) argue that market increase the level of welfare in monetary terms. This approach was
principles should be used as decision support tools for the implemen- applied until the late 1960s.
tation of policies and selection of measures to assist environmental 2) Socio-economic approach: arises when the concept of social equity
protection. is incorporated. The aim is to achieve equitable income
In the field of water resource management, the EU Water Framework distribution.
Directive (WFD) has introduced a new approach to water planning for 3) CBA with environmental externality valuation is the third
the achievement of the environmental objectives of obtaining a good approach and results from the incorporation of environmental
ecological status for European water bodies. The directive allocates a criteria are included in the decision-making process. This type of
very important role to economic analysis (Helming & Reinhard, 2009). CBA originated in the 1980s (Pearce & Nash, 1981; Pearce &
For dealing with the requirements demanded by the WFD, Markandya, 1988; Sugden & Williams, 1988; among others) and
especially those related to the cost recovery for water services, became more widespread in the 1990s (Gramlich 1990; Johans-
economic valuation is presented as a useful tool for implementing son, 1993; Hanley & Spash, 1993; Weiss, 1994; among others).
efficient and effective policies and strategies for the management of
water resources (Moran & Dann, 2008). The WFD requires that cost– In the water resource context, it is known that wastewater
benefit analyses (CBA) are made with the aim of identifying cases in treatment has important associated environmental benefits, and in
which the adoption of measures to achieve a good ecological status for economic terms we could define these as positive externalities.
However, in most cases these environmental benefits are not
quantified because they have no market value. In spite of this, the
⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: +34 963828349; fax: +34 963828354. monetary valuation of these externalities is necessary to justify the
E-mail address: Maria.Molinos@uv.es (M. Molinos-Senante). economic feasibility of wastewater treatment projects.

0048-9697/$ – see front matter © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2010.07.014
M. Molinos-Senante et al. / Science of the Total Environment 408 (2010) 4396–4402 4397

