Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 76

BOND ANALYSIS AND VALUATION

CEFA 2003/2004

LECTURE NOTES

Mats Hansson

Svenska handelshögskolan

Institutionen för finansiell ekonomi och ekonomisk statistik


i

Contents

1.
TU UT FIXED INCOME SECURITIES - AN INTRODUCTION
TU UT 1

1.1.
TU UT What’s so special about fixed income securities?
TU UT 1

1.2.
TU UT The risks of investing in debt and why everybody always talks about the yield
TU UT 2

1.3.
TU UT The money and bond markets
TU UT 3

1.4.
TU UT Market size
TU UT 4

1.5.
TU Factors affecting the level of the nominal return
UT TU UT 5
1.5.1. The real return
TU UT TU UT 5
1.5.2. The inflation rate
TU UT TU UT 6
1.5.3. The risk premium
TU UT TU UT 7

2.
TU UT BOND AND INTEREST RATE MATHEMATICS
TU UT 8

2.1.
TU The frequency of compounding
UT TU UT 8
2.1.1. Effective money market yields
TU UT TU UT 10

2.2.
TU Building blocks: zeros and forwards
UT TU UT 11
2.2.1. Zero-coupon bonds
TU UT TU UT 11
2.2.2. Forward rates
TU UT TU UT 13

2.3.
TU Zero-coupon pricing of coupon bonds
UT TU UT 15
2.3.1. The coupon rate
TU UT TU UT 15
2.3.2. The present value of a coupon bond
TU UT TU UT 15
2.3.3. Yield to maturity for a coupon bond
TU UT TU UT 17
2.3.4. The par yield
TU UT TU UT 20

2.4.
TU The yield: common misconceptions
UT TU UT 21
2.4.1. The yield is not the return
TU UT TU UT 21
2.4.2. Yields are not additive
TU UT TU UT 22

2.5.
TU UT From coupon bonds to zeros: bootstrapping
TU UT 23

2.6.
TU UT Spot and forward rates with semi-annual compounding
TU UT 25

3.
TU UT DAY COUNTS AND ACCRUED INTEREST
TU UT 27

3.1.
TU UT Day count basis
TU UT 27

3.2.
TU UT The money market
TU UT 28

3.3.
TU UT Zero-coupon bonds: annual compounding
TU UT 29

3.4.
TU UT Zero-coupon bonds: semi-annual compounding
TU UT 30

3.5.
TU Coupon bonds
UT TU UT 30
3.5.1. Dirty prices and clean prices
TU UT TU UT 31
3.5.2. Behavior of dirty and clean prices over time: convergence towards par
TU UT TU UT 32
ii

4.
TU UT MEASURING INTEREST RATE RISK: DURATION AND CONVEXITY 34
TU UT

4.1.
TU UT The yield-price relationship for bonds
TU UT 34

4.2.
TU Duration
UT TU UT 35
4.2.1. Macaulay duration
TU UT TU UT 36

4.3.
TU Modified duration and PVBP
UT TU UT 37
4.3.1. The duration of a bond through time
TU UT TU UT 38
4.3.2. Key rate duration
TU UT TU UT 39

4.4.
TU Convexity
UT TU UT 40
4.4.1. Duration matching and the value of convexity
TU UT TU UT 42

4.5.
TU UT Bond portfolio duration and convexity
TU UT 44

4.6.
TU Butterfly trades: A critical assessment of yield, convexity and duration
UT TU UT 45
4.6.1. Weighting a butterfly
TU UT TU UT 45
4.6.2. A critical assessment of yield, convexity, and duration
TU UT TU UT 47

5. APPLICATIONS OF BOND MATHEMATICS I: FRA:S AND BOND


TU UT TU

FUTURES UT 49

5.1.
TU UT Forward Rate Agreements
TU UT 49

5.2.
TU Bond futures
UT TU UT 51
5.2.1. Futures pricing: The general approach
TU UT TU UT 51
5.2.2. Repo transactions in the bond cash and futures markets
TU UT TU UT 52
5.2.3. Coupon payments
TU UT TU UT 53
5.2.4. Notional bonds and delivery options
TU UT TU UT 54
5.2.5. Futures pricing using quoted prices and accrued interest
TU UT TU UT 55

6.
TU UT APPLICATIONS OF BOND MATHEMATICS II: SWAP CONTRACTS 58
TU UT

6.1.
TU Interest rate swaps
UT TU UT 58
6.1.1. The swap rate
TU UT TU UT 59
6.1.2. The swap rate and FRA-rates
TU UT TU UT 60
6.1.3. Interest rate swap valuation
TU UT TU UT 61

6.2.
TU Currency swaps
UT TU UT 62
6.2.1. Currency swap rates and currency forward rates
TU UT TU UT 63
6.2.2. Currency swap valuation
TU UT TU UT 64

7.
TU UT PRICING CREDIT RISK
TU UT 65

7.1.
TU UT Credit ratings
TU UT 65

7.2.
TU UT The traditional approach to pricing credit risk
TU UT 66

7.3.
TU UT Using option theory to price credit risk
TU UT 67

7.4.
TU Default probabilities, rating transitions, recovery rates and how to use them to estimate
UT TU

bond returns UT 69

7.5.
TU UT Selected empirical results on spreads
TU UT 72
1

1. Fixed income securities - An introduction

Debt instruments or fixed income securities are financial instruments that commit the
issuer to a series of fixed payments (for example a series of coupons and principal).
Examples are treasury bonds and bills, corporate bonds and loans, certificates of deposit,
and interest rate and currency swaps. The issuer of these securities promise a certain cash
flow at certain specified times in the future, hence the definition “fixed income”. Also,
fixed income securities typically have a finite maturity.

1.1. What’s so special about fixed income securities?

A fixed income security follows the same basic principles of valuation as for e.g. stocks:
future cash flows are discounted to present time. Fixed income securities, however, have
a number of special features that make a separate treatment of these instruments
warranted:

1. Fixed cash flows. Most bonds pay fixed interest (altough floating rate notes are also
common), which is also paid on specified dates. Thus, cash flows are known both
with respect to size and maturity, except in the case of default.
2. Finite and known maturity. Except for some rare cases (perpetuities), fixed income
securities have a limited maturity, which is known in advance. Item 1) and 2) makes it
possible to construct special risk measures for bonds, like duration and convexity.
3. Only downside with respect to promised cash flow. The cash flow received from
a straight bond can never exceed its promised coupons and face value.
4. A wide variety of instruments are available. A wide range of maturities (1 day to
30 years or more), cash flow structures (zero-coupon bonds, coupon bonds, annuities
etc.), issuers (corporations, governments, municipalities etc.), and derivatives (swaps,
bond and money market futures, forwards, options etc.). Since a bond or a loan is a
legal contract between borrower and lender, the payoff and risk structure (payment
schedule, covenants etc.) of the bond/loan is determined in this contract, and hence
there is no limit to where product development can go in the debt markets.
5. Lower risks, lower returns. The financial risk associated with fixed income is lower
than with equities. This means lower expected and, on average, lower realised returns.
This in turn calls for more precision in the pricing process, since if returns are low,
every basis point counts. Since upside potential is low, paying too much (mispricing)
usually means that the investor’s return is ruined for good, while on the stock
markets one can always hope for a more substantial increase in value.
6. The term structure of interest rates is used for valuation. When valuing stocks, a
single discount rate is used to discount all cash flows. In doing this we assume that all
cash flows are equally risky and that the time value of money is the same for all
maturities. The wide diversity of instruments available on fixed income markets
makes a more precise valuation of debt instruments possible. In the ideal case, we
can find information on the interest rates for many different maturities, making it
possible to value each cash flow of a bond using a separate interest rate that reflects
the risk of that maturity.
7. Arbitrage. The variety of instruments with very low credit risk (interbank market) or
in practice no credit risk (Treasury markets) makes arbitrage and arbitrage pricing
possible and links prices of instruments to each other.
2

8. Volatility is a function of time. As we will later see, the volatility of a fixed income
security depends on 1) changes in the interest rate level, and 2) the duration of the
bond. Thus, even if interest rate volatility is constant, the volatility of the bond will
decrease with time.
9. Changes in the interest rate level is the most important source of risk. The
nature of debt instruments implies that the valuation process is to a large extent
concerned with the time value of money. Time value of money is closely related to
the level of interest rates, and hence debt instruments could also be labeled interest
sensitive assets.
10. Institutional details. The practice of expressing prices as interest rates (yields), or
”clean prices”, different day count conventions and compounding frequencies etc.

1.2. The risks of investing in debt and why everybody always


talks about the yield

• the most common type of interest rate payment is a fixed coupon


• since the cash flows are fixed, there is less upside than in stocks, and all the changes
in price will come from the change in the discount rate, or the yield
• hence, much of the fixed income investment analysis is centered around the yield
and the yield spread

SPREAD EXCESS RETURN

(Risk premium) Transaction cost

Covenants

Credit risk
YIELD
BENCHMARK
Seniority
YIELD

(Default risk
free yield)
Real interest rate

Interest rate risk

Inflation risk

• many of the risks contributing to total yield are difficult to measure and price
• excess return is the expected excess return from investing in corporates over
Treasuries after taking into account all the risks incorporated in the spread that can
materialise
• excess return must be must be positive in the long run, otherwise a risk-averse
investor will not invest in corporates
3

• up to date there exists no pricing model (a la CAPM) flexible enough to incorporate


all the terms and covenants in the debt contract affecting return and risk, yet general
enough to lend itself to practical use

1.3. The money and bond markets

Fixed income securities can be classified in as many sectors as one likes, but the most
common categories are by maturity:

1. Short term securities. Maturity up to 1 year.


2. Long term securities. Maturity of more than 1 year.

This classification comes from the similarity of the pricng technique within one category,
short term debt usually pays no interest (zero-coupon bonds, discount bonds), so there is
only one cash flow at maturity, and simple interest is used when discounting. Long term
bonds usually pay interest, and compound interest is used for discounting.

One could also classify securities into:

1. Default risk free securities. These securities are issued by governments


(Treasuries) of developed countries, and are considered to be in practice free of
default risk.
2. Securities with default risk. Corporate bonds and for example emerging market
sovereign debt are not free of default risk.

• securities with a maturity of maximum 1 year are frequently referred to as “money


market” instruments
• typical money market instruments include:

1. short term deposits (nontradable)


2. certificates of deposit (interbank market)
3. commercial paper (corporate sector)
4. Treasury bills (government sector)

• typical bond market instruments include:

1. Government bonds (also called Treasury or Sovereign bonds)


2. Corporate bonds
3. Mortgage bonds (securitised mortgage debt)

The government sector is usually more liquid than the corporate sector due to larger
markets, and in many countries the bulk of corporate borrowing is still mainly routed
through bank loans, altough this has been changing in Europe since the Euro. Loans of
large corporations are usually syndicated loans, a group of banks divides the loan
between themselves for diversification. Most bonds and loans are "bullets", where
interest is paid annually or semiannually, and the principal is paid back at maturity. In
many countries, a substantial part of the government bonds are so called benchmark
bonds (or serial bonds), for example the Finnish benchmarks are:
4

Bond Maturity CPN Issue price Current Yield% Amount


price EUR
(m)
% 10.11.0 10.11.0 29.10.03
3 3
Serial bond 2003/I 4.7.2006 2.750 99.714 99.040 3.032 6 500
Serial bond 2001/I 4.7.2007 5.000 100.021 105.040 3.495 6 231
Serial bond 4.7.2008 3.000 99.552 96.830 3.754 5 999
2003/II
Serial bond 25.4.200 5.000 99.500 105.170 3.922 5 753
1998/II 9
Serial bond 2000/I 23.2.201 5.750 99.110 109.350 4.227 5 673
1
Serial bond 4.7.2013 5.375 99.666 106.910 4.473 6 000
2002/II
36 156

1.4. Market size

• many bonds are listed at an exchange, but trading is (so far) mostly OTC
• global markets by country of issuer:

By sector: 1) Government and agency, 2) Corporate and


financial institutions

20000

15000
USD billions

10000

5000

0
USA Germany France Japan Finland
Government 9697 867 791 5316 77
Corporate 8805 2190 887 1606 41
Total 18502 3057 1678 6922 118

• risk management and the desire to explore cost-effective borrowing through swaps
has lead to enromous global fixed income derivatives markets:
5

By sector: 1) Foreign exchange, 2) Interest rate, 3) Equity linked, and


market (OTC or Exchanges)

100000
USD billions

80000
60000
40000
20000
0
OTC OTC
OTC FX Ex. FX Ex. Interest Ex. Equity
Interest Equity
Forwards 10723 8792 364 72 13444 422
Swaps 4509 79161 0 0 0 0
Options 3238 13746 1944 33 22024 2307
Total 18470 101699 2308 105 35468 2729

1.5. Factors affecting the level of the nominal return

Why are interest rates not equal for all time-periods, and why is the term structure of
interest rates usually (but not always) upward sloping? To answer these questions we
need to have a look at what factors affect required returns, and why these factors need
not be equally large for all time periods.

The return for any asset can be decomposed into three factors:

1. the required real return


2. expected inflation over the investment horizon
3. a risk premium

• the real return and expected inflation affect the returns on all assets in an economy
• the magnitude of the risk premium is asset specific

1.5.1. The real return

• first suppose there is no inflation and the investment is risk-free: the return consists
solely of the investors perception of time value of money, or real return
• thus, the real return says how much the investor wants his purchasing power to
increase when investing
• investing is delaying consumption to the future, for doing this the investor
requires a compensation
• if this compensation is equally large for each time period (e.g. each year), the yield
curve will be flat (compensation proportional to time)
• in the simplest setting, the level of the real return depends on money supply and
demand:
6

1. the supply depends on investors willingness to postpone consumption


2. the demand depends on opportunities for productive investment

• for example, suppose that investment opportunities improve and firms are willing to
invest more at any interest rate level
• then, interest rates must rise to induce investors to save more ⇒ investors require a
higher compensation to postpone a larger amount of their consumption

1.5.2. The inflation rate

• if there is inflation in the economy, investors will require a premium over the real rate
equal to the expected inflation rate for the investment horizon
• if inflation is constant, this will result in a still flat, but higher yield curve
• thus, still ignoring risk premiums, the required nominal interest rate (rn) on a riskless
B B

security depends on: 1) the real required return (rr). and 2) the expected inflation
B B

[E(i)] is approximately:

rn ≈ rr + E (i )

Example: An investor is investing for 1 year, and wants the purchasing power of his
U U

money to increase with 3% over the next year. This is his required real return, a
compensation for postponing his consumption 1 year. Also, the investor expects the
inflation to be 2% from today to 1-year ahead. Thus, his nominal required return is

rn ≈ rr + E (i ) = 0.03 + 0.02 = 0.05 = 5%

• inflation and real returns need not be constant over time


• if investors expect inflation and/or real rates to increase, longer rates should be higher
• if investors expect inflation and/or real rates to decline, longer rates should be lower
• but: even if the level of inflation is not expected to rise, the level of future inflation is
still uncertain, investors may require a premium for longer rates due to inflation risk
⇒ your real return is uncertain ⇒ require risk premium for risky real return
• if, in addition, the level of real returns is uncertain ⇒ further risk of real return risk
• thus we may have premiums for both inflation risk, and real return risk
• investors require a premium for investing for long maturities
• implies an upward sloping yield curve (despite small declines inflation/real rates)
• downward sloping curves only if future inflation/real rates substantially lower
• flat curves occur only if future yields expected to decline
7

1.5.3. The risk premium

• a security that has no default risk is considered riskless with respect to default risk
• for example government securities are considered free of default risk (or at least have
the lowest possible level of default risk)
• a risk premium must be added on top of required real returns and expected inflation
for issuers that have default risk
• but even in the treasury markets we typically observe that interest rates (for example
yields) increase with maturity
• interest rate risk (typically measured by duration) increases with maturity
8

2. Bond and interest rate mathematics

• in this chapter we assume there is no credit risk, such that money can be moved back
and forth in time without caring about the riskiness of future payments
• nobody has ever claimed that bond calculations are fun or interesting, but given the
size of the market and the amount of money potentially lost because one simply didn’t
know, one cant’t ignore the subject
• let’s have a look at a some numbers we can use to describe a coupon bond:

Face value: 1000.00


Present value: 1150.62
Maturity: 3.00 years
Coupon rate: 10.00% (annual)
Yield to maturity: 4.5188%
Par yield: 4.5344%
Zero-coupon rate (3 yrs.): 4.55%

We can make some observations: first, we note that the PV is higher than the face value.
Second, we note that the coupon rate (10%) is higher than the yield to maturity (what is a
yield to maturity anyway?). Third, we note that the zero-coupon rate (what’s that again?)
is higher than the yield. Fourth, we have something called par yield (what?) which is
different from all previous interest rates (coupon, zero, yield). Fifth, we note that we are
confronted with four different interest rates: the coupon rate, the yield, par yield, and the
zero-coupon rate. The final blow is that none of these is the return of the bond, despite
its ”fixed income” features.
All these relations are not an accident: the price and face value are related
through coupon rates, yields, and zero yields. This example should make it clear that the
expression ”interest rate” can mean a variety of things. In the following chapter(s) we will
explore these concepts in detail.

