Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 21

Banking Restructuring Process in Indonesia 1997 - 2003:

To save or to freeze?‡

Cicilia Harun†

This version: April 5, 2005


Preliminary and Incomplete, comments are welcome

Abstract
This paper observes the pattern of banking restructuring process in Indonesia at the aftermath of
financial crisis in 1997-1998. The absence of suspension of convertibility and deposit insurance
scheme provided caused banking panic to occur. The banking restructuring process limits the
competitive nature of deciding to stay or exit the market. With objective to improve the banking
system performance, government and central bank had to decide how much effort to put in a
particular bank, which lead to the decision to save or to freeze the bank. The size of the bank
was a major factor in this decision. Once the authority decided to save a bank, the worse the
bank’s earning and management, the more effort put to restructure the bank.

                                                      

Although this paper is supported by data from Bank Indonesia, the central bank of Indonesia, the evaluation, opinion
and analysis expressed in this paper are of the author only and do not reflect the policy and stance of Bank Indonesia.
Author’s e-mail address: charun@bu.edu.

Boston University and Bank Indonesia.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 2

1. Introduction
The financial crisis in Indonesia in late 1997 provides an interesting condition for
economic research. The crisis was accompanied by the collapse of the national banking
system. Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) described this type of crisis as “the twin crises”,
where banking crisis precedes currency crisis and currency crisis deepens banking crisis
creating vicious spiral. The currency crisis in East Asia was a result of widespread contagion
effect triggered by an attack to Thai currency Baht in June 1997. The impact of the crisis in
Indonesia was more devastating than the rest of crisis countries in the region since it also
severely hurt the heart of the financial system.
Throughout the banking restructuring process, a number of banks went under
restructuring program. The government was able to take control of almost the entire
national banking system as a result of the liquidity support extended through the central
bank during the banking panic period. By June 1998, the liquidity support reached
approximately 50% of GDP. At the time, injecting the liquidity to the banking system was
considered a good policy compared to letting the entire financial market collapse. Under
the restructuring process, banks were frozen (closed down), taken over, recapitalized or
merged to other banks by the government. In the midst of the decisions to save or to freeze
the banks, there were considerations whether the banks were “big enough”1 so that closing
them down could be very costly to the economy. Therefore, it was expected that certain
wisdom applied when deciding which banks to freeze and to save. State-owned banks and
regional banks (owned by provincial government) were expected to be saved. Some of
them were recapitalized and merged. The dilemma appeared on deciding whether to save
or to freeze a private bank that has had a significant share in the banking system in terms of
asset value. This type of bank along with state-owned banks counted for more than 60%
share of the entire banking system.
Being an institution that is heavily regulated, a bank is required to submit financial
reports to the central bank (as banking supervisory authority) and periodically visited by
bank examiners. The bank supervisors and examiners assess the bank health by evaluating
the CAMEL (Capital, Asset Quality, Management, Earning, and Liquidity) of the bank. We
would assume that the decision to freeze or to recapitalize a bank will heavily depend on
this evaluation. However, the cost of saving (by recapitalizing and/or merging) or
liquidating (by fulfilling the claim of customer's deposit and liquidating the bank's assets) is
also considered. During the restructuring process, these 2 factors CAMEL or “performance
indicator” and cost consideration or “melting factor” provides dilemma in the decision
whether to save or to freeze a bank.
This research is aimed to look at the pattern of the banking restructuring process in
Indonesia. Although theoretical model on banking panic and banking crisis have been
                                                      
1
At the time, the term used by the Indonesian government and central bank for big banks is “systemically important
banks”. Since most literatures used only the term “big banks”, this term will be used in this paper.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 3

around for a long time, including the influential work of Diamond and Dybvig (1983),
theoretical framework and empirical research on banking restructuring process was hard to
find. What makes this paper unique is the fact that not many countries experienced
relatively massive banking restructuring process the way Indonesia did. This paper provides
documentation on the dilemma a government has to face during banking restructuring
process. Using panel data of Indonesian banks from January 1997 to December 2003
provided by Bank Indonesia, this paper tries to answer at least the question: given the
characteristics of a bank, how much effort did the authority put for the bank during
restructuring process? How big the effort will lead to the decision to save or to freeze the
bank. It is interesting to realize although the framework looks like a firm exit model, this
paper is different from other research in that type of model2. While other models focus on
firm’s decision whether to stay in or exit the market, the model of bank exit in this model is
illustrating the central planner problem in restructuring the entire banking system. This
means the firms, or in this case the banks, have very little influence on the decision to stay
in or exit the market. The authority in this model focuses on the objective of improving the
banking system through restructuring process.
The empirical evidence shows that the size of the bank overwhelmed the concern
over the performance indicators. The larger bank, the more effort put by the government
to restructure or keep the bank in the system. In fact, the worse the management and
earning indicators, the more restructuring effort put to the bank, once the decision to keep
the bank in the system was made.
The rest of the paper will be arranged as the followings. Section 2 will provide
theoretical background on bank panic and banking restructuring. This section will be
dedicated to provide background on understanding what possibly happens during banking
panic and bank restructuring. Stylized facts about Indonesian banking system especially
during the crisis will be presented in section 3. Section 4 describes the data and
methodology used in this empirical research, while the findings and discussions will be
presented in section 5. And finally section 6 concludes.

2. Banking Panic and Bank Restructuring


Calomiris & Gorton (1991) defined banking panic as the event when bank debt
holders (depositors) at all or many banks in the banking system suddenly demand that banks
convert their debt claims into cash (at par) to such extent that the banks suspend
convertibility of their debt into cash or, in certain case, act collectively to avoid suspension
of convertibility. In the case of the US, banks can collectively issue clearing-house loan
certificates. Banking panic requires most banks - not only one - to experience massive
withdrawal of fund, which distinguish it with the event of bank run.

