Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 28

Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

National innovative capacity in East Asia


Mei-Chih Hu ∗ , John A. Mathews
Macquarie Graduate School of Management, Macquarie University, Sydney, NSW 2109, Australia

Received 27 October 2003; received in revised form 17 October 2004; accepted 18 April 2005
Available online 16 September 2005

Abstract

The innovative capacity of a country is the basic driving force behind its economic performance; it provides a measure of the
institutional structures and support systems that sustain innovative activity. Recent work, such as that by Furman, Porter and Stern
(FP&S) frames a concept of national innovation capacity measured by patenting rates, and estimates its institutional sources for a
group of 17 OECD countries. In this present paper, we extend and modify the FP&S approach by applying it to five “latecomer”
countries from East Asia, none of which was included in the FP&S study. First, we reproduce the FP&S methodology in relation
to the five East Asian countries, gathering comparable data over a comparable (but truncated) time period. While our results are
in broad agreement with the findings of FP&S, we document some important differences for latecomer East Asian economies: a
smaller number of national factors matter, and there seems to be an important (though subtle) role for public R&D expenditure.
These findings have important implications for successful catch-up strategies. We supplement these aggregate findings with firm-
and institution-level data from Taiwan, where the breakthrough to innovation has arguably proceeded farther than in any other
East Asian country. In these ways, we shed light on the process through which a latecomer country is able to close the gap with
the more developed countries, by channeling resources towards the raising of its innovative capacity.
© 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: National innovative capacity; Innovative performance; East Asia; Patents

1. Introduction the technological frontier where innovation becomes


a principle driver. In the case of the outstanding late-
Innovation is widely regarded as the central process comer economies of the 19th century, Germany and the
driving economic growth and the competitiveness of US, it took from 50 to 100 years for these countries to
nations. But it takes a long time for a country to reach catch-up with and overtake the leader, the UK. In the
20th century, first Japan has caught up with the leaders,
∗ Corresponding author. Present address: Feng Chia University,
and in the postwar period, the outstanding cases have
Taichung, Taiwan. been those of the East Asian “Tiger” economies, Korea,
E-mail addresses: mchu@fcu.edu.tw (M.-C. Hu),
john.mathews@mq.edu.au (J.A. Mathews).
Taiwan, Hong Kong and Singapore, described by the
URL: http://www.gsm.mq.edu.au/facultyhome/john.mathews/index. World Bank as the “East Asian Miracle” (World Bank,
html. 1993). Given that these East Asian countries have per-

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.respol.2005.04.009
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1323

fected world-class production systems, the issue arises: important than “new-to-the-world” innovation. We
to what extent have they been able to shift from “from find that latecomer countries are much more focused
imitation to innovation” (Kim, 1997b). in their development of the institutional foundations of
Innovation in the case of latecomer countries needs national innovative capacity, and more targeted in their
to be understood in a way that is rather different from reliance on certain industrial sectors for innovative
innovation in the case of leaders. The lead countries activity and patenting (such as IT and electronics).
are interested in maintaining their lead through “new- We examine these issues in aggregate across our five
to-the-world” innovations, in products, or processes sample countries, and also in greater depth in the case
or abstract knowledge generally (such as the human of one of the countries, namely Taiwan, where we
genome). For the latecomer countries whose primary examine patenting activity at the level of the firm and
strategic goal is to catch-up, innovation means “new- institution.
to-the-country” innovation, which involves the man- Our paper engages with two quite distinct kinds of
agement of accelerated diffusion of technologies from literatures. On the one hand, there is the literature on
advanced to catch-up countries (Amsden, 1998; Hob- East Asian industrial development and technological
day, 1994; Mathews, 2001). upgrading, which has emphasized capture of tech-
One of the clearest indications of innovation perfor- nologies by East Asians as a process of moving from
mance is the rate of take-up of patents issued by the ‘imitation’ to ‘innovation’ but has not necessarily
US Patent and Trademarks Office (USPTO). Here, it is considered the next step in this process, namely that
found that East Asian firms and institutions have made which takes countries to the point where innovation
astonishing strides in recent years (Hu and Jaffe, 2001; rates can be captured in terms of patenting within
Jung and Imm, 2002). Taiwan in particular has risen to the USPTO. On the other hand, there is the literature
third highest in the world in terms of per capita take-up on national systems of innovation, where the bias of
of USPTO patents over the past 5 years (1997–2001). scholarship has been towards the developed countries,
Accordingly, in this paper we analyze the patenting per- and towards ‘new-to-the-world’ innovation. We see the
formance of five East Asian countries in terms of their novelty of our paper as straddling these literatures, and
uptake of patents from the USPTO. In order to do so, we demonstrating, firstly, that there is a real innovative
utilize a methodology recently introduced by Furman tendency at work in the East Asian countries and
et al. (2002); Furman, Porter and Stern (FP&S), applied not just an increase in the ‘propensity to patent’,
to a panel of 17 OECD countries with data covering the and secondly, that the systems of innovation in the
period from 1973 to 1996. This study excluded all East catch-up countries of East Asia differ in significant
Asian countries apart from Japan. Our study is thus at ways from those demonstrated for the advanced OECD
once a primary investigation of the innovative capac- countries.
ity of five East Asian countries, and an extension of On the first point, our principle finding, apart from
the FP&S approach to a set of countries not previously the striking increases in patenting rates themselves,
included in their analysis. is the demonstration that the recent increases in
In this study, we build a dataset that is comparable patenting rates in East Asia, particularly in Taiwan,
to that employed by FP&S for the OECD countries, are accompanied by an increase in R&D expenditure.
from primary sources available from the individual We interpret this to mean that there is a real increase
countries and from international sources. We then in innovative activity, and not just in a ‘propensity
utilize this dataset to demonstrate that the principle to patent’. This stands in marked contrast with the
relationships identified and estimated by FP&S in findings for the US or OECD countries generally,
OECD countries carry over to the five East Asian coun- where it has been found that the ratio of the number
tries, but with some differences in emphasis that are of patented inventions to real R&D expenditure or to
entirely to be anticipated in examining the innovative numbers engaged in science and engineering, have
capacity of countries either still in, or recently emerged generally been in decline since the 1960s (Evenson,
from, a catch-up, latecomer phase. In such a phase, 1993).
technology transfer and management of diffusion On the second point our principle finding is that in
(“new-to-the-country” innovation) are relatively more latecomer countries, in addition to the significance of
1324 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

private R&D in accounting for much of the innovative 2. Use of patent statistics as indicators of
capacity (as found in FP&S), there is also a significant innovation and the experience of East Asia
effect of public R&D expenditure; this latter emerges
as an important determinant of the degree of special- While technological innovation cannot be precisely
ization of the East Asian countries. We interpret this measured, patenting rates have long been considered
as a significant difference in the kind of innovative a well-grounded proxy for the level of innovation
system developed in a latecomer country seeking to (Schmookler, 1966; Soete and Wyatt, 1983; Griliches,
catch-up from that in an advanced country. The role of 1990; Trajtenberg, 1990; Dosi et al., 1990; Eaton and
public R&D expenditure can be seen both as a source Kortum, 1996, 1999; Kortum, 1997; Kanwar and Even-
of innovative capacity in itself, and as a guide to son, 2001; Jones, 2002; Furman et al., 2002; Hage-
steer the utilization of limited resources in latecomer doorn and Cloodt, 2003). When patents cause sources
countries. bias, the advantage associated with using international
The paper is organized as follows. First, by way of patents are described in many prior studies (e.g. Soete
preliminaries, we discuss the role of patent statistics and Wyatt, 1983 and Furman et al., 2002). In addition, a
(in terms of quantity and quality) as indicators of strong link between foreign patent grants and domestic
innovation, and the experience of East Asian countries R&D investments as well as foreign patents and inter-
in this regard, bearing in mind some of the caveats national trade and foreign investments demonstrates
involved in utilizing this measure of innovation. the important variables like foreign patenting and
Then, we introduce the concept of national innovative international trade (Soete, 1987). While researchers
capacity (NIC) and trace its origins to three streams of have emphasized involvement in global production
literature (as done by FP&S) but add a fourth stream for networks as an important source of knowledge for
latecomer countries, where NIC must rest on new-to- outstanding export performance in late industrializ-
the-country innovation rather than new-to-the-world ing countries, several studies have also explored the
improvements. In this setting we frame six research relationship and importance of differences in technol-
questions that guide our study and differentiate it ogy interaction with international trade performance
from that conducted by FP&S. We then introduce our (e.g. Dosi et al., 1990). These support the relationship
own dataset, laboriously collected from the individual between innovation activity and its outstanding export
countries, and our measures of the principal categories performance for East Asian latecomer countries.
to be employed, and in Section 4 we demonstrate conti- Scholars associated with the NBER have developed
nuities between our data and results and those obtained methodologies for studying the flow of knowledge,
by FP&S. Our distinctive results are reported in Sec- from one country to another, utilizing patent statistics.
tion 5, where we extend the FP&S methodology for In particular data from patents taken out in the USPTO
measuring NIC by including a variable “public R&D” by both American and foreign firms enables researchers
not included in the OECD study, and examining its to trace the influence of knowledge spillovers and
impact. Then in Section 6 we provide insights into the degrees of specialization associated with industrial
strategies involved in public R&D and patenting by one clustering (Jaffe and Trajtenberg, 1998). Studies have
of the five countries concerned, namely Taiwan, based utilized such USPTO patenting activity to examine the
on our own case interviews with firms and agencies experience of a specific institution, such as biological
in the country, and on analyses from independent data resource centres (Furman and Stern, 2002), an indi-
sources (such as CHI Research Inc.). This case study vidual country, such as Israel (Trajtenberg, 1999), and
reinforces the overall findings of our analysis, as well international knowledge flow as in the case of Taiwan
as providing institutional and strategic detail that gives and South Korea (Hu and Jaffe, 2001) or the case of
enhanced insight into the strategies employed by late- Singapore (Hu, 2003). Many have argued that only cer-
comers. We summarize our findings in Section 7, where tain types of innovation can be measured (Arundel and
again we emphasize the differences found between the Kabla, 1998; Griliches, 1990; Mansfield, 1986), and
approach to innovation taken by latecomer countries that many important innovations are not patented (e.g.
in East Asia and the approach of the leading OECD food and tobacco) while some patents are awarded for
countries. very modest discoveries (e.g. basic metal and automo-
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1325