In this sense, the economic valuation of externalities in the field of from the wastewater treatment process is carried out by calculating
water reuse is acquiring particular importance. An example of this the shadow prices associated with undesirable outputs obtained in
growing interest is found in the paper of Godfrey et al. (2009), who the wastewater treatment process. Once the environmental benefit in
made a CBA applied to a greywater reuse system in India. Monetary monetary terms is estimated and the economic cost of the wastewater
values of external benefits and costs in terms of environmental and treatment is known, a CBA is carried out to obtain a representative
health benefits were derived by using conventional economic indicator of the economic feasibility for each WWTP.
methods for valuation like hedonic prices and contingent valuation. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2
Likewise, Seguí et al. (2009) used travel cost method to determine the describes the methodology used to determine the net profit. Likewise,
environmental benefits arising from wastewater reuse in the context this section provides the methodology used to quantify the environ-
of a wetland restoration project. Chen & Wang (2009) propose a net mental benefits of the wastewater treatment process. In Section 3, the
benefit value model for the cost–benefit evaluation of reuse projects data are described for implementing a shadow pricing model for the
which is applied in a residential area of China. wastewater treatment plants under study. In Section 4 empirical
Different methodologies for the quantification and internalization results in relation to operating cost, environmental benefits and net
of environmental externalities arising from investment projects have profit are described and, finally, Section 5 shows the conclusions.
been developed from economic theory. The literature shows that, in
most applications related to water resources, the quantification of 2. Methodology
these externalities has been made using the contingent valuation
method (CVM) (Bergstrom et al., 2000; Bateman et al., 2006; Birol The CBA is made to compare the economic feasibility associated
et al., 2006; Del Saz et al., 2009; among others). with the implementation of different proposals. CBA starts from the
Although many authors consider the CVM a consolidated technique premise that a project should only be commissioned if all the benefits
since it is supported by numerous practical applications, in the scientific exceed the aggregate costs. Accordingly, the benefits of each proposal
community there is no unanimous consensus on the validity of this are compared with their costs by using a common analytical
methodology as a tool for the valuation of environmental goods (Boyle methodology. The net profit of each option is the difference between
et al., 1993; Diamond & Hausman, 1994; Shabman & Stephenson, 2000; benefits and costs (see Equation 1).
among others).
In fact, from the pioneering work by Färe et al. (1989) and NP = ∑Bi −∑Ci ð1Þ
successive developments (Färe et al. 1993, 1996, 2006; Yaisawarng
and Klein, 1994; among others) a valuation methodology has been where NP is the net profit, Bi is the value of the benefit item i, and Ci is
developed for undesirable outputs with no market value. By using the the value of the cost item i. For a given project, if the result of the
concept of distance function, a shadow price is calculated for those calculation is NP N 0, then the project is economically viable, while if
goods arising from human and productive activities that have no the result of the calculation is NP b 0 then the project is not viable in
market value, but create substantial environmental impacts. Some economic terms. The best option offers the highest net profit (Chen
empirical applications of this method are found in papers by Coggin and Wang, 2009).
and Swinton (1996), Swinton (1998), Reig et al. (2000), Nguyen Van In the field of wastewater treatment, an economically feasible
Ha et al. (2007), and Hernández et al. (2010). WWTP means that all the benefits arising from this process exceed its
It is important to emphasize that these undesirable outputs can be total costs and, therefore, it is shown that wastewater treatment is a
considered negative environmental externalities associated with a positive process not only from an environmental point of view, but
production process. Shadow prices calculated according to this also economically.
methodology represent the value of external effects that could Obviously, for the implementation of a CBA, benefits and costs
damage the environment in the case of inadequate management. must be expressed in the same units. However, in projects with
This is equivalent to the value of the positive externalities associated environmental externalities this rarely happens. Due to the hetero-
with avoiding the discharge of pollution into the environment. geneity in the measurement units of costs and benefits, it is necessary
The advantages of this externality valuation methodology include to use monetary units as a method of homogenization — and this
the following: (i) shadow prices could be used to determine income enables the application of a CBA.
gained in case of privatization of some resources, (ii) authorities can
use the information provided by the shadow prices to set rates for the 2.1. Cost of wastewater treatment process
use of environmental services, or to compare the current rates with the
marginal revenue generating (Färe et al. 2001), (iii) can help society to The quantification of the costs associated with the operation of
understand the benefits generated as a result of environmental WWTPs is straightforward because these costs are strictly controlled
improvement programs and (iv) shadow price models can allow by the operating companies. In this paper, operation costs have been
economists a further check into estimated measures of willingness to grouped into five categories — as shown in Table 1.
pay from alternative models such as the CVM, or capitalization
methods (Färe et al. 2001). Shadow price quantification has very low Table 1
costs in comparison to always expensive surveying processes. Sample description (Source: EPSAR).
In spite of these advantages, the quantification of environmental Average Deviation Maximum Minimum
externalities using shadow price methodology also has some limita-
Inputs (€/year) Energy 113,233 50,470 219,847 46,082
tions in relation to stated preference methods, such as CVM and
Staff 205,375 116,874 519,225 57,117
choice experiment method. These methods could be more appropri- Reagents 86,545 64,553 199,846 18,793
ate than the shadow price method when we try to estimate the total Waste 97,448 105,198 347,832 18,793
economic value that are the only techniques that in theory are capable management
Maintenance 129,735 80,564 295,101 9201
of estimating both use and non-use values.
Desirable output Treated 2,879,352 2,029,767 7,895,321 1,050,327
The aim of this paper is to obtain a useful indicator of the economic (m3/year) water
feasibility of the operation and maintenance of the wastewater Undesirable outputs SS 1,111,429 1,085,214 2,116,821 341,727
treatment plants (WWTPs). Considering the pros and cons of different (kg/year) COD 2,072,557 1,737,257 4,701,455 773,965
environmental externality valuation methodologies, in this empirical N 83,789 63,722 233,847 20,860
P 16,124 15,977 64,593 2482
application the quantification of the environmental benefits derived
4398 M. Molinos-Senante et al. / Science of the Total Environment 408 (2010) 4396–4402

