Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 57

The Impact of Managerial Incentives on IPO Mortality

Dimitrios Gounopoulos, Georgios Loukopoulos, and Panagiotis Loukopoulos 1

This draft: September 16, 2018

Abstract
We find that IPO firms with generously compensated CEOs and large pay disparities between the CEO and
other top executives have lower failure rates and longer time to survive in subsequent periods following the
offering. Economically, firms with CEO pay (pay gaps) in the 75th percentile have a failure risk that is, on
average, 11.56% (13.20%) lower than the failure risk of firms with CEO pay (pay gaps) in the 25 th
percentile. The relationship between CEO pay and IPO survival is strengthened among firms with lower
agency conflicts, whereas the link between pay gap and IPO survival is pronounced among firms with
stronger internal promotion incentives. The results are robust to alternative specifications and additional
sensitivity tests.

JEL Classifications: G24; G30; G31; G32; J31; J33; L25

Keywords: Executive Compensation, Pay Gap, IPO Survival, Initial Public Offerings

1
Dimitrios Gounopoulos (corresponding author) is from the University of Bath, E-mail: d.gounopoulos@bath.ac.uk.
Georgios Loukopoulos is from the University of Bath, E-mail: g.loukopoulos@bath.ac.uk.
Panagiotis Loukopoulos is from the University of Strathclyde, E-mail: panagiotis.loukopoulos@strath.ac.uk
We are grateful to Daisy Chou (EFMA discussant), Douglas Cumming, Marc Goergen, Bjorn Jorgensen, Ludovic
Phalippou, David Newton, Markus Schmid, and Silvio Vismara for their helpful comments. We would also like to thank
the seminar participants from Southampton Business School as well as participants from the PhD Conference at the
University of Bath. We also thank the Irish Accounting and Financial Association (IAFA) Conference 2018, Young
Finance Scholars (YFS) Conference 2018, and European Financial Management Association (EFMA) Conference 2018
for their valuable feedback.

1
1. Introduction
“Compensation is not the work of a cartel, but it is light years from being an ideal market”
[The Economist, 2016]
The dramatic rise in executive compensation witnessed in public firms over the last decades
has fueled an intense debate on the effectiveness of compensation arrangements. In particular, the
superiority of Chief Executive Officers (CEOs) in the decision making process has raised a
fundamental question: Does the level and composition of compensation contracts elicit the
appropriate effort by senior management, or it is a symptom of agency conflicts at the expense of
shareholders? While a substantial number of studies have examined this question from different
perspectives, the evidence continues to be conflicting (Bebchuk and Fried, 2003; Conyon, 2006;
Gabaix and Landier, 2008; Kaplan, 2008; Murphy, 1999, 2013).
In this longstanding debate, a number of theories have been proposed for the growth of CEO
compensation. One view draws from the “efficient contracting camp” and postulates that the
observed level and composition of compensation is set through an arms-length negotiation, and as
such, it reflects a competitive equilibrium in the market for managerial talent (Murphy and
Zabojnik, 2004, 2010). According to this perspective, compensation levels are simply a reflection of
the demands of a position that requires considerable time, skill, and attention (Kaplan, 2008). In line
with this view, Gabaix and Landier (2008) show that the rise CEO pay is primarily due to increases
in firm size, and interpret this as a natural outcome of an ability-matching mechanism where the
impact of managerial talent is magnified in large firms (Tervio, 2008).
On the other side of the spectrum lies the “managerial power” camp, i.e., those who firmly
believe that the CEO pay process is not determined by competitive market forces but rather by
captive board members catering to rent-seeking, entrenched CEOs (Bebchuk and Fried, 2004;
Kuhnen and Zwiebel, 2009). To support this perspective, they cite as evidence the large and
growing disparity between pay granted to CEO and the compensation of the average worker (Hayes
and Schaefer, 2009), and more often than not, the widening pay gap among the members inside the
boardroom (Kale et al., 2009). Further, numerous studies demonstrate that CEO compensation is
related to a series of unfavorable corporate outcomes, such as excess risk (e.g., Haß et al., 2015;
Kini and Williams, 2012).2

2
In addition to the conflicting empirical evidence, several researchers emphasize that neither camp offers convincing
explanations for the well-documented CEO pay patterns. With respect to the contracting view, Frydman and Jenter
(2010) and Nagel (2010) note that the correlation between size and compensation is sensitive to sample selection and
depends on very strong parameter assumptions. As for the managerial power view, the continuous corporate governance
reforms over the last decades (Holmstrom and Kaplan, 2001) cannot be easily reconciled with the story of increased
CEO pay due to weak corporate governance mechanisms (Kaplan, 2008).

2
In this study, we endeavor to inform this debate by studying the implications of CEO pay on
the survival of firms undergoing Initial Public Offerings (IPOs). A vibrant IPO market is vital for
the development of privately-held, entrepreneurial firms. As such, the survival of IPO stocks
constitutes an appropriate performance measure, as it determines the length of time for young,
entrepreneurial firms continue to have access to external capital, and hence the ability to remain
innovative and competitive in the public arena (Audretsch and Lehmann 2005; Caves, 1998). On
the other hand, the prosperity of IPO issuers is also crucial for stimulating aggregate economic
growth and job creation (e.g., Doidge et al., 2013). Hence, the survival of newly public firms may
further serve as a measure of capital market development, as the mortality of IPOs may lead to
substantial economic and welfare costs (Fama and French, 2004; Bhattacharya et al., 2015;
Catteneo, et al., 2015).
Yet, despite the growing awareness of the importance of IPOs among both academics and
the investor community, most of the theoretical and empirical work on the performance
consequences of corporate pay packages has predominantly focused on mature publicly-traded
firms, giving far less attention to newly-listed firms. This is particularly important, since the extent
to which compensation practices developed in well-established organizations are fully suitable for
the “entrepreneurial nature” of the IPO process is still open to discussion among academics and
practitioners (see Filatotchev and Allcock, 2013). In this respect, IPOs represent a fertile setting for
enhancing our understanding about the implications of executive compensation packages.
Importantly, given that the likelihood of survival reflects the long-term net effect of corporate
decisions on both risk and return, studying the role of executive pay on the mortality of IPO stocks
might enable us to gain a clearer understanding on whether the pay-setting process is driven by
shareholder value or rent extraction considerations.
The main purpose of our identification strategy is to assess whether the survival of an IPO
can be predicted at the IPO date. To do so, we rely on a sample of 1,178 IPO firms that went public
from 2000 to 2012 and track them until 31 December 2017. Then, we utilize their prospectuses and
construct a unique hand-collected data-set that exploits variation in the compensation arrangements
of all executive board members prior to the offering. The advantage of this strategy is that it
considers the pay distribution of the whole management team. This permits us to examine not only
the pay implications about the CEO but also to evaluate the criticisms about the growing disparities
between the compensation of the CEO and the next layer of executive officers.
Building on this idea, our investigation is guided by two opposing hypotheses. According to
the efficient contracting view, we anticipate that higher CEO pay and large pay disparities alleviate
agency conflicts and hence lead to lower failure rates. In contrast, following the arguments of the

3
advocates of the managerial power view, large CEO remuneration or a high pay gap would
represent deviations from optimal contracting schemes, and thus are viewed as contributing factors
to higher failure rates.
We assess the survival profile of IPO issuers by evaluating their survival and hazard
functions. To achieve this, we initially apply the Cox proportional hazard analysis. In line with the
efficient contracting view of compensation, we find that IPO firms with either generously
compensated CEOs or high pay disparities have a lower probability of failure. To get a sense of
economic magnitude, the results imply that, firms with CEO pay (pay gaps) in the 75th percentile
have a failure risk that is, on average, 11.56% (13.20%) lower than the failure risk of firms with
CEO pay (pay gaps) in the 25 th percentile. In terms of survival time, our accelerated failure time
(AFT) models indicate that, on average, the survival of firms with CEO pay (pay gaps) in the 75 th
percentile is increased by 20.23% (28.11%), which translates to an increase of 9.64 (13.39) months
of survival time, compared to firms with CEO pay (pay gaps) in the 25 th percentile. Interestingly,
additional tests on the incentive structure of compensation reveal that our baseline results are driven
by the equity-based components (stock and option award, and other long-term incentive payouts)
rather than the cash-based (salary and bonus) components. This heterogeneous impact is consistent
with the notion that long-term compensation lengthens an executive’s time horizon, rendering its
wealth a function of long-term firm value.
A major challenge in interpreting our results is that the association between our
compensation-based incentive measures and IPO failure rates could be driven by unobservable
factors related to both pay-setting and IPO failure. To alleviate these endogeneity concerns, we
incorporate into our baseline models an array of additional variables that allow us to control for
executive talent, experience, as well the quality of pay-related governance mechanisms.
Furthermore, we employ a two-stage Heckman model and a propensity score approach. Across
these identification strategies, our results are consistent with our baseline inferences.
Further, we examine whether and how the impact of the compensation and tournament
incentives varies in the cross-section. With respect to CEO compensation, we find that the
effectiveness of CEO remuneration packages is pronounced in samples with firms run by CEOs
who are specialists, short-tenured, young, and also founders. Similarly, the impact of CEO pay is
strengthened among firms with low CEO entrenchment and high quality governance mechanisms.
Overall these contingencies suggest that the influence of CEO pay on IPO survival is optimized in
settings that are characterized by low agency conflicts, as predicted by the efficient contracting
camp. Regarding tournament incentives, we find that the negative link between CEO pay and IPO
failure varies in ways predicted by tournament theory, as it is strengthened among firms with higher

4
likelihood of promotion, i.e., when the CEO is not a founder, a generalist, long-tenured, and close to
retirement.
Our paper makes contributions to both the literature and current policy debate on the
efficacy of executive pay schemes. To begin, previous literature has explored whether
compensation-based incentives affect either corporate performance (e.g., Bebchuk et al., 2011;
Chen et al., 2013; Kale et al., 2014) or risk taking behavior (e.g., Kini and Williams, 2012; Goel and
Thakor, 2012). These studies focus on various means to an end. We add to this line of inquiry by
focusing on the end itself: the ability of the firm to survive. Further, given the aforementioned
advantages of firm survival over traditional measures of risk and return, our focus on the IPO
aftermarket may offer a sharper test on the drivers and implications of compensation arrangements.
Particularly, since it suggests that, at least in newly listed firms, a meaningful part of executive
compensation is largely driven by a competitive market for talent or intra-firm tournament
incentives rather than weak boards, it adds to the ongoing debate concerned with the effectiveness
of internal incentive structures.
In addition, our work is related with previous studies focusing on the interrelationships
between corporate governance and aftermarket performance of the IPO firm. This line of research
has identified a wide range of governance mechanisms that may reduce the extent of adverse
selection and moral hazard problems, including board characteristics (Cohen and Dean, 2005;
Chemmanur and Paeglis, 2005), the strategic role of founder CEOs (Certo et al., 2001;
Nelson, 2003), and the governance role of early stage investors (Jain and Kini, 2000). To the best of
our knowledge, this study is the first to establish a link between compensation-based managerial
incentives (i.e., CEO compensation and CEO pay gap) and the long-term prospects of newly-public
firms. By doing so, it adds a new dimension to the nascent literature concerned with the influence of
governance factors on the decision of IPO issuers to delist.
Our work is also closely related to a limited number of studies that examine the association
between executive incentives and IPO outcomes. Lowry and Murphy (2007) and Chahine and
Goergen (2011) consider whether IPO options grants relate to underpricing, while Certo et al.
(2003) study the impact of options on IPO valuation. These studies focus on the price discovery
process, and particularly, on the initial reactions of investors with regard to equity-based incentives
at the time of the IPO. Our study differs along two primary dimensions. First, by investigating the
link between compensation-based incentives and firm survival we acknowledge that actual ability
or effort as reflected in the level and structure of compensation arrangements, rather than solely
investor’s perceptions, is also relevant for ensuring the firm’s long-term viability. Second, we
document that not only the CEO performance-based incentives matter for assessing the prospects of

5
an IPO, but also the promotion-based incentives of the lower ranked executives. In doing so, we
provide a more complete picture of how the internal incentive structures of young ventures and
entrepreneurial firms can serve as an effective governance tool.
Overall, our findings are relevant to owners and business executives, as they imply that
internal incentive structures at the time of the IPO can help to better assess the survival profile of
the firm, and hence, how long it can raise funding from public markets. At the same time, our study
is of interest to governments, regulators, and policy makers, because it indicates that, to the extent
that the survival of IPOs helps to stimulate and sustain an innovative culture, the effectiveness of
corporate compensation arrangements should also affect the prosperity and growth of the aggregate
economy.
The rest of the study is organized as follows. The subsequent section discusses the
hypothesis development. Section 3 provides an overview of the sample selection procedure and
outlines the survival analysis methodology. Section 4 presents preliminary statistics and the
empirical findings of the impact of total CEO compensation and firm pay disparities on the
probability of failure and time to survive of IPO firms in periods subsequent to the offering.
Sections 5 and 6 provide several robustness and endogeneity tests. Section 7 analyzes the
differential impact of CEO compensation and tournament incentives across several governance and
CEO characteristics. Section 8 concludes the paper.

2. Related Literature and Hypothesis Development


The purpose of this section is to critically analyze what causes the observed trends in
executive pay and to discuss its potential effects in the context of IPO survivability. In doing so, our
discussion is revolved around CEO pay, given that CEOs hold ultimate responsibility for all aspects
of corporate performance (Aggrawal and Samwick, 2003; Bebchuk and Fried, 2004). However,
high CEO pay could also result in large pay disparities within the boardroom. To the extent that
such disparities affect the incentives and behavior of the whole top management team, CEO pay
should not be considered in isolation but rather in conjunction with the remuneration of the other
members of the top management team (Lazear 1989; Landier et al., 2009; Acharya et al., 2011).
With this in mind, we organize our discussion on the implications of CEO compensation as
well as the associated pay disparity on IPO survival based on the two dominant views of executive

6
compensation, namely, the efficient contracting view and the managerial power view (Frydman and
Jenter, 2010).3

A. Efficient Contracting View of Performance-Based Compensation Incentives


According to the efficient-contracting view, the observed level and composition of CEO
pay is shaped by an efficient process, which is presumably driven by competitive market forces.
Proponents of the efficient contracting view of compensation advocate that chief executives are
paid the going fair-market rate. In this respect, high compensation levels reflect incentive structures
that aim to retain highly-skilled managers, reward managerial ability and effort, and motivate
managers to optimize firm value. In support of this idea, several prominent studies argue that pay
design is the outcome of a process that reflects a positive assortative matching mechanism, and the
scarcity of CEO talent or CEO effort.
For instance, Gabaix and Landier (2008) develop a theory based on the effect of firm size on
the demand for CEO talent and show that the growth in the aggregate value of the median S&P 500
firm can explain the entire growth in CEO pay from 1980 to 2013. The authors view this size-pay
relation as consistent with the notion that more talented CEOs match with larger firms, where their
value added is greater. Chang et al. (2010) argue that CEO pay reflects differences in ability or at
least, for labor market opportunities, as they show that upon CEO departure, higher CEO’s prior
pay is associated with negative stock price reaction and with higher probability of subsequent labor
market success. Similarly, Falato et al. (2015) proxy for ability or talent using reputation and
educational degrees and find these credentials to be positively related to pay, whereas Engelberg et
al. (2013) show that CEO’s personal connections with high-ranking executive and directors in other
firms is an important driver of pay premium, as such contacts help managers to improve firm value.

Efficient Contracting View of Tournament-Based Compensation Incentives


The literature discussed above has predominantly focused on the CEO but usually does not
take into account the incentives of the executives at the next level down the corporate ladder. In
addition to facing the traditional performance-based incentives (i.e., cash and equity remuneration
schemes), non-CEO executives respond to incentives stemming from the opportunities from
promotion to the higher level of corporate hierarchy – i.e., the CEO position (Green and Stokey,
1983; Baker et al, 1988). Towards this direction, Lazear and Rosen (1981) were the first to
3
Edmans, et al., (2017) and Murphy (2013), propose an additional perspective that shapes executive pay, that is,
institutional forces such as innovations in legislation, disclosure requirements, accounting treatments and tax treatment.
In this study, we focus on the debate between the efficient contracting view and the rent extracting view since this
approach leads to more clear predictions about the performance implications of pay.