tive). However, patents can be an appropriate indicator on this measure two East Asian countries have pene-
in the context of high-tech sectors. trated this listing, namely Taiwan and Korea, which
Since patents can vary enormously in their impor- now rank 8th and 12th, respectively, in the world in
tance or value, simple patent counts are unlikely to terms of patents accumulated. This indicates that they
totally capture the innovative output of companies (see, are now to be considered as much innovators as imita-
for example, Trajtenberg, 1990; Jaffe et al., 1993; Jaffe tors.
and Trajtenberg, 2002). The alternative is patent cita- The specific experience of East Asia in patenting
tions rate, which is recognized as a sharper indicator of with the USPTO is shown in Table 1, as compared
innovation and is often used to measure the impact of with G7 countries and a reference group of comparable
knowledge flow (see the NBER studies). While inno- countries, including Finland, Israel, Ireland and Spain.
vative performance (e.g. patenting rate) in East Asian Table 1 reveals just how rapid has been the rise of East
countries mostly emerged in the 1990s (particularly Asia as an innovative force. In terms of utility patents
in the second half of the 1990s), the measurement of taken out in the US over the past 5 years, per capita,
innovation using citations as indicators would create Taiwan now ranks third in the world behind the US
a truncation problem.1 Thus, we utilize the more tra- and Japan, with 17.2 patents per head over the period
ditional measure of innovation in terms of patenting 1997–2001; Korea ranks as number 8, with 6.6 patents
rates. per head per year over the same period, while Singa-
With all their deficiencies, then, patenting rates, and pore is rising fast. All five countries in East Asia show
particularly data concerning what the USPTO calls the highest annual growth rates in the world, all exceed-
“utility patents” (which represent real inventiveness, ing 20% per year (final column). These data reveal the
rather than repeat patents and other “noise” in the data extent to which the East Asian countries have been
for patents overall) represent a uniform and time-robust making the shift from imitation to innovation, and mak-
measure of innovative output with an immediate eco- ing it very quickly, particularly over the most recent
nomic significance: the time and trouble involved for period 1997–2001.
firms to seek patents within the USPTO system filter If we look at the firms and institutions involved,
out trivial or idiosyncratic innovations. The US market we gain a clearer idea of what has been happening in
is widely recognized as the largest and the most tech- these latecomer catch-up countries. Fig. 1 shows the
nologically advanced in the world and the US patent world’s top 12 firms in terms of their patenting activity:
statistics are more reliable indicators because of the each of the top 12 recorded on average more than 1000
common screening procedures imposed by the USPTO patents per year with IBM a long way in the lead. It is
(Pavitt, 1988). Furthermore, patenting in the US is in interesting to note that of the top 12, three are US firms,
itself an important technological achievement for East no less than eight are Japanese, while the Korean firm,
Asian firms, and one that has a substantive signifi- Samsung, has penetrated to the top echelons. Indeed,
cance as well as providing a measure of innovative Samsung registered the highest growth rate, increasing
capacity. the number of its patents at just over 25% per year over
By the most conservative measure, namely accu- the past 5 years.
mulated total of utility patents taken out in the USPTO An even clearer picture of what drives the perfor-
over the past quarter century (from 1975 to 2001), the mance of Korean, Taiwanese (and Singaporean) firms
G7 countries do as well as expected. The US is far in is revealed in Table 2, which shows the number of
the lead, with close to 1.4 million patents accumulated, patents taken out in each of the 5 years 1997–2001
followed by Japan, with nearly half a million, and then by East Asian organizations (both firms and institu-
Germany, UK and France and Canada. Switzerland has tions) and the totals. Almost all of these firms and
historically done well, particularly because of its phar- organizations operate in the electronics, IT, commu-
maceutical firms, as well as Italy and Sweden. But even nications and particularly the semiconductor sectors.
These are the advanced sectors where the East Asian
1 Older patents would have received a higher fraction of the total firms have been making their mark, driving the overall
number of eventual citations, whereas for more recent patents would totals reported in Table 1 and Fig. 1. Korea has been
have lower (Jaffe and Trajtenberg, 2002). much more focused and concentrated in its patenting
1326
Table 1
Country statistics: averages for 5- and 30-year periods (utility patent only)
Country Patents per year Patents per capita Success rate Annual growth rate (%)

M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349


1968–1997 1992–1997 1997–2001 1968–1997 1992–1997 1997–2001 1968–1997 1992–1997 1997–2002 1968–1997 1992–1997 1997–2001
G7
USA 44850 56683 79717 15.5 21.5 28.6 58.9 52.2 53.2 4.9 7.9 9.7
Japan 11216 22433 29949 10.3 17.9 23.7 55.5 57.9 61.5 8.6 6.5 10.2
Germany 5806 6895 9387 9.2 8.4 11.4 59.5 59.8 59.3 2.7 4.3 13.0
France 2432 2881 3662 4.3 5.0 6.2 66.5 61.9 60.4 16.4 3.7 8.5
UK 2492 2427 3469 4 4.2 5.9 53.5 50.2 50.6 2.7 6.7 10.8
Canada 1380 2119 3121 4.9 7.2 10.2 50.7 49.3 48.6 6.5 7.5 11.2
Italy 855 1215 1548 1.7 2.1 2.7 54.1 58.3 61.5 4.4 4.5 9.2
Reference group
Israel 183 400 757 4.2 7.2 12.4 42.2 40.5 37.1 12.5 15.4 17.3
Finland 181 370 609 4.2 7.2 11.8 48.6 51.3 47.0 11.4 10.0 13.6
Ireland 31 60 101 1 1.7 2.7 43.0 48.8 36.1 11.9 7.1 18.9
Spain 92 152 237 0.3 0.4 0.6 42.8 46.0 49.3 10.0 12.0 12.7
East Asian 5
Taiwan 437 1535 3778 2.3 7.3 17.2 35.5 39.3 45.7 26.2 21.4 27.8
Korea 267 1134 3113 0.7 2.5 6.6 37.3 39.0 56.1 39.1 36.1 20.4
Hong Kong 31 72 162 0.6 1.2 2.3 40.3 38.7 42.6 14.2 23.0 35.6
Singapore 16 59 174 0.6 1.7 4.4 40.2 41.5 33.3 44.9 26.2 33.7
China 19 52 108 0 0 0 36.5 40.6 32.8 – 12.4 34.3
Source: USPTO; World Development Indicators database, 2003. Note: (1) The data for Germany include Germany west only before 1990.
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1327

Fig. 1. Top 12 patenting organizations, 1997–2001. Source: USPTO: patenting by geographic region (state and country), breakout by organization
count, 1997–2001 utility patent grants by calendar year of grant.

activities than other East Asian countries. In Korea, the USPTO system as a critical driver of interna-
the top five chaebol account for a large proportion of tional innovative performance, and are building their
patents overall (69%) from 1997 to 2001, whereas in knowledge management capabilities as they deal with
Taiwan, the top five firms and organizations are all con- ever-expanding international patent portfolios. In addi-
centrated in the semiconductor sector, but they account tion to providing companies like Samsung, TSMC and
for a smaller proportion overall (27.1%). Thus, pat- UMC with the knowledge represented by the patents,
terns established in the realm of production appear to this practice has numerous other benefits, not the least
be carried across to the sphere of innovation. of which is the capacity to engage in mutual “patent
What is clear is that all of these firms and orga- recognition” practices with leading established firms,
nizations have identified the winning of patents in whereby each firm recognizes the other’s patents and

Table 2
Top patenting firms and institutions: Taiwan, Korea, Singapore, China, 1997–2001
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Total 1997–2001
Taiwan
UMC 149 174 266 430 584 1603
TSMC 130 218 290 385 529 1552
ITRI 153 218 208 198 221 998
VISC 53 120 112 131 112 528
Winbond 24 59 115 115 126 439
Mosel-Vitelic 15 32 38 66 68 219
Korea
Samsung electronics 584 1305 1545 1441 1450 6325
Hyundai electronics 154 212 242 294 533 1435
LG electronics 113 215 229 220 248 1025
Daewoo electronics 215 319 273 120 54 981
LG semiconductor 119 235 311 255 42 962
ETRI 58 120 130 124 72 504
KIST 29 44 41 35 35 184
Singapore
Chartered 30 39 44 79 135 327
China
WSMC 0 0 6 61 37 104
Source: USPTO: patenting by geographic region (state and country), breakout by organization count, 1997–2001 utility patent grants by calendar
year of grant. Note: Company is included only for the total patent number more than 100.
1328 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

agrees not to sue for patent infringement (Hall and notion of national competitiveness, and its grounding
Ziedonis, 2001). This is one of the critical but hidden in the interaction between several factors, such as the
features in the growth of firms.2 rivalry between national firms, the level of demand of
These “raw data” demonstrate the performance of local industries, the clustering of local and supporting
innovation activity in the East Asian latecomer coun- industries and factor (input) conditions (Porter, 1990,
tries, as measured by patenting rates at the USPTO. We 1998), where again it is the intensity of these condi-
now turn to the analysis of these data, to gain a feel for tions, and their interaction, that is held to accentuate
what drives the innovative capacity of these catch-up the competitiveness of firms in international competi-
countries. Our principle tool in so doing is the concept tion.
of national innovative capacity. Furman et al. (2002) presented an integrated frame-
work of a national innovation system, where the deter-
minants of innovative capacity in the OECD countries
3. The concept of national innovative capacity were revealed in a comparative static fashion through
and latecomer catch-up innovation regression analysis. The FP&S study tracks a dynamic
process of building innovative capacity using interna-
National innovative capacity may be broadly tional patenting, taken as the number of patents granted
defined as the institutional potential of a country to sus- from the US Patent and Trademark Office, as a single
tain innovation. It has been investigated by numerous measure of innovation. Consistent with work in the area
scholars, at least since Suarez-Villa (1990) formulated by such scholars as Jones (1998) they adopted a log–log
a clear definition of the concept and a measure of it in formulation of the following kind:
terms of patenting rates. The notion can be formulated
at regional and other subnational levels (Neely and Hii, LÀj,t = δYEAR YEARt + δcountry Cj + δINF LXj,t
INF