                                                      
2
See for example Deily (1991) or Lieberman (1990) on firm exit models in competitive environment.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 4

Diamond and Dybvig (1983) provides a framework for bank runs with two types of
consumers: the patient and the impatient. Bank functions as provider of insurance against
different consumption levels through time. The demand deposit contract guarantee the
depositors to be able to withdraw their fund at time T = 1 or T = 2 satisfying sequential
service constraint, or first-come-first-served basis. Bank places fund on production with non-
risky technology that takes 2 periods (from T = 0 to T = 2). Deposits are collected by bank
at time T = 0. The patient depositors/consumers prefer to consume early and will
withdraw their deposits (at T = 1) before their fund could be used to its full capacity as
production capital. Thus, they withdraw their fund at par. The patient consumers would
rather consume later and wait until their fund grow as a result of production, thus earning
more (at T = 2) than what the impatient consumers received (at T = 1). Under full
information, the optimal risk sharing or the “good” equilibrium is achieved. The “bad”
equilibrium involves bank run, and happens when fraction of patient/impatient consumers
is stochastic and all consumers are panic and try to withdraw their funds at T = 1, thus
interrupting all production.
The assumption of sequential service constraint is important for bank run to happen
in Diamond and Dybvig model. As soon as consumers have a reason to believe that there
will be many withdrawals then they will withdraw their funds from banks. In this model,
panics are due to random withdrawals cause by self-fulfilling beliefs. This is posed as a
problem in the model by Calomiris and Gorton (1991). First, the justification for sequential
service constraint is unclear. If this assumption is dropped – say, consumers have limits in
the amount of fund they can withdraw at one time - then there will be no panics. Second, it
is hard to find example of events that can cause a change of belief that leads to banking
panic. The banking crisis in Indonesia is a good example of this type of event. This will be
discussed in section 3.
The second framework of banking panics is based on asymmetric information model
pioneered by Akerlof (1970). Banks can raise fund based on consumers’ trust. Depositors
have very little information on where their fund is invested, thus this is asymmetric
information between depositors and bank managers. Bank run - a massive withdrawal on
only one bank - happens when depositors lose confidence on the ability of banks to fulfill
the demand deposit contract. Because of this asymmetric information and the terms in
contract, bank run served as mechanism for depositors to monitor the performance of the
bank [Calomiris and Kahn 1991]3. In an extension of Diamond and Dybvig model, Jacklin
and Bhattacharya (1988) formulated an information-based runs characterized by two-sided
asymmetric information: unobservable consumption preference of the depositors by bank
managers and unobservable bank asset quality by depositors. In this set up, bank run
happens because of new information on bank asset quality rather than fear of other
                                                      
3
Calomiris and Kahn (1991) provides framework on how demand deposit contract has important advantage as part of
an incentive scheme for disciplining bankers. The maturity mismatch embedded in banking business and the ability of
depositors to make early withdrawals provide incentives for depositors to monitor the bank.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 5

depositors’ actions. In the presence of asymmetric information, depositors are forced to use
aggregate information to assess a bank’s performance [Gorton 1988]. There are three non-
mutually exclusive causes of banking panics: 1) extreme seasonal fluctuations, 2)
unexpected failure of large - typically financial – corporation, and 3) major recessions4.
Asymmetric information problem can be the source of banking panics because depositor
rush to make withdrawals from solvent as well as insolvent banks since they cannot
distinguish between them [Mishkin 1991].
In the event of banking panic, if convertibility is not suspended, as long as the
deposit withdrawal lasts, the lender of the last resort needs to provide liquidity support.
The US savings and loan debacle in …. is one example of this type of crisis. At the time, the
Federal Reserves Bank has to step in and provide liquidity in order to avoid further
widespread effect on the US financial system. Widespread banking panic can cause liquidity
problem to even a solvent banks. It is also important to know that liquidity support is
usually accompanied by high interest rates. Unless a troubled bank comes up with a brilliant
portfolio management and/or manages to provide additional capital to correct its balance
sheet, then it is very likely that the bank will become insolvent. To make things worse,
there usually exist regulations and legal limits on banks that are allowed to continue to
operate.
The arguments to save or to freeze bank(s) seem to be conflicting over the time.
Theoretically, under perfect competition framework, banks should be allowed to fail, just
like any firms in other industries. However, the nature of business of a commercial bank
makes this institution, even more than any other financial institutions, socially fragile. This
is precisely the reason bank is heavily regulated. Freezing or liquidating a bank means to
revoke its license to operate, sell its assets and pay off its liabilities. However, in practice,
the cost of liquidating a bank is not small. Using US data on bank failures from 1985
through mid-year 1988, James (1991) comes up with an average number of 30% of the
failed bank’s assets of loss when a bank is liquidated. This cost is including direct costs of
resolution (i.e. administrative and legal expenses), which counts for 10% of the bank’s
assets and larger than the direct cost of bankruptcy of non-financial firm. The rest of the loss
comes from selling the assets at recovery value5. Tussing (1970) argues that there are two
important linkages that make it hard to freeze banks. The first one is the linkage between
the failure of unsound or poorly managed bank and the failure of other banks6. As it was
discussed before, because depositors have very little information about the financial
condition of banks, depositors may exhibit herding behavior by withdrawing fund from
solvent banks. The second linkage is called the customer linkage. This linkage involves the