2.1. The frequency of compounding

• stock returns and standard deviations are usually expressed as percent per year
• a stock return in the US has the same interpretation as a stock return in Finland
• interest rates, however, come in many varieties and are usually not directly comparable
• each market and currency has its own agreed upon rules of how to convert a
discount rate into a price or the other way around:

1. when should one use simple interest, and when compound interest?
2. if compound interest is used, what is the frequency of compounding?
3. how should one count days to arrive at a fraction of a year (one unit of time in
finance is 1 year)?

• rules about how to discount and to define fractions of a year are important in fixed
income markets because prices can be given both as discount factors (yields) or prices
• these are not as important on stock markets, since there is anyway great uncertainty
about the timing and size of cash flows, and since prices are never given as yields
9

• simple interest is used when no interest is paid before maturity

FV = PV * [1 + (r * t )]
FV
and PV =
[1 + (r * t )]

FV = future value
PV = present value
r = interest rate expressed as decimals on a per annum basis
t = maturity in years

• compound interest is used when interest is paid and added to the principal

FV
FV = PV * (1 + r ) t and PV =
(1 + r ) t

• the usual rule is that short-term rates (money market) are treated as simple interest
rates, while long-term rates are treated as compound interest rates
• bonds pay interest before maturity, and the “opportunity cost” can be seen as a long-
term deposit that pays interest m times a year and is added to the capital
• this is standard when analysing returns on any market, for example long-term returns
on stock markets always assume dividends are reinvested (= compound interest)
• all interest rates are expressed as annual rates (unless stated otherwise)

Example: A bank offers a 3-month deposit rate of 3.50%. If you deposit EUR 1 000
U U

today, how much cash do you have after 3 months? (For simplicity, assume 3 months is
0.25 years)

FV = PV * [1 + (r * t )] = 1000 EUR * [1 + (0.035 * 0.25)] = 1008.75EUR

• note that the actual return earned over 3 months is only 0.875%

Example: A bank offers a 2-year deposit rate of 4.25%. The deposit pays interest
U U

annually. If you deposit EUR 1 000 today, how much cash do you have after 2 years?

FV = PV * [1 + r ] = 1000 EUR * [1 + 0.0425] = 1086.80


t 2

• note that the actual return earned over a 2-year period is 8.68%
• note that the time t, is seldom an integer value (this happens once a year), hence the
need to convert a number of days to a fraction of a year by some defined rules
• converting all rates to annual rates makes comparison easier
• converting actual returns over N years to a one-year return (using the previous
example):
10

[
r = (1 + rActual )
1/ N
]− 1 = [(1 + 0.0868) ]− 1 = 0.0425
1/ 2

• suppose that the compounding frequency (m) is not 1 year but 0.25 years instead
(interest is paid quarterly):

t *m 2*4
⎡ r⎤ ⎡ 0.0425 ⎤
FV = PV * ⎢1 + ⎥ = 1000 EUR * ⎢1 + = 1088.23EUR
⎣ m⎦ ⎣ 4 ⎥⎦

• an interest of 4.25/4 = 1.0625% is paid each 0.25 years and compounded 8 times
• the higher frequency of compounding increases the return to 8.82% if the annual
rate remains unchanged since interest can be added to principal more frequently
• in the limit: continuous compounding when the interval of frequency becomes very
small:

FV = PV * e r *t = 1000 EUR * e 0.0425*2 = 1088.72 EUR

• rates based on continuous compounding are mainly used in theoretical literature,


never in practice

2.1.1. Effective money market yields

• money market rates are simple yields and cannot be directly compared due to
differences in compounding frequency
• 1 month deposit can be rolled over 12 times during a year, but a 2 month deposit only
6 times
• conversion to annual effective yields is required:

⎡⎡ rSIMPLE ⎤
360 / t

Yield EFF = ⎢ ⎢1 + ⎥ ⎥ −1
⎢⎣ ⎣ (360 / t ) ⎦ ⎥⎦

Example: Both the 30-day and the 60-day simple annual interest rates are 4%. What are
U U

the effective annual yields?

The 30-day effective annual yield is

⎡⎡ 0.04 ⎤
360 / 30

Yield EFF = ⎢ ⎢1 +
⎢⎣ ⎣ ( 360 / 30) ⎥
⎦ ⎥⎦
[
⎥ − 1 = [1 + 0.003333] ]
12 .00
− 1 = 0.040742 = 4.0742%
11

The 60-day effective annual yield is

⎡⎡ 0.04 ⎤
360 / 60

Yield EFF = ⎢ ⎢1 + ⎥
⎢⎣ ⎣ (360 / 60) ⎦ ⎥⎦
[
⎥ − 1 = [1 + 0.006666]]6.00
− 1 = 0.040673 = 4.0673%

• if the simple rates are at level, the 30-day effective yield is higher because it can be
rolled over more frequently
• note also that the roll-over of the 30-day investment is risky, since the second 30-day
rate was unknown at the beginning of the 60-day investment period

2.2. Building blocks: zeros and forwards

• when analyzing fixed income securities, sooner or later one will be confronted with
zero coupon rates (also called spot rates)
• a zero coupon rate is the discount rate (yield) for a zero-coupon bond, that is for a
bond paying a single cash flow received at time t
• zero rates are the building blocks of all fixed income analysis, and as we will see later,
using the yield of a coupon bond for valuation can lead to severe mispricing
• since the zero coupon rate is the only unambiguous interest rate for a particular
maturity, everything else needed can be calculated using zero rates: discount factors,
coupon bond prices and yields, par yields, forwards, swap rates etc.

2.2.1. Zero-coupon bonds

• zero-coupon bonds exist almost exclusively on treasury markets, for example US


Treasury or German Bund STRIPS
• the discounted value of the face value (negative cash flow) is invested and the face
value is received at maturity (positive cash flow)
• the time period (t) may be anything from one day to several years
• a separate spot rate is required for each period in time (t) to value a cash flow at time
t, and hence, we have a term structure of spot rates
• consider for example the following sequence of spot rates:

Maturity Spot rate


Years %
1 4.00
2 4.30
3 4.55
4 4.75
5 4.90

• then, we can graph the term structure of these spot rates:


12

6.00

5.00
Spot rate (%)

4.00

3.00

2.00

1.00

0.00
0 1 2 3 4 5

Maturity (Years)

• all interest rates are expressed on an annual basis (p.a.) to be more easily compared
• because most securities with maturity of over 1 year pay interest, the convention is to
express all interest rates for maturities over 1 year as annually or semi-annually
compounded rates
• thus, even if a zero-coupon bond pays no interest, we like to compare it with interest
paying securities, and do this by expressing them as annually compounded rates

Example: The 3-year zero-coupon rate is 4.55%. This does not mean that if you invest
U U U U

100 today in a 3-year zero-coupon security, you get 104.55 back after 3-years. Since the
spot rate is expressed as an annually compunded rate, your investment yields:

FV = 100 * (1 + 0.0455) 3 = 114.28

which corresponds to an actual interest over the 3-year period of 14.28%. But comparing
this figure for example with a 3-year deposit that pays 4.5% p.a. is not very meaningful.
Hence, the conversion of the spot rate to an annually compounded rate.

• another way of expressing an interest rate is as a discount factor


• in the above case the discount factor is:

1 1
Df 3 = t = = 0.8750
(1 + r ) (1 + 0.0455) 3

• the discount factor is the PV of one unit (1) of currency received at time t
• the discount factor reflects both 1) time and 2) the discount rate
• discount factors are decreasing with maturity and always between 0 and 1:
13

1.00

0.95
Discount factor

0.90

0.85

0.80

0.75
0 1 2 3 4 5

Maturity (Years)

• the discount factor is also the price (in % of face value) of a zero-coupon bond
• for example, the price for a 3-year zero quoted at a yield 4.55% with face value 1000
(promises to pay 1000 after 3 years) is of course:

1000 1000
PV = = = 875.00
(1 + r ) t
(1 + 0.0455) 3

or equivalently:

PV = CF * Df = 1000 * 0.8750 = 875.00

2.2.2. Forward rates

• a forward interest rate is a rate set today for an investment that starts at a specified
time in the future
• spot rates for different maturities are linked by forward rates
• e.g. the interest rate for a 1-year investment that starts in the future is called a forward
rate
• e.g. the 2-year spot rate, r2 (from period 0 to 2), can be expressed using the 1-year spot
B B

rate (from 0 to 1) and a forward rate from year 1 to year 2, which we denote f12 : B B

r2
B B

r1
B f12
B B B

• an investor with a 2-year investment horizon has two choices:


14

1. invest at the 2-year spot rate r2 B B

2. invest at the 1-year spot rate r1 and roll over the deposit with the forward. f12
B B B B

• since all rates (r1, r2, and f12) are known today the two investments can be compared:
B B B B B B

(1 + r2 ) 2 = (1 + r1 ) * (1 + f 12 )

• this is an important arbitrage statement: the payoff from the two investments are
known today, and must be the same to prevent arbitrage
• if, for example:

(1 + r2 ) 2 > (1 + r1 ) * (1 + f 12 )

• we could borrow at the 1-year rate, roll over the borrowing with the forward and
invest at the 2-year rate for an arbitrage profit (since all rates are known today)
• note that the time periods need not be 1 year, they could be e.g. 3 months, and show
how 3-month forwards are linked to 3- and 6-month money market rates
• the figure below shows how spot rates are built up of one-period forward rates:

f01 B B f12 B B f23


B B f34
B B f45
B B

r1
B B

r2
B B

r3
B B

r4
B B

r5
B B

Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 4 Period 5

• the forward rate for period 2 (f12) can be found by setting: B B

(1 + r2 ) 2
f 12 = −1
(1 + r1 )

• or, more generally:

(1 + rt ) t
f n ,t = −1
(1 + rn ) n

t= maturity for the longer spot rate


n= maturity for the shorter spot rate
15

Example: Assume the 1-year spot rate is 4.00%, the 2-year spot rate is 4.30%, and the 3-
U U

year spot rate is 4.55%. What are the one-year forward rates for year 2 and 3?

(1 + 0.0430) 2
f12 = − 1 = 1.046009 − 1 = 0.046009 = 4.60%
(1 + 0.040)

(1 + 0.0455) 3
f 23 = − 1 = 1.050518 − 1 = 0.050518 = 5.05%
(1 + 0.0430) 2

• we can extend the information in the table:

Maturity Spot rate Actual Discount Forward


return factor 1-year
Years % (p.a.) %
1 4.00 4.00 0.9615 4.0000
2 4.30 8.78 0.9192 4.6009
3 4.55 14.28 0.8750 5.0518
4 4.75 20.40 0.8306 5.3523
5 4.90 27.02 0.7873 5.5022

2.3. Zero-coupon pricing of coupon bonds

2.3.1. The coupon rate

• most bonds pay annual or semi-annual fixed interest payments, called coupons
• coupon is paid on the face value, and is thus for fixed rate bonds a fixed value, since
the face value of a bullet bond does not change
• the interest paid can also be a floating rate, based on some benchmark interest rate
(e.g. LIBOR), and is reset at each coupon payment date (FRN= floating rate notes)
• the coupon rate is usually set to reflect the current interest rate level, and rounded to
the nearest 25 or 12.5 basis points, and the issue price adjusts to reflect the difference
between investor’s required yield and the coupon rate

2.3.2. The present value of a coupon bond

• suppose the (rising) term structure previously used applies, and an investor
chooses between two bonds by the same issuer:

1. a 3-year zero-coupon bond with face value 100


2. a 3-year bond paying 5% annual coupons and face value 100

• what return should the investor require from investing in these two bonds?
• we know that r3 = 4.55% so this seems a reasonable yield for bond 1
B B

• should we require the same yield from bond 2 just because the last cash flow occurs
at the same time?
16

• no, there is no reason to let maturity alone determine the discount rate!
• these are clearly two different bonds, 4.55% is a yield for one single payment at t = 3,
and the second bond provides us with a series of payments in t = 1, 2 and 3
• theoretically, a coupon bond is a collection of zero-coupon bonds, where each
payment (coupon or principal) can be seen as a separate zero-coupon bond
• hence, the price of a coupon bond is the sum of all the individual payments (zeros):

CF1 CF2 CFT


PV = + +…+ = CF1 * Df1 + CF2 * Df 2 + … + CFT * Df T
(1 + r1 ) (1 + r2 )
1 2
(1 + rT ) T

where

CFi B B = cash flow received at time i


ri B B = zero-coupon rate for maturity i
Dfi B B = discount factor for maturity i

For a bullet bond the cash flow is coupon payments until the last cash flow at maturity T
(CFT) which is the last coupon + face value. The time periods (1...T) are usually fractions
B B

of a year (e.g. the first payment could occur after 0.8 years, the second after 1.8 years etc.)

• from the PV-equation, it would seem very odd to use r3 = 4.55% for all payments B B

• instead we use a series of zero coupon rates to value a the bond:

Example: The value of a 3-year bond that pays a 5% annual coupon on EUR 1 000 face
U U

value assuming the spot rate 4.00% for one year, 4.30% for two years, and 4.55% for
three years:

CF1 CF2 CF3 50 50 1050


PV = + + = + +
(1 + r1 ) (1 + r2 ) 2
(1 + r3 ) 3
(1 + 0.04) (1 + 0.0430) 2
(1 + 0.0455) 3

= 48.07 + 45.96 + 918.79 = 1012.83

The coupon bond sells above par (101.283% of the face value), since the coupon
payments exceed the current interest rate level (term structure of zeros). A market for
zeros guarantees that the bond must be priced using zero rates: otherwise, a bond could
be stripped and the parts (coupon and/or principal) could be sold at a different price in
the strips market. Or, one could assemble a bond from strips and sell the package as a
coupon-paying bond. This arbitrage/replication approach to bond pricing is of course is
directly applicable where a liquid zero-coupon market exists along a coupon-bond
market.

Nevertheless, zero-coupon pricing captures the whole shape of the term-


structure, and correctly prices each part of a specific cash-flow structure.
17

This is particularly important when observed market yields correspond to certain


cash-flow structures (zeros, deferrals, step-ups, coupon bonds, annuities etc.), and one
is to price non-standard cash flow structures.