1999). Thus, the capacity to innovate is not concerned


+δCLUS LYj,t
CLUS
+ δLINK LZj,t
LINK
with any single aspect of innovation performance, but
A
with the sources of its sustainability. +λLHj,t + ϕLAj,t + εj,t (1)
The most recent formulation of the concept, by
Furman et al. (2002) (FP&S) traces three main sets
of ideas that converge on NIC. The first is endogenous In the equation, L stands for the logarithm, À stands
growth theory, and specifically the idea of the “knowl- for the production of innovation, YEARt stands for
edge production function” (Romer, 1990; Jones, 1995, year-specific technology shock, Cj for country-specific
2002). Second, there is the notion of the national inno- technology shock, HA for human capital and financial
vation system (NIS), and the linked idea of a techno- resources as R&D inputs, A for cumulative techno-
logical system, where the key idea is the interaction logical sophistication, XINF for resource commitments
of disparate elements to build innovative capacity over and policy choices, YCLUS for cluster-specific environ-
time. In the NIS literature (Nelson, 1988, 1993; Lund- ment for innovation, ZLINK for the quality of linkages
vall, 1988), it is institutions, such as innovating firms, between innovation infrastructure and the environment
public R&D institutions (PRIs) and universities that of cluster-specific innovation, and finally ε for the
interact in a systemic way, providing complementary sources of error.
services to each other, that is seen to work to build
innovative capacity overall. Third, there is the Porter 3.1. National innovation capacity in latecomer
countries
2 For example, it was its joint venture at first with Philips that

enabled TSMC to get started, with absorption of technology, but also In latecomer countries, the issue faced is catch-up
it was Philips’ patent portfolio that protected TSMC from patent with the advanced countries, rather than the promotion
infringement suits early in its career. The Korean companies took of innovation through private sector R&D expendi-
longer to learn this, and suffered severely in the 1980s from patent
infringement suits, particularly from IBM and TI. It is this experience
ture. We thus expect the ‘system’ of innovation in
above all that helps to explain the dedication of Samsung et al. to the latecomer countries to vary in accordance with this
continuing acquisition of USPTO patents. different emphasis. The very term ‘latecomer’, first
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1329

introduced by Gerschenkron (1962) in his studies of ple, to private R&D funding and to R&D personnel
19th century patterns of industrial catch-up by Ger- levels).
many and Russia, implies that a different strategy is 2. Latecomer countries will be expected to demon-
being pursued from that utilized by countries that are strate greater targeting of industrial sectors on which
already developed. It implies that ‘latecomers’ have to they may concentrate their innovating activity, in
utilize the advantages that are available to them, such particular on high-tech sectors, such as electronics
as the ability to tap into advanced sources of manage- (IT and semiconductors), mechanical and chemical
ment, organization and technology, with lower costs engineering. These have certainly been the sectors
than their advanced competitors. that have led the catch-up industrializing efforts in
The East Asian latecomer countries perfected a East Asia (but not in other industrializing countries,
model of industrialization based on export activity such as Latin America). Thus, we should expect
and linkage with advanced firms in the advanced to find patenting rates by East Asian countries at
countries, through original equipment manufacturing the USPTO more highly focused on certain sectors
(OEM) relationships (Hobday, 1994; Goh, 1996; Kim, where production systems have already been highly
1997a,b; Mathews and Cho, 2000). Their success was developed.
based on building mass production systems where 3. Latecomer countries will tend to rely more on public
there was a bias towards industrial upgrading, achieved R&D expenditure than on private R&D expendi-
through the linkages within global value chains as well ture in the early stages of their industrial devel-
as through domestic pressures (Amsden and Chu, 2003; opment, where public R&D can boost the overall
UNIDO, 2002). But these successful systems have infrastructure development; Suarez-Villa and Has-
experienced two kinds of pressure, both from newer, nath (1993) postulated and measured such a role
low-cost competitors in China or in South East Asia, for public infrastructure development. In particu-
and from the advanced firms growing more protective lar, in East Asia, where targeting of industrial sec-
of their technology as they find East Asian firms clos- tors has characterized the development process, we
ing the gap. Thus, the East Asians have been confronted would expect to find the impact of specialization
with the necessity to build national innovation systems to be more pronounced in the presence of public
of their own, particularly in the field of process inno- R&D.
vation. 4. Intellectual property held by advanced countries can
We now focus our discussion on six research ques- act both as a means to promote latecomer industrial
tions that will serve to guide our study and to capture development (through licensing of technologies to
the systemic differences that we may expect to find latecomers) and as a barrier (where high royalty
between the national innovative capacity of latecomer charges are imposed on licensees, or patent infringe-
countries generally, and the NIC of individual OECD ment cases are brought). Strong IP protection in the
countries. latecomer country can be expected to have a neu-
tral, or even negative, effect on innovation, at least
3.2. Research questions in the countries early years. We seek a clarifica-
tion of this issue through our case study research on
1. Latecomer countries will be expected to focus their Taiwan.
innovative activity on fewer national variables than 5. Latecomer countries will be expected to exhibit
advanced (OECD) countries, and in particular may ‘real’ innovation in these targeted sectors, and not
be expected to place most reliance on the world just an increased ‘propensity to patent’ as measured
stock of technological knowledge (as held for exam- by a relationship between increased patenting rates
ple in the form of patents at the USPTO). Thus, the and increased levels of R&D expenditure. Although
latecomer East Asian countries might be expected we do not conduct a time-series analysis in this
to demonstrate that if patent stock is the indepen- study, we would expect to find such a relationship
dent variable, then patenting rates at the USPTO will in our case study of Taiwan.
be influenced by fewer national variables than for 6. Given the diversity of approaches to innovation to
OECD countries (giving less emphasis, for exam- be found in latecomer countries, there is no reason
1330 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

to expect to find convergence in patenting activities Moreover, the data sources utilized in this study do
amongst a sample of such countries, such as those in not align exactly with the data on OECD countries in
East Asia. On the contrary, we would expect to find Furman et al. (2002). 3 These scholars sourced some
countries experimenting with different strategies of data from the OECD Science and Technology Indi-
catch-up, with Korea relying more on large firms, cators, where the data is available for OECD members
and Taiwan on newly established firms, and Singa- only. The difficulty is that East Asian Newly Industrial-
pore on established multinationals, as demonstrated ising Economies (NIEs) are not members of the OECD
for the semiconductor sector by Mathews and Cho (with the exception of Korea from the late 1990s),
(2000). So, we would not pose an expectation of nor of the APEC or ASEAN International Associa-
convergence as one of our research questions in this tions. Fortunately, the relevant data can be extracted
study. from other reliable sources, such as the Asian Devel-
opment Bank and countries’ official statistics, along
These research questions will guide our study of with necessarily estimation in some unavailable data
national innovative capacity of latecomer countries and years.4
help to differentiate it from results found for advanced Our data set, covering the required variables, is as
countries, such as through the study by FP&S of OECD shown in Table 3. Broadly, our variables and defini-
countries. Our aim is to be able to demonstrate the tions are identical to those utilized in FP&S, subject to
continuities between NIC in advanced and latecomer the alternative data sources used as spelt out in Table 3.
countries, as well as the differences as summarized in However, we add a further variable, namely PUBLIC
these six research questions. We do so in the setting of R&D FUNDING, considering the significance of this
the specific experience of five East Asian countries, all for latecomer countries. Hence, we split R&D EXPEN-
of which have experienced rapid industrialization over DITURE into: (1) its public component, (2) its private
the course of the past quarter century. component PRIVATE R&D and (3) an academic com-
ponent UNIV R&D. We analyze the impact of public
R&D below.
4. Data and measures used in this study The results established by FP&S reveal that the
variation in NIC between OECD countries is influ-
In order to compare the patterns of development enced by different levels of R&D inputs (R&D man-
and policy implications of national innovative capacity power and expenditure) associated with differences in
between latecomer countries and their initial knowl- R&D productivity and policy choices (e.g. extent of IP
edge sources (e.g. OECD countries), this study tries to
align the same data sources and bases with the national 3 For example, in order to eliminate the difference of purchasing
innovative capacity research work for OECD countries power in the five East Asian countries and make the data comparable
by Furman et al. (2002). Taking the FP&S formula- to the OECD countries, this study utilizes the method of purchasing
tion as a given, we have extended its application by power parity (PPP) to convert the data from various sources into PPP-
adjusted US dollars, following the relevant year-base in the study by
applying it to the innovation experience of five East Furman et al. (2002); and the variables in the World Competitive
Asian countries, namely Taiwan, Korea, Singapore, Report for these latecomer countries are only available from 1988.
Hong Kong and China. The difficulty in doing so is There is a different Likert scale in each year so we transform the
that some of the sources of data used in this study different Likert scores into a 1–10 score. The missing data before
are necessarily incomplete. Not until two decades ago, 1988 is not interpolated because it is recognized that the 1990s is
the most crucial development stage of national innovative capacity
did the industrial development of East Asian latecomer in the latecomer countries.
countries attract global attention. Hence, some official 4 For example, for those FTE S&T data unavailable in Singapore,

economic data and indicators are not complete until the Hong Kong and China before 1985, we use the same growth percent-
1990s (e.g. R&D expenditure by the private sector and age of FTE researchers, 77%, as in Taiwan and Korea in the same
academic sector), particularly for the cases of Hong years; for those data unavailable in total R&D expenditure, such as
before 1981, Taiwan data is estimated by the average increasing rate,
Kong and China. However, it is widely recognized 16.4%, from 1981 to 2000. The same estimated approach is applied
that this was the time when developing countries were to Singapore data before 1991 (17.4%), Hong Kong data before 1995
creating their national systems of innovative capacity. (19.4%) and China data before 1987 (17.4%).
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1331

Table 3
Data sources of variables and measures
Variable Full variable name Definition and measure Source FP&S’s source
Innovation output
Patents International patents Patents granted in USPTO to the USPTO CHI US patent database
country j in year (t + 3)
Patents/million International patents Patents divided by million persons Asian Development Bank CHI US patent database
POP per million persons in the population
Common innovation infrastructure
GDP per capita GDP per capita Gross domestic product in Asian Development Bank World Bank
thousands of PPP-adjusted 1997
US$
Patent stock Stock of international Cumulative patents from 1973 to USPTO CHI US patent database
patents (t − 1)
POP Population Population (millions of people) Asian Development Bank OECD science and
technology indicators
FTE S&E Aggregate employed Full-time equivalent scientists and Countries’ official OECD science and
S&T personnel engineers in all sectors statisticsa technology indicators
R&D Aggregate R&D R&D expenditures in all sectors in Countries’ official OECD science and
expenditure expenditure millions of PPP-adjusted 1997 US$ statisticsa technology indicators
Openness Openness to Average survey response by IMD world IMD world
international trade and executives on a 1–10 scale competitiveness report competitiveness report
investment regarding relative openness of
economy to international trade and
investment
IP Strength of protection Average survey response by IMD world IMD world
for IP executives on a 1–10 scale competitiveness report competitiveness report
regarding relative strength of IP
ED share Share of GDP spent Public spending on secondary and Countries’ official World Bank
on higher education tertiary education divided by GDP statisticsa
Antitrust Stringency of antitrust Average survey response by IMD world IMD world
policies executives on a 1–10 scale competitiveness report competitiveness report
regarding relative strength of
national antitrust policies
Environment for industrial cluster
Private R&D Percentage of R&D R&D expenditures funded by Countries’ official OECD science and
funding funded by private industry divided by total R&D statisticsa technology indicators
industry expenditures
Specialization E-G concentration Relative concentration of USPTO Patent Author computation from
index Innovative output in chemical (E), Technology Monitoring USPTO
electrical (F), and mechanical (G) Division (formerly TAF
in USPTO patent classes Branch)
Quality linkages
University Percentage of R&D R&D expenditures performed by Countries’ official OECD science and
R&D performed by universities divided by total R& D statisticsa technology indicators
performance university expenditures
VC Strength of venture Average survey response by IMD world IMD world
capital markets executive on a 1–10 scale regarding competitiveness report competitiveness report
relative strength of venture capital
availability
Downstream related outcome factors
Journals Publications in Number of publications in National Science Board CHI database of science
academic journals international academic journals, citation index
using 1981 journal set
GDP Gross domestic Gross domestic product in billions Penn World Tables Penn World Tables
product Of PPP-adjusted 1990 US$
1332 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