The energy cost (x1) includes the cost related to the fixed part of The translog function offers the greatest flexibility, and is therefore
the energy consumption (power term) and the variable part (energy the most used. When applied to a problem with k units, n inputs and
consumption) of the installation. Staff costs (x2) reflect wages, social moutputs the formula is:
security charges, taxes, and social insurance. The term reagents (x3)
includes the cost of the reagents required for water and sludge. Waste k k 0
N
k
M
k
costs (x4) include the costs associated with waste and sludge ln D0 ðx ; u Þ = α0 + ∑ βn ln xn + ∑ αm ln um ð3Þ
n=1 m=1
management. Finally, the cost of maintenance (x5) is considered —
including concepts such as equipment and machinery maintenance 1 N N
k k
+ ∑ ∑ βn n 0 ðln xn Þðln xn 0 Þ
and replacement. 2 n = 1 n0 = 1
In general, WWTP operating costs are influenced by the effluent
1 M M
k k
quality. In this sense, one can roughly distinguish three types of + ∑ ∑ αm m 0 ðln um Þðln um Þ
2 m = 1 m0 = 1
treatment: (i) primary treatment which involves screening, grinding
and sedimentation to remove the floating and settleable solids found N M
k k
in wastewater, (ii) secondary treatment that is accomplished by a + ∑ ∑ γn m ðln xn Þðln um Þ:
n=1 m=1
biological process and sedimentation allowing to remove organic
material that is either colloidal in size and dissolved, and (iii) tertiary
To calculate the parameters (α, β, γ) the following linear program
treatment which permits the removal of specific contaminants not
was used:
normally removed during conventional secondary treatments such as
nutrients and pathogens. According to EPSAR (2009), the average K h i
k k
WWTP operating costs are 0.12, 0.26 and 0.32 €/m3 for primary, MaxZ = ∑ ln D0 ðx ; u Þ− ln 1
secondary and tertiary treatments respectively. k=1
s:t: :
k k
2.2. Environmental benefits of the wastewater treatment process ðiÞ ln D0 ðx ; u Þ ≤ 0
k k
∂ ln D0 ðx ; u Þ
The quantification, in monetary terms, of the environmental ðiiÞ ≥ 0; ðm = 1Þ
benefits derived from wastewater treatment is much more complex ∂ ln ukm
ð4Þ
than calculating costs — because these benefits are not captured by k
∂ ln D0 ðx ; u Þ
k

the market. ðiiiÞ ≤ 0; ðm 0 = 2; 3; 4:::Þ


∂ ln ukm 0
In this paper, and in accordance with Hernandez et al. (2010),
M N N
quantification of environmental benefits has been made by calculating ðivÞ ∑ αm = 1; ∑ βnn0 = ∑ γnm = 0
0
the shadow prices of undesirable outputs obtained from wastewater m=1 n =1 n=1

treatment. Wastewater treatment can be considered a production 0


ðvÞ αmm0 = αm0 m ; m = 1; :::; M; m = 1; :::; M
process in which a desirable output (treated water) is obtained 0
βnn0 = βn0 n; n = 1; :::; N; n = 1; :::; N:
together with a series of pollutants (organic matter, phosphorus, and
nitrogen, etc.). Contaminants extracted from wastewater are consid-
ered undesirable outputs because if they were dumped in an The relationship of duality between the distance function and the
uncontrolled manner they would cause a negative impact on the revenue function (Shephard, 1970) creates the link between relative
environment. and absolute prices (Färe et al. 1993). The relationship between the
The shadow price valuation methodology for undesirable outputs two functions can be expressed as:
(Färe et al. 1989) is based on the concept of the distance function.
Conceptually, a distance function generalizes the concept of conven- Rðx; uÞ = Max fru : D0 ðx; uÞ ≤ 1g ð5Þ
u
tional production functions and measures the difference between the
outputs produced in the process under study and the outputs of the Table 2
more efficient process. It is considered that the most efficient process Operating costs of WWTPs expressed in €/m3.
is that which minimizes input consumption and undesirable output
WWTP Energy Staff Reagents Waste Maintenance Total
generation while maximizing the generation of desirable output. The management
distance function provides the distance of a vector of outputs from the
1 0.0342 0.0801 0.0371 0.0212 0.0471 0.2197
maximum output frontier and starts from a vector of constant inputs.
2 0.0156 0.0442 0.0245 0.0108 0.0292 0.1243
Assuming that the production process uses a vector of N inputs x ∈ RN + 3 0.0221 0.0628 0.0288 0.0385 0.0398 0.1920
to produce a vector of M outputs u ∈ RM +, the distance function is 4 0.0243 0.0563 0.0181 0.0458 0.0243 0.1688
defined as: 5 0.0432 0.0611 0.0185 0.0149 0.0383 0.1760
6 0.0329 0.0425 0.0162 0.0105 0.0235 0.1256
7 0.0214 0.0499 0.0123 0.0084 0.0238 0.1158
8 0.0521 0.0851 0.0209 0.0194 0.0411 0.2186
9 0.0708 0.0698 0.0305 0.0453 0.0471 0.2635
D0 ðx; uÞ = Min fθ : ðu = θÞ ∈ PðxÞg ð2Þ 10 0.0952 0.1243 0.1137 0.2542 0.1617 0.7491
11 0.0469 0.0952 0.0535 0.0085 0.0668 0.2709
12 0.0864 0.1038 0.0419 0.0541 0.0652 0.3514
13 0.0278 0.0482 0.0128 0.0136 0.0252 0.1276
where P(x) is a vector of outputs that are technically viable and use 14 0.0367 0.0896 0.0096 0.0686 0.0183 0.2228
the vector of inputs x, (u/θ) is output ratio in production frontier, 15 0.0507 0.1274 0.0403 0.0232 0.0645 0.3061
while θ is a ratio between zero and one, that is, D0 (x,u) ∈ [0,1]. Thus, 16 0.0841 0.0554 0.0575 0.0115 0.1009 0.3094
17 0.0965 0.1758 0.0915 0.1537 0.1272 0.6447
D0 (x,0) = 0 and D0 (x,u) = 1 if u belongs to production frontier, i.e.,
18 0.1758 0.2441 0.0821 0.0527 0.1407 0.6954
the most efficient. High values of D0 indicate a good approximation to 19 0.0369 0.1142 0.0715 0.0413 0.1232 0.3871
the production frontier and therefore high efficiency. That is, a 20 0.0573 0.0718 0.0274 0.0928 0.0538 0.3031
production process using a minimum of inputs to produce a particular 21 0.0628 0.0473 0.0144 0.0181 0.0373 0.1799
output (in our case wastewater treated with a certain quality) will be 22 0.0265 0.0435 0.0142 0.0068 0.0248 0.1158
Average 0.0392 0.0712 0.0301 0.0342 0.0453 0.2200
placed on the production frontier (Hernández and Sala, 2009).
M. Molinos-Senante et al. / Science of the Total Environment 408 (2010) 4396–4402 4399