2.3.3. Yield to maturity for a coupon bond

• what is the yield to maturity for a coupon bond priced using zeroes?
• the yield to maturity for a zero is unambiguous: it is the zero-coupon rate
• for coupon bonds the yield is the internal rate of return for the bond
• thus, once the price of the bond is known, we must solve the present value equation
with respect to yield (y):

CF1 CF2 CF3 50 50 1050


PV = + + = + + = 1012.83
(1 + y ) (1 + y ) 2
(1 + y ) 3
(1 + y ) (1 + y ) 2
(1 + y ) 3

the yield can be found by trial-and-error (for example using a solver-function) and is

y = 0.045329 or 4.5329%

• note that since the yield is a kind of ”weighted average” of the zero coupon rates, and
the largest cash flow (principal + last coupon) is paid at year 3, the yield is close to the
longest zero rate
• another, less frequently used measure is the current yield:

Current yield = Coupon/PV

for example:

Current yield = 50/1012.83 = 4.9367%

• ... which is a more or less meaningless measure


• try to value the bond using the yield:

50 50 1050
PV = + + = 47.83 + 45.77 + 919.24 = 1012.83
(1 + 0.045329) (1 + 0.045329) 2
(1 + 0.045329) 3

• the values of the individual cash flows have changed


• a bond can be stripped into zero-coupon instruments:

Coupon bond:
Principal
Coupon 1 Coupon 2
Coupon 3
18

Stripped bond:

Coupon 1
Coupon 2 Principal

Coupon 3

0 1 2 3 Time

• the law-of-one-price does not hold, since the stripped coupons and zeros do not
have the same price if the bond is valued using the yield
• now, consider the same spot rates but a bond that pays a 10% coupon:

100 100 1100


PV = + + = 1150.62
(1 + 0.04) (1 + 0.043) 2
(1 + 0.0455) 3

• the yield for this bond is 4.5188% or 0.014% lower than for the the 5% coupon bond
• despite the same spot rates and the same maturity, bonds can have different yields:

Bond type Yield Price


3 year bullet, 0% coupon 4.5500% 875.00
3 year bullet, 5% coupon 4.5329% 1012.83
3 year bullet, 10% coupon 4.5188% 1150.62
3 year annuity, 5% coupon 4.3680% 994.47

• a tricky (that is, impossible) question to answer is ”what is the yield for 3-year bonds”:
there is no unambiguous answer to that question
• the only result that prevails is that the only unambiguous interest rate for a certain
maturity is the zero-coupon rate
• a yield for a 3-year coupon bond is clearly not a true 3-year rate since cash flows are
distributed over the time span 1-3 years
• even if the yield has limitations in measuring the interest rate level, it is still a
convenient “summary” measure, and used as such in practice
• one more example of the pitfalls of pricing with the yield:

Example: The treasury is offering a new product:


U U

Maturity: 3 years
Face value: EUR 1 000 000
Bond type: Annuity
19

Coupon: 5.00%
Annuity: EUR 367 208.56 annual

The annuity is calculated as:

⎡ r (1 + r ) t ⎤ ⎡ 0.05(1 + 0.05) 3 ⎤
Annuity = PV * ⎢ ⎥ = 1000000 * ⎢ ⎥ = 367208.56
⎣⎢ (1 + r ) − 1 ⎦⎥ ⎣⎢ (1 + 0.05) − 1 ⎦⎥
t 3

You work for the treasury, and your task is to price the bond to decide which treasury
auction bids to accept. You observe some treasury bond yields on the market:

Treasury zero-coupon bonds:

1 year: 4.00%
2 years: 5.00%
3 years: 6.00%

Treasury 3 year benchmark, 5% coupon bond:

3 years 5.933%

You have never even heard about the CEFA-program, and hence, you are unaware of
term-structure theory and bond mathematics, and you decide to price the new annuity
bond using the 3-year treasury yield for the 5% coupon bond. You find that the price
should be (you discount the annuities with the yield):

I) Using yield (5.993%) for coupon bond:

367208.56 367208.56 367208.56


PV = + + = 982770.06
(1 + 0.05993) 1
(1 + 0.05993) 2
(1 + 0.05993) 3

At this price, the annuity naturally carries a yield of 5.933%

II) Using term-structure of zero-coupon rates:

367208.56 367208.56 367208.56


PV = + + = 994469.54
(1 + 0.04)1 (1 + 0.05) 2 (1 + 0.06) 3

At this price, the annuity carries a yield of 5.2965%

Now, your pricing adventures of having applied a 5% coupon bond yield to an annuity
has three consequences: 1) you mispriced (underpriced) the annuity with about 70 basis
points, 2) investors would kill to lay their hands on the annuity, 3) you will lose your job
or alternatively the Treasury will send you to next year’s CEFA program.

The following table will highlight the problem of using the yield for a particular cash flow
structure when pricing a different cash flow structure:

5% CPN bond Annuity


Maturity Cash flow % of total CF Cash flow % of total CF
20

1 50 000 4.35% 367 208.56 33.33%


2 50 000 4.35% 367 208.56 33.33%
3 1 050 000 91.30% 367 208.56 33.33%
Total 1 150 000 100.00% 1 101 625.68 100.00%

2.3.4. The par yield

• we now know that the yield for bonds of a certain maturity will depend on the
coupon rate (or more generally the cash flow structure, for example the annuity)
• thus, it is impossible to say what the yield is for a certain maturity
• a commonly used yield is, however, the par yield
• a bond whose price equals its face value is said to sell at par (100% of the face value)
• the yield for such a bond is then the par yield
• for par bonds:

Yield = coupon rate ⇒ PV = 100% of face value

• the par yield for maturity T can easily be calculated using discount factors:

(1 − Df T )
Yield Par = T

∑ Df
i =1
i

which says that you 1) calculate the discount factors for all cash flows upt to T, 2) divide
1 minus the discount factor for maturity T with the sum of all discount factors.

Example: Calculate the par yield for 3-year bonds. From previous tables, we know that
U U

the discount factors for years 1 to 3 are: 0.9615, 0.9192, and 0.8750. Then:

(1 − 0.8759)
Yield Par = = 0.045344
(0.9615 + 0.9192 + 0.8750)

which is 4.5344%. Thus, if we would issue a 3 year bond with 4.5344% annual coupons,
it would trade at par. We can complete the table:

Maturity Spot rate Actual Discount Forward Par yield


return factor (1-year)
Years % (p.a.) %
1 4.00 4.00 0.9615 4.0000 4.0000
2 4.30 8.78 0.9192 4.6009 4.2937
3 4.55 14.28 0.8750 5.0518 4.5344
4 4.75 20.40 0.8306 5.3523 4.7238
5 4.90 27.02 0.7873 5.5022 4.8639
21

and draw some graphs of the different interest rate curves:

6.00

5.50

5.00
Rate (%)

Zeros

4.50 Forwards
Par yields

4.00

3.50

3.00
0 1 2 3 4 5

Maturity (Years)

2.4. The yield: common misconceptions

• from the previous section, it should have become clear that in some circumstances,
the yield to maturity can be a misleading measure for coupon paying bonds
• however, since the cash flows for most bonds look similar (fixed coupon payments
inside a certain range, no negative cash flows), the yield is a convenient summary
measure of the bond price relative to its cash flows as an annual per cent rate
• one should, however, be aware of what a yield is and what it is not:

2.4.1. The yield is not the return

• one could easily think that the yield for a bond is the promised return for the bond,
since the bond is a ”fixed income” security
• the yield = return only for zeros that are held until maturity, in all other cases this will
not hold
• the yield is a discount rate, not a return!
• we will analyze a special case when the yield at the time of purchase actually will equal
the return:

Example: Earlier, we priced the 3-year, 5% coupon bond at PV = 1012.83, and


U U

calculated the yield, y = 4.5329%. Suppose we intend to keep the bond until maturity,
and want to calculate the return over this investment horizon (3 years). We have a
problem of reinvesting the 5% annual coupons, but we assume this can be done at a
reinvestment rate that equals the yield. Then the future cash flows are:

1st Coupon:
P P 50*(1 + 0.045329)^2 =56.6357
2nd Coupon:
P P 50*(1 + 0.045329) = 52.2665
22

3rd Coupon + Face value =


U UP UP 1050.00
Total future value = 1156.90

The price of the bond was PV = 1012.83, so the horizon return is:

1/ 3
⎡1156.90 ⎤
r=⎢ − 1 = 0.045329 = 4.5329%
⎣1012.83 ⎥⎦

which equals the yield at the time of purchase. Anybody would, however, agree that this
scenario is unrealistic:

1. The bond is seldom held until maturity. The interest rate level at the time of
selling the bond is uncertain, and hence the price is uncertain ⇒ price risk
2. The coupons can usually not be reinvested at a rate that equals the yield. This
would require a flat term-structure. The reality is uncertainty about the future
value of the reinvested coupons ⇒ reinvestment risk

• the previous exercise is called horizon analysis


• this is a useful approach in bond investing, since unlike stocks, the life of the bond is
finite, and hence ”invest-and-forget” (buy-and-hold) strategies are not applicable
• the investor might be interested in possible outcomes for the future value of the
investment at a certain pont in time (before or at maturity)
• for example, insurance companies have known liabilities which require funds to be
invested such that the liability can be met at that point in time
• the total, or horizon return from a bond consists of:

1. Coupon interest payments


2. Income from reinvesting the coupons
3. Capital gain or loss if the bond is sold before maturity

• it’s clear that today’s yield cannot capture all these sources of return
• of course, let’s not forget that for example treasury bonds usually have higher yields
than treasury bills, and also tend to outperform treasury bills in terms of return
• the point is that the yield is merely and indication of return, not a promise

2.4.2. Yields are not additive

• what this means is that yields for bond portfolios can not be calculated like returns
for stock portfolios

Example: Let’s construct a simple bond portfolio that contains one 1-year zero coupon
U U

bond, and one 5-year coupon bond that pays 5% annual coupons. We use the term
structure from previous examples to price the bonds, and assume that both bonds have
a face value of 1000:

Bond Coupon Price Weight Yield


1 year zero 0.00% 961.54 0.4887 4.0000%
23

5 year bullet 5.00% 1005.95 0.5113 4.8631%


Portfolio 1967.49 1.0000

First, let’s try to calculate the portfolio yield by treating yields as returns:

N
rP = ∑ wi ri = 0.4887 * 0.04 + 0.5113 * 0.048631 = 0.044413
i =1

or 4.4413% (which is wrong)

The only correct way to calculate the yield on a bond portfolio is, however by solving for
the yield for the portfolio, given the portfolio price and cash flows:

1000 50 50 1050
+ + +…+ = 1967.49
(1 + y ) (1 + y ) (1 + y ) 2
(1 + y ) 5

where, in this example, the first cash flow comes from the first bond, and all other cash
flows from the second bond. We solve the yield (y), and find that:

y = 0.0471349 = 4.7135%

Note the difference (over 27 basis points!) between the true yield y = 4.7135%, and y =
4.4413% calculated earlier.

• of course, nothing prevents the bond portfolio manager from expressing the yield of
his portfolio as a weighted average, but in that case care should be taken to make
clear how this figure has been obtained
• to a very close approximation, the portfolio yield can be calculated using weights, if
the equation is adjusted for modified duration

2.5. From coupon bonds to zeros: bootstrapping

• suppose you need zeros for pricing, but no zeros with the same credit risk exist
• zero-coupon or spot rates reflecting a specific level of default risk can be found by:

1. Observing yields in the zero-coupon market (strips)


2. Bootstrapping a yield curve using coupon paying bonds or the swap curve
(these two spot rate curves of course have different credit risks)

• using observable zero-coupon rates for pricing coupon bonds may be problematic:

1. Liquidity. Lower liquidity in the zero market might lead to higher yields.
2. Taxes. Zeros and coupon bonds might be taxed differently along the whole
maturity spectrum, which translates to differences in required yields.
24

3. The preferred habitat hypothesis. There might be maturity sectors where


taxation between zeros and coupon bonds differ, if principal strips are taxed
differently than coupon strips.

• an important application of bootstrapping is to derive theoretical zero-coupon rates


from swap rates, which represent par-yields in the interbank market
• these bootstrapped zero-rates can then be used as a benchmark for pricing non-
standard cash flow structures in the corporate market
• the need for zero rates is more obvious the more ”non-standard” the bond or
valuation need is

Example: Suppose that a market participant needs zero-coupon rates up to 3-years


U U

maturity, but no zero market exist. Instead, he observes the prices for the following
bonds:

Bond Maturity Coupon rate Face value Price


1 year zero 1 year 0.00% 1000.00 961.54
2 year bullet 2 years 4.50% 1000.00 1003.88
3 year bullet 3 years 5.00% 1000.00 1012.83

The 1 year zero rate is easy:

1000
− 1 = 0.04
961.54

Turning to the 2 year zero rate we use the 2 year coupon bond and we now know that:

45 1045
+ = 1003.88
(1 + 0.04) (1 + r2 ) 2

Clearly, there is only one solution for the 2 year zero rate (r2) that satisfies the equation.
B B

After some calculation we find that

r2 B B = 0.043 = 4.30%

does the trick. We continue in the same fashion with the 3 year coupon bond:

50 50 1050
+ + = 1012.83
(1 + 0.04) (1 + 0.043) 2
(1 + r3 ) 3

and find that

r3
B B = 0.0455 = 4.55%

(which does not surprise the careful reader, who might have suspected that the coupon
bonds in the example were priced using the same term structure as before.)

• the same technique applies to swap-rates, assuming payments are annual:


25

Maturity Maturity Swap rate


1 year 1 year 4.50%
2 year 2 years 4.70%
3 year 3 years 4.80%

• since swaps are priced at ”par” (the swap rate is a par-yield), and a ”price” of 100 can
be assumed:

104.50
− 1 = 0.045
100

and

4.70 104.70
+ = 100
(1 + 0.045) (1 + r2 ) 2

and r2 = 4.7047%, and so on for the rest of the swap-curve.


B B

2.6. Spot and forward rates with semi-annual compounding

• bonds and swaps may pay semi-annual or even quarterly or monthly coupons, and
hence there is a need to handle spot rates and forwards for higher compounding
frequencies than 1 years
• in general, the present value formula can be expressed:

CF
PV = mt
⎡ rt ⎤
⎢1 + m ⎥
⎣ ⎦

where

rt
B B = the zero coupon rate for maturity t
m = the compounding frequency
t = the maturity of the cash flow in years

• we will exemplify this using the following semi-annual zero-coupon rates:

Maturity Spot rate


Years % (p.a.)
0.5 7.45
1.0 7.68
1.5 7.69
2.0 7.75

• to convert these rates to discount factors:


26

1
Df t =
rt t *2
(1 + )
2

For example for the 1 year, semiannual rate of 7.68%:

1 1
Df t = = = 0.9274
rt t *2 0.0768 1*2
(1 + ) (1 + )
2 2

• the forward rates are now 6-month forwards


• e.g. the forward from year 1 to year 1.5 (from period 2 to period 3 in half-years):

⎡ r3 3 ⎤
⎢ (1 + 2 ) ⎥
f 23 = 2*⎢ − 1⎥ = 0.0771
⎢ (1 + r2 ) 2 ⎥
⎢⎣ 2 ⎥⎦

• note the multiplication by 2 to get the 6-month forward to an annual rate


• we can produce a similar table like in the case for the 1-year periods:

Maturity Spot rate Actual Discount Forward


return factor 6-month
Years % (p.a.) %
0.5 7.45 3.7250 0.9641 7.4500
1.0 7.68 7.8275 0.9274 7.9103
1.5 7.69 11.9842 0.8930 7.7100
2.0 7.75 16.4244 0.8589 7.9301
27

3. Day counts and accrued interest

• so far, we have worked in a fairly unrealistic setting: we have analyzed bonds and
rates with maturity of integers of one year
• the reason for abstracting from details is to make the concepts and technique clear
• we will now take a small step from the classroom towards the cruel world of day
count conventions and accrued interest
• reading stock market quotes is quite clear: you can observe the price at which you
buy and the price at which you sell
• in fixed income markets, things become a mess: prices are frequently quoted as
yields, or in percent of face value less accrued interest, which means that just by
looking at bond quotes you can never tell what the price is
• further, a yield quote is not unambiguous across the world: 5% in the US treasury
markets does not mean the same thing as 5% in the Finnish or German treasury
markets: there are differences in day count conventions and compounding frequency
• as an example, compare the following zero-coupon bonds:

Security Maturity Coupon Quote Price


(Years) (yield to maturity) (% of face value)
German Bund 15.35 0% 5.96% 41.12
US Treasury 15.35 0% 5.96% 40.60

What’s wrong? Shouldn’t the price also be equal? No, since all Bund quotes are based on
annual compounding, while US Treasury bond quotes are based on semi-annual
compounding they will have different prices if the yields are the same.