Table 3 (Continued )
Variable Full variable name Definition and measure Source FP&S’s source
Labour Labour force Number of full-time equivalent Penn World Tables Penn World Tables
persons employed in the labour
force
Capital Capital Non-residential capital stock in Penn World Tables Penn World Tables
billions of PPP-adjusted 1990 US$
Market Share Market share Share of exports in high-tech National Science Board National Science
industries (among 5 economies) Foundation
South Korea: National Statistical Office, various years; The Bank of Korea, various years. Singapore: Department of Statistics (DOS), various
years; Economic Development Board (EDB), various years. Hong Kong: Census and Statistics Department (C&SD), 2001–2003 issues. China:
National Bureau of Statistics (NBS), various years.
a Taiwan: National Science Council, various years; Directorate General of Budget, Accounting and Statistics (DGBAS); Ministry of Finance,

various years.

protection and openness to international trade), R&D there has been convergence in these variables within
expenditure by the private sector, the degree of tech- OECD countries particularly over the course of the past
nological specialization, the share of R&D undertaken decade. The framework to be utilized is illustrated in
in the university sector, and the knowledge stock in Fig. 2, where pubic R&D funding is added as a nec-
the form of accumulated patents. They further found essarily supplementary for the East Asian latecomer
that downstream measures of competitive performance countries.
such as the share of high-tech products in exports are A brief explanation of the variables utilized, and
also impacted by the components of NIC; and that their significance, follows.

Fig. 2. The conceptual framework of national innovative capacity. Source: Adapted from FP&S (2002).
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1333

4.1. Common innovation infrastructure ture as a supplementary variable, which is omitted in


the examination of OECD countries. When state inter-
Without skilled R&D and management labour to vention and the public sector have a central role in
facilitate absorptive capacity, growth and assimilation creating, maintaining and developing the national inno-
of external knowledge is unlikely to be effective in vation system, the public sector can work as a regulator
these latecomer countries. Hence, we include popula- in order to create a dynamic industrial environment
tion (POP), each country’s number of full-time equiva- where private firms may flourish (Gregersen, 1992). In
lent scientists and engineers (FTE S&E) and total R&D latecomer countries, the public sector can play a signif-
expenditures (R&D EXPENDITURE) in HA (human icantly larger role, as identified first by Gerschenkron
capital and financial resources for R&D activities). (1962) in his study of 19th century patterns of late-
comer industrial catch-up. The same patterns can be
4.2. Cumulative knowledge stock discerned in the East Asian NIEs. In order to advance
overall industrial R&D and provide strategic direction,
A nation’s ability to develop an absorptive capac- public funding in latecomer countries takes a great deal
ity relies heavily on previous investment. The initial of the proportion of total R&D expenses, at least in the
investment allows them to make better technological early stages of development. For example, in Taiwan
choices and to exploit new opportunities better (Cohen the government funded institutes, such as the Industrial
and Levinthal, 1990). Therefore, we employ GDP PER Technology Research Institute (ITRI) or the Institute
CAPITA and PATENT STOCK as variables of knowl- for Information Industry (III) are seen as the appro-
edge stock because they reflect the potential and direct priate sites for fundamental and applied research in
capacity to support knowledge accumulation.5 industry and as agencies for the management of tech-
nology diffusion.
4.3. Resource commitments and policy choices The decline of government funds for R&D and other
economic activities is a trend common to all major
Some policy choices are considered as affecting a industrial nations (Hu and Shin, 2002). However, state
country’s innovative environment, including the coun- involvement may be seen as facilitating the success of
try’s openness to international trade and investment the catch-up strategy in these East Asian countries by
(OPENNESS), its regime for the protection of intellec- guiding and allocating the limited resources into the
tual property rights (IP) and the strength of its antitrust strategic industries where technological advance and
law (ANTITRST). Those are the dimensions used to knowledge diffusion are critical (Hobday, 1994; Goh,
measure the competitiveness of a country in the IMD 1996; Mathews, 2001; Amsden and Chu, 2003).
World Competitiveness Report.6 We also include ED
SHARE, the percentage of GDP spent on secondary 4.4. Environment for innovation in industrial
and tertiary education, to measure the impact of human clusters
capital investment on international patenting.
Considering PUBLIC R&D FUNDING as an indis- Apart from the special role of Public R&D in late-
pensable variable for East Asian latecomer countries, comer countries, we expect the environment for inno-
we add it into the measure of innovative infrastruc- vation to include private R&D expenditure, as well as
specialization, in common with the results for OECD
5 As distinct from FP&S’s approach in measuring PATENT
countries. We measure the effect of PRIVATE R&D
STOCK at a depreciated rate of 30% per year, we use a measure on national innovation capacity, shown as a percentage
that is not depreciated over time. of total R&D EXPENDITURE. But a sectoral effect is
6 These variables in various issues of the World Competitiveness also important. Therefore, we utilize another important
Report for these latecomer countries are only available from 1988. measure of industrial clustering, SPECIALIZATION,
There is a different Likert scale in each year so we transform the dif- which captures the nation’s relative specialization in
ferent Likert scores into 1–10 score. The missing data before 1988
is not interpolated because we recognize that the 1990s is the most
three important technological sectors (namely chemi-
crucial development stage of national innovation capacity in the late- cals, electrical and mechanical), and which has been
comer countries. examined and shown to have considerable impact on
1334 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

the whole economy (Patel and Pavitt, 1994; Ellison Table 4


and Glaeser, 1997), is also included. Technology spe- Descriptive statistics
cialization is defined as a focus on fields with fre- Variable N Mean S.D.
quent reference that generate inter- and intra-industrial Innovative output
knowledge flows, and therefore reinforce the strength PATENTS 129 413.45 932.65
of an industrial cluster.7 Common innovation infrastructure
GDP/POP 130 7229.61 4489.67
4.5. The linkages between innovative PATENT STOCK 130 1737.66 4182.36
POP 130 232.49 434.75
infrastructure and cluster-specific innovation
FTE S&E 80 86012.75 136244.03
R&D EXPENDITURE 76 4383.21 4979.97
In latecomer countries, which focus on catch-up and OPENNESS 60 6.81 1.13
industrial practice, many fields of academic science IP 55 5.93 1.29
are expressly applications orientated. The very names ANTITRUST 55 5.32 1.32
PUBLIC ED $ 52 2.62 1.65
“material science”, “computer science”, “industrial
PUBLIC R&D FUNDING 68 33.35 17.72
engineering”, “technology management”, and even
“applied foreign languages” signal fields of inquiry Cluster-specific innovation environment
PRIVATE R&D FUNDING 71 49.79 24.01
closely linked to particular practical problems. These SPECIALIZATION 130 0.20 0.03
formulations not only train people for work in industry,
Quality of linkages
but also develop the scientific foundations of indus-
UNIV R&D $ 51 15.73 17.52
trial technologies. Therefore, we employ the share VENTURE CAPITAL 60 5.98 1.46
of total R&D EXPENDITURE spent on universities
Downstream outcome factors
(UNIV R&D $) to measure this contribution. Finan- JOURNALS 70 2784.46 2536.64
cial institutions and the way firms are governed and GDP 130 441.72 783.36
controlled profoundly influence the technical activi- LABOUR 130 1.34E+08 256848975.94
ties. However, venture capital (VENTURE CAPITAL) CAPITAL 48 117064.42 79833.66
should be regarded as another factor promoting inno- MARKET SHARE 95 20.00% 8.31%
vation in industrializing East Asia. Note: R&D EXPENDITURE = PUBLIC R&D FUND-
ING + PRIVATE R&D $ + UNIV R&D $.

5. National innovative capacity of five East ity patents granted to inventors from a country by the
Asian countries USPTO in a given year. The number of patents assigned
to a country in a given year (PATENTS), as averaged
We now proceed to give the empirical results of our over the 25-year period, is 413 (with S.D. of 932).
study. The descriptive statistics utilized in our analy- Patent uptake has dramatically increased over time,
sis, summarizing the experience of the five countries particularly since the mid-1990s, achieving a summit
concerned over the period 1975–2000, and used in the in the final year of the sample with the average level
analysis, are listed in Table 4. of PATENTS rising from 9 in 1975 to 214 in 1990 and
1699 in 2000. Remarkably, Taiwan was ranked as the
5.1. Innovative output: international patents fourth in the USPTO when South Korea was ranked as
the eighth, in 2000, as discussed above.
The change in innovative output of international We construct the country-level measures of differ-
patents (PATENTS) is defined as the number of util- ences in the factor inputs of innovation across countries
in terms of total PATENTS, PATENTS granted per
million persons, and PATENTS PER R&D EXPENDI-
7 The USPTO has developed a deliberate patents classification sys-
TURE, respectively. Fig. 3 demonstrates divergences in
tem that consists of 400 or so main patent classes, and over 150,000
patent subclasses. We follow the measure of SPECIALIZATION
R&D productivity, captured as PATENTS PER 10,000
(i.e. on mechanical, chemical and electrical classes) as developed by FTE S&E. As with FP&S, three significant features
Ellison and Glaeser (1997) and adopted by FP&S. spring to notice. First, all five countries had a sim-
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1335

Fig. 3. International patents per 10,000 FTE S&E. Source: USPTO.