4. Results

4.1. Operation costs

As a starting point for a CBA, WWTP operating costs in €/m3 are


listed below. These costs have been grouped into five categories:
energy, staff, reagents, waste management, and maintenance (see
Table 2).
As shown in Table 2, the operating costs of the studied WWTPs are
very variable, since the minimum value is 0.1158 €/m3, while the
maximum is 0.7491 €/m3 (6.5 times higher). The weighted average,
according to the treated volume of wastewater is 0.2200 €/m3.
Fig. 1 shows the operating cost distribution in weighted averages
Fig. 1. Operating cost distribution. depending on the treated wastewater volume by each WWTP. The
most important item is staff, representing approximately one third of
the total costs. Maintenance and energy costs are the next in
importance and represent 21% and 18% respectively. Waste manage-
D0 ðx; uÞ = Max f ru : Rðx; uÞ ≤ 1g ð6Þ ment and reagent costs have a similar percentage weight, contribut-
r
ing 15% and 14% respectively to the total cost.
Taking into account the large differences in WWTP operating costs
where R(x, u) is the revenue function and r represents output prices. (Table 2) and the fact that some include specific nutrient removal
Under the assumption that distance and revenue functions are treatment while others lack this process, it is interesting to study
differentiable, the Lagrange multiplier method and Shephard's dual operating costs in the function of the type of treatment made by the
lemma enable us to calculate shadow prices. This deduction of WWTPs under study. According to treatment description provided in
shadow prices for undesirable outputs means assuming that the subsection 2.1, the first group of WWTPs has tertiary treatment while
shadow price of an absolute desirable output coincides with the the other has secondary treatment. This is important because the
market price. If m is a desirable output whose market price is rm equal presence or absence of nutrients in treated wastewater is a key aspect
to its shadow price (r0m), and if m' is an undesirable output and rm′ is in relation to environmental benefits derived from wastewater
the shadow price of each undesirable, for all m' ≠ m the absolute treatment processes.
shadow prices are given by (Färe et al. 1993): On this basis, two groups of WWTPs have been differentiated:
plants that have specific nutrient removal treatment; and those that
do not. We hypothesized that there are significant differences in
 operating costs between these two groups.
o ∂Do ðx; uÞ ∂um Table 3 shows the distribution of the average operating costs,
rm0 = rm  : ð7Þ
∂Do ðx; uÞ ∂um0 weighted by the volume of wastewater treated for both groups.
It is shown that WWTPs with specific nutrient removal treatment
have average operating costs higher than those that only remove
This paper proposes an application of the methodology described nutrients associated with the growth of micro-organisms. A variance
above in the field of wastewater treatment in order to make a cost– analysis was made to assess whether these cost differences are
benefit analysis that includes environmental externalities. The results statistically significant. The obtained p-value is 0.306, and therefore
will provide information about the economic feasibility of WWTP with 95% confidence we can say that the differences for the average
operation. operating costs between the two groups of WWTPs are not significant.
Only if we analyze in detail the operating cost structure for each
group of WWTPs can it be seen that plants with a specific nutrient
3. Sample data removal treatment have much higher costs for reagents. The
divergence between both groups of WWTPs in this input is 0.0158
The sample used in this empirical application consists of 22 WWTPs €/m3, representing 50% of the total operating cost difference between
in the region of Valencia on the Spanish Mediterranean coast. the two groups of plants.
Statistical information for the year 2007 has been supplied by the To see if these cost differences in reagents are really significant, a
regional wastewater treatment authority (EPSAR). The volume treated variance analysis was made. The obtained p-value was 0.0084, and
by each WWTP varies between 1,000,000 and 8,000,000 m3/year therefore with 95% confidence it is demonstrated that reagent cost
(Table 1). differences are statistically significant. This result is logical if we bear
Wastewater treatment process is characterized by a desirable in mind that for the plants under study, phosphorus removal is
output production, treated water (u1), and four undesirable outputs: achieved by chemical precipitation with the addition of various
suspended solids (SS) (u2), chemical oxygen demand (COD) (u3), chemical reagents.
nitrogen (N) (u4), and phosphorus (P) (u5). Necessary inputs to carry Once the WWTP operating costs are quantified, the next step in
out the treatment are: energy (x1), staff (x2), reagents (x3), waste performing the CBA is determining the environmental benefits
management (x4), and maintenance (x5). derived from the wastewater treatment process for each plant.