• the lesson is that one should always be aware of what market conventions apply to
the interest rate you are analyzing
• the next section is by no means intended to give a comprehensive treatment of the
subject, but merely to introduce the reader to some concepts, and to make the reader
aware of the pitfalls that exist

3.1. Day count basis

• the bond market is like no other place: 31 days can be 30 days, and a year can be
more or less than 365 days
• recall that all interest rates are expressed on an annual basis
• day count conventions deal with how to compute fractions of a year
• to give an example of what day count basis means:

Example: Suppose you are investing in a 1-month short-term deposit. The financial
U U

institution promises an interest of 4.00%. This is of course a per annum figure. Since the
interest rate is an annual rate, we must know how large a fraction is this particular month
of 1 year. Suppose we count the days, we find that there are 31 days in that month. We
also know that there are 365 days in a year, so the maturity of the investment in years is:
28

31
t= = 0.084931
365

thus, if we invest 100 units of currency:

⎡ 31 ⎤
FV = 100 * ⎢1 + 0.04 * = 100.3397
⎣ 365 ⎥⎦

This day count basis is called ”Actual/Actual”, because all days are counted, in our case
”31/365”. This need not be the case, since there exist many ways of counting days. The
most common day count conventions include:

Actual/Actual The denominator is the number of days in the coupon period times the
coupon frequency.

Actual/365 Like Actual/Actual but always uses 365.

Actual/360 Like Actual/365, but always uses 360 (assumes there are only 360 days in
a year). (Euro money market)

30/360 Assumes that there are 30 days in each month and 360 days in a year. In
our previous example, we would have measured the time period as only
30 days instead of 31, and divided with 360 (30/360 = 0.083333). There
are som further variations for this rule.

3.2. The money market

• prices for money market instruments are usually expressed as yields


• on the Euro market, the day count is Actual/360
• the price (PCD) of a money market security:
B B

CF
PCD =
⎡ t ⎤
1 + ⎢r * ⎥
⎣ 360 ⎦

where

CF = cash flow at maturity


r = interest rate for period t
t = time to maturity in days

Example: The maturity of a money market security is 30 days, face value EUR 1 000
U U

000, and the quotes are:

Maturity Bid Ask


30 days
Quote (%) 3.01% 2.96%
29

What’s the price? Note that bid and ask are from the dealer’s point of view: the dealer
buys at 3.01%, and sells at 2.96%. Using the bid to find out what the dealer is willing to
pay for the security:

1000000 1000000
PCD = = = 997497.94
⎡ 30 ⎤ 1002508
.
1 + ⎢0.0301 *
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦

The ask (2.96%) again corresponds to a price of EUR 997 539.40. That is:

Maturity Bid Ask


30 days
Quote (%) 3.01% 2.96%
Price (EUR) EUR 997 497.94 EUR 997 539.40

3.3. Zero-coupon bonds: annual compounding

• bond prices are expressed as yields or prices as percent of the face value
• to calculate the price in currency, one has to know the face value, day count basis, and
compounding frequency

Example: On the Bund STRIPS-market a zero that matures 4.7.2015 is quoted on


U U

1.3.2000:

Maturity Bid Ask


4.7.2015
Quote (yield) 5.96% 5.91%
Price (% of face value) 41.12 41.41

The maturity of the zero is 15.35 years using Actual/Actual day count basis. Further we
need to know that on the Bund market, annual compounding is used. If the face value of
the zero is EUR 100 000, the bid price in euros is:

EUR100000
PV = = EUR 41121.70
(1 + 0.0596)15.35

and the price quote is (K):

41121.70
K= = 0.4112 = 41.12%
100000
30

3.4. Zero-coupon bonds: semi-annual compounding

• suppose that the same market quotes (yield and price quote) are observed on the US
Treasury STRIPS markets
• is the price in currency the same?
• no, since US Treasury yields are semi-annual (assuming day count basis is the same):

USD100000
PV = 15.35*2
= USD 40596.29
⎡ 0.0596 ⎤
⎢1 + 2 ⎥
⎣ ⎦

and the price quote K = 40.60%

• if there should have been differences in the day count basis between the markets, this
difference would have shown up in the calculation of maturity, and the fraction of a
year (0.35) might have been different

3.5. Coupon bonds

• bonds are usually quoted in per cent of their face value, e.g. 110.827% or just 110.827
• the yield to maturity (YTM) of a bond is another way to express the price
• recall that the present value of a bond is simply:

n
CFt
PV BOND = ∑
t =1 (1 + rt )
t

where

CFt B B = cash flow (coupon and/or face value repayment) at time t


rt
B B = spot rate for maturity t
t = time in years

Once the yield to maturity is known, one can of course to cut some corners use the yield:

n
CFt
PV BOND = ∑
t =1 (1 + y )
t

• in most of the forthcoming examples, we will use the yield to demonstrate the
calculations
• let’s start our example of dirty and clean prices by pricing a bond:
31

Example: Suppose todays date is 17.1.1997, and a government bond that matures
U U

15.3.2004 and pays a CPN of 9.50%. Assume a yield of 5.55% and, a face value of EUR
1 000 000. What is the PV of the bond on 17.1.1997? There are 57 days between 17.1
and 15.3 which is 0.1562 years under the Actual/Actual basis so:

95000 95000 1095000


PV = + +…+ = 1307995.13
(1 + 0.0555) 0.1562
(1 + 0.0555) 1.1562
(1 + 0.0555) 7.1562

• note that:

1. the value of the first coupon can, depending on the market conventions, be
calculated using simple or, as in this example, compound interest
2. there may not be exactly 1 year between the coupon payment dates if payments
occur on weekends or holidays, this has not been taken into account here

• the effect on value of 1. and 2. is of course minimal, but it will be there


• the bond will, however, nor be quoted as ”1 307 995.13” on the market...

3.5.1. Dirty prices and clean prices

• the present value is called the ”dirty price”, ”full price”, or ”invoice price”
• what are ”clean prices”?
• the price that dealers quote is the clean price, not the PV (dirty price):

Clean price = Dirty price – Accrued coupon interest since last coupon payment

The accrued interest (AI) is:

v
AI = * rCPN * N
365

where

v = number of days since last coupon payment


rCPNB B = coupon rate
N = face value of the bond
365 = day count basis for the bond, here assumed to be 365

The clean price (K) of a bond is:

PV BOND − AI
K=
N
32

Example: Using the bond from the previous example we know that:
U U

Purchase date: 17.1.1997


Next coupon payment date: 15.3.1997
Days to next coupon date: 57
Days of accrued interest (v): 308
PV (dirty price): 1 307 995.13 EUR
Face value: 1 000 000.00 EUR

(Note again that here, we abstract from taking into account delivery days applied on the
market (usually T +1...+3), that is, the bond and the money does not move today, and
you actually trade 1-3 day forwards).

The days of accrued interest v = 365 – 57 = 308 using actual/actual day count basis. We
can now compute:

308
AI = * 0.095 * 1000000 EUR = 80164.38 EUR
365

and hence

1307995.13 − 80164.38
K= = 1.22783 = 122.783%
1000000

Remember that the even if the quote is 122.783%, you still pay the dirty price 1 307
995.13 for the bond (that’s why the dirty price is also called the invoice price).

3.5.2. Behavior of dirty and clean prices over time: convergence


towards par

• the present value (dirty price) will vary according to the number of days to the next
coupon payment: immediately after a coupon payment, the PV will fall, and then rise
again as the next coupon approaches in time
• the clean price, on the other hand behaves more smoothly

Example: Consider the same bond that matures 15.3.2004 and pays a CPN of 9.50%.
U U

Assume a (constant) yield of 5.55% and, for ease of exposition, a face value of only EUR
100. Starting from the CPN date 15.3.1996, we calculate the PV for each month. Note
how the PV falls on the CPN date 15.3.1997, just to start rising again. (This example still
uses the 30/360 day count basis).
33

Date Days to next CPN PV (Dirty Price) Price (Clean Price)


15.3.1996 360 124.972 124.972
15.4.1996 330 125.535 124.744
15.5.1996 300 126.102 124.518
15.6.1996 270 126.671 124.296
15.7.1996 240 127.242 124.075
15.8.1996 210 127.816 123.858
15.9.1996 180 128.393 123.643
15.10.1996 150 128.972 123.430
15.11.1996 120 129.554 123.220
15.12.1996 90 130.138 123.013
15.1.1997 60 130.725 122.805
15.2.1997 30 131.315 122.607
15.3.1997 360 122.407 122.407
15.4.1997 330 122.960 122.168
15.5.1997 300 123.514 121.931
15.6.1997 270 124.072 121.697

• the clean price (K) of the bond approaches 100 (par) when maturity decreases
• the dirty price (PV) of the bond approaches 100 + last coupon when maturity
decreases

Example: Consider a bond that matures 18.4.2006. Assume the yield remains at 6.00%.
U U

Date Years Clean price Dirty price


17.1.1997 9.2528 108.642 114.060
17.1.1998 8.2528 107.913 113.331
17.1.1999 7.2528 107.140 112.358
17.1.2000 6.2528 106.321 111.739
17.1.2001 5.2528 105.453 110.870
17.1.2002 4.2528 104.533 109.950
17.1.2003 3.2528 103.557 108.974
17.1.2004 2.2528 102.523 107.940
17.1.2005 1.2528 101.427 106.844
17.1.2006 0.2528 100.265 105.682

• a discount bond would have started below par and approached par from below
34

4. Measuring interest rate risk: duration and convexity

Since cash flows for bonds are usually fixed, a price change can come from two sources:

1. The passage of time (convergence towards par). This is of course totally


predictable, and hence not a risk.
2. A change in the yield. This can be due to a change in the benchmark yield,
and/or change in the yield spread.

The yield-price relationship is inverse, and we would like to have a measure of how
sensitive the bond price is to yield changes. A good approximation for bond price
changes due to yield is the duration, a measure for interest rate risk. For large yield
changes convexity can be added to improve the performance of the duration. A more
important use of convexity is that it measures the sensitivity of duration to yield
changes. Similar risk measures are used in the options markets are the delta and gamma.

4.1. The yield-price relationship for bonds

• we again discuss interest rate changes in terms of yield changes: this is more
convenient as the yield is the mostly used interest rate measure for coupon bonds
• when yields increase, bond prices decrese
• when yields decrease, bond prices increase
• for small yield changes, the percentage price change is roughly the same whether the
required yield increases or decreases
• for large yield changes, the percentage price increase is larger than a price decrease

Example: On 17.1.1997, the (dirty) price of the RoF2006 Government bond is 114.060,
U U

and the yield is 6.00%. Consider the impact of an one percent yield increase/decrease:

Yield Yield change Dirty Price Price change


(%) (% units) EUR (%)
5.00 -1.00 121.732 +6.73
6.00 0.00 114.060 0.00
7.00 +1.00 107.033 -6.16
35

Price and Yield for RoF2001 and RoF2006 Government bonds

180.00

160.00

140.00
Dirty Price

RoF2001
120.00
RoF2006

100.00

80.00

60.00
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

Yield

4.2. Duration

• different ways to calculate duration:

1. Macaulay duration (DMAC): B B

i) The present value of time-weighted cashflows, divided by the


present value of the bond. Uses yield to calculate present values.
ii) The discounted, average payback time.
iii) Balancing point in time between interest rate and price risk.

2. Fisher-Weil duration (DFW): B B

i) The same as DMAC, but uses zero rates.


B B

3. Modified duration (DMOD): B B

i) Macaulay duration/(1 + y)
ii) The % price increase (decrease) in the bond price if the yield
decreases (increases) by a unit of 1%.

4. Key rate duration (DKR): B B

i) Calculates the price response separately for a 1% change in each


zero-coupon rate used to calculate the PV of the bond. Gives a
better picture of which parts of the term-structure is responsible
for how much of total interest rate risk. The key rate durations
can then be summed up to give an overall interest rate risk
measure, comparable with modified duration.
36

4.2.1. Macaulay duration

• Macaulay duration (DMAC) using the yield:


B B

CFt * t i
1 ⎡ CF1 * t1 CF2 * t 2 CFn * t n ⎤ (1 + y ) ti
n
Duration( D MAC ) = *⎢ t1 + +...+ =∑
PV BOND ⎣ (1 + y ) (1 + y ) t 2 (1 + y ) tn ⎥⎦ t = t 1 PV BOND

Example: Calculate the Macaulay duration for the bond:


U U

Maturity: 2.0 years


Face value: EUR 1 000 000.00
PV: EUR 1 141 635.55
Coupon rate: 11.0% annual
Yield: 3.54%

1 ⎡ 110000 *1.00 1110000 * 2.00 ⎤


Duration( DMAC ) = *⎢ + ⎥=
1141635.55 ⎢⎣ (1 + 0.0354)1.00 (1 + 0.0354) 2.00 ⎥⎦

* [106239.13 + 2070792.83] = 1.9069


1
1141635.55

• since the yield is used to discount, the Macaulay duration assumes that the term
structure is flat and that yield shifts are parallell
• the duration of a zero coupon bond equals its maturity
• for example, N = 100, y = 3.54%, PV = 93.28

⎡ 100 * 2.00 ⎤
* [186.56] = 2.00
1 1
Duration ( D MAC ) = *⎢ ⎥=
93.28 ⎢⎣ (1 + 0.0354) 2 .00
⎥⎦ 92.28

• holding everything else equal:

1. increasing coupon rates decreases duration


2. increasing yield decreases duration
3. increasing maturity increases duration (in most cases)

• Macaulay duration for different maturities (T), yields, and coupon rates (annual):

Yield 5% Yield 10% Yield 20%


Coupon 0% 5% 10% 0% 5% 10% 0% 5% 10%
T
5 5.00 4.55 4.25 5.00 4.49 4.17 5.00 4.36 3.99
10 10.00 8.11 7.27 10.00 7.66 6.76 10.00 6.65 5.72
20 20.00 13.09 11.48 20.00 10.74 9.36 20.00 6.87 6.20
50 50.00 19.17 17.76 50.00 11.24 10.91 50.00 6.01 6.00
100 100.00 20.84 20.54 100.00 11.01 11.00 100.00 6.00 6.00
37

• some refinements to the 3 rules of thumb:

1. The duration of a zero-coupon bond equals it’s maturity.


For coupon bonds, duration approaches D = 1 + 1/y when maturity increases.
2. Duration for coupon bonds with coupon rate higher or equal to the yield will rise
with maturity and reach a maximum of D = 1 + 1/y.
3. Duration for bonds with coupon rate lower than the yield will first rise with maturity
and reach it’s maximum and then decline with maturity to D = 1 + 1/y.

4.3. Modified duration and PVBP

• the approximate percent price change for a 1.00% yield change (100 bps) is given by
the modified duration:

D MAC
Duration( D MOD ) =
(1 + y )

The percent price change (dP/P) for any yield change dy:

dP
= − D MOD * dy
P

and hence we have the EUR price change (dPV) for any yield change dy:

dPV = − DMOD * PV * dy

• note the ”-” sign before the expressions, indicating the inverse relationship between
yield change and price change

A commonly used measure is the Price Value of a Basis Point (PVBP):

D MOD
PVBP = * PV
10000

and says how much the value of the bond changes in EUR when the yield changes with 1
bps (0.01%).

Example: Calculate the modified duration and the PVBP for the same bond:
U U

DMOD = 1.9069/(1 + 0.0354) = 1.8417


B B
38

DMOD 1.8417
PVBP = * PV = * 1141635.55FIM = 210.26 EUR
10000 10000

Example: If the yield increases by 1.00% to 4.54%, how much will the price decrease?
U U

dP/P = -1.8417*0.01 = -0.018417 = -1.8417%

dP = -1.8417*1 141 635.55*0.01= -21 026.00 EUR

The new price should then be: 1 141 635.55 – 21 026.00 = 1 120 609.55 EUR

But recalculating the price using the yield 4.54, we find that the true price should be EUR
1 120 905.42, and the error is EUR 295.87

• the error occurs because duration assumes a linear price-yield relationship when it in
fact is convex

4.3.1. The duration of a bond through time

• between coupon payments duration decreases one-by-one with time if yields stay
unchanged
• at a coupon payment duration jumps up and increases ⇒ in the long run duration
decreases more slowly than time
• does this matter in the practical sense?
• duration increases after a coupon ⇒ the bond becomes more sensitive to yield
changes after a coupon payment
• but this is only in % terms, the absolute (EUR) value change is unaffected

Example: The RoF2006 bond pays a 7.25% coupon 18.4.1997. Consider what happens
U U

to duration and volatility due to a 0.10% yield increase immediately before and after the
coupon payment:

Duration % change due to EUR change due


Date duration to duration
17.4.1997 6.5703 -0.6138 -7 173.59
18.4.1997 7.0063 -0.6610 -7 171.72

The % change in value of the bond changes, but the change in EUR value changes only
because of the slight duration change from 17.4.1997 to 18.4.1997.