7
demonstrate analytically that the increase in compensation that a senior executive would obtain
from being CEO serves as a powerful incentive that motivates each executive to outperform its rival
executives in order to increase the likelihood of becoming the firm’s next CEO.
In fact, as the difference between the CEO and the other subordinate executives increases,
the promotion prize becomes larger and the incentive to be promoted to the CEO becomes stronger,
thereby creating intense competition among non-CEO executives (Prendergast, 1999). In such a
tournament scheme, agents have strong incentives to perform well and expend higher effort,
because the best relative performer wins and will receive the tournament price, which includes
higher pay, more privileges and greater prestige (Murphy, 1999). At the same time, this behavior
increases the firm’s output and maximizes shareholder value (Lazear and Rosen 1981; Rosen,
1986).
Rank-order tournaments are schemes of relative performance evaluation that are commonly
used to explain the observed large pay gaps between the CEO and the next-highest executive (e.g.,
Bognanno, 2001). Importantly, they are regarded as optimal labor contracts because the pay
disparities between the CEO and the other senior executives are aimed at a better alignment of the
interests of principals and agents. In this respect, they provide a solution to the agency problems
emanating from monitoring issues, especially in firms where agency costs of managerial discretion
can be hazardous (Henderson and Fredrickson, 2001). An early examination of the pay distribution
within the top management team supporting this idea is provided by Main et al. (1993). More
recently, Lee et al. (2008), Kale et al. (2009), and Chen et al. (2011) focus on the pay differential
between the CEO and senior executives and collectively document that corporate tournament
incentives are positively associated with firm performance. 4 Also, it is interesting to note that Burns
et al. (2017) show that the positive association between internal tournament incentives and firm
performance (value) is a cross-country phenomenon.
Taken together, the above theoretical and empirical evidence imply that the presence of a
large CEO pay or pay gap between the CEO and the other senior executives represents an efficient
pay-setting process, which in turn implies lower agency costs, higher productivity, and
consequently the long-term health (viability) of a firm.

4
Masulis and Zhang (2013) provide an additional but consistent with the optimal contracting framework explanation
for the existence of large pay gaps. Particularly, they argue that differences in talent, ability, and effort between the
CEO and the subordinate senior executives may also explain the observed corporate pay disparities. Consistent with this
productivity-based explanation of pay disparities, Chang et al. (2010) find that firms with CEO departures characterized
by high pay disparity experience negative stock price responses around the announcement of the departure. The authors
interpret this finding as consistent with the view that financial markets tend to associate CEO pay disparity with CEO
managerial contribution.

8
H1: Efficient Contracting Hypothesis. The level of CEO pay as well as the magnitude of pay gap
between the CEO and the other executives is positively associated with the IPO survival.

B. Managerial Power View of Performance-Based Compensation Incentives


In contrast to the optimal contracting school of thought, the managerial power view asserts
that high CEO pay does not reflect a competitive equilibrium in the market for managerial talent,
neither does it reflect incentives designed to optimize firm value. Instead, this view postulates that
because managers are self-interested, they have their own agenda, and accordingly adds a new
element to the agency problem: the ability of executives to influence both the level and composition
of their own compensation packages, often (if not invariably) at the expense of other executives and
the shareholders (Core et al., 1999; Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2001; Bebchuck et al., 2002;
Bebchuk and Fried, 2003, 2004).
The potential adverse consequences of this rent extraction perspective can be quite
substantial if one considers that the cost to shareholders may be far greater than the direct cost of
excess compensation. As Edmans et al. (2017) note, if market forces permit large deviations from
efficient contracting, pay contracts will be ineffective in providing sufficient motives to exert effort
or refrain from empire building, short termism and manipulation. In such a case, the losses in terms
of firm value can be quite large. This assertion is formally developed in the theoretical framework
of Kuhnen and Zwiebel (2009) where the manager can extract hidden pay, which in turn may either
hinder the shareholders’ ability to assess the manager’s contribution and reduce profits. 5
The literature has documented several ways through which CEOs can exercise their power
in order to interfere in compensation arrangements and extract economic rents. Specifically,
managerial rent extraction implies that executive pay will be higher mainly through forms of pay
that are less observable or more difficult to value, such as stock options (Murphy, 2002; Hall and
Murphy, 2003; Aboody et al., 2006; Hayes et al., 2012), perquisities (Jensen and Meckling, 1976;
Jensen, 1986; Bebchuk and Fried, 2004), pensions (Stefanescu et al., 2018), and severance pay
(Yermack, 2006; Goldman and Huang, 2014). Consequently, even if the level of compensation is
not excessive; it is arguably more difficult to justify the widespread use of stealth compensation as
an efficient outcome of an optimal contract.6

5
What is perhaps more interesting in this model, is that rent extraction through executive pay can survive even in
equilibrium, because firing is costly and any CEO replacement is also expected to extract rents.
6
Additionally, the rent extraction view predicts that executive pay will be less sensitive to performance and this
phenomenon is most prevalent when corporate governance is weak (Yermack, 1996; Fahlenbrach, 2009). This is
particularly important in the managerial labor market because poorly governed firms (and hence higher compensation)

9
Managerial Power View of Tournament-Based Compensation Incentives
Apart from the inefficiently high levels of compensations, it is important to understand why
a large pay gap between the CEO and the other executives might not serve the interests of the
shareholders. Several researchers predict analytically and empirically that while agents respond to
tournament incentives by putting forth greater effort, this behavior may lead to dysfunctional
responses (e.g., Baker, 1992; Holmstrom and Milgrom, 1991; Jacob and Levitt, 2003). The specific
negative consequences of employing a tournament may range from cheating (see Berentsen and
Lengwiler, 2004) and manipulating or misreporting performance (Park, 2017;Armstrong et al.,
2013) to sabotage of other competitors (Lazear, 1989). As Bainbridge (2004) argue, as the
executive pay widens, executives are more likely to resort unethical behavior to win the tournament
prize.
Existing literature also suggests that stronger tournament incentives are associated with
higher propensity to engage in fraudulent activities (Wang and Winton, 2002; Haß et al., 2015) and
greater likelihood if securities action lawsuits (Shi et al., 2015) as well as greater risk-taking (e.g.,
Goel and Thakor, 2012; Kini and Williams, 2012) in order to increase the likelihood of winning the
tournament (i.e., getting the promotion). However, such actions alter the firm’s risk profile, and
eventually can be detrimental to a firm if executives take excessive risks. This is evident by
Bebchuk et al. (2011), who find that larger tournament prizes (i.e., higher pay gaps) are associated
with lower performance and Chen et al. (2013) who show that pay disparity is positively associated
with the implied cost of equity.
Collectively, the managerial power view postulates that large CEO pay reflects excessive
compensation and an insufficient link between CEO awards and performance, whereas large
disparities may also promote greater risk-taking at the expense of the shareholders.

H2: Managerial Power Hypothesis. The level of CEO pay as well as the magnitude of pay gap
between the CEO and the other senior executives is positively associated with the IPO failure risk.

3. Sample Selection and Methodology


Our sample selection starts with retrieving all the initial public offerings (IPOs) between
2000 and 2012 from Thomson One Banker database. Following the common filtering criteria in the
IPO literature, we eliminate financial institutions, American Depository Receipts (ADRs), closed-
end funds, unit offers, and any other non-common stock type of shares. In addition, we eliminate

impose a negative externality on better governed firms, inducing inefficiently higher levels of compensation in all firms
(Acharya and Volpin, 2010; Dicks, 2012).

10
any IPOs with offer price below $5. We obtain IPO background and issuance information from the
SDC, including the issue data, offer price, total proceeds raised, whether the firm is backed by
venture capital and the prestige of underwriters. For underwriter prestige ranking, the study
employs Loughran and Ritter’s (2004) measures of underwriter quality. Accounting data are
retrieved from the Compustat database, and public trading prices are from the Center for Research
and Security Prices (CRSP).
Data regarding the executive compensation (e.g. salary, bonus, restricted stock, options,
non-equity incentive plans, and total compensation) of the CEOs of IPOs are carefully hand
collected from firm prospectuses (S-1) on Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC)’s EDGAR.
Also, we use the IPO prospectuses to construct the biographical profiles of CEOs (e.g., CEO
duality, tenure) and the BoardEx database for information about their work experience. After
merging the data from the above databases and eliminating observation with missing values, our
final sample consists of 1,178 IPO firms.
Since our survival window is five years, we track these IPO issuers until 31 December 2017
to determine whether they were delisted or not.7 CRSP provides delisting codes to indicate the
status of the issuing firm, specifically, whether the firm is still trading and specific reasons for
delisting, such as failure to meet listing standards, corporate governance violation, liquidation,
insufficient capital, bankruptcy, etc. Based on the CRSP delisting codes, we distinguish the IPO
firms into five groups based on their 3-digit CRSP delisting code: acquired (200-290), exchanged
(300-390), liquidated (400-490), dropped (500-591) and survived. Following prior literature (Jain
and Kini, 2000; Gounopoulos and Pham, 2018) survived firms are defined as firms that continue to
operate independently as public corporations and appeared on the CRSP tape from the IPO date to
at least five years after the offering. Our sample of 1,178 IPOs is comprised of 814 survived firms,
274 acquired firms, 82 dropped firms, 6 exchanged firms and 2 liquidated firms. 8

4. Survival Analysis Methodology


4.1.1 Cox Proportional Hazard Model
To assess our hypotheses, and specifically, whether the survival profile of our IPO firms is a
function of executive compensation incentives we apply both nonparametric and semi-parametric
approaches. To this end, we employ survival analysis in order to obtain non-parametric estimates of
survival and hazard probabilities Survival analysis is a statistical technique for analyzing the

7
For example, a firm that went public in 2000 is tracked for 17 years compare to 5 years for a firm that went public in
2012.
8
Our sample has no firms whose delisting codes are 600-900.

11
expected duration of time until one or more events happen (such as the death of a public firm) and
has been used extensively in prior research to examine determinants of IPO survival (e.g., Keasey et
al., 1990; Hensler et al., 1997; Jain and Kini, 2000; Carpentier and Suret, 2011; Alhadab et al.,
2014).
Its primary benefit over ordinary least squares (OLS) and the binary dependent variable
model is that it allows us to take into account the length of time that a company survives.
Additionally, it is particularly useful to censored data, i.e., events (delisting of IPOs) that have
either different time horizons or have not yet occurred. In our study, the survival time of IPO firms
is right censored because many firms that went public are still trading. Also, the time window is
different for each firm depending on the IPO date. For instance, a firm that went public in 2000 is
tracked for 17 years compared to 5 years for a firm that went public in 2000.
Technically, the hazard function is the conditional failure rate given that the firm has
survived up to the specified time. If well compensated CEOs can reduce the failure risk, the hazard
function for IPO firms with a high compensated CEO will remain below that of firms with a low
compensated CEO. We estimate the hazard functions for the two groups of IPO firms using the
Nelson-Aalen estimator, which is defined as:

̂( ) ∑ (1)

where is the number of failed firms at time and is the number of firms at risk at time .
The survival function provides the probability that the firm survives up to a particular time.
If high compensated CEOs can enhance the survivability of issuing firms, the survival function
curve of firms with a high compensated CEO will be above that of firms with a low compensated
CEO. We estimate the survival rates of the two groups of IPO firms using the Kaplan-Meier
estimator which is a non-parametric maximum likelihood method and is defined as:

̂( ) ∏ (2)

where ̂( ) is the probability of being listed at time , is the number of failed firms at time and
is the number of firms at risks at time . In addition, we use the log-rank test for testing the
statistical differences between the estimated survival curves of IPO firms with a high compensated
CEO and those with a low compensated CEO.

12
Then, we employ the Cox proportional hazard model. The advantage of this model over
other hazards models is that the baseline hazard function follows the firm over a specified time
period and focus at which point in time it experiences an event of interest (see for example, Allison,
2000). We estimate the following model:

( ) ( ) (3)

where ( ) is the baseline hazard function, and is the time to failure (i.e., the duration to the
delisting date). The dependent variable is a dichotomy variable that indicates the failure risk (i.e.,
whether the firm delists within 5 years after the IPO); thus, a negative (positive) coefficient that an
increase in the managerial incentives leads to a decrease (increase) in the probability of delisting in
the subsequent periods. The hazard ratio for each independent variable is computed as the
exponentiated coefficient for the variable. It measures the increase in failure risk for a unit increase
in the value of the independent variable. If the hazard ratio is above one, then an increase in the
covariate increases the failure rate, while a hazard ratio of less than one indicates than an increase in
the covariate decreases the failure rate.9
The compensation-based incentives variables are total CEO compensation and firm pay gap.
We define the total CEO compensation as the natural logarithm of the sum of salary, bonus, stock
and option awards, non-equity incentives, and other long-term incentive pay-outs. Also, we measure
the strength of tournament incentives (pay disparity) as the natural logarithm of the difference
between CEO’s total compensation and the median of the other senior executives (Kale et al.,
2009).10 11

4.1.2 Accelerated Failure Time (AFT)


For robustness check and comparative purposes, we also use another survival model, the
Accelerated Failure Time (AFT), to examine the determinants of the survival rates. In contrast with
Cox (1972) model, the AFT method allows the impact of the independent variables on survival time
to vary over the post-IPO period depending on the length of time since listing (Hensler et al., 1997;

9
In our case, we use continues variables, thus, the estimated change in the hazard rate for a unit increase in the
independent variable is 100*(hazard ratio-1) (Allison, 2000; Jain and Martin, 2005; Alhadab et al., 2014).
10
We use the top three executives including the CEO rather than the four top executives that is common in the literature
because the average number per year of non-CEO executives in our sample period is close to three. However, our
results are robust if we use the top four executives for the median estimation whenever possible.
11
When the compensation gap is negative, we monotonically transform all observations by adding a constant equal to
the absolute value of the minimum gap. However, our results remain the same if we do not apply this transformation.

13
Jain and Kini, 2000). The AFT model is typically expressed in terms of log-linear function with
respect to survival time (e.g., Hensler et al., 1997; Bradburn et al., 2003):

( ) (4)

where , …., are parameters to be estimated, , …., are covariates, and is the error term
with a specific distributional form which determines the regression model. We estimate the
following specific model where the natural logarithm of the time to delist (survival time) is
presented as a linear function of the covariates 12:

( ) (5)

where ( ) is the natural logarithm of the survival time or time to failure (measured in months).
In this model, the exponential of the coefficient is an ‘acceleration factor’ also known as the time
ratio. Time ratio measures the extent to which changes in the independent variables speed up or
slow down the occurrence of delisting. A positive coefficient implies a time ratio above one,
indicating that an increase in the covariate increases survival time, while a negative coefficient (a
time ratio below one) shows that an increase in the covariate decreases survival time (Bradburn et
al., 2003; Espenlaub et al., 2012).

4.2 Control Variables


We control for various firm, CEO and offering characteristics that are suggested by prior
literature as determinants of IPO survival. Nelson (2003) finds that a CEO who also is the founder
of the firm at the time of IPO increases firm’s valuation. Accordingly, Adams et al. (2005)
document that CEOs who are not the chairman of the board have less influence over board
decisions and the firm is less likely to survive. In line with these studies, Gounopoulos and Pham
(2018) suggest that IPO firms with CEO-Chairman (CEO Duality), CEO-Founder and CEOs with
high tenure survive longer in the following years. Thus, we include CEO duality, tenure and CEO-
Founder to account for these CEO characteristics.
Also, we include proceeds and initial returns to account for the positive effects of firm size
and underpricing on IPO survival as documented by Schultz (1993) and Hensler et al. (1997).

12
AFT models being the parametric models require specific underlying distribution (i.e., Weibull, Gama, lognormal
etc.). Unreported results for Akaike’s Information Criterion (AIC) identify Weibull as the most appropriate distribution
with the lowest AIC value.

14
Schultz (1993) finds a positive relation between reputable underwriters and IPO survival, while Jain
and Kini (2000) indicate that the involvement of venture capitalists (VCs) in the IPO process
improves the survival profiles of IPO firms. Another strand of literature (e.g., Jain and Martin,
2005; Bhattacharya et al., 2015) document that IPO firms audited by high-quality accounting firms
survive longer in the following years. Furthermore, Certo et al. (2001) support the opinion that the
presence of venture capital seen to affect outcomes in IPO studies. To capture the impact of these
financial intermediaries on IPO survival, we include the following indicator variables: underwriter,
VC, and Big 4 Auditor. Additionally, we add financial leverage to control for the firm’s borrowing
capacity based on the finding of Demers and Joos (2007) that the leverage ratio of IPO firms is
positively related to the probability of failure.
With respect to investment policies, Jain and Kini (2008) suggest that the probability of IPO
survival is positively associated with R&D expenditures, whereas Demers and Joos (2007)
document that R&D expenses is expected to provide an indication of the firm’s riskiness. Following
these studies, we control for the impact of strategic investment on IPO survival by including the
intensity of R&D and capital expenditures. In addition, Gounopoulos and Pham (2018) find a
positive association between survivorship and profitability, hence, we account for the effect of firm
performance by including the earnings per share (EPS). We consider measures of market conditions
in the IPO market (market return) as well as industry conditions (industry concentration) and board
governance quality. Lastly, we control for the presence of Internet, Technology firms, and firms
incorporated in Nasdaq.

5. Empirical Results
This section reports the results of our analysis on IPO survival. Firstly, we present summary
statistics along with graphical evidence using the Nelson-Aalen and Kaplan-Meier methods to
estimate the hazard and survival functions. Next, we focus on the duration analysis results using the
Cox proportional hazard model as well as the Accelerate Failure Time (AFT) approach.