Table 3
Operating costs depending on nutrient removal treatment in €/m3.

WWTP Number WWTP Energy Staff Reagents Waste management Maintenance Others Total

Without nutrient removal treatment 10 0.0312 0.0651 0.0213 0.0235 0.0345 0.0071 0.1827
With nutrient removal treatment 12 0.0356 0.0705 0.0371 0.0272 0.0354 0.0091 0.2149
4400 M. Molinos-Senante et al. / Science of the Total Environment 408 (2010) 4396–4402

Table 4
Shadow prices of undesirable outputs in €/kg.

COD SS N P

−0.1312 −0.0051 −8.0604 −30.9442

4.2. Environmental benefits

The environmental benefits, expressed in monetary terms, have


been estimated by calculating the shadow prices of undesirable
outputs obtained in the wastewater treatment process. These shadow
prices reflect the value of the environmental damage resulting if these
pollutants were dumped in an uncontrolled manner, i.e., these prices
Fig. 2. Environmental benefit according to pollutant removal.
represent an approximation of the environmental benefits derived
from the treatment process.
In this sense, we consider wastewater treatment as a productive
process in which five inputs (energy, staff, reagents, waste manage- weighted average, depending on the treated volume of wastewater, is
ment, and maintenance) are used to produce a desirable output (clean 0.3609 €/m3.
water) together with four undesirable outputs (nitrogen, phosphorus, Fig. 2 shows the environmental benefits derived from the
suspended solids, and chemical oxygen demand). elimination of pollutants. The greatest environmental benefit is
Following the methodology described above, function distance associated with nitrogen removal because it represents 66% of the
and shadow prices for undesirable outputs are estimated for each total profit. Phosphorus is the next most important pollutant, with a
WWTP under study. Table 4 shows the obtained values (expressed in 21% percentage weight of the total benefit. The environmental benefit
weighted average according to treated wastewater volume) for the accounted for by organic matter (COD) is only 12.4% because, despite
four undesirable outputs considered. the fact that a large volume is removed, its shadow price is
According to the literature (Nguyen Van Ha et al. 2007; Hernandez comparatively low. A similar situation occurs with suspended solids,
et al. 2010; among others), shadow prices obtained for undesirable as they have a very low shadow price and so make little contribution
outputs are negative as they are not associated with marketable (0.2%) to the environmental benefit — even after large quantities are
outputs. However, from an environmental point of view these shadow removed from wastewater (Table 4).
prices can be interpreted positively because they represent damage Once both environmental benefits and operating costs have been
avoided, or an estimation of the environmental benefits obtained by identified and quantified, we can calculate the net profit associated
treating wastewater. with the wastewater treatment process for each WWTP under study.
By considering the volume of pollutants removed in the treatment
process (kg/year), the volume of treated wastewater (m3/year), and 4.3. Net profit
the shadow prices obtained for each pollutant (see Table 4), the
overall environmental benefit resulting from wastewater treatment is In this section, net profit is calculated by comparing the total
calculated as shown in Table 5. According to this table, the WWTPs benefits derived from wastewater treatment with the operating costs
produce highly variable environmental benefits since the minimum for each WWTP of the sample. It is important to remember that CBA
value is 0.0099 €/m3, while the maximum value is 1.0039 €/m3. The