                                                      
4
Gorton (1988), pp. 224.
5
This recovery value is discounted from the book value. It is unavoidable since the objective of the sale of failed bank’s
assets is to recover the asset value as fast as possible to be able to pay off the bank’s liabilities. Also, the client – bank
relationship is embedded in bank’s non-fixed assets, which makes them hard to value at par.
6
The popular term for this linkage is “domino effect”.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 6

harmful effects on clients, customers, businesses that benefited from the relationship with
the failed bank, but are not responsible for the failure of the bank.
Because of the possibility of the loss incurred when a bank is liquidated, the larger
the bank’s assets, the more costly it is to liquidate the bank. Therefore, it is justified to
consider that large banks have less probability to be liquidated. Aside from the reason of the
liquidation cost, it is also believed that large banks are not likely to have bad management
and less susceptible to face major financial problem over a single incident of
misappropriation of funds or poor judgment [Horvitz 1975]. However, this view was only
shared a long time ago (early 1960s within the US banking system). As the financial market
developed and opportunity to gain profits is bigger then large banks start to take more risk,
and push the boundary of the allowable activities by a conventional bank. This development
raised the probability of a large bank to fail by bad management.
Nevertheless, there was always different treatment in handling a small bank failure
and a large bank failure. In general, there are three different ways of handling a bank failure.
First, the authority can take over the bank’s asset. It will liquidate the assets and pay off the
liabilities (including to depositors) from the fund recovered from the assets liquidation.
Second, authority can force the bank to be acquired by or merged to another bank. This
way is more desirable if the cost of liquidating the bank is higher than saving it. The third
way is to provide temporary loan to the failed bank to overcome its problem, assuming that
the problem is not systemic. The decision among these three ways is easier if the failed bank
is small. The administrative cost to verify which way is the best will be bearable so that it is
likely that the authority will make the right decision. The cost is much higher when the
failed bank is significantly large. The complexity of the business transactions, the number of
accounts, and the magnitude of the liabilities may be too costly to verify. This all could lead
to the only alternative: to save the bank.
Historically, it is expected that small and large banks received different treatments.
Liquidation of large banks is perceived to be a bad idea since the cost of verifying all the
accounts involved will be a lot higher than providing temporary relief fund while looking
for a better way to save the bank [Mayer 1975]. The different treatment also supports the
previous discussion. Even before taking into account the social cost coming from the
customer linkage, the cost of liquidating large bank is already higher than small bank.
Therefore even though it is theoretically considered inefficient since it eliminates the
potential positive externality generated by liquidating the unhealthy large banks and may
even cause moral hazard behavior of the management of large bank, liquidating large banks
are always avoided.

3. Banking System in Indonesia during the Crisis: Stylized Facts


By the end of 1996, financial system of Indonesia is dominated by commercial
banks. Commercial banks’ assets count for …..% of the entire financial system, which
includes insurance companies, savings and loans, and investment brokerage. The banks are
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 7

divided in five different groups depending on the ownerships: state-owned (owned by


central government), regional (owned by provincial government), private-forex (privately
owned and allowed to conduct foreign exchange transactions), private-non-forex (privately
owned and not allowed to conduct foreign exchange transactions), joint-venture (privately
owned by foreign banks and domestic investor), and foreign (subsidiary of foreign banks).
These banks, capital requirements fulfilled, can open branch offices in any cities in the
country. The market power of commercial bank is segmented. By 2001, the ten biggest
banks count for almost 60% of the entire banking system7. Six out of a total of seven state-
owned banks in the system are among these top ten banks.
Before the crisis, Indonesia enjoyed free capital mobility on a managed floating
exchange rate regime. The predictability of the exchange rate combined with the freedom
to borrow from abroad and interest rate differential made it possible for the financial system
to somewhat gain arbitrage profit by borrowing foreign fund and lending it to local business
either in foreign currency or local currency (Rupiah) at higher interest rates. However, high
degree exposure of banks’ liabilities in foreign currency made the financial system
vulnerable to sharp depreciation of the exchange rate.
As some other emerging markets that were experiencing balance of payment
problem, the Indonesian government turned to IMF for relief fund and economic
restructuring program. At the time, IMF thought that financial reform was the key to
resolve the problem8. Having made the commitment to the IMF for serious restructuring on
the financial system that was heavily dominated by commercial banks, Indonesian
government decided to liquidate 16 private banks on November 1, 1997. At the time, it
was considered a breakthrough effort since there had never been any significant efforts to
provide some sort of "punishment" to moral hazard behavior in the banking system.
However, on the other side of the story, it was also considered a reckless execution, since it
was not supported by a clear procedure on how to guarantee the public claim on the
liquidated banks. A move that was expected to be a signal of serious restructuring effort
turned out to cause banking panics. People had very little information about the real
financial conditions of their banks because of the lack of transparency and knowledge in
banking financial reports. Out of fear that their banks would also be closed down, the
public rushed the banks, withdrawing their fund. At the time, government did not suspend
the convertibility, prompting massive withdrawal of fund from mostly private banks. Some
of the fund was moved to state-owned banks or foreign banks (‘flight to safety’), and some
was “kept under the pillow”9. Under the central bank regulation, suspension of
convertibility can be imposed toward a bank in the way of banning the bank from
                                                      
7
The ten biggest banks count for 59.35% of the entire banking system, which consists of 239 banks by the end of 1996.
8
Various publications of IMF around the time of the East Asian Crisis suggested that IMF thought the common
problems in Indonesia, Korea, and Thailand (three countries which were hurt the most by the currency crises) was the
fact that their financial systems were below the standard.
9
“keeping money under a pillow or mattress” is the expression used in Indonesia for keeping money at home and not
taking advantage of the fact that interest can be earned if the money was kept in a bank account.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 8