5.1 Descriptive Statistics


Table 1 utilizes the trading status of our sample firms and categorizes them into five groups:
dropped, acquired, exchanged, liquidated, and survived firms. Then, it presents how the
distributional variability of these sub-samples varies by year and by industry. Panel A shows that
tracking for five years after the issue date, 69.10% of the firms survived, 23.26% acquired, 6.96%
failed, 0.51% exchanged and 0.17% liquidated. Finally, we find that approximately 30% of IPOs
either dropped or are acquired within five years after the offering.

15
Panel B repeats the same exercise by year. The number of IPOs tends to decline after
economic crises, as indicated by the Dot-com bubble and the Credit Crunch in 2000 and 2007,
respectively. The percentage of firms being dropped is highest for firms going public in 2000
(12.12%) and 2008 (11.76%). This is consistent with the economic crises in those years, which had
an adverse impact on the IPO firms’ survivability. The percentage of firms being acquired is highest
in 2012 (34%) and lowest in 2008 (6%). Further, the proportion of exchanged and liquidated firms
is less than 1% in the most cases, except from 2008 where it were approximately equal to 6%.
Generally, more than half of the firms survive for at least five years after the IPO. The highest
proportion of survived firms is found in 2005 (76%) while the lowest proportion of survived firms
is in 2012 (62%).
Panel C classifies IPO firms in sectors and reveals a relatively high concentration of IPOs in
the computer equipment and services as well as in the chemical products sectors. The industry with
the highest percentage of acquired IPOs is scientific instruments (26.67%) followed by electronic
equipment (26.23%). Furthermore, entertainment services (13.33%) and manufacturing (9.38%) are
the industries with the highest percentage of dropped firms, while those with the lowest proportion
are food products and wholesale and retail trade. It is worth noting that the percentage of survived
firms in all industries is no less than 57%. Particularly, the proportion of survived firms is highest in
entertainment services (86.67%) and transportation and public utilities (78.57), whereas the lowest
percentage of survived firms is found in the manufacturing (57.29%) and computer and equipment
services (61.57%).
Panel D of Table 1 demonstrates the cumulative survival rates (using the non-parametric
Kaplan-Meier method) of our sample as well as for IPOs with high and low compensated CEOs for
one, three, and five years after IPO. The findings present a substantial degree of variation dependent
on the year of issue with one-year survival rates ranging from 88.23% to 100%. In particular,
survival rates drop from the maximum of 100% recorded in 2001 to 88% in 2008. It is also worth
noting that cumulative survival rates over one, three and five years after IPO are higher for IPO
firms with high remunerated CEOs in most of the years (except for the years 2004, 2008, and 2010).
Panel A of Table 2 compares the values of our compensation variables over the three
samples (overall sample, firms with high and low compensated CEOs). Over the sample period, the
mean total CEO remuneration is $1.297 million which is comparable with the corresponding
descriptive results of Gounopoulos and Pham (2018). The average gap between CEO pay and the
median pay of other executive members is $0.9 million, which is considerably lower than that of
studies focusing on seasoned firms (e.g., Kale et al., 2009; Vo and Canil, 2016). Also, the median
compensation of others executives is around $0.5 million. Regarding the CEO pay components,

16
salary accounts for the largest proportion of total CEO compensation (52%), followed by option
awards (17%) and bonus (16%). Finally, high remunerated CEOs have high pay packages mainly
due to bonuses and option awards.
Panel B of Table 2 describes the average CEO profile for the overall sample and the low and
high compensation sub-samples. On average, a CEO is 50 years old with tenure of approximately 4
years. 30% of CEOs are also founders of the firm and 54% hold a chair position (CEO duality). In
addition, it seems that firms prefer to hire new CEOs with general skills. In line with the
compensation literature, CEOs in the high compensation sub-sample tend to have more experience
or knowledge than otherwise, as documented by their higher age. Furthermore, consistent with the
prior literature (Custodio et al., 2012; Gounopoulos and Pham, 2018) firms are willing to provide
more generous remuneration packages to generalists as well as to CEOs who are also the chairman
of the board. In contrast, the proportion of founder-CEOs is considerably lower than professional
CEOs in the high-compensation regime, which is consistent with the notion that founder-CEOs
have intrinsic motivation, and hence, lower dependence to external incentives.
Panel C presents the firm and offering characteristics for the overall sample and the sub-
samples of firms with high and low remunerated CEO. On average, the IPO firms are relatively
young (15 years) and around half of them are ventured-backed. In addition, 40% of firms are in a
high-tech industry and almost 10% are characterized as internet stocks. Around 35% of the IPOs are
underwritten by top-tier investment banks and 47% are audited by the big four. Moreover, the
average IPO first-day returns are 22.22%, while the vast majority of the firms (72%) are
incorporated in Nasdaq.
Panel C of Table 2 suggests a positive pay-performance link between accounting-based
profitability (EPS) and remuneration, which is consistent with the well-documented finding that
CEO pay reflects —at least partially— a reward for prior or contemporaneous performance (Coles
et al., 2006). It also confirms the idea, that larger and older firms provide more generous
remuneration packages than small firms (e.g., Conyon, 2006; Gabaix et al., 2008). It is also worth
mentioning that these firms are able to attract more reputable investment banks (underwriters), but
have less backing by venture capitalists. Regarding the initial returns, it seems that the market
perceives high compensation CEOs as better skilled and more capable than low compensated CEOs,
as the former are associated with lower underpricing.
In Panel D (Table 2), we present a list of ten IPO issuers along with the CEO compensation
and their trading status in the high and low compensation sub-samples, respectively. This list is
provided only for illustrative purposes; nonetheless, it is suggestive that higher CEO compensation
is related with greater chances of IPO survivability. Finally, it should be noted that we obtained

17
similar results when we repeated the above analysis in sub-samples based on the median of pay gap
as a cut off. For brevity, we do not report this analysis, but it is available upon request.

5.2 Plots of Hazard and Survival Functions


To investigate more thoroughly whether executive remuneration can be regarded as a
predictor of IPO survival, in this section, we estimate the hazard and survival functions for both
firms with high compensated (high firm gaps) CEOs and with low compensated (low firm gaps)
CEOs. The plots of Nelson-Aalen cumulative hazard and Kaplan-Meier survival estimates are
provided in Figure 1 and Figure 2, respectively. In Figures 1a and 2a, the hazard function of IPO
firms with a high compensated CEO (large pay disparity) are below than that of firms with a low
compensated CEO (low pay disparity), respectively. The gaps widen slightly but steadily as the
length of time following the issue year increases. On the other hand, as it can be seen from Figures
1b and 2b, the survival functions of IPO firms with high compensated CEO (large pay disparity) are
consistently above that of firms with a low compensated CEO (low pay disparity). Also, the gap
between the survival functions for both total compensation and firm gap widens after 2005.
In detail, the probability of surviving 5 years after the issue is around 83% (79%) for firms
with a high compensated CEO (high firm gap), compared to 71% (52%) for firms with a low
compensated CEO (low firm gap). The survival probability after 10 years following the issue
decreases considerably for firms with low pay gap (low compensated CEO) 47% (45%), while this
probability is 59% (62%) for firms with high pay gap (high compensated CEO). Furthermore, the
log-rank test for equality of survival functions shows that the estimated survival curves of the four
groups are different at the 1% significance level. Overall, the plots of survival and hazard functions
document that IPO firms with a high compensated CEO (large pay gap) have a more attractive
survival profile compared to firms with low compensated CEOs (low pay gaps).

5.3 Estimation of the Cox Proportional Hazards Model on Total CEO Compensation
Table 4 assesses the impact of total CEO compensation on the probability of IPO survival
using Cox proportional hazards model after controlling for various firm and CEO attributes that
may influence the IPO long-term prospects. Specification (1) documents a strong and significant
negative coefficient on total CEO compensation, suggesting that IPO firms with better remunerated
CEOs have a lower probability of failure. This finding supports the efficient contracting hypothesis
that IPO firms with a high compensated CEO have better chances of survival than IPOs with a low
compensated CEO. The economic effect is significant: the magnitude of the coefficient estimate

18
suggests that firms with CEO pay in the 75th percentile have a failure risk that is, on average,
11.56% lower than the failure risk of firms with CEO pay in the 25 th percentile. 13
In specifications (2) and (3) we examine the possibility that the coefficient of the total CEO
compensation masks information embedded in the individual remuneration components. As
expected, the decomposition of total compensation into its cash and equity components reveals that
the link between compensation and IPO mortality is driven by the long-term portion of
remuneration. Consequently, the results based on both the level and structure of CEO compensation
support the efficient contracting hypothesis.
As for the results about the remaining control variables, their sign and significance is
generally consistent with prior literature in all specifications. In particular, we find that firms with
CEOs who also serve as chairman tend to have a lower probability of failure, which is in line with
the study of Adams et al. (2005). By contrast, managers who have been serving as CEOs for many
years (CEO tenure) have a higher probability of failure. Additionally, firms with higher IPO first-
day returns tend to have higher failure risks in subsequent periods. In contrast to the findings of Jain
and Kini (2000), our results suggest than venture-backing is not significantly associated to IPO
mortality.
Moreover, we do not find a significant relation between IPO survival and profitability. The
results regarding proceeds and its impact on IPO survival contradict with the prior literature (e.g.,
Espenlaub et al., 2012), as there is not a statistically significant association with survivorship. With
respect to underwriters and big auditors, our results suggest that only top-underwriters are
important, consistent with the prior literature (Bhattacharya et al., 2015; Espenlaub et al., 2016).
Also, we find that well-governed firms as well as firms operating in a low competitive environment
have lower failure risks in periods following the offering. With respect to the investment variables,
capex increases the survival rates, whereas R&D is increases the failure rates (Demers and Joos,
2007); however, only the latter seems is significant.

5.4 Estimation of the Cox Proportional Hazards Model on Total Firm Pay Disparity
Next, we continue our analysis by replacing the total CEO compensation with the firm pay
gap. Specification (1) of Table 5 indicates that, the coefficient on total firm pay gap is negative and
significant at the 5% level. In economic terms, the magnitude of the coefficient estimate suggests
that firms with pay gaps in the 75th percentile have a failure risk that is, on average, 13.20% lower

13
This estimate represents the change in the hazard rate for a firm that moves from the 25th percentile to the
th
75 percentile of the distribution of the natural logarithm of total CEO compensation (13.99-12.76) and is calculated as
follows: exp(-0.10 x 1.23) -1 = -11.56%.

19
than the failure risk of firms with pay gaps in the 25th percentile. 14 Specifications (2) and (3) of
Table 5 provide further insights by examining the impact of short-term and long-term firm pay
disparities on IPO survival. The estimated coefficients on short-term and long-term pay gap produce
different results. In particular, the coefficient on short-term pay gap is positive and insignificant,
while the coefficient on long-term pay gap is negative and significant at 1% level. This suggests
that, as in the case of total compensation, IPO firms with large pay disparities face a lower
probability of failure than those with low pay disparities, and this relationship is largely driven by
the long-term component of pay gap.
With respect to the coefficients and the significance of the remaining covariates, the results
are comparable to those of the previous sub-section across all specification. As a consequence, the
evidence in this section corroborate the efficient contracting hypothesis of executive compensation,
and particularly the tournament view of pay disparities, given that firms with high pay disparities
are more likely to survive after the IPO than firms with low pay disparities among top executives. 15

5.5 Accelerated Failure Time (AFT) Method


The results thus far show that high CEO remuneration and firm tournament incentives
enhance IPO survivability. In this section, we further test this hypothesis, by estimating an AFT
model of IPO time-to-failure. Under this approach, the dependent variable is the natural logarithm
of the survival time or time to failure. Therefore, a positive (negative) coefficient in the independent
variable of interest implies a longer (shorter) period to survive.
In Table 6 we present both the coefficient estimates and the time ratios along with the
associated p-values. The results indicate a positive association between total CEO compensation
and survival time. The coefficient on total remuneration is positive and significant at the 1% level.
On average, the survival time of firms with CEO pay in the 75 th percentile increases by 20.23%,
which translates to an increase of 9.64 months of survival time, compared to firms with CEO pay in
the 25th percentile. Similarly, the coefficient on the firm pay disparity is positive and significant at
the 5% level. Specifically, the survival time of firms with pay gaps in the 75th percentile is increased

14
The change in the hazard rate for a firm that moves in the interquartile range of the distribution of the natural
logarithm of pay gap (13.55-11.78) is calculated as follows: exp(-0.08 x 1.77) -1 = -13.20%.
15
In additional robustness checks we repeated all of our baseline regressions after clustering the standard errors by
either industry or year. We find that both of these choices increase the statistical significance of our variables of interest.

20
by 28.11%, which translates to an increase of 13.39 months of survival time, compared to firms
with pay gaps in the 25th percentile. 16
The results regarding the control variables and their impact on time-to-failure are similar
and opposite in sign to those in the Cox models. Starting from the managerial power proxies, it is
evident that firms run by a CEO who is also a chairman are more likely to survive longer, whereas
the coefficient on CEO tenure is negative and significant. In addition founder-CEOs are positively
but insignificantly related with time to failure.
The coefficient on immediate aftermarket returns is negative (as expected) and statistically
significant. The positive association between underwriter and IPO survival is consistent with
Bhattacharya et al. (2015), who find that IPOs which attract top-tier investment banks have
significantly increased survival times. Contrary to Jain and Kini (2000), we find an insignificant
effect of venture capitalists and Big 4 auditors on survival. Our results also provide support to the
argument that a firm with high board governance quality and industry concentration has much
higher survival time compared to others (Chancharat et al., 2012). Lastly, our findings document
that undertaking risky investment activities (R&D) significantly decreases the survival time of the
issuing firms.

6. Robustness Tests
In this section, we examine the robustness of our results in various ways. We begin by
adopting alternative definitions of the dependent variable (i.e., survivors or non survivors) and then
alternative definitions for the tournament incentives variable.

6.1 Re-classification of M&A Stock Delisting


In the analysis so far, we classified M&As as genuine delistings (non-survivors), thus
treating M&A delistings in the same way as delistings due to other negative reasons. However, not
all M&A-related delistings are necessarily bad news to investors of target companies. Zingales
(1995) shows that the IPO may be the first step in a gradual sale of the company. On the contrary,
Fama and French (2004) note that managers who enjoy private benefits may be reluctant to cede
control unless forced to do so because of financial distress, arguments suggesting that low-quality

16
The first estimate represents the change in the time ratio for a firm that moves from the 25th percentile t the
th
75 percentile of the distribution of the natural logarithm of total compensation and is calculated as follows: exp(0.15 x
1.23) -1 = 20.23%. Similarly, the change in the time ratio for a firm that moves in the interquartile range of the
distribution of the natural of pay gap is calculated as follows: exp(0.14 x 1.77) -1 = 28.11%. This translates into 9.64
months for CEO pay (i.e., 20.23% x 47.64 months for survival time in the 25th percentile) and 13.39 months for CEO
pay gap (i.e., 28.11% x 47.64 months for survival time in the 25 th percentile).

21
IPO firms are more likely to be acquired. Given this ambiguity, we examine the robustness of our
results by treating some delistings due to M&A as “censored survivors”, that is, stocks that are still
considered alive at the end of our study period.
To identify the censored survivors, we acknowledge that, due to poor performance or
financial difficulties, some M&A delistings are typically less attractive to target shareholders than
other M&As. Following Espenlaub et al. (2012, 2016), we seek to differentiate such poorly
performing M&A stocks from the remaining by imposing a performance criterion. To do so, we
locate M&A delisting of well-performing companies either in the year prior to the IPO or in the
year prior to the acquisition by ranking companies on the basis of four performance measures: cash
to total assets, total liabilities to total assets, operating income to total assets, current assets to
current liabilities. Companies that rank above (below) the median based on all four indicators are
considered censored survivors (non-survivors or failures).
Our final alternative definition of survival is concerned with the time to delist after the issue
date. Bhattacharrya et al. (2015) show that, in contrast to the common perception that survival risk
decreases as a firm ages, public firms need to survive up to the age of three years after the IPO
before their survival rate starts diminishing. Based on this finding, the authors suggest that the first
three years after a firm goes public are critical to its long-term survival. Following this suggestion,
we re-evaluate the relationship between managerial incentives and IPO survival by identifying
whether each firms continues to be listed three instead of five years after the issue date.
The results of our robustness checks are shown in columns (1) and (2) of Panel A and B
(Table 6) and are qualitatively similar to the baseline findings. Notwithstanding the above evidence,
one might still argue that true failures are considered as cases of firms that involve delisting only for
negative reasons (i.e., liquidated or dropped). Following Jain and Kini (2000) and Gounopoulos and
Pham (2018) we consider all M&A delistings as survivors, and hence, classify as failures only the
companies that were liquidated or dropped. We continue to find that CEO compensation and CEO
pay gap have a significant negative impact on failure risk (column 3 of Panel A and B). Finally,
column (4) of Panel A and B reveals that the relationship between our managerial incentives
measure and IPO failures continues to be negative, albeit weaker both in economic and statistical
terms.