• does the duration jump mean that we are suddenly exposed to immunization risk?
• the duration of the investor’s portfolio now consists of the bond and 72 500 EUR in
cash (cash has zero duration)
• but the investor still has to decide:

1. how to reinvest the cash


2. how much of the original bond (portfolio) to hold
39

• implications for an investment with a duration target:

1. should not invest cash in the same bond (duration will exceed target)
2. if the cash is invested in a security with any significant duration, a part of the
bond (portfolio) must be sold and invest proceeds in shorter duration assets

4.3.2. Key rate duration

• duration can only measure parallell yield changes, and does not tell us where on the
yield curve the largest risks are located
• for a single bullet bond, the largest risk of course comes from the last payment of
face value + last coupon, since it is:

1. the largest payment


2. located furthest out in time and hence through compounding most affected by a
yield change

• for a bond portfolio or a more complex product than a bullet one can perform a
more detailed analysis of interest rate risk along the whole yield curve using key rates
• we use the following bond as an example:

N = 100
Maturity = 5 years
Coupon rate = 5% (annual)

We compute the PV, Fisher-Weil duration, and Key rate durations assuming the term
structure below:

rt
B B Df CF PV Fisher-Weil Key rate
(CF*t)*Df duration
1 4.00% 0.961583 5.00 4.8077 4.8077 0.0460
2 4.30% 0.919245 5.00 4.5962 9.1925 0.0876
3 4.55% 0.875040 5.00 4.3752 13.1256 0.1248
4 4.75% 0.830585 5.00 4.1529 16.6117 0.1577
5 4.90% 0.787268 105.00 82.6631 413.3157 3.9193
100.5952 4.5435 4.3354

For example, the 5 year key rate duration for a +/- 1% zero rate change is calculated:

PV+ − PV−
DA =
2 * PV0 * drt

where

PV+ B B = the price of the bond if the zero-coupon rate for maturity t decreases with 1%
PV- B B = the price of the bond if the zero-coupon rate for maturity t increases with 1%

and we have
40

PV0 B B = 100.5952 (r5


B B = 4.90%)
PV- B B = 96.7653 (r5
B B = 5.90%)
PV+ B B = 104.6505 (r5
B B = 3.90%)

PV+ − PV− 104.6505 − 96.7653


DA = = = 3.9193
2 * PV0 * dr5 2 * 100.5952 * 0.01

by “common sense”, calculate the average absolute price change for a +/- 1% in rates:

dPV, if r5 = 5.90% B B (96.7653 – 100.5952)/100.5952 = -3.81%


dPV, if r5 = 3.90% B B (104.6505 – 100.5952)/100.5952 = +4.03%

on average (3.81%+4.03)/2 = 3.9193%

which is the price responsiveness if the 5-year zero rate changes 1% and all other rates
remain unchanged.

4.4. Convexity

• for yield increases, duration overestimates the price decrease


• for yield decrases, duration underestimates the price increases

The convexity for a bond is:

⎡ n t (1 + t ) * CFt ⎤ ⎡ 1 ⎤
Convexity = ⎢∑ t +2 ⎥ * ⎢ PV ⎥
⎣ t =1 (1 + y ) ⎦ ⎣ BOND ⎦

• the first term in brackets is sometimes called “dollar-convexity”


• in isolation, this measure means nothing, and does not have a straightforward
interpretation like duration or modified duration
• convexity has two uses:

1. Convexity measures and can be used to correct the price response-error


caused by duration. But: convexity is still an approximation for this correction,
since the shape of the price-yield cannot be fully described with the two measures
modified duration and convexity.
2. Convexity measures the change in duration due to yield changes.

The percent price change due to convexity is:


41

dP 1
= * ( Convexity ) * ( dy ) 2
P 2

The EUR price change due to convexity is:

1
dP = * ( Dollar − convexity ) * ( dy ) 2
2

Example: Calculate the convexity of the bond used in previous examples. The coupon is
U U

11%, and the yield is 3.54%.

⎡1.00 * (1 + 1.00) * 110000 2.00 * (1 + 2.00) * 1110000 ⎤ ⎡ 1 ⎤


Convexity = ⎢ + ⎥*⎢ ⎥
⎣ (1 + 0.0354) 3.00
(1 + 0.0354) 4.00
⎦ ⎣1141635.55 ⎦
= 5.2495

Example: If the yield increases by 1.00% to 4.54%, how much of the price decrease is
U U

due to convexity?

dP/P = 0.5*5.2495*(0.01)^2 = 0.00026248= 0.026248%

dP = 0.5*5 993 039*(0.01)^2 = 299.65 EUR

We can now get a better estimate of the price decrease:

Duration + Convexity = Estimate of total price change

-21 026.00 + 299.65 = -20 726.35

which is only EUR 3.78 less the actual decrease of -20 730.13

• note that convexity is always a positive number, correcting the price upward
• sometimes convexity is expressed as:

Convexity/200 = 5.2495/200 = 0.0262%

which is the % correction directly, and as such has a meaningful interpretation


42

• some examples of convexities:

Yield 5% Yield 10% Yield 20%


Coupon 0% 5% 10% 0% 5% 10% 0% 5% 10%
T
5 27.21 23.94 21.83 24.79 21.45 19.37 20.83 17.35 15.36
10 99.77 75.00 64.02 91.91 63.40 52.79 76.39 44.11 35.13
20 380.95 211.33 171.95 347.11 146.10 116.22 291.67 62.30 50.64
50 2312.9 564.13 484.41 2107.4 206.74 190.55 1770.8 50.52 50.14
100 9161.0 764.95 732.90 8347.1 200.44 199.85 7013.8 50.00 50.00

• one could argue that convexity has value since the price of a highly convex bond

1. increases more when yields fall


2. decreases less when yields rise

• one might argue that investors should be willing to pay more for a convex bond,
particularly when yields are volatile

4.4.1. Duration matching and the value of convexity

• if interest rates fall, two opposite effects:

1. your bond portfolio will increase in value


2. the coupons will be reinvested at a lower rate

• if interest rates rise, two opposite effects:

1. your bond portfolio will decrease in value


2. the coupons will be reinvested at a higher rate

• at an investment horizon equal to the bond’s duration these two effects will
(approximately) offset
• duration is the balance point between market risk and reinvestment risk
• if the investors horizon is h:

1. if h = D ⇒ dW/dy = 0 ⇒ no risk
2. if h < D ⇒ dW/dy < 0 ⇒ market risk
3. if h > D ⇒ dW/dy > 0 ⇒ reinvestment risk

• note that all formulas assume a single yield y ⇒ a flat yield curve is assumed
• convexity is beneficial for an investor who buys a bond with duration equal to his
horizon, and the yield curve shifts once to some arbitrary level
− in case of a sudden, large yield change the investor is more protected than
with a bond with lesser convexity
− in the case of a duration matched to the horizon, and a convex bond, a
yield increase will yield a higher end-of-period wealth, since the value of the
reinvested coupons exceed the loss of the lower redemption value
43

− a yield decrease will yield a higher end-of-period wealth, since the higher
redemption value will more than compensate for the lower reinvested coupon
values

Example: An investor buys a bond with Macaulay duration of 3.3841, and assume for
U U

simplicity that the investor’s horizon equals this duration. Thus, the investor is
immunized, and he is going to sell the bond 0.4714 years before maturity, since the
maturity is 3.8556 years. Suppose the yield is initially 5.15%, and now consider the effect
of a sudden, immediate yield change to 4.15%, and 6.15%, respectively:

Yield 4.15% 5.15% 6.15%


FV of coupons 319 413.72 324 207.23 329 046.01
Redemption value of bond 1 079 113.49 1 074 262.91 1 069 479.73
Total FV 1 398 527.21 1 398 470.14 1 398 526.74
Yearly return 5.1513 5.1500 5.1512

• note that a flat term structure is assumed (all coupons reinvested at the yield)
• the change in the reinvestment values of the coupons just about offset the change in
the redemption value of the bond
• the more convex the bond, the larger would the return changes have been
• convexity is nearly irrelevant if yields change smoothly and continuously rather
than in large, sudden jumps
− if yields change smoothly in small increments, the investor has the opportunity
to adjust for duration changes continuously
− thus, no large yield changes like in the previous example will occur
• convexity is harmful if there is uncertainty about how the yield curve will change
− the effect of changes in the shape of the yield curve on the duration of a
bond will be greater, the greater the convexity
− this is beacuse convexity implies larger dispersion of cash flows
− thus, convexity implies that there is more uncertainty about how the
duration of the bond will behave when the yield curve changes

• immunize risk to meet future obligations, for e.g. pension funds


• protect invested money from interest rate shifts
• what if zero-coupon bonds with same maturity do not exist?
• “base-case” solution: invest in a bond or bond portfolio with equal (Macaulay)
duration and present value as the future obligation or stream of obligations
• e.g. a payment in 5 years could be matched by a bond portfolio with DMAC = 5.0
B B

• protects only against parallell yield curve shifts


• problems with immunization:

1. duration drift over time not equal to time (duration decreases more slowly than time)
2. yield changes will change duration
3. Macaulay-duration based: immunizised only if yield curve is flat and changes are
parallell

• rebalancing needed: transaction costs versus immunization target


44

Contingent immunization

• less-than-perfect immunization for a higher return


• set a band within the duration is allowed to fluctuate
• within these bands, active portfolio management to enhance return
• if duration hits the bounds, back to “strict” immunization policy

Multiperiod immunization

• a stream of obligations
• immunize every payment separately

Dedicated portfolio

• cash flow matching


• no duration requirements
• no rebalancing

4.5. Bond portfolio duration and convexity

• calculating duration, modified duration and convexity for a bond portfolio is easy if
one assumes that all bonds in the portfolio has the same yield:

N
D P = ∑ wi Di
i =1

where

DP B B = duration or modified duration of the portfolio


wi B B = weight of bond i in the portfolio
Di B B = duration or modified duration for bond i

• portfolio convexity is calculated in the same way

Example: Assume the following bond portfolio:


U U

Bond Coupon Price Weight Yield DMAC


B B DMOD
B B

1 y. zero 0.00% 961.54 0.4887 4.0000% 1.0000 0.9615


5 y. bullet 5.00% 1005.95 0.5113 4.8631% 4.5475 4.3366
Portfolio 1967.49 1.0000

then:

N
DMAC = ∑ wi Di = 0.4887 * 1.0000 + 0.5113 * 4.5475 = 2.8138
i =1
45

and

N
DMOD = ∑ wi Di = 0.4887 * 0.9615 + 0.5113 * 4.3366 = 2.6872
i =1

4.6. Butterfly trades: A critical assessment of yield, convexity


and duration

Butterfly trades are return-enhancement devices that consist of selling an intermediate


maturity issue, and a simultaneous purchase of one shorter and one longer maturity issue.
A butterfly is deemed beneficial if the average yield of the purchased bonds exceed the
yield of the sold bond, while holding duration constant.

4.6.1. Weighting a butterfly

• assume three bonds indexed as i = 1,2, and 3, and that we try to obtain a higher return
by selling bond 2 and buying bonds 1 + 3
• to satisfy the cost constraint the butterfly requires that

Q2 * P2 = Q1 * P1 + Q3 * P3

where

Q = face value of bond (in millions of units of currency)


P = PV of the bond in % of face value

• the risk constraint on a butterfly requires that

Q2 * PVBP2 = Q1 * PVBP1 + Q1 * PVBP1

where

PVBP = price value of a basis point (in EUR per 1 000 000 face value)

• the equations can be reduced to solve for the values of Q1 and Q2


B B B B

⎡ P2 * PVBP3 − P3 * PVBP2 ⎤
Q1 = ⎢ ⎥ * Q2
⎣ P1 * PVBP3 − P3 * PVBP1 ⎦

and

⎡ P1 * PVBP2 − P2 * PVBP1 ⎤
Q3 = ⎢ ⎥ * Q2
⎣ P1 * PVBP3 − P3 * PVBP1 ⎦
46

Example: (This example is based on actual market conditions on the Finnish Treasury
U U

market in November 1997). Consider the following bonds:

Bond 1 Bond 2 Bond 3


Coupon 10.00% 9.50% 7.25%
P (%) 117.991 126.329 113.360
Yield 5.15% 5.62% 5.81%
PVBP (EUR) 379.74 590.50 692.89
Modified duration 3.2184 4.6743 6.1123
Macaulay duration 3.3841 4.9370 6.4674
Convexity 14.2244 30.1321 50.0322

Note that we express P in percent. The PVBP is however expressed based on EUR 1 000
000 face value. This scaling is a matter of convenience and does not affect the
calculations.

⎡ 126.329 * 692.89 − 113.360 * 590.50 ⎤


Q3 = ⎢ ⎥ * 1000000 = 532017 EUR
⎣ 117.991* 692.89 − 113.360 * 379.74 ⎦

and

⎡ 117.991* 590.50 − 126.329 * 379.74 ⎤


Q3 = ⎢ ⎥ *1000000 = 560655EUR
⎣ 117.991 * 692.89 − 113.360 * 379.74 ⎦

Thus you should buy Bond 1 to a face value of 532 017 EUR and Bond 3 to a face value
of 560 655 EUR

The values satisfy the cost constraint since

(53.2017*1.17991 + 56.0655*1.13360) = 62.7732 + 63.5558 = 126.329

which equals the price of the bond to be sold (Bond 2). This also shows that it is
straightforward to weight the butterfly as PV in EUR, since the face value Q can be
multiplied with the % price P. The values satisfy the risk constraint since

(0.5320*379.74 + 0.5606*692.89) = 202.0281 + 388.4719 = 590.50

which is equal to the PVBP of Bond 2, and equivalent to using modified durations and
PV:s:

⎡ DMOD (1) ⎤ ⎡ DMOD (3) ⎤


⎢ ⎥ * PV ( EUR)1 + ⎢ ⎥ * PV ( EUR) 3
⎣ 10000 ⎦ ⎣ 10000 ⎦
⎡ 3.2184 ⎤ ⎡ 6.1123 ⎤
=⎢ ⎥ * 627738 + ⎢ ⎥ * 635551 = 202.03 + 388.47 = 590.50
⎣ 10000 ⎦ ⎣ 10000 ⎦

or even simpler, weighting modified durations with the PV:s:

(0.4969*3.2184)+(0.5031*6.1123)=4.6743
47

where 0.4969 and 0.5031 are the weights in the butterfly based on the PV:s. The PV of
the portfolio is 126.329, and the weights are 62.7732/126.329 = 0.4969 and
63.5558/126.329 = 0.5031

4.6.2. A critical assessment of yield, convexity, and duration

• calculating yield on the portfolio using the value-weighted average = 5.4820%


• the “conventional” estimate of the portfolio yield would indicate a 13.80 bp loss in
yield versus Bond 2
• the yield on the portfolio using the duration-weighted approximation:

(627738 * 3.2184 * 0.0515) + (635551 * 61123


. * 0.0581)
yP = = 0.055842 = 55842%
.
(627738 * 3.2184) + (635551* 61123
. )

• thus, in this case, the butterfly produces a yield loss of 3.58 bp


• the convexity of the portfolio is a weighted average of the bonds or:

(0.4969*14.2244) + (0.5031*50.0322) = 32.2392

• thus, the butterfly gives away 3.58 bp of yield, but increases convexity with 2.11
• the change in the value of a bond is

dP = − D MOD * PV * dy

• since the trade was structured as a butterfly dP2 = dP1+3 B B B B

• duration-based measures assume parallell shifts in yield curves


• if this is not the case, a butterfly not a perfect substitute for one single bond
• the standard deviation in % of a bond is:

PVBP * σ * 10000
s = D MOD * σ =
PV

• the standard deviation of the EUR-value of a bond is

S = PV * D MOD * σ = PVBP * σ * 10000

where

σ = the standard deviation of the yield change

• the EUR-standard deviation of a two-bond portfolio is (using duration):

SP = PV12 * D MOD 12 * σ 12 + PV22 * D MOD 22 * σ 22 + 2 * PV1 * PV2 * D MOD 1 * D MOD 2 * Corr1,2 * σ 1 *σ 2


48

the correlation of dP2 with dP1+3 denoted CorrdP is


B B B B B B

( PV1 * PV2 * D MOD1 * D MOD2 * Corr1,2 * σ 1 * σ 2 ) + ( PV3 * PV2 * D MOD3 * D MOD 2 * Corr3,2 * σ 3 * σ 2 )
CorrdP =
S 2 * S1,3

• CorrdP < 1 unless the yield shifts are parallell


B B

Example: Suppose the yield change correlation matrix, yield change standard deviations,
U U

and EUR standard deviations for bonds 1,2, and 3 on:

Bond 1 Bond 2 Bond 3


S (EUR) annual 28 460.15 46 963.19 56 311.57
σ (dy) annual 0.007495 0.007953 0.008127
s (%) annual 2.4121 3.7175 4.9675
Correlation matrix (dy)
Bond 1 1.0000 0.8926 0.8529
Bond 2 0.8926 1.0000 0.9467
Bond 3 0.8529 0.9467 1.0000

(Yield changes are daily closing quoted bid yields from 2.1.1997 - 7.11.1997)

E.g. for Bond 2:

s = 4.6743*0.007953 = 0.0371 = 3.71%


B B

and

S = 3.71% * 1 263 290 EUR = 46 963.19 EUR

The EUR standard deviation for the portfolio Bond 1 + Bond 3:

S1,3 = 45 182.05 EUR


B B

which is slightly lower than the risk of Bond 2. The correlation of the change in value of
the portfolio and the single bond is:

CorrdP = 0.9606 B B

• note that

1. the correlation between value changes is not perfect


2. due to a yield correlation of 0.8529 between Bond 1 and 3, the actual risk of
the portfolio is slightly lower although the risk constraint was satisfied
3. the difference in actual risk is a consequence of yield changes not being
parallell, and different maturities having unequal standard deviation, which
are not captured by using duration based measures only
4. the non-parallell behaviour was captured using yield change correlations, and
standard deviation estimates whose measurement is an empirical issue
(frequency, length of time-period)
5. the butterfly is not a perfect substitute for a single bond
49

5. Applications of bond mathematics I: FRA:s and bond


futures

We will consider three major fixed income derivative instruments available on most
markets: Forward Rate Agreements (FRA:s), swaps, and bond futures. FRA and swap
pricing are straightforward applications of the term structure of spot rates in the
interbank market. Bond futures pricing relies on arbitrage between cash and futures
markets.

5.1. Forward Rate Agreements

• FRA:s or Short Interest Rate Futures are used to hedge future short term borrowing
or lending in the money market, or to speculate on future interest rates
• the future interest rate (FRA or future rate) is fixed today
• underlying instrument: usually a 1- or 3-month deposit or borrowing in a certain
reference rate, e.g. 3-month LIBOR or EURIBOR or other money market rate
• expiration usually on the third Wednesday in March, June, September, and December
• the buyer makes a future borrowing in the reference rate (buys money)
• the seller makes a future deposit in the reference rate (sells money)
• cash settlement
• how is the rate for an FRA determined?
• recall from the relationship between spot rates and forward rates that:

(1 + r2 ) 2
(1 + f 12 ) = ⇒ (1 + r1 ) * (1 + f 12 ) = (1 + r2 ) 2
(1 + r1 )

using money market notation:

[1 + r * (t 1 1 ] [ ] [
/ 360) * 1 + f 12 * (t12 / 360) = 1 + r2 * (t 2 / 360) ]

where f12 stands for the FRA-rate, or the forward rate directly:
B B

⎡ 1 + r2 * (t 2 / 360)
f 12 = ⎢
[⎤
− 1⎥ * (360 / t12 )
]
⎢⎣ 1 + r1 * (t1 / 360) [⎥⎦ ]

where

f12 B B = the FRA rate


r1 B B = interest rate from today to FRA deposit start date
r2 B B = interest rate from today to FRA deposit maturity date
t12
B B = the FRA deposit lenght in days
t1
B B = days from today to FRA deposit start date
50

t2 B B = days from today to FRA deposit maturity date

Example: Suppose that on January 17, the 2-month (actual: 61 day) money market rate
U U

is r1 = 2.97%, the 5-month (actual: 152 days) money market rate is r2 = 3.03%, and thus
B B B B

t1 = 61 and t2 = 152. What is the correct FRA rate for a 3-month (actual: 91 days) that
B B B B

starts 61 days from today? The setting is:

Date: January 17 March 19 June 18

Action: FRA made FRA Deposit


Days: t1 = 61
B B t12 = 91
B B

t2 = 152
B B

⎡ [1 + 0.0303 * (152 / 360)] ⎤


f 12 = ⎢ − 1⎥ * (360 / 91) = 0.030548
⎢⎣ [1 + 0.0297 * (61 / 360)] ⎥⎦

• this relation must hold in order to prevent arbitrage


• otherwise, if e.g. the t1 deposit + the FRA yields more than the t2 depo: borrow at r2
B B B B B B

and invest in r1 + f12 B B B B

• FRA:s are cash settled up front:

The gain or loss for the buyer of an FRA:

⎡ t ⎤
(rR − rFRA ) * ⎢ *N
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦
Gain / Loss =
⎡ t ⎤
1 + ⎢rR *
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦

The gain or loss for the seller of a FRA:

⎡ t ⎤
(rFRA − rR ) * ⎢ *N
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦
Gain / Loss =
⎡ t ⎤
1 + ⎢rR *
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦

where

rFRA B B = the FRA contract interest rate


rR B B = the reference rate, (e.g. EURIBOR) at maturity or closing
N = nominal amount of contracts
t = maturity of the FRA deposit to be made
51

Example: On January 17th, a firm decides to hedge a EUR 5 000 000 future deposit to
U U P P

be made on March 19th. The depo matures on June 18th, or in 91 days. The firm sells 5
P P P P

March FRAs. The bid for FRAs is 3.0548. On March 19th , the 3-month EURIBOR is at
P P

2.96.

⎡ 91 ⎤
(0.0306 − 0.0296) * ⎢ * 5000000
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦ 119817
.
Gain / Loss = = = 1189.27
⎡ 91 ⎤ 1007482
.
1 + ⎢0.0296 *
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦

The gain from the contract is EUR 1189.27. On March 19th the buyer thus deposits EUR
P P

5 001 189.27 for 91 days at 2.96%:

5 001 189.27*[1 + 0.0296*(91/360)] = 5 038 609.28

To check that this really is the payoff at the FRA contract rate of 3.0548:

[5 038 145.21/5 000 000)-1]*(360/91) = 0.0306 = 3.0548%

5.2. Bond futures

• underlying instrument is a physical asset a, typically a coupon paying treasury bond


• most markets have expiration dates in March, June, September, and December
• settlement can be either 1) delivery or 2) cash
• the buyer of a future buys the underlying bond on the expiration day
• the seller of a future sells the underlying bond on the expiration day
• need to forecast future prices?
• no ⇒ the forces of arbitrage again determines the correct futures price

5.2.1. Futures pricing: The general approach

• cash and carry pricing: you have two alternative strategies:

1. buy the bond today at the cost PV and finance the purchase by borrowing
until future expires
2. buy future at the futures price F, and pay F when future expires

• implies that:

1. with both strategies 1 and 2 you own the bond at the future time t
2. no net cash outlay today
3. cost of both strategies are known today
4. cost of both strategies must equal to prevent arbitrage
52

• that is, the futures price F must be:

⎡ t ⎤
F = S * ⎢1 + r *
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦

where

1. the left-hand side is cost of strategy 2 at time t, and


2. the right-hand side is the cost of strategy 1 at time t

where

F= the futures price


S= the “spot” price (the price of the bond today = PV)
r= the money market rate (interest rate at which the purchase of the bond
can be financed)
t= time until future expires (in days)

Example: The PV of a Government bond is 1 100. The future expires in 60 days, and
U U

the 60 day money market rate is 3.50%. What is the futures price F?

⎡ 60 ⎤
F = 1100 * ⎢1 + 0.035 * = 1106.42
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦

If the futures price is higher, say, F = 1 110 you could:

1. Buy the bond today, and finance it at 3.5% at the cost: 1 106.42
2. Make a futures contract today to sell the bond at F = 1 110
3. After 60 days you deliver the bond to the buyer of the future and get F = 1100
in cash and pay off your borrowing 1 106.42
4. Your riskless arbitrage profit is thus 3.58

5.2.2. Repo transactions in the bond cash and futures markets

• a bond can be purchased by financing the purchase in the sale and repurchase
(repo) market (if such a market exists)
• in a repo the financial asset is is lent (“repo’d out”) to a second party who in turn as a
collateral lends an equal amount of cash to the owner of the asset (in practice the
collateral is usually slightly higher than the bond’s PV)
• when the repo is terminated, the second party returns the bond to the owner, and the
owner returns the cash loan (collateral) plus interest to the second party
• the interest rate paid on the cash loan is called the repo rate

For simplicity, we assume that:


53

1. collateral for shorting is 100% of the bond’s value today


2. there is only one rate of interest, 3.5%

Then, if the futures price is lower, say F = 1 105 you could:

1. Short the bond in the repo market (borrow the bond). Pay collateral 1 100,
which earns 3.5% interest
2. Finance the collateral by selling bond at market price S = 1 100
3. Make a futures contract to buy the bond back at F = 1 105
4. After 60 days you get the bond from the seller of the futures contract, and
deliver to the bond lender in 1).
5. You pay F = 1 105 for this bond, but get 1 106.42 from interest paying
collateral.
6. Your riskless arbitrage profit is 1.42

5.2.3. Coupon payments

• suppose a coupon is paid before the future expires


• then the price of the (reinvested) coupon must be deducted from the futures price F

Example: Consider the same bond as before, but now the bond pays a 5% (50 EUR)
U U

coupon after 30 days. The coupon can be reinvested at the 30 day money market rate (rR) B B

, which is assumed to be 3.00%. What is the futures price F?

⎡ t ⎤ ⎡ tR ⎤
F = S * ⎢1 + r * − ⎢ +
360 ⎥⎦
CPN * 1 r *
⎣ 360 ⎥⎦ ⎣
R

⎡ 60 ⎤ ⎡ 30 ⎤
F = 1100 * ⎢1 + 0.035 * ⎥ − 50 * ⎢1 + 0.03 * = 1106.42 − 50125
. = 1056.30
⎣ 360 ⎦ ⎣ 360 ⎥⎦

Why? If you want to hold the bond after 2 months, you can:

1. Buy the cash bond now and finance it at 3.5%. The cost is EUR 1106.42, and the
EUR 50 coupon is reinvested at 3.00%: EUR 50.125 which can be deducted from
your total costs from buying the bond: EUR 1106.42 - EUR 50.124 = EUR 1056.30
total after 2 months.
2. Buy the future. It's now clear that the futures price F must equal the cost in 1., since
F is also paid after 2 months in exchange for the bond, and both strategies lead to
holding the bond after 2 months.

• similar arbitrage positions like demonstrated earlier can be created for a bond that
pays a coupon to exploit mispriced futures contracts
• one has to remember that when shorting a bond, the coupon payments belong to the
owner of the bond, not the arbitrageur holding the bond short
54

5.2.4. Notional bonds and delivery options

• a common practice on futures exchanges is to use a notional bond as the underlying


security
• a notional bond does not exist (!)
• the notional bond is defined only subject to 1) face value, 2) coupon rate, and 3) a
maturity range
• for example, for LIFFE’s Long Gilt Future, the notional bond is simply defined as
”£ 100 000 nominal value notional Gilt with 7% coupon”
• several existing treasury bonds can be chosen by the short futures holder to deliver
• the use of a notional bond instead of a real one, and the use of many deliverable
bonds are used so that no market participant(s) can corner the market in the
underlying security
• since the deliverable bonds will have different present values the price paid by the
future’s buyer at delivery must be adjusted using a conversion factor
• the conversion factor is determined by the future’s exchange and calculated by
pricing the deliverable bonds using the yield stated in the futures contract

Example: A bond futures contract has the (very simplified) following contract
U U

specifications:

Five-Year Bund Future

Unit of trading: EUR 100 000 nominal value notional Bund with 6% coupon
Delivery months: March, June, September, and December
Contract standard: Delivery may be made of any Bunds on the List of Deliverable
Bunds
Deliverable bonds: Any Bund with the following characteristics:
• redemption in a single installment not earlier than 4 years, and
not later than 6 years
• having no terms permitting early redemption
• bearing interest at a single fixed rate

Further, to more clearly demonstrate the process, we assume that all bonds, when
delivered, have no accrued interest.

Suppose that the ”List of Deliverable Bunds” contains 3 bonds:

Bond: Coupon Face value PV calculated PV using Conversion


at delivery date contract yield factor
(6%) at
delivery date
4-year 5% annual EUR 1 000 1 009.90 965.35 0.9653
5-year 6% annual EUR 1 000 1 049.69 1 000.00 1.0000
5-year 7% annual EUR 1 000 1 093.42 1 042.12 1.0421

The PV is as usual found by discounting the bond with the term structure of zeros. To
find the conversion factor, the bond is discounted with the yield stated in the futures
contract. This value is then divided with the face value to find the conversion factor.
55

Since the future’s contract is for EUR 100 000 nominal value, and all deliverable bonds
have a nominal value of EUR 1 000, this means that 100 bonds must be delivered, no
matter which bond the seller decides to deliver.

The conversion factor then decides how much the buyer must pay for the 100 bonds to
be delivered, such that:

Invoice price = Contract size * Futures settlement price * Conversion factor +


accrued interest

Suppose that the futures contract settles at: F = 105%, and that the seller decides to
deliver the 5-year, 7% bond with conversion factor 1.0421, then:

Invoice price =EUR 100 000 * 1.05 * 1.0421 + 0 = EUR 109 420.50

Thus, the seller delivers 100 of the 5-year 7% bonds, and the buyer pays EUR 109 420.50

• how is the future’s price determined when there is no underlying security?


• usually, one of the deliverable bonds will, despite the use of conversion factors be
cheaper to deliver than the other bonds (since the conversion factor is fixed)
• this bond is called the cheapest to deliver bond (CTD)
• the CTD-bond can be found by calculating the return from the following exercise for
each deliverable bond:

1. Buy the bond.


2. Make a futures contract to sell the bond.
3. Deliver the bond at the future’s settlement date.
4. The return is called the implied repo rate, and the bond with the highest
implied repo is the cheapest to deliver bond.