participating in the clearing process. Furthermore, when the situation gets worst, the
central bank can revoke the bank’s license. However, out of fear of losing public confidence
toward the entire banking system, the government decided not to suspend the
convertibility. The rush continued and only slowed down when the government announced
explicit guarantee on public deposit on January 26, 1998. However, the bank panic already
caused severe financial bleeding for most banks. Because of the terms on bank contract over
third party deposits, even a healthy bank will suffer after experiencing massive withdrawal.
Because the government decided not to suspend the convertibility, banking panic
forced most banks to become insolvent. Banking panic then became banking crisis.
Diamond and Dybvig model provides two measures to prevent bank run. They are
suspension of convertibility and deposit insurance. None of these two measures appeared to
support the banking system in Indonesia at the time. During the banking panic, the
Indonesian government was also directly providing deposit insurance through the role of the
central bank as lender of the last resort. In a way, Indonesian banking crisis provides the
stylized fact that matched the assumption of the Diamond and Dybvig model10. Thus this
resolves the problem in Diamond and Dybvig model posed by Calomiris and Gorton
(1991). Indeed there is such a condition in the economy could create the appropriate shock
that caused bank panic, just as described in Diamond and Dybvig model. In this case it was
the currency crisis that hurt most banks because of the high exposure on the foreign
currency liabilities. However, Diamond and Dybvig also concluded that if the production
technology is risky, the lender of the last resort can no longer be as credible as deposit
insurance. In the case of Indonesia, the production technology also became risky, since the
real sector was also highly exposed to foreign currency liabilities. Banking panic was
unavoidable even though the role of the lender of the last resort was present.
In January 1998, the Indonesian Banking Restructuring Agency (IBRA) was created
to be a government agent responsible for implementing banking restructuring process in
Indonesia. This responsibility includes selling and recovering assets of frozen banks, paying
off the liabilities of frozen banks and implementing the banking recapitalization program.
The central bank continued the role of bank supervision. By May 1999 it also resumed the
role of banking licensing authority. IBRA is in charge in supervision of banks that are taken
over and recapitalized by the government. By …, … % of the entire banking system was
controlled by the government. The liquidity support from the central bank during the
banking panic period has made this possible as most banks then had large balance of
liabilities to the government. If the government and the central bank decided to save the
bank, these liabilities then converted into government ownership. Otherwise, the bank’s
license was revoked and IBRA would be in charge to recover the value of the assets through
the bank’s assets sale and pay off the bank’s liabilities. Further restructuring process on a
saved bank could also involve merging it to another bank.
                                                      
10
Recall that Diamond and Dybvig model requires an event when all consumers/agents change their belief on the
banking system so that they all decided to withdraw at T = 1.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 9

The banking recapitalization program was announced in March 1999 based on the
due diligence process conducted earlier (August – October 1999) and a joint-decree of the
Minister of Finance and Bank Indonesia Governor dated February 8, 1999 on “Commercial
Bank Recapitalization”. In the due diligence, banks are categorized in 3 groups based on the
capital condition. Category A is for banks that have CAR of 4% or more. Category B is for
banks that have CAR between -25% and 4%. And category C is for banks that have CAR
below -25%. Ironically, all 7 state-owned banks and as many as 4 regional banks were
under category C at the time. 8 other regional banks were in category B. In the
recapitalization program, the shareholders of banks in category B and C were required to
add at least 20% of additional capital needed to reach the 4% CAR requirement. According
to the decree, if banks fell in category B or managed to add capital to satisfy category B
requirement within 30 days, they are eligible for recapitalization program. The decree also
mentioned that all 7 state-owned banks and 12 regional banks will be included in the
recapitalization program for reasons of the significance of those banks in the market,
especially for small to medium business. 20 private banks which include 13 banks that
already taken over before went under the recapitalization program. 7 of these banks fell
under category C as reported in due diligence. The recapitalization program had significant
impact on the financial conditions of the banks included in the program, since the injection
of government capital changed the entire financial structure of the banks. The restructuring
process further went on merging some of the recapitalized banks. After mergers in 1999 to
2002, only 3 out of 20 private banks involved in this program have maintained their own
identities. 1 bank was merged into a state-owned bank. The rest were merged into 2
different private banks11. The following Table 1 illustrates the development of the number
of banks at the end of the years in review according to the bank groups. Table 2 listed the
events during banking restructuring process. And Figure 1 illustrates the end of year
position of total assets.

Table 1.
Number of Banks by Bank Group
End of Year
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
State-owned 7 7 8 5 5 5 5 5
Private-Forex 85 79 77 48 38 38 36 36
Private-Non Forex 79 65 64 45 43 42 40 40
Regional 27 27 27 26 26 26 26 26
Joint-venture 31 34 34 30 29 24 24 20
Foreign 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 11
Total 239 222 220 164 151 145 141 138
Source: Commercial Banks Monthly Report and Bank Indonesia Annual Reports

                                                      
11
Although one of these 2 new banks resume the old name of one of the banks merged.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 10

Table 2
List of Events during Banking Restructuring (1997 – 2003)

Date Events
Nov 1, 1997 16 private banks liquidated.
Feb 14, 1998 3 private banks taken over.
Apr 4, 1998 7 private banks frozen, 3 private banks and 1 state-owned bank taken
over♠.
May 29, 1998 1 private bank taken over.
Aug 21, 1998 3 private banks (taken over in Apr 4, 1998) frozen.
Oct 31, 1998 Due diligence of banks (started in Aug 1998) completed.
Mar 13, 1999 37 private banks, 1 joint-venture bank frozen, 7 private banks taken over.
This date also marked the announcement of the due diligence results
which determined the requirements of banks that would be eligible for
recapitalization program (or would be eligible to be saved by the
government). All state-owned banks and 12 regional banks are included in
this program.
Apr 21, 1999 1 private bank taken over, 7 other private banks recapitalized.
May 28, 1999 12 regional banks recapitalized.
Jul 23, 1999 1 private bank taken over.
Jul 31, 1999 1 private bank (recapitalized in Apr 21, 1999) merged into a state-owned
bank.
Aug, 1999 4 state-owned banks (including the one taken over on Apr 4,1998)
merged.
Dec 20, 1999 2 private banks (taken over on Apr 4, 1998) merged, 2 joint-venture
banks merged.
Jan 29, 2000 1 private bank frozen♣.
Jun 30, 2000 8 private banks merged into 1 private bank (merged earlier in Dec 20,
1999). This new merged bank then recapitalized.
June 30, 2000 2 private banks (taken over in Apr 21, 1999 and July 23, 1999)
recapitalized.
Mar – Jul 2000 4 state-owned banks recapitalized.
Oct 20, 2000 2 private banks frozen.
Feb 5, 2001 1 joint-venture bank frozen.
Mar 27, 2001 2 joint-venture banks merged.
Sep 7, 2001 2 joint-venture banks merged.
Sep 28, 2001 3 joint-venture banks merged.
Oct 30, 2001 1 private bank frozen.
Oct 28, 2002 5 private banks (4 recapitalized on Apr 21, 1999, 1 on June 30, 2000)
merged.