6.2 Alternative Measures of Tournament Incentives


Thus far, we have used the CEO pay-gap measure of Kale et al. (2009) as our proxy for
tournament incentives, which is calculated as the natural logarithm of the difference between the
CEO’s total compensation and the median value of the compensation of the firm’s other senior

22
executives in a given firm-year. This approach has intuitive appeal as it roughly captures the
increase in a non-CEO executive’s compensation after winning the tournament (i.e., “the typical
size of the prize”). Nonetheless, we acknowledge that the use of the median executive pay could
overestimate (underestimate) tournament incentive if only one or two executives have significantly
higher (lower) compensation and higher (lower) chances of obtaining promotions than the
remaining top executive members (Masulis and Zhang, 2012). To eliminate this measurement error
in our pay disparity measure, we use the natural logarithm of the difference in pay between the CEO
and the mean of the other members of the top management team.
Another potential concern with our main measure of tournament-based incentives is that it
may be highly correlated with a particular major determinant of CEO compensation firm size, since
pay differential tend to increase with firm size (Gabaix and Landier, 2008). A pay-gap-based
promotion metric is therefore subject to the concern that the link between tournament incentives and
IPO failure is contaminated by firm size. To mitigate such concerns, we disentangle the pay
disparity measure from firm size by using an alternative pay disparity measure: the CEO pay slice
(CPS) – calculated as the fraction of the aggregate compensation of the top 3 executives paid to the
CEO (e.g., Bebchuk et al., 2011).
Our results in Panel C (Table 6) remain unchanged as we continue to find significant results
for the mean gap between the CEO and the next layer of executives (at the 5% level), either in the
Cox or in the AFT models. The results in Panel D reveal that the CEO pay slice decreases the
failure rates and increases the survival time. However, only the influence of survival time is
statistically significant (5% level).

6.3.1 Alternative Industry Definitions


In our baseline tests, we use the Fama-French 17 industry classification scheme to control
for time-invariant unobservable industry characteristics that may be driving the association between
compensation-based incentives and IPO survival. To examine the robustness of our main results we
use alternative industry definitions, and specifically, the Fama-French 30 and Fama-French 49 or
exclude the industry fixed effects. In Table 7, we compare the results and obtain negative and
similar coefficients for CEO compensation and pay-gap, which implies that our reported results are
not materially affected by industry membership.

6.4 Correction for Endogeneity and Sample Selection Bias


In studying the relation between managerial incentives and IPO failure, it is critical to
recognize the possibility that our managerial incentives variables are determined endogenously, as

23
they could be determined by factors that are also related to firm survival (e.g., Coles et al., 2006;
Kale et al., 2009; Kini and Williams, 2012).
In the main tests we tried to account for this in several different ways when relating
executive compensation with the delisting decision in subsequent periods. Initially, we used lagged
values (that is, in the fiscal-year prior to the IPO) instead of contemporaneous values (i.e., at the
IPO fiscal-year) of CEO compensation and pay disparities, in order to make the analysis less
vulnerable to simultaneity issues. In addition, we used an extensive set of control variables, and
added fixed effects which capture time-series (year) and cross-sectional (industry) dynamics
between managerial incentives and IPO survival, in order to mitigate the unobserved heterogeneity
problems. To ensure the robustness of our results, we conduct three additional tests: (1) we account
for potentially correlated omitted variables, (2) the two-stage Heckman procedure, and (3) a
propensity score matching procedure.

6.4.1 Omitted Variable Bias


Our measures of executive compensation incentives, the CEO remuneration and the CEO
pay gap, are likely be related to CEO attributes which themselves might be related to IPO failure
risk. Hence, a major concern is that our baseline results might be driven by omitted CEO-related
variables that affect both compensation-based incentives and IPO survival. To address this concern,
we add to our baseline Cox model (Equation (3)) an array of variables associated with CEO risk
aversion, experience, power, talent, and ability. Specifically, we incorporate into our model the:
CEO gender (Faccio et al., 2016), CEO age (Serfling, 2014), CEO power (Adams et al., 2005; Yim,
2013), and educational attainments (whether the CEO has an MBA, PhD, JD or MD).
In addition, it is possible that our measures of managerial incentives will be related to
corporate governance mechanism which may influence the pay-setting process and lead to a higher
or lower failure rates (e.g., Bebchuk et al., 2011). Although, we already control for overall
governance quality in the baseline models, we also consider the quality of the compensation
committee as an additional control (Compensation Committee Quality), given that it is the most
relevant governance mechanism to the design of compensation-based incentives.
As shown in Table 8, results continue to support the efficient contracting hypothesis.
Specifically, we observe negative and significant coefficients on our variables of interest (CEO pay
and CEO pay gap) suggesting that the additional CEO-related and governance variables do not
dampen the effect of CEO compensation and tournament incentives on IPO survival.

24
6.4.2 Two-stage Heckman Process
To further address the issue of endogeneity and self-selection bias associated with our
managerial incentive variables, we estimate a two-stage Heckman-style model (e.g., Espenlaub,
2016). In the first-stage, we estimate two Probit models: one modelling for the likelihood of a given
IPO having a highly compensated CEO, and a second Probit model of the likelihood of having large
disparity in the pay distribution of the top management team. In the second stage of our selection
model, the Inverse Mills Ratios (IMR) from each Probit model is included as additional variable in
our baseline Cox model. The results of the second-stage of the selection model are reported in Panel
B of Table 9. They show that sample selection bias is not a concern in our baseline analysis, as
neither of the two Inverse Mills Ratios is statistically significant at conventional levels.

6.4.3 Propensity Score Matching Procedure


As a final check, we acknowledge that a CEO may be selected due to the fit between the
individual’s preferences and job requirements. For instance, a well-performing firm might have
better chances in attracting experienced and talented CEOs. Alternatively, a conservative (risk-
averse) CEO might prefer to work in a low-growth firm (Hoitash et al., 2016). In these cases, our
results may be subject to sample selection bias. Following Gounopoulos and Pham (2018), we
address the endogenous matching between CEOs and firms by employing a propensity score
matching procedure. This approach permits us to compare the occurrence of delisting within five
years after the IPO between a firm with high managerial incentives (i.e., with high compensated
CEO or large pay disparities) with the occurrence of delisting of the same firm if it had low
managerial incentives.
To do so, we calculate the propensity score, i.e., the conditional probability receiving the
treatment (having a high compensated CEO or large pay disparities) given a firm’s and CEO’s pre-
treatment characteristics, for all the IPOs by estimating a probit model which accounts for the
following variables: Founder, CEO Age, Triality, Generalist, Leverage, Proceeds, Internet,
Compensation Quality Committee, Board Independence, R&D Intensity, Capital Intensity, and year
dummies. Based on the resulting propensity score we match each observation of the treated group
with an observation of the control group and estimate the average treatment effect on the treated
(ATET) in order to assess the influence of high managerial incentives on the delisting probability.
Table 10 presents the results for the ATET on the decision to delist for IPO firms with high
managerial incentives versus those with low managerial incentives. The ATET is negative and
significant at the 1% for CEO compensation, whereas it is also negative and significant at the 10%

25
level for the CEO pay gap. Hence, these finding are consistent with the results presented in the main
analysis. 17

6.5 The Effect of Managerial Incentives on Post-IPO Performance


The results so far univocally support the positive impact of managerial incentives on post-
IPO survival. The probability of survival is a sophisticated measure for IPOs, as it specifically
addresses the issues related to newly listed companies. In addition to that, we assess the evaluation
made by external investors (i.e., the market) by calculating the buy-and-hold (BHAR) returns
adjusted for market value weighted returns as well the post-IPO return volatility for the three years
subsequent to the IPO or until the year before delisting for failed firms.
In Panel A of Table 11 we report the mean of the stock performance for the managerial
incentives subsamples using as a cut off the median of total CEO compensation and CEO pay gap,
respectively. The univariate results indicate that over the 36 month period after the IPO, the
performance differential across the subsamples becomes larger. Additionally, the mean differences
are significant for both compensation-based measures, except for the 12-month BHAR in the pay
disparity subsamples. In Panel B and C we examine whether the managerial incentive measures
affect stock performance in a multivariate setting. The results reveal a similar picture, albeit
statistically weaker.
Similarly, in Panel A of Table 12 we report the mean of post-IPO volatility for the
managerial incentives subsamples using as a cut off the median of total CEO compensation and
CEO pay gap, respectively. The univariate results indicate that over the 36 month period after the
IPO, the risk differentials across the subsamples become larger and are consistently statistically
significant. In Panel B and C we examine whether the managerial incentive measures affect stock
volatility in a multivariate setting. The regression results indicate that the negative association
between the pay measures and post-IPO volatility is significant only within 6 months after the IPO.
Overall, the positive linkage between our incentives measures and stock returns is consistent
with the notion that former reflect scarcity of talent of greater effort, which is in line with Kale et al.
(2009). In contrast, their negative association with return volatility does not support the idea that
greater performance is achieved by undertaking riskier activities (e.g., Kini and Williams, 2012).
Nonetheless, these results corroborate our main findings that greater CEO compensation incentives,
either in absolute or relative form, are associated with greater chances of IPO survival.

17
In untabulated results, we reach to similar conclusions when the dependent variable is survival time instead of failure
risk

26
7. Cross Sectional Variation in Compensation and Tournament Incentives
In this section, we explore cross-sectional variations in the importance of CEO
compensation and firm pay disparities on IPO survivability along different dimensions of corporate
governance and CEO characteristics. An important benefit of this analysis is that it can depict a
more nuanced picture of the effect of these managerial incentives by highlighting settings in which
their effectiveness is pronounced or weakened.

7.1 Governance and Monitoring Mechanisms and Compensations Incentives


Chahine and Goergen (2011) argue that the role of incentivizing tools, such as compensation
rewards, is better understood if it is studied in the context of the firm’s overall corporate
governance. From this perspective, the central question is whether the traditional agency conflicts
that tend to plague the link between CEO pay and firm performance are mitigated by the strength of
corporate governance mechanisms.
We begin our cross-sectional analysis by examining how the role of compensation awards
varies with board independence. Prior empirical studies show that independent boards may help
mitigate the agency problems caused by the divergent objective functions between senior
management and shareholders (Ryan and Wiggins, 2004; Elbadry et al., 2015). Extending this
reasoning to the IPO setting implies that IPO firms with more independent boards are more likely to
ensure the effectiveness of CEO awards as motivating factor, and as a consequence, improve the
survival chances of the firm.
In addition to board independence, we consider the quality of the remuneration committee
due to its crucial role in the pay-setting process. 18 Daily et al. (1998) note that the remuneration
committee should not be simply regarded as a complementary discipline mechanism performing
solely a monitoring role on the growth in executive pay. Instead, it should be viewed as an
organization device setting the appropriate reward structure for board members. As a result,
compensation packages are more effective incentivizing devices in the presence of strong rather
than weak remuneration committees.
Agency theory posits that the balance of power is also determined by the roles undertaken
by the CEO. For instance, a common belief is that combining the CEO-chairman role leads to

18
To do so, we construct a compensation committee quality index taking the first factor of applying principal
components analysis to five proxies of remuneration committee index: the compensation committee independence, the
percentage of outside directors on the compensation committee that were appointed after the current CEO took office, a
dummy variable, equal to one if the majority of outside directors on the compensation committee serve on three or more
other boards, and equal to one otherwise, the natural log of the number of directors serving on the compensation
committee, and the number of compensation committee meetings.

27
managerial power that may be excessive compared to the efficient levels suggested by optimal
contracts (Bebchuk et al., 2002). Similar arguments can be made with other proxies of managerial
power such as triality (i.e., when the CEO is both chairman and president), CEO tenure and CEO
ownership. To capture the common influence of the aforementioned factors we take the first
principal component, which we refer as CEO power. Accordingly, we anticipate that if managers
exercise their excessive power to act at their personal interest at the expense of the shareholders, the
pay-performance link will be weakened, and as such, the beneficial role of CEO pay on IPO
survival will be weakened in firms with powerful CEOs.
We apply a similar reasoning to another choice of organizational form, that is, firms with
founders and non-founders or professional CEOs. Compared to professional CEOs, founder CEOs
are more likely to exhibit entrenchment behavior, thereby influencing negatively post-IPO
economic outcomes (Shleifer and Vishny, 1989; Wasserman, 2003; Adams et al., 2009). However,
research also highlights certain positive aspects of founder-CEO leadership that would imply lower
agency costs. In fact, some researchers underscore the potential of lower agency costs in founder-
led firms due to the stronger psychological attachment and identification within the organization,
greater firm specific skills, and longer investment horizons relative to non-founder CEOs (e.g.,
Certo et al., 2001; Nelson, 2003). As a result, the potential for lower agency costs in founder-led
CEO firms is likely to be particularly beneficial in setting incentive arrangements, since it can
provide management greater flexibility in designing compensation contracts. This conjecture is
supported by empirical evidence showing that founder-CEOs are associated with lower total
compensation due to their stronger intrinsic motivation (He, 2008).

7.2 CEO Characteristics and Compensations Incentives


Murphy and Zaboojnik (2004, 2007) and Frydman (2017) report a secular increase in CEO
pay over the last decades and attribute it (to some extent) to the increasing demand for CEOs with
general managerial skills, whereas Gounopoulos and Pham (2018) confirm the existence of a
similar trend in the IPO market. Despite that the prevalence for hiring generalists CEO is often cited
as evidence for the efficient contracting approach, this practice may also have some undesirable
consequences to organizational outcomes. As opposed to specialist managerial skills which are
focused to particular firms and industries, general managerial skills are readily transferable across
firms and industries (Crossland et al., 2014). This translates into higher mobility in the CEO job-
market, suggesting that wealth of generalists is less contingent on the performance of the firm they
manage.

28
Additionally, given the tendencies of CEOs with varied career experiences to deviate from
pre-determined firm strategies (Hambrick et al., 1993), openness to experiences (Zimmerman,
2008; Boudreau et al., 2001), and preferences to experimentation and change (Crossland et al.,
2014), generalist CEOs will be inclined to undertake risky strategies without much concern about
such choices on the firm’s prospects. Based on this reasoning, Mishra (2014) argues that the risk
profile of a generalist CEO may be misaligned with the interests of the shareholders, thus
exacerbating the agency problems of the firm. As a result, we anticipate that the negative
relationship between CEO pay and IPO failure is weakened (strengthened) for firms with
generalists (specialists) CEOs.
Another managerial trait commonly used in the literature is CEO age or CEO tenure. The
advantage of these variables is that they capture the interplay between career concerns and real
investment decisions. Li et al. (2017) point out that career concerns are of particular importance
because managers are expected to deliberately adjust their investment behavior in order to influence
favorably the labor market perceptions regarding their abilities, reputation and future prospects. The
impact of career concerns is stronger for managers that are further away from retirement or
relatively new to the position, as these agents are more likely to capitalize market’s belief about
their abilities (Gibbons and Murphy, 1992). As a consequence, the effort exerted by younger or low
tenured CEOs is generally higher than that of older CEOs, which implies a greater effectiveness of
compensation schemes for such CEOs.
In Table 13, we break the sample on the median of each of the aforementioned variables and
examine in which subsamples the link between CEO pay and IPO failure is strengthened or
weakened. Our findings suggest a significant and negative association between total CEO
compensation and IPO failure risk that concentrates among firms with CEOs who are young,
specialists, founders, and with short-tenure. Additionally, our results regarding the positive relation
between remuneration and survivorship is pronounced in firms with less powerful CEOs and with
high governance quality.

7.3 Promotion Incentives – Tournament based Promotion Incentives


Kale et al. (2009) argue that, holding constant the magnitude of the tournament prize, the
effectiveness of pay gap as a motivator is strengthened when the probability of promotion to the
CEO position is relatively high. Motivated by this hypothesis, we attempt to obtain a clearer
understanding of the association between pay disparities and IPO survival, by assessing this
association in various settings that might affect the probability of promotion.

29
Yan and Rajagopalan (2004) argue that founder-CEOs possess high firm-specific capital and
are more psychologically committed to the long-term viability of the firm than professional CEOs.
Because their long-term interests are closely tied to their firms’ future prospects, we anticipate that
they are less likely to leave the firm they established. Hence, the probability of promotion for the
lower-ranked executives should be lower in founder-led CEO firms, which in turn, implies a less
negative relationship between pay gap and firm delisting.
On the contrary, CEOs that possess general managerial skills are more likely to take
advantage of a promising job market and undertake job-hopping, since their skills are easily
transferable across firms and industries (Giannetti, 2011). They also more easily recruited, as they
are increasingly sought after in the executive labor market (Custodio et al., 2013). As such, we
expect that the probability of promotion is higher in firms with generalist CEOs, and accordingly,
the negative impact of pay disparity on failure rates to be pronounced in firms run by generalists.
Lastly, prior literature mentions that when a CEO is old, and specifically close to retirement,
the likelihood of promotion for the other top management members should increase (e.,g., Jia,
2017). On the other hand, Kale et al. (2009) suggest that when the CEO is relatively new to the
position (i.e., with low tenure), then the other top executives have lower probability of promotion to
the position of CEO. Thus, our expectations are that the negative association between firm pay gap
and IPO failure is strengthened in firms with CEOs who are relatively old and with a long time in
the office.
In Table 13, we break the sample on the median of each of the aforementioned variables and
examine in which subsamples the link between pay gap and IPO failure is strengthened or
weakened. Consistent with our expectations, firms with high pay disparities tend to have lower
failure rates among firms with CEOs who are also non-founders, generalists, close to retirement,
and with high tenure.