• because a rational investor will deliver the CTD, the futures will be derived from the
CTD-bond
• the CTD bond may of course change over the life of the futures contract

5.2.5. Futures pricing using quoted prices and accrued interest

• the previous examples showed how futures contracts are generally priced
• in practice, bond futures prices are quoted as clean prices, and we have to take
accrued interest into account when calculating the clean futures price
• cash and carry pricing: you have two alternative strategies:

1. buy the bond today at K + AI and finance [K + AI] by borrowing until future
expires
2. buy future at F + AI today, and pay F + AI when future expires

• alternatively you could think that you have the money now and can earn interest on
[K + AI] by investing this amount in the money market
56

• implies that:

1. with both strategies 1 and 2 you own the bond at time t (when future expires)
2. cost of both strategies are known today
3. cost of both strategies must equal

The price of a bond future can be solved from:

[K + (rCPN * v/365 * N)]*[1 + (rt * t/360)] = [F + (rCPN * (v+t)/365 *N)]


B B B B B B

where

F = the future price


t = days to maturity for the future
v = days since last coupon payment
rt B B = money market rate from now to maturity of the future

more compactly

[K + AIc]*[1 + (rt * t/360)] = [F + AIt]


B B B B B B

where

AIc B B = accrued interest on the contract date


AIt B B = accrued interest on the maturity date

• the left-hand side of the equation: cost of K + AIc financed in the money market to B B

maturity date of future


• the right-hand side of the equation: cost of F + AIt on maturity date of future B B

• there is no need to forecast future bond prices to price a future

rearranging

F = [K + AIc]*[1 + (rt * t/360)] - AIt B B B B B B

Example: On January 17th, a Treasury bond with 10% CPN bond trades at K = EUR 1
U U P P

218 000. The 2-month EURIBOR is at 2.96%. Assume there are 122 days since the last
coupon, and 61 days to the maturity of the future. What is the March 19th futures price? P P

F =[1 218 000 + (0.10*122/365*1 000 000)]*[1 + (0.0296*61/360)] - [0.10*(122 +


61)/365*1 000 000]

F = [1 218 000 + 33 424.66]*[1.000495] - [50 136.99] = 1 207 564.26


57

• if a coupons are paid between the the contract date and maturity date, the money
market rate for investing the coupon must be deducted from K

[K + AIc]*[1 + (rt * t/360)] = [F + AIt] + Σ CPNi *(1 + rCPN,t)


B B B B B B B B B B

F = [K + AIc]*[1 + (rt * t/360)] - AIt - Σ CPNi *(1 + rCPN,t)


B B B B B B B B B B

where

rCPN,t
B B = money market rate from the receipt of the i:th coupon to maturity

Example: On January 17th, a Treasury bond with CPN 7.25% trades at K = EUR 1 086
U U P P

423.26. A coupon is received on 18.4. The 5-month (rt) EURIBOR is at 3.04%, and the B B

2-month (rCPN,t) EURIBOR is at 2.96%. What is the June 18th futures price?
B B P P

1. Buy bond on Jan 17th ⇒ price paid is [K + AIc] = 1 140 596.87 EUR, financed at
P P B B

money market rate, and total cost is 1 140 596.87 EUR*[1 + (0.0304*152/365)] = 1
155 036.51 EUR which is paid on June 18th P P

2. 7.25% coupon is paid on April 18th ⇒ invested at money market rate to yield 72 P P

500*[1 + (0.0296*61/365)] = 72 858.65 EUR on June 18th P P

3. Total cost on June 18th is [1 155 036.51 - 72 858.65] = 1 082 177.86 EUR
P P

4. Total cost for future on January 18th must equal 1 082 177.86 EUR [K + AIt] P P B B

Using the formula:

F =[1 086 423.26 + (0.0725*269/360*1 000 000)]*[1 + (0.0304*152/365)] -


[0.0725*60/360*1 000 000] - 72 500*[1 + (0.0296*61/365)]

F = [1 086 423.26 + 54 173.61]*[1.012660] - [12 083.33] - [72 858.65] = 1 070 094.53


58

6. Applications of bond mathematics II: Swap contracts

• a forward contract is a contract to exchange one payment in the future


• a swap contract is a contract to exchange a stream of payments at a series of
specified dates in the future
• swap contracts are usually used together with bonds or loans, to exchange the cash
flows (interest rate payments and principal) to some other interest rate base or
currency than the originally specified in the bond
• an interest rate swap is a contract between two parties to exchange fixed interest
rate payments against floating interest rate payments (fixed-to-floating swap), or the
other way round
• a currency swap is a contract between two parties to exchange interest rate
payments in one currency against interest rate payments in another currency (the
interest rates can be either fixed or floating interest)
• swap contracts are usually OTC contracts, and are made between banks and large
corporations
• an interest rate swap can be regarded (same PV) as a series of interest rate forward
contracts
• a currency swap can be regarded (same PV) as a series of currency forwards
• swaps are used for:

1. Hedging purposes. A stream of cash flows can be hedged. For example,


floating rate loans can be hedged against rising interest rates by swapping the
interest rate payements to fixed rate payements, or a EUR based bond issuer
might swap a USD-nominated bond to EUR.
2. Cost saving. A bond issuer might be able to borrow floating rate debt at
better terms (lower rates) than fixed rate debt. Then a package of floating rate
debt + swap to fixed can be more cost effective than to borrow directly at a
fixed rate. A bond issuer might also find for example the domestic bond
market “saturated”, and that demand for bonds in the issuers home currency
is low. Then a better price (lower yield) might be obtained in a foreign
currency, and a swap back to home currency might be desired to hedge the
currency risk.

6.1. Interest rate swaps

• with interest swaps, a customer (corporation or bank) can transform floating rate
debt to fixed rate or the other way round
• swaps are usually semi-annual and the floating rate in swap contracts is usually 6
month LIBOR or EURIBOR

Example: Consider a corporation borrowing a floating rate EUR 100 million for 3-years.
U U

Interest rate payments are annual, and the reference rate is 12 month LIBOR flat (the
company has a good rating and can borrow at LIBOR without a credit spread). The
company fears increasing interest rates, and decides to swap the floating payments to
59

fixed. The current 12-month LIBOR rate is 4.00%, and bank offers a fixed swap rate of
4.3885% against 12 month LIBOR. The company agrees to pay the bank an annual
4.3885%, and receives LIBOR from the bank. The cash flows are (EUR millions):

LIBOR debt Swap floating to fixed TOTAL


Maturity LIBOR Receive LIBOR Pay fixed Debt + swap
1 -4.0000 +4.0000 -4.3885 -4.3885
2 -LIBOR +LIBOR -4.3885 -4.3885
3 -LIBOR +LIBOR -4.3885 -4.3885

Note that the payements from the LIBOR debt and the swap LIBOR payments cancel,
out and what is left are the fixed rate swap payments. Also note that the first payment of
the LIBOR debt is known, since the first payment is set at the reference rate, and reset at
the LIBOR rate after each interest rate payment.

• note that principal (EUR 100 m) is not exchanged


• the interest rate payments, must however be based on this value, why it is called
“notional principal”

6.1.1. The swap rate

• how is the fixed swap rate set?


• the swap rates that swap-dealers quote are usually valid only for well-known
counterparties with a good credit rating
• swap rates are typically slightly higher than the yield for treasuries of the same
maturity, but lower than yields on corporate debt
• swap rates are lower than corporate bond yields since the principal is not exchanged,
and hence the counterparty risk is limited to the exchange of interest payments
• differences in counterparty credit quality can be managed by for example charging an
upfront fee, which will be higher for counterparties with lower credit quality,
collateral requirements, or other provisions
• since bond yields depend on the coupon level, the swap rate is defined as a par bond
yield (the yield on a bond that trades at par, coupon rate = yield)
• there is a tight link between swap rates and the interest rate futures (money market)
markets, since both contracts are priced used the same yield curve, swap dealers often
operate on both markets and can use futures for hedging swaps, and since a series of
futures can be constructed to replicate a swap
• the par yield again:

1 − Df T
Par − yield = T

∑ Df
i =1
i

where:

DfT B B = the discount factor using zero-coupon rates for the maturity T
Dfi B B = the discount factors using zero-coupon rates up to maturity T
60

Example: Calculate the swap rate if the zero-coupon rates are 4.00% for 1 year, 4.20%
U U

for 2 years, and 4.40% for 3 years. Then:

1 − 0.8788
Par − yield = = 0.043885
(0.9615 + 0.9210 + 0.8788)

• we will now show why this must be the case, since an interest rate swap can be
constructed using interest rate forwards

6.1.2. The swap rate and FRA-rates

• the 1-year interest rate forwards f12, and f23 are:


B B B B

(1 + 0.042) 2
f12 = − 1 = 0.044004
(1 + 0.40)

(1 + 0.044) 2
f 23 = − 1 = 0.048012
(1 + 0.42)

Now, we construct a table where we instead hedge the LIBOR debt with forwards. We
buy 1-year FRA:s up to 3 years, which means that settlement is based on (LIBOR-FRA
rate). Assume the FRA:s are settled in cash. This means that if the LIBOR exceeds the
FRA rate, the difference is paid in cash. Cash flows in EUR millions:

LIBOR TOTAL TOTAL Difference


debt
Maturity LIBOR FRA-rate FRA settlement Debt+FRA Debt+swap Swap – FRA
1 -4.0000 4.0000 -4.0000 -4.3885 +0.3885
2 -LIBOR 4.4004 LIBOR-4.4004 -4.4004 -4.3885 -0.0119
3 -LIBOR 4.8012 LIBOR-4.8012 -4.8012 -4.3885 -0.4127

The hedged interest rate payments are clearly not the same as the swap cash flows. How
about the present value of the series of FRA:s versus the swap?

4.3885 4.3885 4.3885


PVSwap = + + = 4.2197 + 4.0419 + 3.8567 = 12.1183
(1 + 0.04) (1 + 0.042) 2
(1 + 0.044) 3

4.0000 4.4004 4.8012


PV FRA = + + = 3.8462 + 4.0528 + 4.2193 = 12.1183
(1 + 0.04) (1 + 0.042) 2
(1 + 0.044) 3

That is, even if the individual cash flows are not equal, the PV of the swap payments
equals the PV of the swap. If the principal of EUR 100 million (PV = 87.8817) is
included in the calculations the PV is of course EUR 100 million.
61

6.1.3. Interest rate swap valuation

• a swap is priced at par, such that the NPV is zero to both parties
• after this the value of the swap may change
• a swap can be valued as either:

1. valued using the same principle as when valuing outstanding forwards: compare
the contract rate with the current market rate for the same maturity, and disocunt
the difference to present value, the result is a net present value (NPV)
2. valued as a bond, the result is a present value (PV), including the principal

• the values for outstanding forwards or futures:

Ft − F0
Long forward: PV ( F0 ) =
(1 + rt )

F0 − Ft
Short forward: PV ( F0 ) =
(1 + rt )

where

Ft
B B = the new forward rate prevailing at time t, for a forward identical to FT
B B

• Ft is the new swap rate for the same maturity T as the original swap to be valued (F0)
B B B B

• note that since there usually are multiple cash flows left, the equation will be
extended to a sum of all the differences Ft and F0 B B B B

• we also assume that the PV of the floating rate leg is zero at the coupon payment
date (not true between coupon payment dates)

Example: Suppose that after 1 year, the 1 and 2 year zero-coupon rates are 4.10%, and
U U

4.25%. Then the 2 year swap rate is 4.2469%, with maturity T equal to the old 3 year
swap. What is the market value of the old swap now? We are “long” in the swap, since
we pay the fixed leg, and the bank is “short”. Then

F0 B B = 4.3885%
Ft B B = 4.2469%

and:

T
Ft − F0 4.2469 − 4.3885 4.2469 − 4.3885
NPV ( F0 ) = ∑ = + = −0.2664
i =1 (1 + rt ) t (1 + 0.041) (1 + 0.0425) 2

which is in this example is in millions, or roughly EUR -266 400. The negative value for
the fixed rate payer is a result of lower swap rates, the fixed rate payer is now paying
above the market rate for swaps with equal maturity T. The bank, who is short the swap,
has naturally made an equally large gain.
62

Using the bond valuation approach:

T
CFt 4.3885 104.3885
PV ( Bond ) = ∑ = + = −100.2664
i =1 (1 + rt ) t
(1 + 0.041) (1 + 0.0425) 2

• the swap can naturally be valued at any time, not only at interest payment dates
• then the value of the floating rate leg is not zero ⇒ the first payment should be
valued as a money market security

6.2. Currency swaps

• now consider a borrower wishing to swap fixed payments in one currency to fixed
payments in another currency
• using the previous 3 year EUR 100 debt issue as an example, consider that the issuer
wants to swap the debt to USD
• the issuer may for example be a US issuer, finding better borrowing terms in EUR,
and wishing to hedge EUR outflows or a EUR-based issuer financing its US
operations with the debt, and wanting to use the US-revenue to repay the debt
• an interest rate swap could be regarded as a sequence of FRA:s
• a fixed-to-fixed currency swap can be regarded as a sequence of currency forwards
• the swap rates for both legs are set as par yields as before
• with interest rate swaps, principals are usually exchanged, and a currency swap then
consists of the following steps:

1. Initial exchange of currency principals. The currency spot rate is used to


determine the principal values. If for exampel S = EUR/USD 0.95, and EUR
100 million is swapped to USD, the notional principal in USD is USD 105.26
million. The interest rate payments will be based on these values. (If both
parties agree, no principal is exchanged, since the exchange is done at the
current spot rate and carries no risk, and thus does not require hedging).
2. Exchange of interest rate payments during the life of the swap.
3. Exchange back of principal. This step is taken even if principals were not
exchanged in 1., since the exchange back is risky and needs to hedged, why it
is included in the contract.

NOTE!: In these lecture notes a currency quote S(X/Y) means ”how many units
of currency Y does it take to buy 1 unit of currency X”. That is EUR/USD 0.95
means it takes 0.95 EUR to buy 1.00 USD. I know this is frustrating for those used
to the conventions used in the foreign currency markets. The reason is that this
way of quoting is algebraically correct, and hence more easily lends itself to
exercises involving inverting the quote, cross-rates, etc.

Example: Consider a corporation borrowing a fixed rate EUR 100 million for 3-years.
U U

Interest rate payments are annual and the rate is 4.3885%. The company wishes to swap
the debt into USD. A bank offers to swap these EUR payments against a rate of 4.7906%
63

in USD. The spot currency rate is EUR/USD 0.95, and the USD principal is USD
105.26 million.

The interest rate cash flows in %:

EUR debt Swap EUR to USD TOTAL


Maturity Receive EUR (%) Pay USD (%) Debt + swap (%)
1 -4.3885 +4.3885 -4.7906 -4.7906
2 -4.3885 +4.3885 -4.7906 -4.7906
3 -4.3885 +4.3885 -4.7906 -4.7906

The interest rate + principal cash flows in currency (millions):

EUR debt Swap EUR to USD TOTAL


Maturity Receive EUR Pay USD Debt + swap USD
1 -4.3885 +4.3885 -5.0428 -5.0428
2 -4.3885 +4.3885 -5.0428 -5.0428
3 -104.3885 +104.3885 -110.3059 -110.3059

Note that the payments from the EUR debt and the swap payments cancel out and what
is left are the USD swap payments. Note the exchange back of the principals.

6.2.1. Currency swap rates and currency forward rates

• note that the swap from EUR to USD is identical to a series of FX forwards
• the swap is a series of forwards to buy EUR against USD
• the exchange rates for three years implied by the swap:

Year 1: EUR 4.3885/USD 5.0428 = EUR/USD 0.8703


Year 2: EUR 4.3885/USD 5.0428 = EUR/USD 0.8703
Year 3: EUR 104.3885/USD 110.3059 = EUR/USD 0.9464

when the current spot is EUR/USD 0.95. Is something wrong?

• calculate the 1, 2, and 3 years currency forwards using CIRP, assume the USD zeros
are 4.50%, 4.65%, and 4.80% for years 1-3:

⎡1 + rd ⎤ ⎡ (1 + 0.040)1 ⎤
F = S0 * ⎢ ⎥ = 0.95 * ⎢ 1⎥
= 0.9455
⎣⎢1 + r f ⎥⎦ ⎣ (1 + 0.045) ⎦

and similarly for the 2 and 3 years forwards: EUR/USD 0.9418, and EUR/USD 0.9392.

Year 0 1 2 3
EUR debt +100.0000 -4.3885 -4.3885 -104.3885
Swap to USD:
USD payments 5.0428 5.0428 110.3059
PV of USD payments 105.2632 4.8256 4.6046 95.8330
FX to USD:
Forward rate 0.9500 0.9455 0.9418 0.9392
USD payments 4.6417 4.6595 111.1505
PV of USD payments 105.2632 4.4418 4.2546 96.5667
64

Both with the swap and the FX hedge, the firms EUR receipts are set equal to the cash
outflow of the debt, and their PV is then EUR 100 m. Note that the PV of the individual
cash flows of the swap versus the FX hedge are not equal, but their sums are equal ⇒
the value of the swap equals the value of the series of currency forwards.