Taking over a state-owned bank means the supervision of this bank is put under IBRA.

Data for this bank is incomplete and excluded from the observations
Source: Bank Indonesia
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 11

Figure 1.
Total Asset by Bank Group*

700

600

500
Billions of Rupiahs

400

300

200

100

0
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003

State-owned Private - Forex Private - Non Forex Regional Joint Venture Foreign

*
End of year position.
Source: Commercial Banks Monthly Report, Bank Indonesia

During the restructuring program, all banks were required to submit


comprehensive business plan to improve their performance. Although considered healthy,
the banks that fell into category A still need to improve their performance. This is because
the authority was aiming to have 8% CAR requirement by the end of 2001. This
requirement is in accordance to the recommended standard set by Bank of International
Settlements.

4. Data and Methodology


4.1. General description of the data
The data used in this paper is provided by Bank Indonesia, the central bank of
Indonesia, which is also the banking authority of Indonesia12. This set of data was acquired
when author stayed with the bank for five weeks during summer 2004. Data was gathered
from monthly financial report of banks to the central bank since January 1997 to December
2003 (7 years). Once a bank submitted a monthly financial report, it is not necessarily the
final version of the report. Bank is obligated to make revision on its financial report if some
                                                      
12
As banking authority, Bank Indonesia issues banking regulations (based on Banking Act), conduct off site and on site
supervision of bank operation, imposes sanctions on violation of banking regulations. However, only since May 1999
under a new central bank act, the central bank assumed the authority of banking licensing. Before that, the ministry of
finance granted and revoked the bank licenses. The new central bank act also guaranteed the independence of the
central bank (monetary, banking and payment system) policies from the government.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 12

discrepancies or errors were found during the supervision or examination sessions.


Moreover, the numbers reported monthly to the central bank are the numbers calculated
using estimated tax payment. The official tax payment is reported on the annual financial
report that has to be audited by certified public accountant.
Change in reporting format was noted on September 2000. This resulted change in
how the data items were arranged, thus change in the database structure. However, the
clear description of each format allowed for smooth transition from old format to the new
one, so that the variables needed for the econometric model could be maintained
throughout the series.
The main part of the financial report consists of balance sheet and profit and loss
statement. In addition to that, a bank also submits some detailed reports as required by the
banking regulation, such as its portfolio and its off-balance-sheet activities. As some banks
which were closed down before the series ended would have stopped sending report to the
central bank, the panel data is not balance.
Some of the series in the data are missing. This is possible since a bank could miss
submitting a report in a certain month for various reasons. Administrative fine is imposed
on negligence to submit monthly report if indeed it is the bank’s fault13. However, this bank
might not be hold accountable to still submitting the financial report of the particular
month, as long as the report for the subsequent month is submitted. This is possible since
the bank supervisors may already obtained the hard copy of the missing report.
4.2. CAMEL variables
A common way to assess a firm’s health is by evaluating its capital, asset quality,
management, earning and liquidity (CAMEL). Capital ratio is usually used as measurement to
assess the capital adequacy of a bank. A bank with higher capital-to-asset ratio is protected
against operating losses more than a bank with a lower ratio, although this depends on the
relative risk of loss at each bank. There are several standard measures of capital adequacy:
1) Risk-adjusted capital ratio; 2) Total capital to total assets ratio; 3) Leverage ratio; and 4)
Total risk-adjusted capital ratio14. By Bank for International Settlement’s standard, the last
measure is used for banks and so is in Indonesia. However, calculation of this capital
adequacy ratio (CAR) requires risk-weighted assets (RWA) data. Author also attempted to
get the CAR numbers calculated by the central bank. By the time this paper was written,
neither sets of data (RWA and CAR) were completely acquired. Therefore, ratio of total
capital to asset is used as proxy. This capital measure is reported in bank’s balance sheet. It
includes core capital, reserves, retained earning, and profits. Risk-weighted asset will still
be incorporated in a different way. This will be taken care of in the asset quality measure.

                                                      
13
The non-existence of some series of monthly report could also be caused by technical errors from the central bank’s
database, which the author considered irrecoverable. However, none of the missing series are in consecutive order, and
it is less than 0.3% of the entire series.
14
See Fitch 2000, pp. 76 for complete definitions of these measures of capital adequacy.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 13

Asset quality is measured by collecting the data on the category of earning assets of
each bank for every month. Before March 1998, earning assets (credits, bonds, inter-bank
placements, stocks, trade financing transactions and derivative transactions) were
categorized in four levels according to the degree of performing (“4” being “non-
performing”). Beginning March 1998, there are five levels. For simplicity, and also
confirmed by the banking regulations, level 1 and 2 after March 1998 and level 1 before
March 1998 are categorized as “performing earning assets”. Levels 3 and 4 before March 1998
and levels 3, 4, 5 after March 1998 are categorized as “non-performing earning assets”15. The
measure of asset quality will be represented by the fraction of “performing earning assets” within
total earning assets.
Among the CAMEL variables, only management is hard to quantify. In Indonesia,
the evaluation of management is mostly done qualitatively16. One measure that is relevant
to management is the ratio of operational revenue to operational expenditure (OPR_RATIO). This
ratio is also used in representing the earning variable. Assuming that how good the
management is correlated with this ratio, this ratio is used to represent the management
measure.
Earning variable will be represented by the return on asset (ROA) or ratio of profit (net
income) to asset. Another ratio relevant to the earning variable is the ratio of operational
revenue to operational expenditure. However, as it was stated before, this measure will be
used as management variable. Two other measures are also used in assessing earning. They
are net interest margin (NIM) and return on equity (ROE) or ratio of profit to capital. Net interest
margin is the difference between interest revenue and interest payment. To normalize this
measure, NIM will be divided by total earning asset.
Liquidity variable is represented by the ratio of liquid asset to total liabilities. In
Indonesia, liquid assets of banks consist of the bank’s position in cash (in vault) and central
bank placement (including reserve requirement and excess reserves stored in checking
account at the central bank and the central bank CD17). The liquidity ratio measured how
bank manage to fulfill its obligation to provide fund whenever it has to pay off its liabilities,
including deposit withdrawal.
4.3. Methodology
Unlike other panel data research on firm exit models, which are mostly within
competitive market, monopoly, or oligopoly frameworks, this is a central planner problem.
                                                      