8. Conclusion
The recent financial crisis along with the public outcry over the nature of the pay-setting
process have created a renewed interest on whether top executives meaningfully add value to the
companies they manage, and whether their pay arises in a rent extraction or an optimal contracting
framework. However, although these questions are central ones, empirical resolution of these issues
has been difficult. Murphy (2012) points outs that a possible explanation for the mixed empirical
evidence is that observed compensation arrangements result from both a combination of potentially
conflicting forces – executives’ desire to maximize their rents, and shareholders desire to maximize
firm value. Perhaps, more crucial though, is the fact that much of the debate about executive

30
compensation focuses solely either on the performance or the risk implications of executive
incentives rather than on outcomes that should potentially capture both of these aspects.
In this study, we attempt to address these issues by focusing on the IPO setting. Employing
survival analysis, we document that IPO firms with high compensated CEOs and large pay
disparities and have a lower probability of failure and a longer time to survive. In subsequent tests,
we find that the relationship between CEO pay and IPO survival is strengthened in environment
with lower agency conflicts, whereas the link between pay gap and IPO survival is pronounced
among firms with stronger internal promotion incentives.
Our findings are of relevance to academic researchers, business executives, and potential
investors interested in the ability of entrepreneurial firms to survive in the aftermarket.
Additionally, our focus on the interplay between compensation arrangement and IPO mortality
offers additional insights on the role of managerial incentives and informs the debate about the
controversial role of corporate executive pay. As such, our results might also be useful to
government regulators, policy makers, and other stakeholders interested on the role of governance
arrangements in stimulating growth and innovation.

31
References
Abody, D., Barth, M., and Kasznik, R. 2006. Do Firms Understate Stock-Based Compensation
Expense Disclosed under SFAS 123? Review of Accounting Studies 11, 429-461.

Acharya, V., Myers, S., and Rajan, R. 2011. The Internal Governance of Firms. The Journal of
Finance 66(3), 689-720.

Acharya, V. and Volpin, P. 2010. Corporate Governance Externalities. Review of Finance 14(1), 1-
33.

Adams, R. Almeida, B., and Ferreira, D. 2005. Powerful CEOs and Their Impact on Corporate
Performance. The Review of Financial Studies 18(4), 1403-1432.

Adams, R., Almeida, H., and Ferreira, D. 2009. Understanding the Relationship Between Founder-
CEOs and Firm Performance. Journal of Empirical Finance 16(1), 136-150.
Aggarwal, R. and Samwick, A. 2003. Performance Incentives within Firms: The Effect of
Managerial Responsibility. The Journal of Finance 58(4), 1613-1650.
Ahmad, W., and Jelic R. 2014. Lockup Agreements and Survival of UK IPOs. Journal of Business
Finance and Accounting 41(5-6), 717-742.

Alhadab, M., Clacher, I., and Keasey, K. 2014. Real and Accrual Earnings Management and IPO
Failure Risk. Accounting and Business Research 45(1), 55-92.

Allison, P. 2000. Survival Analysis Using the SAS System: A Practical Guide: SAS Institute
Publishing.

Amini, S., and Keasey, K. 2012. The Failure of Small British Initial Public Offerings on the UK
Alternative Investment Marks: A Research Note on Spatial and Industry Effects. International
Small Business Journal 31(6), 722-733.
Armstrong, C., Larcker, D., Ormazabal, G., and Taylor, D. 2013. The Relation between Equity
Incentives and Misreporting: The Role of Risk-Taking Incentives. Journal of Financial Economics
109, 327-350.
Audretsch, D., and Lehmann, E. 2005. Does the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship
Hold for Regions? Research Policy 34(8), 1191-1202.

Bainbridge, S. 2004. Tournament at the Intersection of Business and Legal Ethics. University St
Thomas Law Journal 1, 909-913.
Baker, G., Jensen, M., and Murphy, K. 1988. Compensation and Incentives: Practice vs Theory.
The Journal of Finance 43(3), 593-616.
Baker, G. 1992. Incentive Contracts and Performance Measurement. Journal of Political Economy
100(3), 598-614.

Bebchuk, L., and Fried, J. 2004. Pay without Performance: Overview of the Issues. Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance 17(4), 8-23.

32
Bebchuk, L., and Fried, J. 2003. Executive Compensation as an Agency Problem. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 17(3), 71-92.

Bebchuk, L., Fried, J., and Walker, D. 2002. Managerial Power and Rent Extraction in the Design
of Executive Compensation. The University of Chicago Law Review 69, 751-846.

Bebchuk, L., Cremers, M., and Peyer, U. 2011. The CEO Pay Slice. Journal of Financial Economics
102(1), 199-221.

Berentsen, A. and Lengwiler, Y., 2004. Fraudulent Accounting and Other Doping Games. Journal
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160(3), 402-415.

Bertrand, M. and Mullainathan, S. 1999. Is There a Discretion in Wage Setting? A Test Using
Takeover Legislation. RAND Journal of Economics 30(3), 535-554.

Bertrand, M. and Mullainathan, S. 2001. Are CEOs Rewarded for Luck? The Ones Without
Principals Are. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(3), 901-932.

Bhattacharya, U., Borisov, A., and Yu, X. 2015. Firm Mortality and Natal Financial Care. Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 50(1/2), 61-88.

Bognanno, M. 2001. Corporate Tournaments. Journal of Labor Economics 19(2), 290-315.

Boudreau, J., Boswell, W., Judge, T., and Dretz, R. 2006. Personality and Cognitive Ability as
Predictors of Job Search among Employed Managers. Personnel Psychology 54(1), 25-50.

Bradburn, M., Clark T., Love S., and Altman, D. 2003. Survival Analysis Part II: Multivariate Data
Analysis-An Introduction to Concepts and Methods. British Journal of Cancer, 89, 431–436.

Burns, N., Minnick, K., and Starks, L. 2017. CEO Tournaments: A Cross-Country Analysis of
Causes, Cultural Influences, and Consequences. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
52(2), 519-551.

Carpentier, C., and Suret, J. 2011. The Survival and Success of Canadian Penny Stock IPOs. Small
Business Economics 36(1), 101-121.

Cattaneo, M., Meoli, M., and Vismara, S. 2015. Financial Regulation and IPOs: Evidence from the
History of the Italian Stock Market. Journal of Corporate Finance 31, 116-131.

Certo, T. 2003. Influencing Initial Public Offering Investors with Prestige: Signaling with Board
Structures. Academy of Management Review 28(3), 432-446.

Certo, T., Covin, J., Daily, C., and Dalton, D. 2001. Wealth and the Effects of Founder
Management Among IPO-Stage New Ventures. Strategic Management Journal 22(6-7), 641-658.

Certo, T., Daily, C., Cannella, J., and Dalton, D. 2003. Giving Money to Get Money: How CEO
Stock Options and CEO Equity Enhance IPO Valuations. The Academy of Management Journal
46(5), 643-653.

Chahine, S., and Goergen, M. 2011. The Two Sides of CEO Option Grants at the IPO. Journal of
Corporate Finance 17, 1116-1131.

33
Chang, Y., Dasgupta, S., and Hilary, E. 2010. CEO Ability, Pay, and Firm Performance.
Management Science 56(10), 1633-1652.

Chancharat, N., Krishnamurti, C., and Tian, G. 2012. Board Structure and Survival of New
Economy Firms. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 20, 144-163.

Chemmanur, T., and Paeglis, I. 2005. Management Quality, Certification, and Initial Public
Offerings. Journal of Financial Economics 76(2), 331-368.

Chen, J., Ezzamel, M., and Cai, Z. 2011. Managerial Power Theory, Tournament Theory, and
Executive Pay in China. Journal of Corporate Finance 17(4), 1176-1199.

Chen, Z., Huang, Y., and Wei, J. 2013. Executive Pay Disparity and the Cost of Equity Capital.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 48(3), 849-885.

Cohen, B. and Dean, D. 2005. Information Asymmetry and Investor Valuation of IPOs: Top
Management Team Legitimacy as a Capital Market Signal. Strategic Management Journal 26, 683-
690.

Coles, J., Naveen, D., and Naveen, L. 2006. Managerial Incentives and Risk-Taking. Journal of
Financial Economics 79(2), 431-468.

Conyon, M. 2006. Executive Compensation and Incentives. Academy of Management Perspectives


20(1), 25-44.

Conyon, M., and Sadler, G. 2001. CEO Compensation, Option Incentives, and Information
Disclosure. Review of Financial Economics 10(3), 251-277.

Core, J., and Guay, W. 2002. Estimating the Value of Employee Stock Option Portfolios and their
Sensitivities to Price and Volatility. Journal of Accounting Research 40(3), 613-630.

Core, J., Holthausen, R., and Larcker, D. 1999. Corporate Governance, Chief Executive
Compensation, and Firm Performance. Journal of Financial Economics 51(3), 371–406.

Cunat, V. and Guadalupe, M. 2009. Executive Compensation and Competition in the Banking and
Financial Sectors. Journal of Banking and Finance 33(3), 495-504.

Cunat, V. and Guadalupe, M. 2009. Globalization and the Provision of Incentives Inside the Firm:
The Effect of Foreign Competition. Journal of Labor Economics 27(2), 179-212.

Custodio, C., Ferreira, M., and Matos, P. 2013. Generalists versus Specialists: Lifetime Work
Experience and Chief Executive Officer Pay. Journal of Financial Economics 108, 471-492.

Daily, C., Johnson, M., Ellstrand, J., and Dalton, D. 1998. Compensation Committee Composition
as a Determinant of CEO Compensation. Academy of Management Journal, 41, 209–220.
Demers, E., and Joos, P. 2007. IPO Failure Risk. Journal of Accounting Research 45(2), 333-371.

34
Dicks, D. 2012. Executive Compensation and the Role for Corporate Governance Regulation.
Review of Financial Studies 25(6), 1971-2004.

Doidge, D., Karolyi, A., and Stulz, R. 2013 The U.S. Left Behind? Financial Globalization and the
Rise of IPOs Outside the U.S.. Journal of Financial Economics 110(3), 546-573.
Dow, J., and Raposo, C. 2005. CEO Compensation, Change, and Corporate Strategy. The Journal of
Finance 60(6), 2701-2727.

Edmans, A. Gabaix, X. and Jenter, D. 2017. Executive Compensation: A Survey of Theory and
Evidence. European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI)-Finance, Working Paper No.
514/2016.

Elbadry, A., Gounopoulos, D., and Skinner, F. 2015. Governance Quality and Information
Asymmetry. Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments 24(2-3), 127-157.

Engelberg J., Gao, P., and Parsons, C. 2013. The Price of a CEO’s Rolodex. Review of Financial
Studies 26(1), 79-114.

Espenlaub, S., Khurshed, A., and Mohamed, A. 2012. IPO Survival in a Reputational Market.
Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 39 (3-4), 427-463.

Espenlaub, S., Khurshed, A., Mohamed, A., and Saadouni, B. 2016. Committed Anchor Investment
and IPO Survival – The Role of Cornerstone and Strategic Investors. Journal of Corporate Finance
41, 139-155.

Faccio, M., Marchica, M.-T., and Mura, R. 2016. CEO Gender, Corporate Risk-Taking, and the
Efficiency of Capital Allocation. Journal of Corporate Finance 39, 193-209.

Fahlenbrach, R. 2009. Shareholder Rights, Boards, and CEO Compensation. Review of Finance
13(1), 81-113.

Falato, A., Li, D., and Milbourn, T. 2015. Which Skills Matter in the Market for CEOs? Evidence
from Pay for CEO Credentials. Management Science 61(12), 2845-2869.

Fama, E., and French, K. 2004. New lists: Fundamentals and survival rates. Journal of Financial
Economics 73(2), 229-269.

Fee, O., and Hadlock, C. 2003. Raids, Rewards, and Reputations in the Market for Managerial
Talent. Review of Financial Studies 16(4), 1311-1353.

Filatotchev, I., & Allcock, D. (2013). Corporate Governance in IPOs. Oxford: Oxford University
Press

Frydman, C. 2007. The Evolution of the Market for Corporate Executives Across the Twentieth
Century. Journal of Economic History, 488-492.

Frydman, C., and Jenter, D. 2010. CEO Compensation. Annual Review of Financial Economics
2(1), 75-102.

35
Frydman, C., and Saks, R. 2010. Executive Compensation: A New View from a Long-Term
Perspective, 1936-2005. The Review of Financial Studies 23(5), 2099-2138.

Gabaix, X., and Landier, A. 2008. Why Has CEO Pay Increased So Much? Quarterly Journal of
Economics 121(1), 49-100.

Goel, A., and Thakor, A. 2008. Overconfidence, CEO Selection, and Corporate Governance. The
Journal of Finance 63(6), 2737-2784.

Goldman E., and Huang, P. 2014. Contractual vs Actual Separation Pay Following CEO Turnover.
Management Science 61(5), 1-13.

Gao, N., and Jain, B. 2011. Founder CEO Management and the Long-run Investment Performance
of IPO firms. Journal of Banking and Finance 35(7), 1669-1682.

Giannetti, M. 2011. Serial CEO Incentives and the Structure of Managerial Contracts. Journal of
Financial Intermediation 20 (4), 633-662.

Gibbons, R., and Murphy, K. 1992. Optimal Incentive Contracts in the Presence of Career
Concerns: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Political Economy 100(3), 468-505.

Gounopoulos, D., and Pham, H. 2018. Specialist CEOs and IPO Survival. Journal of Corporate
Finance 48, 217-243.

Green, J. and Stokey, N. 1983. A Comparison of Tournaments and Contracts. Journal of Political
Economy 91(3), 349-364.

Grossman, S., and Hart, O. 1983. An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem. Econometrica 51(1),
7-45.

Hall, B., and Murphy, K. 2002. Stock Options for Undiversified Executives. Journal of Accounting
and Economics 33(1), 3-42.

Haß, L., Müller, M., and Vergauwe, S. 2015. Tournament Incentives and Corporate Fraud. Journal
of Corporate Finance 34, 251-267.

Hayes, R., Lemmon, M., and Qiu, M. 2012. Stock Options and Managerial Incentives for Risk-
Taking: Evidence from FAS 123R. Journal of Financial Economics 105(1), 174-190.

Hayes, R., and Schaefer, S. 2009. CEO Pay and the Lake Wobegon Effect. Journal of Financial
Economics 94(2), 280-290.

He, L. 2008. Do Founders Matter? A Study of Executive Compensation, Governance Structure and
Firm Performance. Journal of Business Venturing 23(3), 257-279.

Heckman, J. 1979. Sample Selection Boas as a Specification Error. Econometrica 47 (1), 153-161.

Henderson, A., and Fredrickson, J. 2001. Top Management Team Coordination Needs and the CEO
Pay Gap: A Competitive Test of Economic and Behavioral View. Academic Management Journal
44(1), 96-117.

36
Hensler, D., Rutherford, R., and Springer, T. 1997. The Survival of Initial Public Offerings in the
Aftermarket. Journal of Financial Research 20(1), 93-110.

Hermalin, B., and Weisbach, M. 1998. Endogenously Chosen Boards of Directors and their
Monitoring of the CEO. American Economic Review 88(1), 96-118.

Hoitash, R., Hoitash, U., and Kurt, A. 2016. Do Accountants Make Better Chief Financial Officers?
Journal of Accounting and Economis 61(2-3), 414-432.

Holmstrom, B., and Kaplan, S. 2001. Corporate Governance and Merger Activity in the U.S.:
Making Sense of the 1980s and 1990s. NBER Working Paper No. 8220.

Holmstrom, B., and Milgrom, P. 1991. Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts,
Asset Ownership, and Job Design. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7(0), 24-52.

Huang, R., Tan, J., and Faff, R. 2016. CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Debt Maturity. Journal
of Corporate Finance 36, 93-110.

Jacob, B. and Levitt, S. 2003. Rotten Apples: An Investigation of the Prevalence and Predictors of
Teacher Cheating, NBER Working Papers 9413. National Bureau of Economic Research.

Jain, A., and Kini, O. 1999. The Life Cycle of Initial Public Offering Firms. Journal of Business,
Finance and Accounting 26(9), 1281-1307.

Jain, B., and O. Kini, O. 2000. Does the Presence of Venture Capitalists Improve the Survival
Profile of IPO Firms? Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 27(9-10), 1139-1183.

Jain, B., and Kini, O. 2008. The Impact of Strategic Investment Choices on Post-Issue Operating
Performance and Survival of US IPO Firms. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 35(3-4),
459-490.