ilarly low level of international PATENTS produc- each other: PATENT STOCK and R&D EXPENDI-
tion and innovation at the beginning of the sample TURE. 8 This is plausible, since at an early stage of
period. Second, Taiwan pulled ahead of the other development there is no reason to expect population or
four countries in terms of PATENTS and productiv- GDP to be correlated with innovative capacity (think of
ity of R&D inputs (i.e. human capital and $ capital China!). We, therefore, evaluate the individual relation-
inputs) in the second half of the 1990s. Third, there ships between each of these components of NIC and
is a noticeable dispersal over time between countries, PATENTS. It is found that PATENT STOCK and R&D
particularly as between Taiwan and Korea. This is EXPENDITURE explain 91.4 and 63.8% of the vari-
very different from the FP&S finding of convergence ance in PATENTS, respectively, and the coefficients
in OECD countries; it implies a distinctive develop- are around 1.1, providing a modest effect on national
ment pattern of national innovation in the latecomer innovation output.
countries. Our main results are reported in Tables 5 and 6.
In Table 5, we investigate the effects of NIC vari-
5.2. Determinants of national innovative capacity ables in moderating the variance of patenting with
GDP/POP (representing potential knowledge availabil-
Like FP&S, we conduct our analysis in stages, ity). In Table 6, we repeat the analysis utilizing patent
examining first the cross-correlations to establish stock (representing accumulated knowledge capacity)
which variables have independent effects; then con- as proxy for knowledge stock. Both tables report the
ducting the major regressions to discover which fea- impact of each variable on national innovative capac-
tures of the NIC have most impact on patenting rates. ity in the sample of East Asian latecomer countries,
We further interrogate the data for measures that we measured in the form of a series of models. The OECD
would expect to be more prominent in latecomer coun- study by FP&S did not utilize a category of public
tries than in advanced countries, in particular examin- sector R&D spending, and so its potential impact on
ing the enhanced impact of specialization when com- NIC was not evaluated. But in the case of latecomer
bined with public R&D. countries, such as our five countries from East Asia,
According to the FP&S analysis, OECD countries the impact of public R&D cannot be ignored. As pre-
have five highly mutual correlated elements, namely viously mentioned, PUBLIC R&D FUNDING plays
population (POP); full-time equivalent science and an indispensable role in the earlier stage of economic
technology workers (FTE S&E); total R&D expen- development for latecomer countries. Therefore, we
diture (R&D EXPENDITURE); GDP per capita and investigate its impact when included as a separate item
the total patents issued (PATENT STOCK). By con- in the regressions of the log of patents on the logs of
trast, pair-wise correlation in the case of East Asian
latecomer countries indicates that only two compo- 8 We define the components as having a highly correlated relation-

nents are highly correlated to a significant degree with ship when Pearson Correlation r ≥ 0.5 (Pallent, 2001).
1336
Table 5
Determinants of national innovation capacity (GDP/POP as knowledge stock)
Dependent variable = ln (PATENTS)i, t+3

Idea production Common innovation National innovative National innovative National innovative
function (5.1) infrastructure (5.2) capacity: including all capacity: preferred capacity: preferred model
variables (5.3) model (5.4) (5.4) with PUBLIC R&D
FUNDING (5.5)
Common innovation infrastructure
A L GDP 3.778*** (0.054) 9.446*** (0.077) 8.081** (0.120)

M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349


A L GDP PER CAPITA 0.007 (0.085) 0.191 (0.060)
HA L POP −2.446*** (0.078) −6.442*** (0.003) −5.519** (0.023)
HA L FTE S&E 1.325*** (0.036) −1.197 (0.012) 0.038 (0.012) 0.368** (0.005) 0.326* (0.004)
HA L R&D $ 2.382*** (0.045) −0.235 (0.045) 0.121 (0.038) 0.175 (0.035)
XINF ED SHARE −0.252*** (0.001) 0.046 (0.001)
XINF IP −0.085 (0.038) −0.023 (0.024)
XINF OPENNESS 0.104 (0.059) 0.034 (0.036) 0.030 (0.034) 0.022 (0.025)
XINF ANTITRUST 0.051 (0.047) −0.006 (0.037) 0.006 (0.051) 0.003 (0.046)
XINF PUBLIC R&D 0.007* (0.008)
FUNDING
Cluster-specific innovation environment
YCLUS PRIVATE R&D 0.004 (0.049) 0.011*** (0.007) 0.012*** (0.003)
FUNDING
YCLUS SPECIALIZATION 4.298*** (0.003) 3.070*** (0.006) 3.060*** (0.004)
Quality of linkages
ZLINK UNIV R&D $ −0.011* (0.090) 0.003 (0.054) 0.005 (0.017)
ZLINK VENTURE −0.058* (0.070)
CAPITAL
Controls
Year fixed effects −0.141** (0.044) −0.099 (0.025) 0.097*** (0.003) 0.095*** (0.003)
Taiwan dummy 0.411 (0.147) 0.575 (0.103) 1.242 (0.000) 1.216*** (0.127)
Constant −5.346*** (0.011) −125.488 (0.180) −186.386*** (0.008) −105.042 (0.000) −121.315*** (0.068)
R2 0.743 0.958 0.998 0.993 0.995
Adjusted R2 0.733 0.934 0.995 0.991 0.993
Number of observations 122 121 118 121 118
Numbers in parenthesis refer to standard error.
* P < 0.1.
** P < 0.05.
*** P < 0.01.
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1337

Table 6
Determinants of national innovation capacity (patent stock as knowledge stock)
Idea production Common innovation National innovation National innovation
function (6.1) infrastructure (6.2) capacity: preferred capacity: preferred model
model (6.3) (6.3) with PUBLIC R&D
FUNDING (6.4)
Common innovation infrastructure
A L PATENT STOCK 1.144*** (0.006) 1.268*** (0.008) 1.278*** (0.016) 1.276*** (0.036)
HA L FTE S&E 0.194*** (0.012) −0.462*** (0.003) 0.231* (0.098) 0.280* (0.094)
HA L R&D $ 0.846*** (0.001) 0.186** (0.001) 0.181 (0.001)
XINF ED SHARE −0.093*** (0.006)
XINF OPENNESS 0.016 (0.021) 0.032 (0.009) 0.022 (0.005)
XINF IP 0.022 (0.047)
XINF ANTITRUST 0.029 (0.039) −0.010 (0.012) 0.003 (0.007)
XINF PUBLIC R&D 0.007 (0.008)
FUNDING
Cluster-specific innovation environment
YCLUS PRIVATE R&D 0.010*** (0.009) 0.013** (0.011)
FUNDING
YCLUS SPECIALIZATION 1.553* (0.065) 3.272*** (0.008)
Quality of linkages
ZLINK UNIV R&D $ 0.003 (0.047) 0.005 (0.032)
Controls
Country fixed Insignificant
effects
Year fixed Significant −0.051*** (0.000) −0.040*** (0.000) −0.043*** (0.035)
effects
YEAR −0.040*** (0.002) 0.019 (0.008) 0.073** (0.006)
Taiwan −0.400*** (0.002) −0.332*** (0.002) −0.352*** (0.007)
dummy
R2 0.941 0.989 0.995
Adjusted R2 0.938 0.984 0.992 0.993
Number of 125 122 121 122
observations
Numbers in parenthesis refer to standard error.
* P < 0.1.
** P < 0.05.
*** P < 0.01.

components of NIC. In this way we extend the work in R&D manpower is associated with 13.3% increase
reported by FP&S into new territory. The new regres- in international patent output. By contrast, FP&S found
sions are reported in columns 5.5 and 6.4, basing on that a 10% rise in GDP is associated with an approxi-
two different knowledge stock representatives. mate 10% increase in international patenting rate, i.e.
the impact of GDP is 2.7 times weaker for OECD coun-
5.2.1. Endogenous growth tries than in the case of our latecomer countries. We
The first regression (column 5.1) evaluates the see this as a highly significant finding, and interpret
national ideas production model that was suggested it to mean that the endogenous growth model seems
by Romer (1990) and Jones (1995). We find that to apply with even greater force in latecomer countries
PATENTS is increasing with the log of GDP (3.78) than in advanced countries, particularly when the econ-
and log of FTE S&E (1.33). This may be interpreted omy of latecomer countries is on the upward position
to mean that a 10% rise in GDP accompanies a 37.8% of the production possibilities frontier. This is indeed
increase in international patenting rate, and a 10% rise plausible, since latecomers are so dependent for their
1338 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

development on the existing stock of knowledge. The cluster-specific innovation environment and the qual-
negative coefficient associated with population (POP), ity of linkages. We control for log R&D $ and log
−2.446, after controlling for the level of GDP and FTE FTE S&E in order to explore the impact of economy-
S&E, implies that the lower level of GDP PER CAPITA wide factors on national R&D productivity. Again, the
reduces innovative outputs, again, responding to the major impact in column 5.3 is that of log GDP (8.081),
argument of endogenous growth theory. following by SPECIALIZATION (4.298), which is
consistent with the highly skewed patenting practices
5.2.2. Common innovation infrastructure noted above, with most emphasis on the electron-
Column 5.2 includes all variables of common inno- ics, semiconductor, IT and communications sectors.
vation infrastructure and year fixed effect (along with Minor effects are found from log of FTE S&E (0.038),
5.3 and 5.4) in order to control for the variation from ED SHARE (0.046) and OPENNESS (0.034). These
changes in the annual rate of patenting. The first thing to findings explain 99.8% of the variance in patenting
note is that the coefficient of GDP increases by 150%, across the different countries. It is noted that total
from 3.78 to 9.45, and moreover the sum of the coeffi- R&D EXPENDITURE and UNIV R&D $ have nega-
cients on log R&D $ and log FTE S&E is comparable tive coefficients while PRIVATE R&D FUNDING still
to the individual coefficient on log FTE S&E in 5.1. retains a positive coefficient. In our model, total R&D
This demonstrates that there is no difference whether EXPENDITURE is composed of PUBLIC R&D, PRI-
we focus on an individual variable or include both vari- VATE R&D and UNIV R&D FUNDING. This may
ables (e.g. FTE S&E in 5.1 or FTE S&E and R&D $ imply that the effect of PRIVATE R&D FUNDING
in 5.2) in their effects on innovation activity, a find- is increasing in the latecomer countries, but PUBLIC
ing in common with that for the OECD countries (and R&D $ is dramatically decreased in the 1990s and
one with policy implications for government). Log of UNIV R&D $ is mostly aimed at rapid economic return,
total R&D $ enters with a significant coefficient, 2.382, namely applied R&D, rather than basic R&D as in
corresponding to the suggestion of endogenous growth OECD countries.10
theory: the level of inputs devoted to R&D is one of the While incorporated country fixed effects, our find-
critical factors in determining innovative output. ings are consistent with the view that countries that
However, education investment (ED SHARE) does become more specialized become more innovative.
not express its contribution to latecomer countries’ Compared with the OECD countries, a single S.D.
innovation output, over the period 1975–2000, per- increase in SPECIALIZATION (0.03) in latecomer
haps implying that the returns of education investment countries is associated with a 13% increase in the
are reflected in the promotion of overall productivity patenting rate (PATENTS) by a country, compared
of labor, rather than directly contributing to interna- with an 8% increase for OECD countries; while a 1%
tional patenting activity. Not surprisingly, the intel- increase in PRIVATE R&D FUNDING is associated
lectual property protection regime has an insignificant with 0.4% increase in PATENTS compared with 1.4%
effect and actually has a negative relationship asso- for OECD countries. Thus, we find that the impact of
ciated with PATENTS output. This indicates that the SPECIALIZATION (focus on three dominant classes
policy regarding IP does not emerge fully until the of patents) on the patenting rate in the latecomer coun-
late 1990s in latecomer countries and is consistent with tries is more pronounced than is found in the OECD
anecdotal evidence that IP protection harms catch-up.9 countries, while the impact of private sector R&D is
less pronounced, lending further support to the idea
5.2.3. Industrial specialization that latecomers target certain specific sectors, first for
Column 5.3 includes all variables of the three production and export, and then for innovation. The
sources of NIC: common innovation infrastructure, patenting statistics reveal these sectors to be electron-