6.2.2. Currency swap valuation

• the currency swap is priced at par, such that the NPV is zero to both parties
• we will price the currency swap using the “bond approach”, since now principals
matter beacuse they are in different currencies and subject to currency risk
• the value of the swap is the difference between the two bonds that constitute the
swap:

T T
CF (Re ceipts) t CF ( Payments) t
PV = ∑ − S ∑
i =1 (1 + rR ) t
i =1 (1 + rP ) t

where

CF(Receipts) = cash flow received in the swap


CF(Payments) = cash flow paid in the swap
rR B B = zero-coupon discount rate for receipt when swap is valued
rP B B = zero-coupon discount rate for receipt when swap is valued
S = spot currency rate between the two currencies when swap is valued

• note that receipts and payments are in different currencies, and interest rates used
should be for that particular currency

Example: Suppose that after 1 year, the 1 and 2 year zero-coupon rates in EUR are
U U

4.10%, and 4.25%, and in USD 4.60%, and 4.75%. The spot rate is EUR/USD 0.93.
What is the market value of the EUR-USD swap made at EUR 4.3885%-USD 5.0428,
with principals EUR 100, and USD 105.2632?

⎡ 4.3885 104.3885 ⎤ ⎡ 5.0428 110.3059 ⎤


PV = ⎢ + 2 ⎥
− 0.93 * ⎢ + 2 ⎥
⎣ (1 + 0.041) (1 + 0.042) ⎦ ⎣ (1 + 0.046) (1 + 0.0475) ⎦
PV = 100.2664 − 97.9754 = 2.2910

which in this example is in millions, or roughly EUR 2 291 000 for the USD payer.

• like an interest rate swap the currency swap can naturally be valued at any time, not
only at interest rate payment dates
65

7. Pricing credit risk

• credit risk is usually priced by determining an appropriate additional credit spread on


top of a Treasury yield with same maturity
• to date there exist no established and widely accepted model for pricing credit risk
• one can roughly distinguish between two approaches:

1. Traditional models. These are not really “pricing models”, since this approach
resembles much of equity analysis and there is no theoretically or other
established way in which to in a consistent manner combine company-specific
information (accounting etc.) into a yield, credit spread, or price. One can of
course use empirical information as guidelines, that is compare issuers with
similar characteristics and use price and spread information on these to get an
idea of what spread should be charged.
2. Models based on option pricing. This approach is strongly based on financial
pricing theory. Here, the value of the firm is seen as options, where equity seen
as a long call (due to limited liability of shareholders), and bonds as short put
options. Hence, bonds can be priced as options.

7.1. Credit ratings

• a credit rating is an assessment of a borrower’s willingness and ability to meet its


obligations for timely payments of principal debt and interest
• the most influential credit rating agencies: Moody’s, Standard & Poor’s, and Fitch
• issuers pay credit agencies an annual fee for maintaining a credit rating
• selling a bond issue without ratings can be difficult or impossible
• ratings scale and definition, long term-debt:

Rating agency Brief definition


I: Investment grade - High creditworthiness
Moody’s S&P
Aaa AAA Gilt edge, prime, maximum safety
Aa1 AA+
Aa2 AA Very high grade and quality
Aa3 AA-
A1 A+
A2 A Upper medium grade
A3 A-
Baa1 BBB+
Baa2 BBB Lower medium grade
Baa3 BBB-
II. High yield - Low creditworthiness
Ba1...Ba3 BB+...BB- Low grade, speculative
B1...B3 B+...B- Highly speculative
III. Predominantly speculative - Substantial risk or in Default
Caa CCC+...CCC- Substantial risk, in poor standing
Ca CC May be in default, extremely speculative
C C Even more speculative than those above
D Default
Table adapted from: Fabozzi. Frank J. (1997): “Handbook of fixed income securities”. p. 226
66

• the better the rating, the lower the credit spread


• the markets roughly divide the bond markets into two sectors by rating:

1. Investment grade. Moody’s: Aaa – Baa3, S&P: AAA – BBB-


2. High yield, or junk bond. Moody’s: Ba1 – C, S&P: BB+ – D

• the scale for short term debt (commercial paper):


• Moody’s: P-1, P-2, P-3, NP (Not Prime)
• S & P: A-1, A-2, A-3, B, C, D

• credit ratings lowers the barrier for an investor to invest in a bond, since most bond
investors think that ratings quite accurately reflect the credit risk of the issuer, and
hence there is less uncertainty for the bond investor when making the investment
decision
• ratings are thus a natural starting point for evaluating credit risk
• note that ratings are only an assessment of credit risk (repayment risk), not interest
rate risk, liquidity risk, call risk or other risks
• ratings are not a recommendation to buy or sell a bond, a good rating does not make a
bond a better investment in terms of risk/return -> markets price credit risk and
ratings, and lower ratings come with higher yields
• the ratings and rating agencies have a very strong role in debt markets, since many
investors define their investment strategies according to ratings (for example mutual
funds), or are prohibited by regulators to invest in certain rating classes (for example
insurers)
• examples of some Nordic issuers (September 2003):

Issuer Moody's S&P EUR CPN Maturity Spread Swap S


ABB Ba3 BB+ 500 9.500 15-01-08 534 522
UPM-Kymmene Baa1 BBB 250 6.350 01-10-09 95 80
UPM-Kymmene Baa1 BBB 600 6.125 23-01-12 107 87
Stora Enso Baa1 BBB+ 850 6.375 29-06-07 70 59
SCA A3 A- 700 5.375 25-06-07 57 35
Elisa Baa2 BBB+ 300 6.375 31-06-06 141 111
Sonera Group Baa1 A 300 4.625 16-04-09 72 53
Metso Baa3 BBB 500 6.25 11-12-06 155 131
Ericsson LM B1 BB 2000 7.875 31-05-06 537 512

7.2. The traditional approach to pricing credit risk

• the most important factors can be summarised into the 6 C:s of credit risk:

1. Character. Management, strategy, track record as borrower (reputation),


debt strategy.
2. Capital. Simply leverage.
3. Capacity. Cash flow, volatility of earnings, competitive position, industry
competition, cash liquidity, company structure
4. Cycle. How sensitive is the company to business cycles, what cycle are
we in now.
67

5. Collateral. Collateral, it’s market value, priority in default, what


possibilities to settle with other investors in default process.
6. Covenants. Callability, putability, restrictions on new debt, asset sales,
dividends etc.

• examples of how to mix these (usually) accounting-related variables into an empirical


model include for example Altman’s (1968) model or later variations of the same idea
• some special issues concerning high-yield (HY) issuers:

1. Debt structure. i) HY-issuers on average rely more on bank loans which


usually are senior to bonds (Cornish, 1990), partly because HY issuers
have limited access to CP-markets, ii) bank debt usually floating rate,
short term, can lead liquidity problems if short-term rates rise, iii) short-
term debt leads to frequent refinancing risk, and can lead to asset sales if
new debt is difficult to raise.
2. Enterprise structure. Leads to questions like: which part of the
enterprise is responsible for the debt, what is the operative and legal
structure, can money and assets be transferred from subsidiary to another,
what responsibility does the subsidiaries have?
3. Covenants. Understanding covenants becomes more important, as
financial distress is more likely.
4. What do the stock markets tell us? HY-debt have more company-
specific risk than investment grade issuers, what information can we use
from the stock markets/stock price about the state of the issuer?

7.3. Using option theory to price credit risk

• the idea of using option theory in bond pricing started with Robert Merton’s article in
Journal of Finance (1974), hence, the term “Merton-like” models
• Merton’s simple model deals with valuing a default risky zero-coupon bond, but the
analysis can of course be extended (with some additional effort...) to coupon paying
bonds, realising that a coupon bond is a series of zero-coupon bond
• the idea of regarding a bond as an option is the limited upside of the bond: the value
of a zero can never exceed it’s par value, but the bond still has downside in terms of
default risk
• the example below shows the present value (PV), and Recovery Rate (RR) of a 3-year
zero-coupon bond relative to total company assets (belong to bondholders in case of
default)
• the idea is that if asset value is below the bond’s par value (100), and the bond
defaults, the Recovery Rate is received and 100 – RR is then the credit loss
• the same analysis can be made for each coupon to arrive at a series of present values
and adding them up to total bond value
68

Merton's model (1974)


Bond: N = 100, T = 3, CPN = 0%, r = 5%
120

100
Value of debt (PV and RR)

80

RR
60
PV

40

20

0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130 140 150
Asset value

• the difference between the standard Black-Scholes-Merton model for pricing stock
options, and Mertons model for valuing risky debt is:

BSM put option: P = f(S, X, r, s, T)


Merton’s model: L = f(A, B, r, sA, T)

A = asset value
B = nominal value of zero-coupon bond
r = riskfree rate (Treasury)
sA = volatility of firm’s assets (A)
T = maturity of bond in years

The model as presented in Saunders et al. (2002) and used for the above chart:

⎡1 ⎤
L = Be −rT ⎢ N (h1 ) + N (h2 )⎥
⎣d ⎦
⎡1 ⎤ ⎡1 ⎤
h1 = − ⎢ s 2T − ln(d )⎥ /( s T ), h2 = ⎢ s 2T + ln(d )⎥ /( s T )
⎣2 ⎦ ⎣2 ⎦

where levarage is measured as: d = Be-rT/A


69

For example, if B = 100, A = 120, d = 0.80, T = 3, r = 0.05, s = 0.12

Bond price (L) = 84.63


Spread = 0.56%
Price of defaultfree bond = 86.07

• the main difference is that the underlying asset is now the assets of the issuer, and
volatility is then the volatility of these assets
• this simple model suffers from obvious problems:

1. What is the market value of the firm’s assets A?


2. What is the volatility of these assets and how to measure it?
3. Based on European option pricing models, but default can happen at any
time.
4. Model allows default only if A = 0, in practice must happen before this.

• extension of this idea include the Black & Cox (1976) model where default can
happen before all assets are exhausted (A = 0)
• KMV (now a part of Moody’s) have attempted to solve problems 1-4 by:

1. Attempting to model the statistical process of A over time (how does the
value of A evolve over time, and what is its volatility).
2. A is modeled by modeling the stock price (E) behavior, and using
leverage as a link between the stock price process and asset value process.
The less debt, the closely A follows E.
3. Default if A goes below a specified value (makes this a barrier option).

• problems still remain:

1. How to in a reliable way model asset value process or default process?


2. How to reliably estimate recovery rate in case of default?
3. How to define the level of A that triggers default?
4. Does default occur because of low A or other reasons not (yet) in the
model such as liquidity crunch?
5. How to model the evolution of leverage since the relation between A and
E depends on this.
6. Very difficult to include all covenants and options (callability, putability)
in the model.

• the more realistic the model, the more difficult it becomes to estimate, use and
understand it -> significant model risk!
• the state of the world today: no accepted model

7.4. Default probabilities, rating transitions, recovery rates and


how to use them to estimate bond returns

• what is the default probability (DP), recovery rate (RR), or loss given default (LGD)
• empirical results on US bond data by Altman & Kishore (1998) on high-yield:
70

Year DR(%) RR(%) Loss


AADR 71-97 2.613
78-97 2.849 42.9 1.83
85-97 3.745
WADR 71-97 3.311
78-97 3.342 2.18
Median 71-97 1.5
Max. 91 10.27 36.0 7.16
Min. 81 0.16 12.0 0.15

AADR = arithmetic average of default rates (DR)


WADR = par-value weighted average of default rates
RR = recovery rate as % of par value
Loss = (LGD + next coupon) x DR

• note the rise and variability in the figures


• some statistics on recovery rates and seniority of bonds:

Seniority RR(%)
Senior secured 58.7
Senior unsecured 48.9
Senior subordinated 35.0
Subordinated 31.7
Zeros 20.7

• investing in bonds with high spreads (yields) does not necessarily lead to high returns:
the risks priced into the spread might be realised causing a further widening of the
spread and price decline and loss of return
• rating ans spread changes are an essential part of corporate bond investing
• 1-year rating transition probabilities (RTP) by Carty & Fons (1994), using Moody’s
ratings 1970-1994:

Rating Rating at end of year (T = 1)


T=0 Aaa Aa A Baa Ba B C, D Total
Aaa 91.90 7.38 0.72 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 100
Aa 1.13 91.26 7.09 0.31 0.21 0.00 0.00 100
A 0.10 2.56 91.20 5.33 0.61 0.20 0.00 100
Baa 0.00 0.21 5.36 87.94 5.46 0.82 0.21 100

• conclusions:

1. Downgrades more likely than upgrades (fallen angels more likely than
rising stars)
2. Spread differences between rating categories widen with lower ratings,
adding to return loss due to price decline.
71

3. Adding up 1 and 2: Return < initial spread

• how use historical bond market information to estimate returns?

1. Estimate the bond’s RTP for the holding period.


2. Calculate the expected price change due to rating and spread change.
3. Calculate the expected return, take into account coupon payements and
reinvestment.

• for example, assume a 3-year AA-rated bond that now trades at a 30 bp spread, and
you want to estimate the expected return over a 1-year holding period:

Horizon Horizon Return Transition Excess


rating spread over Treas. probability return
Aaa 25 38 1.13% 0.43
Aa 30 30 91.26% 27.38
A 35 21 7.09% 1.49
Baa 60 -24 0.31% -0.07
Ba 130 -147 0.21% -0.31
28.9

Horizon spread = spread now


Return over Treasuries = return in excess of Treasury yield assuming that the
rating of the bond changes to rating XXX (for example, a
downgrade to A increases spread to 35 bp and lowers the
price that of the initial spread of 30 bp, only 21 bp is left)
Excess return = Transition probability x Return over Treasuries

• using these values, the expected return of a AA-bond is not the initial spread of 30 bp,
but 28.9 bp
• some figures based on historical averages for different rating classes over different
holding periods (highest returns are bolded):

3-year 5-year 10-year


Rating Initial Excess Initial Excess Initial Excess
T = 0 spread return spread return spread return
Aaa 25.0 24.2 30.0 28.4 35.0 31.7
Aa 30.0 28.9 34.0 31.4 40.0 30.3
A 35.0 31.1 45.0 37.3 55.0 37.9
Baa 60.0 46.3 70.0 39.9 85.0 21.9

• that is for both 3- and 5-year horizons, Baa has the highets returns, but for a 10-year
horizon, A is the best rating class
• note that all such estimates are based on historical averages
72

7.5. Selected empirical results on spreads

Bevan & Garzarelli (2000):

• Moody’s Baa-index spread


• 1% increase in GDP growth -> +18 bp
• 1% increase in financing gap -> +46 bp
• 1 standard deviation increase on S&P 500 volatility -> +25 bp
• in the long run, correlation between spreads and benchmark yields positive, in the
short run negative

Campbell & Taksler (2002):

• AA – BBB rated bonds


• spreads decrease with S&P equity index returns
• spreads increase with increase in S&P equity volatility
• stock market volatility more important factor than ratings
• ratings explain more of spread than accounting information
• equity volatility more important factor for bonds with longer duration

Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, Martin (2001):

• leverage increases spreads, stock returns decreases spreads


• S&P 500 returns 7 times more important factor than company specific equity return
• Treasury yield increases decreases spreads
• S&P 100 index option implied volatility increases spreads
• only 25% of spreads can be explained
• market-wide factors more important than company-specific factors, not consistent
with Merton-type models
• 75% of spreads unexplained, is strong bond/stock market segmentation the reason?
• liquidity, supply-demand shocks explanations?
i

Mind-expanding reading (NOT required for the CEFA-exam):

Das, Satyajit (1994): Swap & Derivative financing. Irwin Professional Publishing.

Eales, Brian A. (1995): Financial risk management. McGraw-Hill.

Fabozzi, Frank J. (2000): Bond markets, analysis and strategies. Prentice-Hall


International.

Galitz, Lawrence C. (1995): Financial engineering: Tools and techniques to manage


financial risk. Irwin Professional Publishing.

Garbade, Kenneth D. (1996): Fixed income analytics. The MIT Press.

de la Grandville, Olivier (2001): Bond pricing and portfolio analysis. The MIT Press.

Hull, John C. (2000): Options, futures, and other derivative securities. Prentice-Hall
International.

Jorion, Philippe (1996): Value at risk: The new benchmark for controlling market risk.
Irwin Professional Publishing.

Sundaresan, Suresh M. (1997): Fixed income markets and their derivatives. South-
Western.

Tuckman, Bruce (1996): Fixed income securities: Tools for today’s markets. John Wiley
& Sons.

Вам также может понравиться