Table 6
Table 5 Net profit from wastewater treatment process in €/m3.
Environmental benefit of wastewater treatment in €/m3.
WWTP Net profit without Net profit with 50% Net profit with 100%
WWTP SS COD N P Environmental water selling water selling water selling
benefits (scenario i) (scenario ii) (scenario iii)

1 0.0001 0.0009 0.0071 0.0016 0.0099 1 −0.2102 −0.0377 0.1348


2 0.0005 0.0156 0.0968 0.0802 0.1932 2 0.0713 0.2438 0.4163
3 0.0001 0.0026 0.0144 0.0238 0.0408 3 −0.1489 0.0236 0.1961
4 0.0001 0.0020 0.0084 0.0028 0.0134 4 −0.1536 0.0189 0.1914
5 0.0023 0.0129 0.1921 0.0691 0.2765 5 0.1020 0.2745 0.4470
6 0.0015 0.0127 0.3288 0.0959 0.4389 6 0.3156 0.4881 0.6606
7 0.0002 0.0070 0.0526 0.0113 0.0711 7 −0.0433 0.1292 0.3017
8 0.0001 0.0018 0.0176 0.0022 0.0217 8 −0.1939 −0.0214 0.1511
9 0.0018 0.0200 0.2928 0.0977 0.4123 9 0.1503 0.3228 0.4953
10 0.0004 0.1999 0.0682 0.1676 0.4362 10 −0.3117 −0.1392 0.0333
11 0.0003 0.0071 0.0647 0.0163 0.0885 11 −0.1790 −0.0065 0.1660
12 0.0006 0.0327 0.2898 0.0451 0.3682 12 0.0187 0.1912 0.3637
13 0.0008 0.0156 0.7780 0.1937 0.9881 13 0.8630 1.0355 1.2080
14 0.0001 0.0021 0.0042 0.0042 0.0106 14 −0.2097 −0.0372 0.1353
15 0.0006 0.0134 0.0593 0.1326 0.2059 15 −0.0990 0.0735 0.2460
16 0.0008 0.2033 0.5184 0.1215 0.8441 16 0.5370 0.7095 0.8820
17 0.0017 0.0231 0.2449 0.1150 0.3847 17 −0.2573 −0.0848 0.0877
18 0.0003 0.0332 0.0664 0.0351 0.1350 18 −0.5588 −03863 −0.2138
19 0.0005 0.0180 0.4018 0.2570 0.8396 19 0.4555 0.6280 0.8005
20 0.0005 0.0594 0.8087 0.1353 1.0039 20 0.7030 0.8755 1.0480
21 0.0004 0.0729 0.3518 0.0275 0.4527 21 0.2747 0.4472 0.6197
22 0.0004 0.0676 0.5907 0.0462 0.7049 22 0.5925 0.7650 0.9375
Average 0.0006 0.0448 0.2390 0.0765 0.3609 Average 0.1413 0.3138 0.4863
M. Molinos-Senante et al. / Science of the Total Environment 408 (2010) 4396–4402 4401