Jain, B., and Martin, J. 2005. The Association Between Audit Quality and Post-IPO Performance: A
Survival Analysis Approach. Review of Accounting and Finance 4(4), 50-75.

Jenkinson, T., and Ljungqvist, A. 2001. Going Public-The Theory and Evidence on how Companies
Raise Equity Finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Jensen, M. 1986. Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American
Economic Review 76(2), 323-329.

Jensen, M., and Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and
Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4), 305-360.

Jensen, M., and Murphy, K. 1990. Performance Pay and Top-Management Incentives. Journal of
Political Economy 98(2), 225-264.

Jensen, M., Murphy, K., and Wruck, E. 2004. Remuneration: Where We've Been, How We Got to
Here, What Are the Problems, and How to Fix Them. ECGI Working Paper Series in Finance, No.
44.

37
Jia, N. 2017. Tournament Incentives and Audit Fees. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 36,
358-378.

Jiraporn, P., Liu, Y., and Kim, Y. 2014. How Do Powerful CEOs Affect Analyst Coverage?
European Financial Management 20(3), 652-676.

Keasey, K., and Mcguinness, P. 1990. The Failure of UK Industrial Firms for the Period 1976-
1984, Logistic Analysis and Entropy Measures. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 17(1),
119-135.

Kale, J., Reis, G., and Venkateswaran, A. 2009. Rank-Order Tournaments and Incentive Alignment:
The Effect of Firm Performance. The Journal of Finance 64(3), 1479-1512.

Kaplan, S. 2008. Are U.S. CEOs Overpaid? Academy of Management 22(2), 5-20.

Kaplan, S., and Rauh, J. 2009. Wall Street and Main Street: What Contributes to the Rise in the
Highest Incomes? The Review of Financial Studies 23(3), 1004-1050.

Kaplan, S., Klebanov, M., and Sorensen. M. 2012. Which CEO Characteristics and Abilities
Matter? The Journal of Finance 67(3), 973-1007.

Kini, O., and Williams, R. 2012. Tournament Incentives, Firm Risk, and Corporate Policies. Journal
of Financial Economics 103(2), 350-376.

Kuhnen, C.M., Zwiebel, J., 2009, Executive Pay, Hidden Compensation and Managerial
Entrenchment. Working paper, Northwestern University.

Lazear, E. 1989. Pay Equality and Industrial Politics. Journal of Political Economy 97(3), 561-580.

Lazear, E., and Rosen, S. 1981. Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts. Journal of
Political Economy 89(5), 841-564.

Landier, A., Sraer, D., and Thesmar, D. 2009. Optimal Dissent in Organizations. Review of
Economic Studies 76(2), 761-794.

Lee, K., Lev, B., and Yeo, G. 2008. Executive Pay Dispersion, Corporate Governance, and Firm
Performance. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 30(3), 315-338.

Li, X., Low, A., and Makhija, A. 2017. Career Concerns and the Busy Life of the Young CEO.
Journal of Corporate Finance 47(3), 88-109.

Liu, Y., and Jiraporn, P. 2010. The Effect of CEO Power on Bond Ratings and Yields. Journal of
Empirical Finance 17(4), 744-762.

Loughran, T., and Ritter, J. 2004. Why has IPO Underpricing Changed over Time? Financial
Management 33(3), 5-37.

Lowry, M., and Murphy, K. 2007. Executive Stock Options and IPO Underpricing. Journal of
Financial Economics 85, 39-65.

38
Main, B., O’Reilly, C., and Wade, J. 1993. Top Executive Pay: Tournament or Teamwork? Journal
of Labor Economics 11(4), 606-628.
Masulis, R., and Mobbs, S. 2011. Are all Inside Directors the Same? The Journal of Finance 66(8),
23-62.

Masulis, R., and Zhang, S. 2013. Compensation Gaps Among Top Executives: Evidence of
Tournament Incentives or Productivity Differentials. Unpublished Working Paper.

Mishra, D. 2014. The Dark Side of CEO Ability: CEO General Managerial Skills and Cost of
Equity Capital 29(3), 390-409.

Murphy, K. 1999. Chapter 38 Executive Compensation, Handbook of Labor Economics, 3 Part B,


2485-2563.

Murphy, K. 2002. Explaining Executive Compensation: Managerial Power versus the Perceived
Cost of Stock Options. The University of Chicago Law Review 69(3), 847-869.

Murphy, K., and Zabojnik, J. 2004. CEO Pay and Appointments: A Market-Based Explanation for
Recent Trends. American Economic Review 94(2), 192-196.

Murphy, K. J., Zabojnik, J., 2007. Managerial capital and the market for CEOs. Unpublished
working paper, University of Southern California.

Nagel, G. 2010. The Effect of Labor Market Demand on US CEO Pay Since 1980. Financial
Review 45(4), 931-950.

Nelson, T. 2003. The Persistence of Founder Influence: Management, Ownership, and Performance
Effects at Initial Public Offering. Strategic Management Journal 24(8), 707-724.

Park, K. 2017. Pay Disparities within Top Management Teams and Earnings Management. Journal
of Accounting Public Policy 36, 59-81.

Prendergast, C. 1999. The Provision of Incentives in Firms. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 7-
63.

Ryan, H. and Wiggins, R. 2004. Who is in Whose Pocket? Director Compensation, Board
Independence, and Barriers to Effective Monitoring. Journal of Financial Economics 73(3), 497-
524.

Shi, W., Connelly, B., and Sanders, W. 2015. Buying Bad Behavior: Tournament Incentives and
Securities Class Action Lawsuits. Strategic Management Journal 37(7), 1354-1378.

Schultz, P. 1993. Unit Initial Public Offerings: A Form of Staged Financing. Journal of Financial
Economics 34(2), 199-229.

Schwarz, M., and S. Severinov. 2010. Investment Tournaments: When Should a Rational Agent Put
All Eggs in One Basket? Journal of Labor Economics 28, 893–922.

39
Serfling, M. 2014. CEO Age and the Riskiness of Corporate Policies. Journal of Corporate Finance
25(3), 251-273.

Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. 1989. Management Entrenchment: The Case of Manager-Specific
Investments. Journal of Financial Economics 25(1), 123-139.

Stefanescu, I., Wang, Y., Xie, K., and Yang, J. 2018. Pay Me Now (and Later): Pension Benefit
Manipulation before Plan Freezes and Executive Retirement. Journal of Financial Economics
127(1), 152-173.

Taylor, C. 1995. Digging for Golden Carrots: An Analysis of Research Tournament. American
Economic Review, 85, 872–890.

Tervio, M. 2008. The Difference that CEOs Make: An Assignment Model Approach. American
Economic Review 98(3), 642-668.

Tesluk, P., and Jacobs, R. 1998. Toward an integrated model of work experience Personnel
Psychology 51(2), 321-355.

Vardaman, J., Allen, D., Renn, R., and Moffitt, K. 2008. Should I Stay or Should I Go? The Role of
Risk in Employee Turnover Decisions. Human Relations 61(11), 1531-1563.

Vo, T., and Canil, J. 2016. CEO Pay Disparity: Efficient Contracting or Managerial Power? Journal
of Corporate Finance, In Press.

Wang, T., Winton, A., and Yu, X. 2010. Corporate Fraud and Business Conditions: Evidence from
IPOs. The Journal of Finance 65(6), 2255-2292.

Wasserman, N. 2003. Founder-CEO Succession and the Paradox of Entrepreneurial Success.


Organization Science 14(2), 149-172.

Welbourne, T., and Andrews, A. 1996. Predicting the Performance of Initial Public Offerings:
Should Human Resource Management Be in the Equation? The Academy of Management Journal
39(4), 891-919.

Yan, Y., N. Rajagopalan, N. 2004. When the Known Devil is Better than the Uknown God: An
Empirical Study of the Antencedents and Consequences of Relay CEO Successions. Academy
Management Journal 47(4), 483-500.

Yermack, D. 1996. Higher Market Valuation of Companies with a Small Board of Directors.
Journal of Financial Economics 40(2), 185-211.

Yermack, D. 2006. Golden Handshakes: Rewards for CEOs who Leave. Journal of Accounting and
Economics 41, 237-256.

Yim, S. 2013. The Acquisitiveness of Youth: CEO Age and Acquisition Behavior. Journal of
Financial Economics 108(1), 250-273.

Zimmerman, R. 2008. Understanding the Impact of Personality Traits on Individuals’ Turnover


Decisions: A Meta-Analysis Path Model. Personnel Psychology 61(2), 309-345.

40
Table 1: IPO Distribution by Year and Industry
This Table presents the distribution of overall sample and the five groups of IPO firms: survived, acquired, exchanged,
liquidated, and dropped firms. Liquidated firms are those that are delisted due to company liquidation (delisting code 400 to
490). Exchanged firms are those that are delisted due to stop/change of trading on exchange (delisting code 300 to 390).
Dropped firms are those that are dropped (delisting code from 500 to 599). Acquired firms are those that are delisted due to
mergers and/or acquisitions (delisting code from 200 to 299). Survived firms are those that are still trading (delisting code of
100). In Panel C the IPOs are distributed by industry. Panel D reports cumulative survival rates calculated using the Kaplan-
Meier method for one, three years and five years after IPO across the subsamples of high and low compensated CEOs
Panel A: Distribution of IPOs by Trading Status from 2000-2012
From the IPO date to five years after the offering
N %
Liquidated 2 0.17
Exchanged 6 0.51
Dropped 82 6.96
Acquired 274 23.26
Survived 814 69.10
Total 1,178
Panel B: Distribution of IPO Trading Status by Year
All IPOs Dropped Acquired Exchanged Liquidated Survived
Year
N % % % % %
2000 264 12.12 23.86 0.38 0.38 63.26
2001 59 6.78 22.03 0.00 0.00 71.19
2002 48 6.25 22.92 0.00 0.00 70.83
2003 47 4.26 31.91 0.00 0.00 63.83
2004 129 2.33 27.91 0.00 0.00 68.99
2005 115 7.83 15.65 0.00 0.78 76.52
2006 126 3.97 24.60 1.59 0.00 69.84
2007 112 5.36 22.32 0.89 0.00 71.43
2008 17 11.76 5.88 5.88 0.00 76.47
2009 38 2.63 26.32 0.00 0.00 71.05
2010 72 9.72 16.67 0.00 0.00 73.61
2011 71 8.45 16.90 0.00 0.00 74.65
2012 80 2.50 33.75 1.25 0.00 62.50
Note: Delisting is tracked for five years after the IPO
Panel C: Distribution of IPO Trading Status by Industry
All IPOs Dropped Acquired Survived
Industry (two-digit SIC codes)
N % % %
Oil and Gas (13) 47 6.38 12.77 74.47
Food Products (20) 13 0.00 23.08 69.23
Chemical Products - (28) 175 8.00 22.29 66.29
Manufacturing (30-34) 27 9.38 23.96 57.29
Computer Equipment &
(35, 73) 336 7.45 24.85 61.57
Services
Electronic Equipment (36) 122 6.56 26.23 64.75
Scientific Instruments (38) 90 5.56 26.67 63.33
Transportation & Public (41, 42,
103 4.32 14.38 78.57
Utilities 44-49)
Wholesale & Retail Trade (50-59) 100 2.19 19.37 64.70
(70, 78,
Entertainment Services 14 13.33 0.00 86.67
79)
Note: Delisting is tracked for five years after the IPO

41
Panel D: Kaplan-Meier Survival Rates of Total CEO Compensation By Issue Year
Firms with High Compensated Firms with Low Compensated
All IPOs
CEOs CEOs
Cumulative Survival Rate Cumulative Survival Rate Cumulative Survival Rate
Year Obs 1 Yr 3 Yrs 5Yrs 1 Yr 3 Yrs 5Yrs 1 Yr 3 Yrs 5Yrs
2000 264 95.45 74.62 63.26 94.85 76.57 62.86 96.63 70.78 59.55
2001 59 100.00 81.36 71.19 100.00 84.37 75.00 92.59 70.37 66.66
2002 48 97.92 81.25 70.83 96.43 82.14 75.00 100.00 80.00 65.00
2003 47 95.74 82.98 63.83 96.00 76.00 72.00 95.45 90.90 54.54
2004 129 98.45 86.82 68.99 96.36 87.27 67.27 100.00 86.48 70.27
2005 115 98.26 86.09 76.52 96.55 87.93 82.76 100.00 84.21 70.17
2006 126 99.20 84.13 69.84 98.33 91.66 78.33 100.00 77.27 62.12
2007 112 97.32 84.82 70.53 98.44 85.94 73.43 95.83 83.33 66.66
2008 17 88.23 76.47 76.47 100.00 72.73 72.73 100.00 83.33 83.33
2009 38 97.37 81.58 71.05 96.77 83.87 74.19 100.00 71.43 57.14
2010 72 94.44 87.50 73.61 91.11 86.66 73.33 100.00 88.88 74.07
2011 71 94.36 83.10 73.24 93.62 85.11 78.72 95.83 79.17 62.50
2012 80 95.00 90.00 62.50 92.98 75.44 70.01 100.00 91.30 54.50

42
Table 2: Descriptive Statistics
The Table presents descriptive statistics for the sample of U.S. IPOs over the period from 2000 to 2012. Total CEO
compensation and its components are presented in Panel A. CEO characteristics are illustrated in Panel B. Firm and offering
characteristics are reported in Panel C. Tests of differences in means between the two sub-samples of IPO firms with a high
compensated CEO and those with a low compensated CEO are based on t-tests. The number of observations for each
variable is 1,178. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
Panel A: CEO Pay Components
IPOs with a high IPOs with a low
All IPOs Difference
compensated CEO compensated CEO
Mean Mean Mean p-value
CEO Total Pay $1,297,351 $2,252,664 $342,038 0.0000
Firm Pay Gap $941,074 $1,466,525 $44,304 0.0000
Other Executives’ Median
$541,937 $786,139 $297,734 0.0000
Total Pay
Salary/Total Pay 0.52 0.32 0.71 0.0000
Bonus/Total Pay 0.16 0.19 0.13 0.0000
Stock Awards/Total Pay 0.04 0.06 0.01 0.0000
Option Awards/Total Pay 0.17 0.25 0.09 0.0000
Non-Equity Incentive
0.05 0.07 0.03 0.0000
Pay/Total Pay
Other Pay/Total Pay 0.06 0.09 0.03 0.0000
Panel B: CEO Characteristics
CEO Tenure 3.97 3.88 4.10 0.2045
CEO Duality 0.54 0.62 0.47 0.0000
Founder 0.32 0.22 0.41 0.0000
CEO Age 49.48 50.66 48.27 0.0000
Generalist 0.60 0.63 0.57 0.0139
Panel C: Firm and Offering Characteristics
Firm Age 15.28 19.43 11.12 0.0000
Proceeds 4.41 4.84 3.98 0.0000
Capital Expenditure 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.0052
R&D Intensity 0.30 0.27 0.32 0.0176
Leverage 0.34 0.33 0.34 0.3819
EPS 0.50 0.56 0.44 0.0000
Initial Returns 22.22 17.51 26.93 0.0003
Overhang 4.46 4.19 4.75 0.0886
Board Governance -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 0.4606
HHI 0.47 0.48 0.47 0.2779
Big 4 Auditor 0.47 0.49 0.46 0.1466
VC 0.53 0.41 0.64 0.0000
Underwriter 0.35 0.47 0.23 0.0000
Technology 0.40 0.47 0.32 0.0000
Internet 0.11 0.10 0.12 0.2023
Nasdaq 0.72 0.60 0.83 0.0000

43
Panel D: Indicative Example with High and Low Compensation Awarding Companies
This Panel reports an indicative list of top and bottom ten paying companies according to CEO compensation. The sample
consists of 1,178 IPOs that floated U.S. stock exchanges from the 1st of January 2000 to the 31st of December 2012. We
relied on the Securities Data Company (SDC) Database to retrieve information on IPO deals. Data on CEO compensation
were hand-collected from EDGAR.
Panel D1: Ten High Compensation Awarding Companies
IPO Date Company Total CEO Compensation Survivorship
18/4/2011 Air Lease Corp $57,768,057 1
9/3/2011 HCA Holdings Inc $38,201,047 1
8/8/2007 DemandTec Inc $26,995,885 0
25/1/2011 Demand Media Inc $25,141,924 1
28/6/2010 Tesla Motors Inc $24,133,808 1
16/11/2011 Delphi Automotive PLC $21,134,503 1
7/2/2012 Caesars Entertainment Corp $17,503,197 1
30/9/2009 Talecris Biotherapeutics Hldg $16,155,671 0
20/1/2005 Celanese Corp $14,554,666 1
24/3/2010 Calix Inc $13,859,389 1
Panel D2: Ten Low Compensation Awarding Companies
23/7/2003 Integrated Alarm Svcs Grp Inc $100,000 0
9/10/2007 Targanta Therapeutics Corp $102,226 0
7/4/2000 Numerical Technologies Inc $104,091 0
20/9/2000 Zengine Inc $108,461 0
20/6/2000 Handspring Inc $111,442 0
20/9/2000 OmniSky Corp $120,192 0
19/2/2008 Bioheart Inc $150,000 0
7/12/2004 CABG Medical Inc $150,000 0
13/3/2000 FairMarket Inc $150,000 0
21/9/2006 DivX Inc $153,375 0