15
The earning asset quality levels after March 1998 are “performing” (1), “under special attention” (2), “less
performing” (3), “questionable” (4), and “non-performing” (5). Level 2 “under special attention” was not part of the
system before March 1998.
16
Bank supervisor will have a set of questions for the management to answer. The bank’s management performance is
determined by the answers to this questionnaire.
17
Until recently, Indonesia does not have a risk free money market instrument besides central bank CD. Domestic
government bond only started to be traded after the financial crisis, although the market is still very thin. The central
bank CD (called SBI, short for Sertifikat Bank Indonesia) is considered liquid since it can be used as collateral to go for
discount window (borrowing from central bank) or interbank borrowing.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 14

During the banking restructuring process, banks do not make decision whether they want
to shut down their operation, merge with other banks, or inject more capital to resolve
their financial problems. The central bank and the government make those decisions. A
bank could exit the market because they have become insolvent and could not fulfill the
requirements of capital ratio imposed by the authority. Insolvent bank could also stay in the
market if the authority chose to save it. The following is the function representing the
central planner’s effort on the restructuring process18.

Yit* = β ' X it + γ ' Z it + δ k + ε it (1)

where
Y* : The restructuring effort on the particular bank
X : vector of CAMEL variables or performance indicator
Z : vector of melting factors
δ : time dummies
i : index for individual bank
t : index for month and year
k : index for year

The model is estimated using ordered probit specification. The dependent variable Y
is an ordered qualitative variable related to the unobserved effort given by the authority on
bank restructuring Y*, such that

1 if Y* < λ0 for liquidated/fozen banks (2)


Y= { 2 if λ0 < Y < λ1 for healthy banks
*

3 if Y* > λ1 for restructured banks

with λ’s being the estimated threshold value representing the effort the authority put for
banks receiving different treatment. Restructured banks are banks that received
restructuring treatment from the authority. They were taken over by the authority and/or
received injection of capital or recapitalized and/or merged to other banks. Healthy banks
are the banks that were diagnosed healthy and did not participate in the recapitalization
program. The liquidated/frozen banks were the banks that were diagnosed unhealthy.
Although there was justification, the authority had the discretionary in deciding whether to
save or freeze these banks. Appendix A provide a more detailed algorithm on how to set up
the ordered dependent variables based on the events listed on Table 2.
We can think of Y* as the amount of money or man-hours the authority is willing to
spend to deal with a bank. The authority has very little interest to put effort on keeping the
                                                      
18
This framework set up follows Deily 1991.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 15

liquidated/frozen banks. The healthy banks are obviously kept by the authority since they
were performing adequately in the banking system. In general, during banking restructuring
system all banks are required to submit business plan to improve their performance. Even if
effort needs to be put on improving healthy banks, it will be less than the effort on
restructuring the unhealthy banks.
The performance indicators are the CAMEL variables explained in the previous sub
section. Meanwhile, there are two different melting factors used in the model. The first one
is DSTATE, which is a dummy variable of whether a bank is government-owned or not.
The second one is LASSET, which is the log of total asset. The estimation also includes
annual time dummies to capture the effects of the differences in economic and political
conditions surrounding the restructuring process every year. Individual effect was not
considered since this is a non-competitive environment. Banking panic and tight monetary
policy also left very little room for the idiosyncratic behavior of the bank. Even when bank
attempted to attract the market with competitive financial products, consumers still
considered safety first. This has been the mood of the banking system throughout the
banking restructuring process.
It is interesting to observe the outcome of β coefficients. The authority decided the
eligibility of a bank to participate the banking restructuring program based on its CAR. This
variable is represented in this paper by Capital-Asset ratio (CA_RATIO) and Asset Quality
(ASSET_QUALITY). ROA, ROE, NIM and Operational Ratio (OPR_RATIO) can be
considered as the variables representing the business side of the bank19. And we can
consider liquidity is an indicator of prudential banking behavior of the bank. However, we
should expect γ to be positive, since the bigger the value of the melting factors, the more
willing the authority to try to keep the bank. Our aim is also to see whether the β
coefficients are more significant than γ coefficients.

5. Results and Discussion


The ordered probit regressions results on different combinations of CAMEL
variables representing earning are presented in Table 3. The first thing that we noticed is
that LASSET is always significant. Coefficient for LASSET is always more significant than
any other coefficients. This confirmed how much the authority care about the size of the
banks. The bigger the bank, the more the authority is willing to put effort in restructuring
the bank. Surprisingly, the coefficient for DSTATE is not significant. The decision on
including all troubled government-owned banks was overwhelmed by the fact that these
banks mostly had big asset.
CA_RATIO and ASSET_QUALITY gave positive relationship over the
restructuring effort. This is not surprising, since these two variables are proxy to the CAR,
which is the indicator used by the authority on deciding the eligibility of banks for banking
                                                      
19
Recall that banks were required to submit business plan to show their plan in improving their performance.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 16

recapitalization program. Higher CAR represents better solvency of bank, which makes it
more desirable for the authority to be restructured/saved or to be kept in the system.
LIQUIDITY basically gave the same effect for authority. This variable represents how much
the bank can satisfy withdrawals or pay off its short-term liabilities. The better the bank’s
liquidity condition, the authority is more interested in putting more effort to restructure
the bank or to keep the bank in the system.