10 Our findings are consistent with the view that PUBLIC R&D
9 For example, some latecomer countries, like Taiwan, have paid FUNDING and PRIVATE R&D FUNDING need to be taken into
large technology licensing fees each year to advanced countries, par- account in the same regression, as the sum of the means of these two
ticularly to the U.S and Japan. variables is above 80%.
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1339

ics (particularly semiconductors), IT and communica- knowledge among countries. When PATENT STOCK
tions. As in the OECD countries, VENTURE CAP- substitutes for GDP/POP as knowledge stock, the coef-
ITAL does not show its impact, which is consistent ficient of log PATENT STOCK (1.144) in latecomer
with the interpretation that VC operates on new-to-the- countries is similar to that in the OECD countries. The
country innovation. impact of FTE S&T (0.194) is smaller than in col-
umn 5.1, again consistent with the same finding for
5.2.4. Restricted focus of NIC in East Asian the OECD countries.
countries In column 6.2, the coefficient of R&D EXPENDI-
Our “preferred model” (i.e. where every variable TURE is reduced from 2.38 (in 5.2) to 0.85, which is a
has a positive contribution to innovative activity) in 64% reduction. This may be interpreted to mean that in
column 5.4 differs from the preferred model found by latecomer countries, R&D EXPENDITURE in the ear-
FP&S. Our preferred model includes only three vari- lier years is mostly aimed at industrial upgrading and
ables with statistical significance, namely SPECIAL- export production, rather than focused on innovation
IZATION (3.070), FTE S&E (0.368) and PRIVATE activity, which becomes important only in the 1990s.
R&D (0.011), each of which has a quantitatively impor- Notably, the variable IP turns positive (even if still sta-
tant impact. The preferred model excludes IP and ED tistically insignificant) in using PATENT STOCK as
SHARE. The variable SPECIALIZATION emerges as knowledge stock, indicating a weak effect of the IPR
that with the biggest impact, as in OECD countries, system on technology knowledge management.
but with a more pronounced magnitude of effect than More interestingly, our preferred model (column
in the OECD countries. This is an interesting diver- 6.3) in using PATENT STOCK as knowledge stock
gence between the NIC found for advanced countries greatly reduces the coefficient (and significance level)
and that found for latecomers, and a finding that has of SPECIALIZATION (the coefficient is reduced from
implications for the development strategy to be pur- 3.070 to 1.553), the largest contributor to international
sued in latecomer countries, as we discuss below. patenting in column 5.4. This may be interpreted as fur-
ther evidence of the importance of the (international)
5.2.5. Impact of public R&D expenditures stock of patents in latecomer countries, in having the
When PUBLIC R&D FUNDING is added into our power to moderate the impact of specialization. This
preferred model, the result is similar to the previous also indicates that innovation activity in latecomer
model in column 5.4. Entering at the 10% significance countries is concentrated on certain high-tech indus-
level and improving the explanation of overall varia- tries (e.g. electronics, IT and communications), which
tion on PATENTS, PUBLIC R&D FUNDING (0.007) lead national industrial development as a whole.11 We
shows a conservative influence toward international also find that ANTITRUST becomes a negative coef-
patenting. Perhaps this demonstrates the inefficiency ficient when other variables maintain a similar magni-
of PUBLIC R&D FUNDING in the current stage of tude (except for SPECIALIZATION).
economic development in latecomer countries, which
was shown to be dramatically decreasing from the mid- 5.2.7. Public R&D expenditure and industrial
1990s. specialization
We now turn to the analysis utilizing patent stock The role of PUBLIC R&D FUNDING is greatly
in the countries concerned, as proxy for accumulated reinforced when we use PATENT STOCK as knowl-
knowledge. In Table 6, we analyze the NIC variables edge stock, as reported in column 6.4. The impact of
using patent stock as the knowledge stock, again fol- SPECIALIZATION rises (with a coefficient of 3.272,
lowing the procedure of FP&S. Patent stocks provide compared with a coefficient of 1.553 when public sec-
a more direct measure of knowledge stock on which a tor R&D was not included as a separate variable (in col-
country draws for its innovative activity.
11 This suggestion is further strengthened by the impact of PATENT
5.2.6. Impact of international patent stock STOCK (1.278) on innovative activity, which is 1.67 times greater
Table 6 controls for year and country effects to than in the OECD countries (again because of the effect of special-
reduce the specific heterogeneity of technological ization).
1340 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

umn 6.3)). Thus, the effect of specialization on patent- inputs is a critical factors in determining a nation’s level
ing rates is enhanced by 110% when the variable PUB- of visible innovation and (2) more delicate measures
LIC R&D FUNDING is added into the model. This of the national innovation environment significantly
result indicates that the effect of SPECIALIZATION impact on R&D productivity.
in East Asian latecomer countries is highly depen- In contrast to the finding of OECD countries, the
dent on cumulative knowledge capacity (e.g. PATENT coefficients of the year dummies in Table 5 (GDP
STOCK) along with PUBLIC R&D FUNDING. per capita as knowledge stock) increase over time,
We suggest that this is perhaps the most signifi- implying that average R&D productivity in latecomer
cant finding of our study. Note that PUBLIC R&D countries has been increasing since 1975. In other
FUNDING only shows its significant impact on SPE- words, resource inputs in the latecomer countries have
CIALIZATION, by taking PATENT STOCK (as in been raising the marginal productivity of innovation
column 6.4) rather than GDP per capita (in column 5.5) (in terms of GDP per capita) over time. In order to
as knowledge stock.12 This corresponds to the efforts test whether our results are affected by any particular
of external technology acquisition, where the goal of country, we utilize a Taiwan dummy variable as well
PUBLIC R&D in these latecomer countries tends to as year dummy variables. The effects of the inclusion
increase the level of innovation (particularly in the of these dummy variables may be contrasted between
high-tech industry) as measured by PATENT STOCK, Tables 5 and 6, when we use two different variables
rather than to increase overall national welfare as mea- (GDP per capita and patent stock) to represent knowl-
sured by GDP per capita. edge stock in our preferred model. In Table 6, the
coefficient of the year dummies declines over time (as
5.3. Comparison of NIC in latecomer countries in the OECD countries), whereas the Taiwan dummy
with the case of OECD countries exerts a significant negative impact on PATENT inno-
vation, implying the important contribution of Taiwan’s
Our main results in Tables 5 and 6 demonstrate PATENT in R&D productivity of East Asian latecomer
the fact that the innovation activity in latecomer coun- countries.
tries is concentrated on three measures, namely R&D Some studies have demonstrated declines in the
inputs (i.e. FTE S&E), cluster-specific innovation envi- magnitude of year fixed effects in the OECD coun-
ronment (SPECIALIZATION and PRIVATE R&D $) tries imply innovation in the advanced countries is
and accumulated knowledge capacity (i.e. PATENT becoming a ‘fished out of the pond’ effect (Jones, 1995
STOCK). The accumulated knowledge capacity refers and Furman et al., 2002). Our model demonstrates this
to accumulated knowledge worldwide: it is the pool of effect still holds tightly in the latecomer countries as the
knowledge from which all latecomer countries draw in innovation activity (in terms of PATENT) in latecomer
order to accelerate their catch-up. This finding, which countries are derived from those advanced countries’
we elaborate in the case study of Taiwan below, is existing knowledge, in which also allows a huge vari-
markedly at odds with those for advanced countries ety of process innovations (or new-to-the-country) to
where national innovation capacity is built on more be generated (and so that increase the innovation level
diverse sources. National innovation capacity in late- in terms of GDP per capita).
comer countries, by contrast, is built on more limited We now summarize our findings on the NIC of
and focused sources in order to accelerate the process East Asian latecomers, emphasizing the differences we
of catch-up. However, the framework as a whole has found between the latecomers and the OECD coun-
remained significant, suggesting that there are char- tries. In general, the contribution of each determinant
acteristic development patterns of national innovation of national innovation capacity in OECD countries is
capacity in latecomer countries, and also responds to greater than in latecomer countries, except for the case
the suggestions by FP&S, namely (1) the level of R&D of SPECIALIZATION. This is a plausible departure,
since the latecomer countries concentrate their inno-
12 We acknowledge that the instability of coefficients might possibly vative efforts so closely on electronics, semiconduc-
reflect multicollinearity, where follow-up work would be needed to tors, IT and communications. Note in particular the
settle remaining uncertainties. point made above, that when the variable, PUBLIC
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1341

R&D FUNDING, is added into the model of late- in China). SPECIALIZATION also has a significant
comer countries, the effect of SPECIALIZATION is impact on national innovation capacity (its coefficient
enhanced by 110% to reach the same level of con- increases by 98.8% compared with that in column 6.4).
tribution as in OECD countries. In the case of the Since the same variable exerts only a 29.4% increased
OECD countries, their national innovative capacity effect in OECD countries, our result indicates that the
is found to depend broadly on the strength of each impact of SPECIALIZATION on innovation outputs is
nation’s common innovation infrastructure (e.g. R&D more sensitive in a given latecomer country than that
manpower, R&D spending, IP protection and openness in an advanced country.
to international trade), the environment for innova-
tion in a nation’s industrial clusters (e.g. PRIVATE
R&D FUNDING and SPECIALIZATION), and the 6. Case study: Taiwan
strength of linkages between these two (e.g. the share
of academic sector’s R&D performance). By contrast, We now illustrate and elaborate these results in
innovation activity in our latecomer sample is more the specific instance of Taiwan, which has arguably
reliant on three measures, the accumulated knowl- been the East Asian country that has made most
edge capacity (e.g. PATENT STOCK), the strength progress in shifting from imitation to innovation (as
of a nation’s common innovation infrastructure (e.g. measured in terms of patenting). The case study for
R&D manpower) and cluster-specific innovation (e.g. Taiwan traces the process of building up the national
SPECIALIZATION and PRIVATE R&D $) along with innovative capacity, exploring the role of IP and the
PUBLIC R&D FUNDING. impact of PUBLIC R&D in achieving its leverage
In order to test the role of PUBLIC R&D and explic- effect.
itly measure the differential impact of PUBLIC R&D As the US is the global critical and cutting-edge
FUNDING in these latecomer countries, we high- market, the outstanding performance of Taiwan’s semi-
light the differences between the 1980s and the 1990s, conductor and IT-related industries in the USPTO has
respectively, along with a dummy variable. It is found become an essential driver of Taiwan’s internal tech-
that PUBLIC R&D FUNDING reaches a significant nology knowledge flow. The practice of Taiwan firms
level in the 1980s and loses its importance in the 1990s, is to patent first in the Taiwan Intellectual Property
indicating that PUBLIC R&D plays an indispensable Office (TIPO), and then to choose relevant patents that
role in the early stage of industrial development in call for the trouble and expense of patenting in the
latecomer countries and changes its role from inno- USPTO. The patenting activity in the TIPO reveals the
vation infrastructure to a function of linkages between extremely strong focus on electronics and IT as in the
common innovation infrastructure and industrial clus- USPTO, in which all the top eight private firms are in
ter when the development of industry has accumulated this sector. The other two are public sector organiza-
a certain level of technology capability in the 1990s. tions, the Industrial Technology Research Institute and
Despite the decreasing rate over the years, PUBLIC the National Science Council (NSC) that patent across
R&D FUNDING is still playing an indispensable role a broader range of industrial sectors.
in facilitating a national cluster innovation environment The striking feature of the patenting activities in the
in latecomer countries. TIPO is the high level of patenting by foreign firms,
We also performed the same robustness check as car- as revealed in Fig. 4. Patenting by foreign inventors
ried out by FP&S and explored the robustness including highlights a nation’s attractiveness as a market for new
country-specific fixed effects.13 GDP PER CAPITA technologies, and patent activity by resident inventors
becomes of statistical and quantitative significance, provides a measure of productivity for a nation’s
suggesting that the level of innovative outputs is sen- science and technology human resources (Rausch,
sitive to the level of GDP PER CAPITA within a 1995). Taiwan’s Intellectual Property Office has
country (GDP PER CAPITA is insignificant in our pre- classified patents into three categories: invention, new
ferred model as a whole is because the huge population utility and new design, where the criteria of Invention
in the TIPO are equivalent to those of utility in the
13 The table can be supplied on request. USPTO. As invention patent is defined as the highest
1342 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