44
Table 3: Estimation of Cox Proportional Hazards Model of Probability of Failure
The Table illustrates the estimation of Cox proportional hazards model of probability of failure. Our dependent variable is
whether or not a firm survived 5 years after its IPO. Regressions control for industry and year fixed effects whose coefficients
are suppressed. T-statistics are included in the parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels,
respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
(1) (2) (3)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio
Total CEO -0.10**
0.902
Compensation (-2.26)
Short-Term CEO 0.06
1.062
Compensation (0.95)
Long-Term CEO -0.09***
0.913
Compensation (-3.85)
0.05*** 0.04*** 0.05***
CEO Tenure 1.051 1.047 1.055
(6.26) (5.77) (6.44)
-1.63*** -1.64*** -1.74***
CEO Duality 0.195 0.195 0.176
(-4.02) (-4.10) (-3.90)
0.03 0.03 -0.09
Founder 1.034 1.033 0.908
(0.33) (0.32) (-0.83)
0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01***
Initial Returns 1.003 1.003 1.003
(3.71) (4.13) (3.74)
-0.13 -0.16* -0.15
Big 4 Auditor 0.874 1.030 0.857
(-1.56) (-1.90) (-1.64)
0.03 0.03 0.06
Leverage 1.030 1.030 1.063
(0.26) (0.26) (0.52)
0.07 -0.01 -0.02
Proceeds 1.069 0.985 0.979
(1.23) (-0.27) (-0.33)
-0.02 0.02 0.06
EPS 0.982 1.016 1.065
(-0.18) (0.17) (0.60)
0.01 -0.01 -0.07
VC 1.013 0.983 0.931
(0.12) (-0.15) (-0.59)
-0.25* -0.28** -0.24*
Technology 0.779 0.757 0.783
(-1.94) (-2.13) (-1.72)
-0.21 -0.22 -0.25
Internet 0.805 0.800 0.775
(-1.31) (-1.32) (-1.40)
-0.37*** -0.42*** -0.41***
Underwriter 0.689 0.659 0.662
(-3.48) (-3.93) (-3.68)
0.12 0.15 0.03
Nasdaq 1.131 1.169 1.028
(1.04) (1.32) (0.22)
0.01 0.01 0.01
Overhang 1.009 1.006 1.007
(1.58) (1.03) (1.12)
-1.92* -2.03* -2.48**
Market Return 0.146 0.132 0.083
(-1.81) (-1.91) (-2.24)
-1.60*** -1.67*** -2.20***
Board Governance 0.200 0.188 0.110
(-2.96) (-3.05) (-3.46)
-0.33** -0.31** -0.35**
HHI 0.718 0.732 0.703
(-2.24) (-2.11) (-2.15)
-0.40 -0.27 -0.12
Capital Expenditure 0.672 0.760 0.886
(-0.71) (-0.49) (-0.20)
0.37*** 0.34*** 0.33***
R&D Intensity 1.450 1.412 1.385
(3.76) (3.47) (2.99)
Industry & Year FE Y Y Y
Chi-Square 430.48 428.31 403.45
Number of
1,178 1,178 1,178
Observations

45
Table 4: Estimation of Cox Proportional Hazards Model of Probability of Failure
The table illustrates the estimation of Cox proportional hazards model of probability of failure. Our dependent variable is
whether or not a firm survived 5 years after its IPO. Regression control for industry and year fixed effects whose coefficients
are suppressed. T-statistics are included in the parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels,
respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
(1) (2) (3)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio
-0.08**
Total Firm Gap 0.917
(-2.55)
0.02
Short-Term Firm Gap 1.018
(0.42)
-0.06***
Long-Term Firm Gap 0.940
(-3.62)
0.05*** 0.05*** 0.05***
CEO Tenure 1.048 1.047 1.050
(5.40) (5.10) (4.62)
-1.62*** -1.81*** -1.68***
CEO Duality 0.196 0.164 0.185
(-4.50) (-4.30) (-3.95)
-0.02 0.03 0.01
Founder 0.978 1.029 1.000
(-0.19) (0.25) (0.01)
0.01*** 0.01*** 0.01***
Initial Returns 1.002 1.003 1.005
(2.96) (3.32) (2.54)
-0.17* -0.17* -0.13
Big 4 Auditor 0.841 0.844 0.882
(-1.84) (-1.68) (-1.03)
0.05 0.01 0.20
Leverage 1.049 1.014 1.223
(0.40) (0.11) (1.40)
0.04 0.03 -0.01
Proceeds 1.041 1.028 0.988
(0.65) (0.47) (-0.14)
-0.01 -0.08 0.01
EPS 0.996 0.922 1.010
(-0.04) (-0.71) (0.08)
0.06 -0.07 -0.01
VC 1.058 0.928 0.993
(0.46) (-0.56) (-0.04)
-0.24* -0.20 0.07
Technology 0.782 0.813 1.007
(-1.73) (-1.37) (0.41)
-0.14 -0.29 -0.19
Internet 0.870 0.745 0.827
(-0.73) (-1.44) (-0.83)
-0.42*** -0.45*** -0.43***
Underwriter 0.655 0.633 0.648
(-3.74) (-3.75) (-2.99)
0.04 0.14 0.05
Nasdaq 1.038 1.148 1.054
(0.29) (0.98) (0.33)
0.01 0.01 0.01
Overhang 1.006 1.015 1.003
(0.84) (1.37) (0.31)
-1.85 -1.81 -2.54*
Market Return 0.157 0.163 0.078
(-1.60) (-1.48) (-1.83)
-2.05*** -2.31*** -2.56***
Board Governance 0.128 0.099 0.077
(-3.38) (-3.54) (-3.13)
-0.34** -0.36** -0.43**
HHI 0.709 0.698 0.649
(-2.20) (-2.16) (-1.99)
0.02 0.48 -0.48
Capital Expenditure 1.025 1.627 0.619
(0.04) (0.75) (-0.62)
0.40*** 0.27** 0.40***
R&D Intensity 1.486 1.311 1.486
(3.72) (2.32) (2.81)
Industry & Year FE Y Y Y
Chi-Square 369.74 372.48 244.54
Number of
1,178 1,178 1,178
Observations

46
Table 5: Accelerated Failure Time (AFT) Model
This Table shows the estimation results of the Accelerated Failure Time (AFT) model. Our dependent variable is the natural
logarithm of the time to delist (survival time) which is measured in months. The Weibull distribution was selected based on
the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC). Time ratios are the exponentiated coefficients, exp(β), and measure the extent to
which changes in covariates accelerate or decelerate the occurrence of event (delisting). A time ratio of above (below) one
indicates that an increase in the covariate increases (reduces) the survival time. T-statistics are included in the parentheses.
***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
Coefficient Time Ratio Coefficient Time Ratio
0.15*** 1.165
Total CEO Compensation
(4.23)
0.14*** 1.147
Total Firm Gap
(5.02)
-0.03*** 0.969 -0.03*** 0.971
CEO Tenure
(-4.25) (-3.56)
1.82*** 6.193 1.76*** 5.814
CEO Duality
(5.10) (4.55)
0.03 1.028 0.10 1.110
Founder
(0.34) (1.17)
-0.01*** 0.997 -0.01*** 0.998
Initial Returns
(-4.27) (-2.62)
0.15** 1.167 0.26*** 1.301
Big 4 Auditor
(2.21) (3.40)
-0.06 0.939 -0.15 0.859
Leverage
(-0.69) (-1.59)
-0.05 0.945 -0.07 0.935
Proceeds
(-1.30) (-1.30)
0.11 1.117 0.14* 1.155
EPS
(1.43) (1.69)
-0.05 0.951 -0.03 0.966
VC
(-0.56) (-0.34)
0.10 1.102 0.13 1.141
Technology
(0.95) (1.14)
-0.05 0.948 -0.17 0.840
Internet
(-0.45) (-1.28)
0.42*** 1.526 0.49*** 1.634
Underwriter
(4.82) (5.27)
-0.38*** 0.684 -0.41*** 0.666
Nasdaq
(-3.93) (-3.86)
-0.01 0.993 -0.01 0.992
Overhang
(-1.34) (-1.40)
1.59* 4.904 1.56* 4.771
Market Return
(1.85) (1.67)
1.26*** 3.545 1.73*** 5.641
Board Governance
(2.75) (3.33)
0.32*** 1.384 0.36*** 1.436
HHI
(2.64) (2.73)
-0.69 1.999 0.08 1.086
Capital Expenditure
(-1.38) (0.16)
-0.52*** 0.594 -0.52*** 0.596
R&D Intensity
(-6.35) (-5.79)
Industry & Year FE Y Y
( ) 774.11 652.43
Number of Observations 1,178 1,178

47
Table 6: Additional Analysis
This Table displays the multivariate analysis using Cox Proportional Hazards Models using alternative definitions of delisted
firms and survivorship. The sample consists of IPOs from 2000 to 2012 in the U.S. stock market. Panel A and B display the
results for total compensation and firm pay gap from Cox models using alternative measures to define failed firms.
Specifications (1), (2), (3), and (4) present the results of Cox model using the alternative measures of failed firms. To define the
first alternative measure, we follow the method of Espenlaub et al. (2016) and use the following four measures to test the
performance of the firms before the IPO: cash to total assets, total liabilities to total assets, operating income to total assets,
current assets to current liabilities. To define the second alternative measure, we follow the same procedure and use the four
performance measures before the M&A. In the third alternative definition, failed companies are only the dropped (delisting code
from 500 to 599). Lastly, following Bhattacharya et al. (2015) we classify a firm as survivor if it still listed within 3 years after
its IPO. Panel C and D present Cox results using initially the mean of other top executives to calculate the pay gap instead of the
median, and then the CEO Pay Slice. T-statistics are included in the parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%,
5%, and 10% levels, respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
Panel A: The Association Between Total CEO Compensation and Failure Risk using Alternative Measures of Failure Risk
First Alternative Second Alternative Third Alternative Fourth Alternative
Definition Definition Definition Definition
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Hazard Hazard Hazard Hazard
Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient
Ratio Ratio Ratio Ratio
Total CEO -0.17*** -0.26*** -0.38** -0.05*
0.846 0.773 0.684 0.944
Compensation (-2.87) (-3.47) (-2.31) (-1.70)
Control Variables Y Y Y Y
Industry & Year
Y Y Y Y
FE
Chi-Square 277.64 228.34 124.43 300.16
Number of
1,178 1,178 1,178 1,315
Observations

Panel B: The Association Between Total Firm Gap and Failure Risk using Alternative Measures of Failure Risk
First Alternative Second Alternative Third Alternative Fourth Alternative
Definition Definition Definition Definition
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Hazard Hazard Hazard Hazard
Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient
Ratio Ratio Ratio Ratio
-0.13** -0.15*** -0.21* -0.05*
Total Firm Gap 0.882 0.859 0.807 0.953
(-2.25) (-2.78) (-1.91) (-1.74)
Control Variables Y Y Y Y
Industry & Year
Y Y Y Y
FE
Chi-Square 228.34 157.98 110.60 371.45
Number of
1,178 1,178 1,178 1,315
Observations

Panel C: Firm Pay Gap using the Mean Compensation instead of the Median Compensation of Other Senior Executives
(1) (2)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Time Ratio
-0.09** 0.13***
Total Firm Gap 0.910 1.139
(-2.02) (4.99)
Control Variables Y Y
Industry & Year FE Y Y
Chi-Square 216.63 624.77
Number of
1,178 1,178
Observations

48
Panel D: CEO Slice as an Alternative Measure of Pay Gap
(1) (2)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Time Ratio
-0.41 0.41**
Total Firm Gap 0.671 1.507
(-1.38) (2.44)
Control Variables Y Y
Industry & Year FE Y Y
Chi-Square 261.71 768.04
Number of
1,178 1,178
Observations

Table 7: Robustness Analysis


This Table displays the multivariate analysis using Cox Proportional Hazards Models with alternative industry definitions.
Panel A illustrates the estimation of Cox model using total CEO compensation as the main independent variable while Panel B
reports the results of Cox model using Firm Pay Gap as the main independent variable. Models (1) and (2) are results using
alternative industry classifications (FF-30 and FF-49). Model (3) shows the result without industry fixed effects. The sample
consists of IPOs from 2000 to 2012 in the U.S. stock market. T-statistics are included in the parentheses. ***, **, and * denote
significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
Panel A: Alternative Industry Definitions for Total CEO Compensation
(1) (2) (3)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient. Hazard Ratio
Total CEO -0.09** -0.11** -0.07*
0.907 0.889 0.927
Compensation (-2.15) (-2.52) (-1.82)
Control Variables Y Y Y
Industry & Year FE Y Y Y
Chi-Square 427.79 386.92 403.77
Number of
1,178 1,178 1,178
Observations
Panel B: Alternative Industry Definitions for Firm Pay Gap
(1) (2) (3)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio
-0.08** -0.09** -0.08***
Total Firm Gap 0.922 0.913 0.918
(-2.45) (-2.59) (-2.65)
Control Variables Y Y
Industry & Year FE Y Y
Chi-Square 365.30 386.92 345.83
Number of
1,178 1,178 1,178
Observations

49
Table 8: Controlling for CEO Characteristics
The Table illustrates the estimation of Cox proportional hazards model of probability of failure and time-to failure. Our
dependent variable is whether or not a firm survived 5 years after its IPO. Models (1) and (2) control for additional CEO and
firm characteristics: CEO gender, CEO age, powerful CEOs, CEO educational attainments (MBA, PhD, HD, and MD), and
Compensation Committee. Regression control for industry and year fixed effects whose coefficients are suppressed. T-statistics
are included in the parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. All variables are
defined in Appendix A.
(1) (2)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio
-0.21*** 0.812
Total CEO Compensation
(-2.75)
-0.14*** 0.868
Total Firm Gap
(-2.66)
-0.13 0.878 -0.11 0.897
CEO Gender
(-0.58) (-0.44)
-0.01 0.993 -0.01 0.993
CEO Age
(-0.85) (-0.68)
-0.03 0.972 -0.06 0.941
Powerful CEOs
(-0.18) (-0.35)
Compensation Committee -0.42*** 0.656 -0.44*** 0.641
Quality (-9.62) (-9.06)
-0.08 0.922 -0.16 0.852
MBA
(-0.57) (-0.99)
0.34* 1.413 0.28 1.319
PhD
(1.8) (1.28)
-0.02 0.976 -0.06 0.938
JD
(-0.08) (-0.18)
-0.16 0.854 -0.20 0.815
MD
(-0.51) (-0.62)
Other Control Variables Y Y
Industry & Year FE Y Y
( ) 343.75 288.31
Number of Observations 1,178 1,178

50
Table 9: Heckman-Two Step Model
This Table shows the estimation results of the Heckman Two-Step Model. Panel A presents the First-Stage results while Panel B
displays the second stage results (outcome). Our dependent variables in Panel A are the High compensated CEOs and High Firm
Gaps, respectively. High compensated CEOs is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEOs have greater compensation than the
sample median. High firm gap is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firms have high disparity greater than the sample median.
***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
Panel A: First Stage Results
Dependent Variable Firms with High Compensated CEOs Firms with High Firm Gap
0.01 0.01
CEO Tenure
(0.63) (0.25)
-0.01 0.04
CEO Duality
(-0.15) (0.36)
-0.32*** -0.34***
Founder
(-3.10) (-3.05)
-0.01 -0.01
Initial Returns
(-1.50) (-1.32)
0.13 0.06
Big 4 Auditor
(1.44) (0.62)
-0.24** -0.01
Leverage
(-2.01) (-0.10)
0.43*** 0.33***
Proceeds
(7.21) (5.25)
0.06 0.02
EPS
(0.62) (0.18)
-0.16 -0.32**
VC
(-1.46) (-2.53)
-0.29** -0.11
Technology
(-2.31) (-0.78)
0.07 0.26
Internet
(0.46) (1.56)
0.34*** 0.18
Underwriter
(3.16) (1.52)
-0.27** -0.16
Nasdaq
(-2.13) (-1.22)
0.01** 0.02*
Overhang
(2.05) (1.85)
-0.01 0.01
Board Governance
(-0.02) (0.02)
-0.18 -0.36**
HHI
(-1.05) (-1.99)
0.34 0.07
Capital Expenditure
(0.75) (0.15)
-0.35* -0.33
R&D Intensity
(-1.87) (-1.16)
Industry & Year FE Y Y
0.1843 0.1429
Number of Observations 1,178 1,178