must include both internal and external costs and benefits. Therefore, Acknowledgement
the total benefit derived from wastewater treatment is the sum of the
environmental benefits and profits from the sale of the treated water. The authors wish to acknowledge the statistical assistance from
As explained previously in the methodology, the quantification of the Entitat de Sanejament d'Aigües (EPSAR) and the financial aid
shadow prices of undesirable outputs requires assuming that the received from the Spanish government (NOVEDAR-Consolider Project
shadow price of the desirable output (in our case treated water) (CSD2007-00055) and FPU program (AP2007-03483)) and the
coincides with its market price. In this sense, and based on the Spanish Generalitat Valenciana government (ACOMP/2010/138). They would
Environmental Ministry report (MMA., 2007) the value of 0.345 € /m3 also like to thank two anonymous referees for their valuable
as the market price of treated water has been allocated. comments and suggestions.
The Spanish region where WWTPs under study are located has
water deficit problems, especially in summer season. However, the
fact that all treated water could be sold is an unrealistic assumption References
since the social acceptance of reclaimed water is still limited.
Bateman IJ, Cole MA, Georgiou S, Hadley DJ. Comparing contingent valuation and
Therefore, the net profit under three different scenarios has been contingent ranking: a case study considering the benefits of urban river quality
determined: (i) no sale of treated water, (ii) sale of 50% of the treated improvements. J Environ Manage 2006;79(3):221–31.
water and (iii) sale of 100% of the treated water (Table 6). Bergstrom JC, Boyle K, Poe G. The economic valuation of water quality. Cheltenham, UK:
Edward Elgar Publishers; 2000.
According to Table 6, for the three scenarios considered, the net Birol E, Karousakis K, Koundouri P. Using economic valuation techniques to inform
profit for all the WWTPs gives an average positive result and this water resources management: a survey and critical appraisal of available
shows that wastewater treatment is beneficial from an environmental techniques and an application. Sci Total Environ 2006;365:105–22.
Boyle KJ, Desvousges WH, Johnson FR, Dunford RH, Hudson SP. An investigation of part-
and economic point of view. For the first scenario, without reclaimed whole biases in contingent valuation studies. J Environ Econ Manage 1993;27(1):
water selling, the term benefit is made only by the environmental 64–83.
benefit. In this case, the percentage of plants with a negative net profit Chen R, Wang XC. Cost–benefit evaluation of a decentralized water system for
wastewater reuse and environmental protection. Water Sci Technol 2009;59(8):
is 50%. The operation of these WWTPs would not be feasible from an 1515–22.
economic point of view and, therefore, should be studied in greater Coggin JS, Swinton JR. The price of pollution: a dual approach to valuing SO2 allowances.
detail in order to improve their situation. However, it is important to J Environ Econ Manage 1996;30(5):58–72.
Del Saz S, Hernández F, Sala R. The social benefits of restoring water quality in the
note that the average net profit of the 22 studied plants is positive
context of the Water Framework Directive: a comparison of willingness to pay and
with a value of 0.1413 €/m3. This result shows that wastewater willingness to accept. Sci Total Environ 2009;407(16):4574–83.
treatment processes can be economically feasible although there is no EPSAR. Manual de gestión 2009. http://www.epsar.gva.es/sanejament/quienes-somos/
INFORME-DE-GESTION-Castellano.pdf2009 (In Spanish).
sale of reclaimed water. Under the assumption that 50% of reclaimed
Diamond PA, Hausman JA. Contingent valuation: is some number better than no
water is sold (scenario ii), the average net profit is increased to 0.3138 number? J Econ Perspect 1994;8(4):45–64.
€/m3. For this scenario, 15 of the 22 WWTPs studied (68%) showed a Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK, Pasurka C. Multilateral productivity comparisons when
positive net profit. Finally, if all the reclaimed water is sold (scenario some outputs are undesirable: a nonparametric approach. Rev Econ Stat 1989;71
(1):90–8.
iii), the average net profit is 0.4863 €/m3 and all of the total WWTPs Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK, Yaisawarng S. Derivation of shadow prices for
(only one exception) have a positive net profit. undesirable outputs: a distance function approach. Rev Econ Stat 1993;75(2):
374–80.
Färe R, Grosskopf S, Tyteca D. An activity model of the environmental performance of
firms — application to fossil-fuel-fired electric utilities. Ecol Econ 1996;18:161–75.
5. Conclusions Färe R, Grosskopf S, Weber WL. Shadow prices of Missouri public conservation land.
Publ Finance Rev 2001;29(6):444–60.
Färe R, Grosskopf S, Weber WL. Shadow prices and pollution costs in U.S. agriculture.
This paper presents a cost–benefit analysis of wastewater Ecol Econ 2006;56:89-103.
treatment with a valuation of environmental externalities. This Gayer T, Horowitz JK. In: Viscusi WK, editor. Market-based approaches to environ-
methodology enables economic feasibility studies to be made for mental regulation, in Foundations and trends in microeconomics; 2006. vol. 1 issue
13.
wastewater treatment and water reuse projects that take into account
Godfrey S, Labhasetwar P, Wate S. Greywater reuse in residential school in Madhya
the monetary value of the so-called environmental externalities. Pradesh, India — a case study of cost–benefit analysis. Resour Conserv Recycl
Under the assumption that wastewater treatment is a productive 2009;53:287–93.
Gramlich EM. A guide to benefit–cost analysis. London: Prentice Hall; 1990.
process in which a desirable output (treated water) is obtained with a
Hanley N, Spash C. Cost–benefit analysis and the environment. Cheltenham: Edward
series of undesirable outputs (suspended solids, phosphorus, nitro- Elgar; 1993.
gen, etc.) we have calculated a shadow price for these undesirable Helming J, Reinhard S. Modelling the economic consequences of the EU Water
pollutants. The value of these represents the environmental damage Framework Directive for Dutch Agriculture. J Environ Manage 2009;91(1):114–23.
Hernández F, Sala R. Technical efficiency and cost analysis in wastewater treatment
avoided, or environmental benefit derived, from the removal of processes: a DEA approach. Desalination 2009;249(1):230–4.
pollutants during wastewater treatment. Hernández F, Molinos M, Sala R. Economic valuation of environmental benefits from
Taking into account the generation of four undesirable outputs, an wastewater treatment processes: an empirical approach for Spain. Sci Total
Environ 2010;408:953–7.
empirical application is presented for a sample of 22 WWTPs located Johansson PO. Cost–benefit analysis of environmental change. Cambridge: Cambridge
in the Spanish region of Valencia. The obtained results show that the University Press; 1993.
maximum environmental benefits are associated with nutrient MMA. 2007. Metodología de análisis de las opciones de oferta para la gestión del agua
en la cuenca Hidrográfica del Segura. (In Spanish).
removal from wastewater, while the removal of suspended solids Moran D, Dann S. The economic value of water use: implications for implementing the
contributes the lowest percentage to the overall environmental Water Framework Directive in Scotland. J Environ Manage 2008;87(3):484–96.
benefit. Ha Nguyen Van, Shashi K, Maclaren V. Shadow prices of environmental outputs and
production efficiency of household-level paper recycling units in Vietnam. Ecol
The results obtained from CBA provide information about the
Econ 2007;65:98-110.
economic feasibility of the treatment processes. Regarding the Pearce DW, Markandya A. Environmental policy benefits: monetary valuation. Paris:
possible sale of regenerated water, three scenarios obtaining the OECD; 1988.
Pearce DW, Nash CA. The social appraisal of projects: a text in cost–benefit analysis.
average value of the net profit for each of them have been studied.
Macmillan, Basingstoke; 1981.
Although both operating costs and environmental benefits derived Reig E, Picazo A, Hernández F. The calculation of shadow prices for industrial wastes
from treatment are highly variable between WWTPs, the average using distance functions: an analysis for Spanish ceramic pavement firms. Int J Prod
value of the net profit for the three scenarios is positive. This Econ 2000;69:277–85.
Seguí L, Alfranca O, García J. Techno-economical evaluation of water reuse for wetland
demonstrates that the operation of the WWTPs under study is restoration: a case study in a natural park on Catalonia, Northeastern Spain.
economically viable although there is no sale of reclaimed water. Desalination 2009;246:179–89.
4402 M. Molinos-Senante et al. / Science of the Total Environment 408 (2010) 4396–4402