Table 3
Determinants of Restructuring Effort

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)


0.0008 0.0009** 0.0008 0.0009** 0.0008 0.0009** 0.0008
CA_RATIO
(0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005)
ASSET_ 0.2217 0.2123 0.2123 0.2216 0.2123 0.2217 0.2217
QUALITY (0.1414) (0.14099) (0.1410) (0.1414) (0.1410) (0.1415) (0.1414)
-0.3822 -0.3862*** -0.3862*** -0.3822 -0.3862*** -0.3822*** -0.3822
OPR_RATIO
(0.1014) (0.1025) (0.1024) (0.1014) (0.1024) (0.1014) (0.1014)
-2.8E-05 -2.8E-05*** - - -2.8E-05*** -2.8E-05*** -
NIM
(3.04E-06) (3.07E-06) (3.07E-06) (3.05E-06)
-6.3E-05 - -6.6E-05 - -6.6E-05 - -6.3E-05
ROA
(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001)
-0.0037** - - -0.0037** - -0.0037** -0.0037**
ROE
(0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0017)
0.0002* 0.0002* 0.0002* 0.0002* 0.0002* 0.0002* 0.0002*
LIQUIDITY
(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001)
0.0395 0.0403 0.0398 0.0401 0.0398 0.0400 0.0396
DSTATE
(0.0406) (0.0405) (0.0406) (0.0406) (0.0406) (0.0406) (0.0406)
0.2149*** 0.2148*** 0.2149*** 0.2148*** 0.2150*** 0.2148*** 0.2149***
LASSET
(0.0111) (0.0111) (0.0111) (0.0111) (0.0111) (0.0111) 0.0111
0.3610*** 0.3585*** 0.3584*** 0.3611*** 0.3584*** 0.3611*** 0.3610***
YEAR1998
(0.0603) (0.0601) (0.0601) (0.0603) (0.0601) (0.0603) 0.0603
1.1543*** 1.1500*** 1.1501*** 1.1543*** 1.1501*** 1.1543*** 1.1543***
YEAR1999
(0.0809) (0.0808) (0.0808) (0.0809) (0.0808) (0.0809) 0.0809
0.9314*** 0.9381*** 0.9381*** 0.9315*** 0.9381*** 0.9315*** 0.9314***
YEAR2000
(0.0660) (0.0659) (0.0660) (0.0660) (0.0659) (0.0660) 0.0660
0.5327*** 0.5473*** 0.5471*** 0.5329*** 0.5471*** 0.5328*** 0.5327***
YEAR2001
(0.0695) (0.0696) (0.0696) (0.0695) (0.0696) (0.0695) 0.0695
-0.4201*** 0.4273*** 0.4269*** 0.4206*** 0.4269*** 0.4205*** 0.4202***
YEAR2002
(.0657) (0.0661) (0.0661) (0.0656) (0.0661) 0.0656 0.0657
-0.0175 -0.0137 -0.0147 -0.0171 -0.0144 -0.0168 -0.0178
YEAR2003
(0.0454) (0.0454) (0.0454) (0.0454) (0.0454) 0.0454 0.0454

Pseudo R2 0.1861 0.1847 0.1848 0.1861 0.1848 0.1861 0.1861

*** significant at 1% level, ** significant at 5% level, * significant at 10% level


Notes: numbers in parentheses are robust standard errors
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 17

The interesting effects came from the variables representing the management and
earning of the bank: OPR_RATIO, NIM, ROA and ROE. It is important to realize that
during the banking crisis, most banks had difficult time to maintain good financial
indicators. For example, average ROE in December 1998 and December 1999 are -
437.23% and -110.8% respectively. Again, this fact was overwhelmed by the authority’s
concern over the cost of liquidating banks. Once the decision to safe a bank is made, the
worse the earning and management of the bank, the more effort will be put by the authority
to improve in the restructuring process. This represented how much the authority is willing
to save a troubled bank once this bank is eligible (by the asset size) for restructuring
process.
All yearly time dummies are significant. The ordered probit results also revealed
that in all combinations of variables, the yearly time dummies are most significant in year
1999 and 2000. The coefficients are also the largest in year 1999 and 2000. These two years
marked the heaviest recapitalization activities from the authority. It is interesting to see that
in addition to the effects from the performance indicators and melting factors, the time
dummies basically capture how big the restructuring effort put by the authority in those
years.
[notes: need more discussions - linking the results to the theory - on this section]

6. Conclusion
The stylized facts presented in Indonesia’s case provide an example on how
sequential service constraint without suspension of convertibility and deposit insurance
could create chaos that caused banking panic and banking crisis in Indonesia. In effort to
save the national banking system, the government had to perform the bank restructuring
process. This paper also showed the dilemma experienced by the banking authority
(government and central bank) in determining which banks to save or to freeze. It is not
surprising that the authority care a lot about the size of the bank. The empirical exercise
over panel data of bank’s monthly financial report provides evidence that the bigger the
bank, the higher the effort put by the authority to improve the bank.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 18

Notes for further work on this paper


Do more analysis on the results using the partial derivatives of the regression results and the
estimated threshold. Need to check how well the predictions of the estimated coefficients. Given
the characteristics of the banks, will it be categorized as healthy, recapitalized or frozen?
Do higher resolution analysis, semester per semester pattern observation, to see if there is any
pattern change in the restructuring effort. Link this to the list of events. See if the effort is
consistent.
Acknowledgement
Author would like to acknowledge the support given by Bank Indonesia’s officials,
researchers, and staffs during data research at Bank Indonesia’s headquarter, Jakarta in summer
2004. Ita Rulina, Dipa Pertiwi (at Bureau of Financial System Stability) and Yan Syafri (at
Directorate of Banking Supervision) especially helped with lots of insights on Indonesian banking
system and supervision. Indah Iramadhini, Dian Oktariani, and Eka Vitaloka (at Banking Data
Department) provided tremendous support for the panel data. This paper also benefited from
Professor Marianne Baxter’s and Professor Victor Aguirregabiria’s valuable advice and direction.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 19