Fig. 4. Domestic and foreign patent granted in the Taiwan’s IPO–Invention Type. Source: Taiwan Intellectual Property Office, www.tipo.gov.tw.

level of innovation, Taiwanese inventors took 27% of foundry Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Corpo-
total awarded patents in 2002, rising from just 5% in ration (TSMC), is striking, as shown in Table 7 and
the 1980s. The percentage is rising but still relatively Fig. 5.
much lower than that of the foreign inventors which TSMC was founded in 1986 and has become Tai-
took over 73% in 2002 and as much as 95% in the wan’s largest IC Company and the world’s largest ded-
1980s and the early-1990s; in terms of new utility and icated integrated circuit foundry. Table 7 shows that
new design patents, where there can be an emphasis TSMC’s dramatic increase in patenting rate is corre-
on process innovations, the reverse is the case. lated with the company’s increase in R&D expendi-
When we look more closely at the level of the ture and its employment of professional manpower.
firms involved, further striking features are revealed, This is an important finding that reinforces the overall
that shed light on the macro-trends revealed in our results in Section 4, namely that the essential drivers of
analysis above. We conducted interviews in Septem- national innovative capacity in latecomer countries are
ber 2003 with several of Taiwan’s leading firms, in derived from specialization in the high-tech industry,
the semiconductor sector, as well as with public sec- R&D expenditure and manpower. Note too the finding
tor organizations including TIPO, III and ITRI. The that TSMC’s royalty income is relative small, whereas
case of Taiwan’s leading semiconductor firm, the pur royalty payments are still relatively high, indicating

Table 7
The operation facts in TSMC, 1995–2002
Year R&D expenditure Net Sales (NT$ Professional Patent Awarded Royalty Income Royalty Expense
(NT$ million) million) Manpowera in the USPTO (NT$ million) (NT$ million)
1995 748 28766 1834 25 – –
1996 1494 39400 2287 74 – –
1997 2505 43936 2881 127 – –
1998 3246 50233 3197 213 8 637
1999 2391 73131 3469 288 64 1032
2000 5131 166228 6988 383 24 2477
2001 10649 125888 6608 527 55 3715
2002 11725 160961 7456 444 204 6232
Source: TSMC Annual Report, various years.
a Professional manpower includes R&D engineers and managers.
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1343

Fig. 5. TSMC’s R&D expenditure and innovation performance, 1995 to 2002. Source: TSMC Annual Report, various years.

that Taiwan is still a learning economy, and still in a (2001) found no evidence amongst US firms of a link
process of catch-up.14 between enhanced patenting rates (what they called
Table 7 and Fig. 5 also indicate that while “patent portfolio races”) and R&D expenditure, the link
R&D expenditure gradually increased, the number of is clearly established for a latecomer firm like TSMC,
TSMC’s US patents awarded declined in 2002 for the which may correspond to the suggestion by Lanjouw
first time, since the company was established. We inter- and Schankerman (1999): the quality of patenting by
pret this to mean that TSMC has been concentrating on firms exhibits a more stable relationship to firm’s R&D
improving the quality and effectiveness of its patents, expenditure.
rather than simply the quantity. This is consistent with Quantity of patents is one index of innovative capac-
our finding that TSMC is aggressively upgrading the ity, but the quality of the patents filed is another, and
effectiveness of its in-house IP management as a result potentially of greater long-term benefit to a country.
of a series of patent infringement disputes, and putting We found evidence in our interviews in Taiwan that
effort into encouraging R&D engineers to engage in firms like TSMC have been reviewing their patent-
patenting activity (for example, through the Employee ing processes in the past year, and have been pay-
Stock Option Program, ESOP).15 ing more attention to the quality of the patents filed.
Note how TSMC, even as a foundry (and thus hav- This is corroborated by striking evidence from the
ing no proprietary products) has still been burdened patents database firm, CHI Inc. (the firm that supplied
with considerable royalty payments (of the order of the data on which the FP&S analysis is conducted).
NT$ 6232 million in 2002, approximately US$ 186 mil- CHI Research define patent quality in terms of a Cur-
lion, see Table 7) which has sharpened its propensity to rent Impact Index (CII) which measures the impact of
build its own patent portfolio, in line with many other patents taken out over the previous five years in terms
semiconductor firms, as revealed in the study by Hall of their current rate of citation, which therefore avoids
and Ziedonis (2001). But whereas Hall and Ziedonis the truncation problem in using citation rate. The CII
is calculated as the number of citations in a given years
14 There was a big jump in all categories in 2000, when TSMC of all patents filed in the previous five years, compared
acquired the semiconductor operations of the TSMC-Acer Manu- with the average across all patents in the USPTO.16
facturing Corp joint venture.
15 ESOP is a flexible system and ties employees’ performance

to rewards. The remuneration package allows the firm to reward 16 To take an example, a Current Citation Index (CII) value of 1.0

employees when they are doing well and enhances the employees’ represents the average. A value of 2.0 would indicate twice the fre-
sense of belonging by giving them a stake. quency of citation (and hence twice the “quality” of the patents over
1344 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

As shown in Table 8, the leading countries in terms above that, in contrast with the experience of the OECD
of the quality of their patents within the USPTO in countries, the latecomers from East Asia focused their
1995 were the U.S. (1.12), Japan (1.02) and Taiwan innovative activities on three key factors, namely on
(1.01). But by the year 2000, Taiwan had emerged as building cumulatively their R&D manpower; in tar-
the world’s leader in terms of patent quality, with a CII geting certain industrial sectors and specializing their
of 1.25, followed by the U.S. (1.15) and Israel (1.01). innovative activities in these sectors; and in promoting
This striking result reflects the quality of the patents public R&D as a means of enhancing national innova-
taken out by Taiwan firms in the years 1995–1999. The tive capacity.
table reveals that in the field of semiconductors and In the case of Taiwan these features are captured by
electronics, Taiwan firms and organizations account examining the role of the public sector R&D agency,
for no less than 11.3% of the world patent stock in the Industrial Technology Research Institute. ITRI’s
those sectors. Thus, the latecomer status of Taiwan is patenting activity has been significant, in both the
reflected in both the frenzied pace of its patenting, in USPTO and the TIPO, as described above. A summary
the quality of the patenting, and in the almost complete of its R&D expenditures, and patenting rates over the
focus on certain critical sectors such as semiconduc- years 1995–2002, is given in Fig. 6.
tors where the country has sought to establish global While the public sector plays the role of leading
production and trade leadership. These are patterns to and guiding Taiwan’s industry, ITRI’s patenting activ-
be expected of the innovative capacity of a latecomer ity has given a significant impetus to IP development
country like Taiwan, but not of a developed country in the private sector. Not only has ITRI been an impor-
within the OECD, thus further emphasizing the differ- tant foundation for the innovative capacity of Taiwan,
ences between our study and that of FP&S. in terms of its building of what must be termed techno-
However, two caveats are in order. First, although logical capabilities in strategically chosen sectors such
the Taiwan patenting rates look high, they are concen- as semiconductors, electronics and IT, but also in terms
trated in a specific sector, namely semiconductors. In of its efforts to diffuse such capabilities to the private
world terms, this sector has also demonstrated high sector, through such institutions as targeted R&D con-
rates of patenting (Hall and Ziedonis, 2001). Taiwan sortia (Mathews, 2002). There is a high turnover of
would thus lose its distinctiveness if one normalised its ITRI technical staff, with much of the staff transferring
patenting rate against the semiconductor trend world- to Taiwan’s private sector, thus again revealing how the
wide. But this point echoes the key finding in the cumulative build-up in full-time equivalent R&D staff
empirical results: the national innovative capacity relies translates across to innovative capacity in the private
heavily on the strategic SPECIALIZATION industry sector.
(which is the most significant driver of NIC for late- Since the 1990s, IP protection is the worldwide trend
comers). Second, the Taiwan citation rate may include and highly related to the sustainability of a company or
high levels of self-citation, i.e. one patent citing earlier an industry. Patent portfolio and analysis play a critical
patents by the same company. In this context it would be role in exploring patent mapping and IP management.
worthwhile to explore the possible differences in cita- Quality patents, therefore, have become the goal of
tion rates between Taiwan’s public and private sectors, patenting strategy for ITRI to utilize and leverage IP
when the patent citation associated with knowledge dif- value, and in order to acquire multiple effects of IP
fusion could be geographically localized. It is known utilization. This trend is reflected in the sharp rise in
that corporate patents are more often self-cited and self- the quality of Taiwan’s patents, as reported by the CHI
citations are more often localized (Jaffe et al., 1993). database.
To summarize our findings on Taiwan, we wish Recent developments in the ITRI (and III) spon-
to highlight the features that emerged in our analy- sored R&D consortia are of relevance to a discussion
sis of the five countries’ innovative capacity. We noted of strategic management of IP, in that consortia have
been formed as “patent pools” in order to provide Tai-
the previous 5-year period, whereas a value of 0.25 would indicate
wan firms with collective defense against infringement
a citation frequency of only 25% of the average across all patent suits of the kind described for TSMC above. To the
classes. The number of classes considered is 30. year 2002, ITRI has formed six new companies by
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1345