Shabman L, Stephenson K. Environmental valuation and its economic critics. J Water Swinton JR. At what cost do we reduce pollution? Shadow price of SO2 emissions.
Resour Plann manage-ASCE 2000;126(6):382–8. Energy J 1998;19(4):63–83.
Shephard RW. Theory of cost and production functions. Princeton: Princeton University Weiss J. The economic of project appraisal and the environment. Cambridge: Edward
Press; 1970. Elgar Publishing Limited. University Press; 1994.
Song, Z.H., Y.L. Li and T.L. Li. 2010. Experiences with market-based instruments for Wissel S, Watzold F. A conceptual analysis of the application of tradable permits to
energy saving and emision reduction: environment protection practices of leading biodiversity conservation. Conserv Biol 2010;24(2):404–11.
western countries. EBM 2010: International Conference on Engineering and Yaisawarng S, Klein JD. The effects of sulfur dioxide controls on productivity change in
Business Management, 1–8, 3672–3677. the U.S. electric power industry. Rev Econ Stat 1994;76(3):447–60.
Sugden R, Williams A. Principles of practical cost–benefit analysis. Oxford University Zhang KM, Wen ZG. Review and challenges of policies of environmental protection and
Press; 1988. sustainable development in China. J Environ Manage 2008;88(4):1249–61.

Вам также может понравиться