References
Akerlof , George A. (1970), “The Market for Lemons: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3 (Aug., 1970), 488 – 500.
Bank Indonesia, Jakarta, Indonesia, “Bank Indonesia Annual Report” 1996/97, 1997/1998,
1998/99, 2000, 2001, 2002, 2003.
Batunanggar, Sukarela (2002), “Indonesa’s Banking Crisis Resolution”, manuscript.
Deily, Mary E. (1991), “Exit Strategies and Plant-Closing Decisions: The Case of Steel,” The RAND
Journal of Economics, Vol. 22, No. 2 (Summer, 1991), 250 – 263.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Philip H. Dybvig (1983), “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance and Liquidity,”
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, No. 3 (Jun. 1983), 401 – 419.
Calomiris, Charles W. and Charles M. Kahn (1991), “The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring
Optimal Banking Arrangements,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 3 (Jun.,
1991), 497 - 513
Calomiris, Charles W and Gary Gorton (1991), “The Origins of Banking Panics: Models, Facts, and
Bank Regulation”, in R. Glenn Hubbard, ed., Financial Markets and Financial Crises, A
National Bureau of Economic Research Project Report (Chicago 1991), pp. 109 – 173.
Enoch, Charles, Barbara Baldwin, Olivier Frécaut, and Arto Kovanen (2001), “Indonesia: Anatomy
of a Banking Crisis Two Years of Living Dangerously 1997-99,” IMF (International Monetary
Fund) Working Paper, WP/01/52 (May 2001).
Fitch, Thomas P. (2000), “Dictionary of Banking Terms,” 4th Ed., Baron’s Educational Series, Inc
(2000).
Gorton, Garry (1988), “Banking Panic and Business Cycles,” Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, Vol.
40, No. 4 (Dec., 1988), 751 – 781.
Horvitz, Paul M. (1975), “Failures of Large Banks: Implications of Bank Supervision and Deposit
Insurance”, The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis”, Vol. 10, No. 4 (Nov., 1975)
589 – 601.
Hsiao, Cheng (2003), “Analysis of Panel Data,” 2nd Edition, Cambridge University Press, 2003.
International Monetary Fund (IMF), various publications: speeches, press briefing, country
information (IMF web site: http://www.imf.org).
Jacklin, Charles J. and Sudipto Bhattacharya (1988), “Distinguishing Panics and Information-based
Bank Runs: Welfare and Policy Implications,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 96, No.
3 (Jun., 1988), 568 – 592.
James, Christopher (1991), “The Losses Realized in Bank Failures”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 46,
No. 4 (Sep., 1991), 1223 - 1242.
Kaminsky, Graciela and Carmen Reinhart (1999), “The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and
Balance-of-Payment Problems,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (Jun., 1999)
473 - 500
Lieberman, Marvin B. (1990), “Exit from Declining Industries: “Shakeout” or “Stakeout”?” The
RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 21, No. 4 (Winter, 1990), 538 – 554.
Mayer, Thomas (1975), “Should Large Banks Be Allowed to Fail?” The Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 10, No. 4 (Nov., 1975) 603 – 610.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 20

Mishkin, Frederick S. (1991), “Asymmetric Information and Financial Crises: A Historical


Perspective,” in R. Glenn Hubbard, ed., Financial Markets and Financial Crises, A National
Bureau of Economic Research Project Report (Chicago 1991), pp. 67 – 108.
Mishkin, Frederick S. (1992), “An Evaluation of the Treasury Plan for Banking Reform” Journal of
Economic Perspective, Vol. 22, No. 3 (Aug., 1990), 370 – 387.
Skully, Michael T. (1982), “Commercial Banking in Indonesia: An Examination of Its Development
and Present Structure”, Asian Survey, Vol. 22, No. 9 (Sep., 1982), 874 - 893.
Takagi, Shinji (2004), “Responding to Currency Crises in Emerging Market Economies: The IMF in
Indonesia, Korea and Brazil”, IMF (Independent Evaluation Office), November 2004 (IMF web
site: http://www.imf.org)
Tussing, A. Dale (1970), “Meaningful Bank Failure: A Proposal”, The Journal of Industrial Economics,
Vol. 18, No. 3 (Jul., 1970), 242 - 252.
Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (2002), “Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data,” The MIT
Press, 2002.
Cicilia Harun - Banking Restructuring in Indonesia 1997 – 2003 / 21

APPENDIX A.
Algorithm of Setting Up the Ordered Dependent Variables
For each bank i:
*For Liquidated/Frozen Banks (Y = 1)
If (t = date of liquidation announcement of bank i) then Yi,t-1 = 1

*For Recapitalized Banks (Y = 3)


trecap = March 1999 (the date the government announce the eligibility of banks
for recapitalization)

If (Bank i is taken over at time t)


then t1 = t
TakenOver = True
If (Bank i is recapitalized at time t)
then t2 = t
Recapitalized = True
If (Bank i is merged at time t)
then t3 = t
Merged = True
If (Bank i is liquidated at time t)
then t4 = t
Liquidated = True

If TakenOver and Liquidated


then Yi,t = 3 for t = t1..(t4-1)
If TakenOver and Recapitalized and (Not Merged)
then Yi,t = 3 for t = t1..(t2-1)
If (Not TakenOver) and Recapitalized and (Not Merged)
then Yi,t = 3 for t = trecap..(t2-1)
If (Not TakenOver) and Recapitalized and Merged
then Yi,t = 3 for t = trecap..t3
If (Not TakenOver) and (Not Recapitalized) and Merged
then Yi,t = 3 for t = t3
If (Not TakenOver) and Recapitalized and (Not Merged)
then t5 = the date when bank i is announced healthy
Yi,t = 3 for t = trecap..t5

*For Healthy Banks (Y = 2)


If missing/undefined Yi,t then Yi,t = 2

Вам также может понравиться