Panel B: Second-Stage Results


(1) (2)
Coefficient Hazard Ratio Coefficient Hazard Ratio
-0.14**
Total CEO Compensation 0.861
(-2.32)
-0.13***
Total Firm Gap 0.917
(-2.67)
Inverse Mills (Total 0.04
Compensation) (0.15)
Inverse Mills (Total Firm -0.01
Gap) (0.01)
Control Variables Y Y
Industry & Year FE Y Y
Chi-Square 270.13 235.32
Number of Observations 1,178 1,178

51
Table 10: Endogeneity Control – Propensity Score Matching
This Table illustrates the average treatment effect of the treated for failure risk in high and low total compensated (firm gap)
CEOs, controlling for the endogeneity of Total CEO Compensation and Pay Gap using propensity score matching. As for the
binary feature of total compensation (High Total Compensation), we calculate the total compensation Total Compensation as the
natural logarithm of the sum of salary, bonus, stock awards, option awards, non-equity incentives and other elements of
compensation in the fiscal year prior to the IPO; if the total compensation is above the median, then High Total Compensation is
set to 1, otherwise is 0. We follow the same process for total pay disparity. The outcome variable is failure risk. The variables
used for matching are: Founder, CEO Age, Triality, Generalist, Leverage, Proceeds, Internet, Compensation Quality Committee,
Board Independence, R&D Intensity, CAPEX, and year dummies. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10%
levels, respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
(1) (2)
Failure Risk Failure Risk

ATET
-0.11*** ATET -0.07*
(High Total Compensation vs. Low
(-2.78) (High Firm Gap vs. Low Firm Gap) (-1.79)
Total Compensation

Number of Observations 1,178 Number of Observations 1,178

Table 11: Managerial Incentives and Post-IPO Performance


This Table shows the results of additional tests using post-IPO volatility measures. Panel A displays the summary statistics
of Buy-and-Hold Returns. Panel B and C present the results of the impact of total CEO compensation and firm pay gap on
Post-IPO Performance. The dependent variable BHAR is the 12-, 24- and 36 month (depending on the specification) buy-
and-hold return calculated from the price at the end of the firm’s first day of trading through the end of the specified return
window. Columns (1), (2) and (3) report results for multivariate regressions of the 12-, 24-, and 36-month post-IPO buy-
and-hold returns. BHAR12, BHAR24, BHAR36 are adjusted for the one, two, and three year buy-and-hold value-weighted
index return. Control variables are: CEO Tenure, CEO Duality, Founder, Initial Returns, Big 4 Auditor, Leverage,
Proceeds, EPS, VC, Technology, Internet, Underwriter, Nasdaq, Overhang, Market Return, Board Governance, HHI,
Capital Expenditure, R&D Intensity. T-statistics are included in the parentheses, are adjusted for heteroskedasticity robust
standard errors and clustered by industry and year. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels,
respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics of Post-IPO Performance Measure
IPOs with a High IPOs with a Low IPOs with High Pay IPOs with Low
Difference Difference
Compensated CEO Compensated CEO Disparities Pay Disparities
Mean Mean p-value Mean Mean p-value
BHAR12 0.02 -0.13 0.0004 -0.04 -0.05 0.4540
BHAR24 0.07 -0.12 0.0019 0.02 -0.08 0.0596
BHAR36 0.12 -0.13 0.0011 0.06 -0.08 0.0438
Panel B: Impact of Total Compensation on Post-IPO Performance
(1) (2) (3)
0.03* 0.07 0.12*
Total CEO Compensation
(1.79) (1.20) (1.76)
Control variables Y Y Y
Year Fixed Effects Y Y Y
Industry Fixed Effects Y Y Y
N 705 634 596
Adjusted 0.1536 0.1520 0.1240
Panel C: Impact of Total Firm Gap on Post-IPO Performance
(1) (2) (3)
0.01 0.01** 0.03***
Total Firm Gap
(1.60) (2.20) (2.67)
Control variables Y Y Y
Year Fixed Effects Y Y Y
Industry Fixed Effects Y Y Y
N 705 634 596
Adjusted 0.1352 0.1209 0.1483

52
Table 12: The Effect of Managerial Incentives on Post-IPO Return Volatility
This Table shows the results of additional tests using post-IPO volatility measures. Panel A displays the summary statistics
of Post-IPO Return Volatility. Panel B and C present the results of the impact of total CEO compensation and firm pay gap
on Post-IPO Return Volatility. Post-IPO return volatility is the dependent variable and is computed over +5 to +26
(trading) days post-IPO in Column (1), +5 to +63 days post-IPO in Column (2), +5 to +126 days post-IPO in Column (3),
and +5 to +189 days post-IPO in Column (4), 5 to +252 days post-IPO in Column (5), 5 to +504 days post-IPO in Column
(6), 5 to +756 days post-IPO in Column (7) (first week is ignored since there may be unusual trading activity because of
share flipping). Control variables are: CEO Tenure, CEO Duality, Founder, Initial Returns, Big 4 Auditor, Leverage,
Proceeds, EPS, VC, Technology, Internet, Underwriter, Nasdaq, Overhang, Market Return, Board Governance, HHI,
Capital Expenditure, R&D Intensity. T-statistics are included in the parentheses, are adjusted for heteroskedasticity robust
standard errors and clustered by industry and year. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels,
respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics of Post-IPO Return Volatility
IPOs with a High IPOs with a Low
Mean IPOs with High IPOs with Low Mean
Compensated Compensated
Difference Pay Disparities Pay Disparities Difference
CEO CEO
Mean Mean p-value Mean Mean p-value
+5 to +21 days post-IPO 0.03 0.05 0.0000 0.03 0.04 0.0007
+5 to +63 days post-IPO 0.04 0.05 0.0000 0.03 0.04 0.0002
+5 to +126 days post-IPO 0.04 0.05 0.0000 0.04 0.05 0.0006
+5 to +189 days post-IPO 0.04 0.05 0.0000 0.04 0.05 0.0035
+5 to +252 days post-IPO 0.04 0.05 0.0000 0.04 0.05 0.0031
+5 to +504 days post-IPO 0.16 0.20 0.0000 0.17 0.19 0.0161
+5 to +756 days post-IPO 0.16 0.20 0.0000 0.17 0.19 0.0164
Panel B: Impact of Total Compensation on Post-IPO Return Volatility
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Total CEO -0.01*** -0.01*** -0.01** -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.01
Compensation (-4.06) (-6.02) (-2.15) (-0.89) (-1.29) (-0.49) (0.42)
Control variables Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Year Fixed Effects Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Industry Fixed Effects Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
N 705 705 705 705 705 634 596
Adjusted 0.5539 0.6594 0.7234 0.7544 0.7440 0.5190 0.4046
Panel C: Impact of Total Firm Gap on Post-IPO Return Volatility
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
-0.01*** -0.01*** -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.01
Total Firm Gap
(-6.23) (-3.20) (-1.54) (-0.73) (-1.24) (-0.80) (0.65)
Control variables Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Year Fixed Effects Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Industry Fixed Effects Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
N 705 705 705 705 705 634 596
Adjusted 0.5532 0.6587 0.7230 0.7543 0.7438 0.5190 0.4047

53
Table 13: Cross-Sectional Tests
The Table illustrates the estimation of Cox Proportional Hazards Models of Probability of failure and time-to-failure. Panel A and
B present sub-sample results on the effect of CEO compensation on failure risk using a set of CEO and governance characteristics,
while Panel C displays sub-sample results of Pay Gap on failure risk using characteristics indicative of promotion probability. T-
statistics are included in the parentheses.***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. All
variables are defined in Appendix A.
Panel A1: Effect of CEO Attributes on Total CEO Compensation
(1) (2) (3)
Generalist Specialist Short Tenure. Long Tenure Young Old
Total CEO -0.08 -0.38*** -0.25*** -0.04 -0.23*** -0.02
Compensation (-1.10) (-3.00) (-3.34) (-1.07) (-3.03) (-0.56)
Control
Y Y Y Y Y Y
Variables
Industry &
Y Y Y Y Y Y
Year FE
Chi-Square 204.81 114.15 268.43 208.05 294.36 144.70
Number of
588 590 587 591 585 593
Observations
Panel A2: Effects of Governance Characteristics on Total CEO Compensation
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Non- High Comp. Low Comp.
Non- Powerful High Board Low Board
Founder Powerful Committee Committee
Founder CEOs Indep. Indep.
CEOs Quality Quality
Total CEO -0.29** -0.07* -0.06* -0.21** -0.27*** -0.07 -0.18** -0.04
Compensation (-2.49) (-1.92) (-1.77) (-2.65) (-3.31) (-0.82) (-2.39) (-1.14)
Control
Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Variables
Industry &
Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Year FE
Chi-Square 192.40 274.90 305.24 174.40 367.00 173.41 262.70 224.50
Number of
377 801 678 500 807 371 594 584
Observations
Panel B: Cross-Sectional Tests: Total Firm Pay Gap
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Non- Short
Founder Generalist Specialist Long Tenure Young Old
Founder Tenure
Total Firm Pay -0.03 -0.17** -0.17** -0.07 -0.03 -0.19** -0.03 -0.16**
Gap (-1.08) (-2.55) (-2.57) (-1.44) (-1.13) (-2.54) (-1.51) (-2.18)
Control
Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Variables
Industry &
Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Year FE
Chi-Square 157.30 244.45 215.70 214.85 167.90 238.68 221.38 175.27
Number of
377 801 588 590 587 591 585 593
Observations

54
Figure 1a: Survival Function of IPO Firms with a High or a Figure 1b: Survival Estimates of IPO Firms with a High
Low Compensated CEO or a Low Compensated CEO

Figure 2a: Survival Function of IPO Firms with High or Low Figure 2b: Survival Estimates of IPO Firms with High or
Pay Disparities Low Pay Disparities

Figure 3: Components of Total CEO Compensation Figure 4: Time Trend of Compensation and Pay Gap

$4,000,000

Total CEO
$3,500,000
CEO Salary Compensation
6%
7% $3,000,000
CEO Bonus
$2,500,000
Others
CEO Stock Awards
Executives'
18% $2,000,000
Median
50% CEO Option Awards Compensation
$1,500,000
5%
CEO Non-Equity $1,000,000 Firm Pay Gap
14% Compensation
CEO Other $500,000

$0
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012

55
Appendix A: Definitions of Variables
Variable Definition
Panel A: IPO Pricing
The difference between the first secondary market closing price available in CRSP and IPO offer price, divided by
Initial Returns
IPO offer price.
Panel B: Compensation Variables
CEO Salary The logarithmic value of cash awarded to the CEO as cash compensation in the fiscal year prior to the IPO.
CEO Bonus The logarithmic value of cash awarded to the CEO as bonus in the fiscal year prior to the IPO.
CEO Stock Awards The logarithmic value of stock granted to the CEO evaluated at grant date using own firms’ estimates.
CEO Option The logarithmic value of options granted to the CEO as option awards under the year (prior to the IPO) plan in
Awards connection with his appointment as CEO.
CEO Non-Equity
The logarithmic value of the actual amount earned under short-term, performance-based cash incentive plan for
Incentive Plan
fiscal year prior to the IPO.
Compensation
CEO All Other
The logarithmic value of all other compensation awarded to the CEO in the fiscal year prior to the IPO.
Compensation
CEO Total The logarithmic value of the sum of all the above compensations awarded to the CEO in the fiscal year prior to the
Compensation IPO.
The natural logarithm of the difference between the compensation of CEO and the median compensation of the
Firm Pay Gap
other senior (Kale et al., 2009).

CEO Slice The fraction of the aggregate compensation of the top 3 executives paid to the CEO (Bebchuk et al., 2011).
Panel C: Governance Characteristics
CEO Duality Dummy variable set to 1 if the CEO is both chairman/chairwoman and CEO, and 0 otherwise.
CEO Triality Dummy variable set to 1 if the CEO is Chairman/Chairwoman, President, and CEO, and 0 otherwise.
First factor of applying principal components analysis to five proxies of general managerial ability: Number of roles,
General Ability
Number of firms, Number of industries, CEO experience dummy, Conglomerate experience dummy (following
Index
Custodio et al., 2012).
Dummy variable equal to 1 if CEO is a generalist, and 0 otherwise. CEO is classified as a generalist if CEO’s
Generalist
general ability index is equal to or above the sample median.
Founder Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO is both founder and CEO, and 0 otherwise.
New CEO Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO tenure is smaller than 2 years, and 0 otherwise.
Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO Powerful Factor score is above the sample median. CEO Powerful Factor
Powerful CEO score from Principle Component Analysis (PCA) using CEO tenure, CEO ownership, CEO Duality and CEO
Triality (CEO, Chairman and President).
Age of CEO (in years). Old CEOs are those who have age over the sample median (51) and young CEOs are those
CEO Age
who have age lower than the sample median.
CEO Gender Dummy variable equal to 1 if CEO is female, and 0 otherwise.
Number of years working as CEO in the firm until the IPO. CEOs with High Tenure are defined those with tenure
CEO Tenure
above the sample median.
New CEO Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO tenure is smaller than 2 years, and 0 otherwise
MBA Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO holds an MBA degree, 0 otherwise.
PhD Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO holds a PhD, 0 otherwise.
JD Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO holds a JD degree, 0 otherwise.
MD Dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO holds an MD, 0 otherwise.
Panel D: Firm Fundamentals
The number of years elapsed since firm’s foundation to IPO date, using foundation dates from Thomson Financial
Firm age database as well as from the Field-Ritter dataset. The variable is transformed into the regressions by adding 1 and
taking the natural logarithm.
VC Dummy variable equal to 1 for venture capital-backed firms, and 0 otherwise.
Proceeds The natural logarithm of gross proceeds raised by the IPO estimated as shared offered times the offer price.
Overhang The ratio of shares retained by the pre-IPO shareholders over shares issued in the offering.
Dummy variable equal to 1 for most prestigious underwriters, 0 otherwise. Most reputable underwriters are those
Underwriter
with a ranking score of 9.0 or above based on Jay Ritter’s underwriter (prestige) rankings.
Internet Dummy variable equal to 1 for IPOs of Internet firms, and 0 otherwise. Internet firms are classified those with
business description containing any of the words “Internet”, “Online”, eBusiness”, “eCommerce”, and/or “Website”.

56
Dummy variable: one for IPO firms with SIC codes 3571, 3572, 3575, 3577, 3578 (computer hardware), 3661,
3663, 3669 (communications equipment), 3671, 3672, 3674, 3675, 3677, 3678, 3679 (electronics), 3812 (navigation
Technology firm
equipment), 3823, 3825, 3826, 3827, 3829 (measuring and controlling devices), 3841, 3845 (medical instruments),
4812, 4813 (telephone equipment), 4899 (communications services), and 7371, 7372, 7373, 7374, 7375, 7378, and
7379 (software).
Dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm is audited by a big four audit firm, and zero otherwise. Big four audit firms
Big 4 Auditor
include Ernst & Young, Deloitte & Touche, KPMG, and PricewaterhouseCoopers.
Nasdaq Dummy variable equal to 1 for NASDAQ-listed IPOs, and 0 otherwise.
R&D Intensity It is the ratio of total R&D expense to total sales in the fiscal year prior to the IPO.
Capital Expenditure It is the ratio of total capital expenditures to total sales in the fiscal year prior to the IPO.
Leverage The ratio of total liabilities over total assets in the fiscal year prior to IPO.
EPS Dummy variable equal to 1 for positive earnings per share in the fiscal year prior to IPO, and 0 otherwise.
Panel E: Other Firm Characteristics
Delist Dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm is delisted within 5 years after its IPO, and 0 otherwise.
Survival Time The natural logarithm of the time to delist (survival time) which is measured in months.
Market Return The compounded daily return on CRSP value-weighted index over the 20 trading days trailing the IPO.
Board Governance measure is constructed by taking the first factor of applying principal component analysis to the
following variables: board independent measured as the ratio of the number of independent outside directors to the
total number of directors; a dummy variable equal to one if the board has a nominating committee that is composed
solely of independent directors, and zero otherwise;, the percentage of outside directors on the board that were
Board Governance
appointed after the current CEO took office; the natural logarithm of the average number of other directorships held
by independent directors serving on the board; a dummy variable, equal to one if the majority of outside directors on
the board serve on three or more other boards; the natural logarithm of the number of board meetings; and the
natural logarithm of the number of directors serving on the board.
The ratio of the number of independent outside directors to the total number of directors. High Board Independence
Board Independence is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firms’ number of independent members is above the sample median.

Compensation committee quality is constructed by taking the first factor of applying principal component analysis
to five proxies of remuneration committee index: the compensation committee independence measured as the ratio
of the number of independent outside directors (of compensation committee) to the total number of directors of
compensation committee; the percentage of outside directors on the compensation committee that were appointed
Compensation
after the current CEO took office; a dummy variable, equal to one if the majority of outside directors on the
Committee Quality
compensation committee serve on three or more other boards, and equal to one otherwise; the natural log of the
number of directors serving on the compensation committee; and the natural logarithm of the number of
compensation committee meetings. High Compensation Committee Quality is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the
index is above the sample median.

HHI (Herfindahl-Hirschman Index) is calculated by squaring the market share if each firm competing in a market
HHI
and then summing the resulting numbers.

57

Вам также может понравиться