Table 8
Taiwan’s US patents performance in CHI’s 30 technology areasa
S. no. Technology areas 1991–1995 1996–2000 Growth rate 1995 Global 2000 Global 1995 CII 2000 CII
patent patent between (1) share of share of (cited from (cited from
numbers (1) numbers (2) and (2) patents patents 1990 to 1994) 1995 to 1999)
1 Agriculture 92 152 66.01 1.05 1.28 1.19 1.56
2 Oil and gas, mining 7 18 176.92 0.08 0.00 0.00 1.22
3 Power generation and 57 141 145.72 1.39 2.77 1.11 1.01
distribution
4 Food and tobacco 51 116 127.95 1.17 2.11 1.12 1.12
5 Textiles and apparel 225 660 193.51 3.46 4.82 1.46 1.57
6 Wood and paper 191 616 222.69 3.77 6.07 0.92 1.18
7 Chemicals 68 218 220.32 0.28 0.55 0.72 0.69
8 Pharmaceuticals 12 52 317.74 0.08 0.20 0.00 0.42
9 Biotechnology 7 47 554.17 0.19 0.32 0.53 0.39
10 Medical equipment 102 239 135.17 1.11 1.23 0.71 0.77
11 Medical electronics 5 27 446.00 0.22 0.40 0.44 0.36
12 Plastics, polymers and 91 215 136.56 0.65 0.88 0.66 0.83
rubber
13 Glass, clay and cement 19 35 83.16 1.34 1.30 1.01 1.28
14 Primary metals 18 20 12.72 0.64 0.31 1.61 1.48
15 Fabricated metals 45 160 252.98 1.29 2.87 1.11 0.97
16 Industrial machinery 406 1138 180.55 2.46 4.08 0.95 1.32
and tools
17 Industrial process 149 420 181.07 1.40 2.33 1.16 1.07
equipment
18 Office equipment and 165 507 207.09 1.14 1.83 0.69 0.78
cameras
19 Heating, ventilation, 62 91 45.97 1.93 1.55 0.78 0.73
refrigeration
20 Misc. machinery 288 739 156.56 2.06 3.25 1.06 1.13
21 Computers and 138 876 537.09 0.71 1.45 0.60 0.83
peripherals
22 Telecommunications 109 682 523.60 0.58 1.43 0.90 0.70
23 Semiconductors and 237 3375 1,325.73 3.87 11.35 1.86 1.61
electronics
24 Measurement and con- 127 400 214.80 0.75 2.15 0.63 0.80
trol equipment
25 Electrical appliances 485 1772 265.26 3.19 7.33 1.01 1.23
and components
26 Motor vehicles and 235 380 61.49 1.67 1.82 1.08 0.76
parts
27 Aerospace and parts 7 17 137.14 0.46 0.54 0.85 0.46
28 Other transport 182 386 112.02 4.73 4.70 2.50 1.51
29 Miscellaneous manu- 480 1081 125.30 2.24 2.47 0.98 1.06
facturing
30 Other 475 926 94.78 4.09 5.18 1.12 0.98
All Patents 4534 15502 241.94 1.60 2.98 1.01 1.25
Source: CHI Research Inc., Taiwan Economic Research Yuan (2002 Economic Report) and calculated by the author.
a Utility patents only.
1346 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

Fig. 6. ITRI’s R&D expenditure and innovation performance, 1995 to 2002. Source: ITRI Annual Report, various years.

means of utilizing patent portfolio. Two developments established in 2002, under the combination of biotech,
demonstrate ITRI’s strategic utilization of its patent electronics, optoelectronics and information technol-
portfolio. The first development of note is the Taiwan ogy areas, and collected 41 domestic and international
TFT-LCD Association, representing all the important patents. The patent portfolio provides an incentive for
firms in Taiwan’s recently emerged flat panel display the Biotech Chips R&D Alliance, which unifies Tai-
industry based on TFT-LCD technologies. In the 1990s, wan’s biotech companies in technology, manpower,
Taiwan’s fledgling TFT-LCD companies acquired tech- finance and intellectual property. This too provides
nologies needed in panel production directly from an example of the strategic management of IP in Tai-
Japanese companies so as to become capable of mass wan, which is now seen to be a key contributor to the
production as soon as possible. The capability of mass enhancement of the country’s innovative capacity (Liu,
production makes Taiwan a significant player in the 2001).
TFT-LCD industry following a series of aggressive Taiwan’s successful diffusion of technology from
investment in 1999, and this has led to numerous patent public institutions (mainly ITRI) has been achieved
infringement claims from Japanese and Korean leading whilst maintaining a high level of R&D in the pri-
companies, such as Sharp and Samsung, and resulting vate sector, and a rather high degree of support from
higher royalty payments to be met by Taiwan firms. national technology policy and trade and research asso-
Now ITRI had accumulated several hundred patents ciations. Now, apart from the cutting-edge technology,
relating to TFT-LCD technologies, and so in 2002 it Taiwan’s IPR organizations and public institutions are
selected a portfolio of 232 patents and assigned them to also committed to training programs in intellectual
seven TFT-LCD companies for the purpose of defense property management, including aspects, such as law,
and negotiation. This is seen as a way to develop a patent engineering, licensing and negotiation. These
stronger position in patent negotiations, and take the efforts demonstrate the strategic role that IP man-
lead in developing new technologies and setting stan- agement comes to play in the building of national
dards. innovative capacity in latecomer countries, such as
A second case is the spin-off biotech firm Pha- Taiwan.
lanx Biotech Chips Company, which was formed with
technology transferred from ITRI, along with a set of
patents that might stand it in good stead in any future 7. Discussion and concluding remarks
patent infringement suit launched by foreign competi-
tors in the field of DNA chips. The technology charac- Both our quantitative empirical results and our qual-
teristics of biotech chips rely on the complementarity itative case studies in Taiwan produce the finding that
of inter-industry technology (ITRI, 2002). In order to while the process of building national innovative capac-
form a strong competitive patent portfolio, Phalanx was ity in latecomer countries is comparable to that fol-
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1347

lowed in more advanced countries, yet it is distinctive technology within R&D outsourcing and involves a
in ways that illustrate the strategies that need to be fee or a royalty as a proportion of sales, its usage is
pursued by latecomers in order to catch-up with the connected closely with the range of intellectual prop-
technological leaders. erty. Another important contribution of this study is that
There is a core finding common between the OECD while public sector R&D has exerted a significant effect
and latecomer countries, namely that variations in the on patenting rates, which reinforces its claim to be con-
rate of patenting across countries is accounted for by sidered as part of the innovative capacity of a latecomer
four variables: patent stocks, levels of R&D man- country, the case of Taiwan provides evidence that the
power, R&D expenditure by the private sector, and effect continues: the efforts of the public R&D sector in
industrial specialization in electrical, mechanical and utilizing and leveraging diverse IP resources with the
chemical engineering fields. The distinctive process aim of facilitating the knowledge flow and overcoming
of building national innovation capacity in latecomer the disadvantages of second movers, as exemplified in
countries, and its divergence from the patterns found the transfer of IP to spin-off enterprises such as Pha-
for the OECD countries, is also demonstrated. In the lanx and to consortia such as the Taiwan TFT-LCD
OECD countries studied by FP&S and others, more Association.
broadly based variables are closely associated with Secondly, the variable PUBLIC R&D FUNDING
variations in the rate of patenting, namely GDP per greatly strengthens the contribution of the most impor-
capita, total R&D expenditure, intellectual property tant determinant (i.e. SPECIALIZATION) in our pre-
protection, public expenditure on higher education and ferred model. Note that this effect will only be regis-
funding on academic R&D. We found these variables tered where a latecomer country is pursuing a targeted
to have less of an impact in the case of latecomer coun- strategy of catch-up, as in East Asia. If no targeting
tries. The most important point of variance is the impact is taking place (i.e. the government is not playing a
of public R&D expenditure, guiding and utilizing the leadership role) then PUBLIC R&D FUNDING will
limited resources in latecomer countries, reinforcing have less of an impact. While the decline of govern-
incentives of national innovative capacity (e.g. SPE- ment spending in R&D relative to private spending is
CIALIZATION) and still playing an indispensable role an unavoidable trend, what is of over-riding importance
in facilitating a national cluster innovation environment is not the amount of public R&D funding per se, but
in latecomer countries. the allocation and emphasis of innovative activities,
Our results raise two interesting issues. In the first which provides incentives in fostering national inno-
place, IP, in practice, is found to have a negative impact vative clusters, such as private R&D and the pattern
on latecomers’ national innovation capacity, as con- of specialization (as found by our empirical results).
trasted with the case for more advanced countries where While the evidence shows that involvement in global
IP institutions are highly correlated with international production networks is an important source of knowl-
patenting activity. The effect of IP thus appears to vary edge for successful late industrializing countries, this
according to a country’s level of industrial, technolog- is critical especially for a knowledge-intensive and
ical and economic development (Lall, 2003). Not until highly globalized high-tech industry. In such industries
the second half of the 1990s, does the importance of clusters of local capabilities have to be closely con-
IP emerge in latecomer East Asian countries. In the nected with international production networks in order
early stage of specializing on OEM business, latecom- to remain abreast of knowledge currents through a vari-
ers simply ignore the costly R&D and IP issues. When ety of multinational linkages. Regardless of whether
these latecomer countries catch-up and keep pace with one agrees with the interpretations in this study, these
advanced countries, IP starts to attract attention. How- empirical regularities exist and must be accounted for.
ever, the evidence that a strong IP policy will stimulate The detailed case study of Taiwan provides some
greater technology transfer and suggest a positive cor- support for our empirical results, where the distinc-
relation with economic development over the long term tive process of building national innovative capacity in
has been put forward by some cross-country econo- latecomer countries, as divergent from the patterns for
metrics (Maskus, 2000). When technology purchasing the OECD countries, is also demonstrated. Latecomers
becomes one of the primary ways to acquire the “key” from East Asia have focused their innovative activities
1348 M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349

on three key factors, namely on cumulative building Arundel, A., Kabla, J., 1998. What percentage of innovations are
of their R&D manpower; in targeting certain indus- patented? Experimental estimates in European firms. Research
trial sectors and specializing their innovative activities Policy 27, 127–142.
Cohen, W.M., Levinthal, D.A., 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new
in these sectors; and in promoting and effecting pub- perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science
lic R&D as a means of enhancing national innovative Quarterly 35 (1), 128–152.
capacity. These features are revealed in the case study Dosi, G., Pavitt, K., Soete, L., 1990. The Economics of Technical
of Taiwan, by examining the role of the public sec- Change and International Trade. Columbia University Press, New
tor R&D agency, the Industrial Technology Research York.
Eaton, J., Kortum, S., 1996. Trade in ideas: patenting and produc-
Institute, and the private sector. While ITRI’s patenting tivity in the OECD. Journal of International Economics 40 (3/4),
activity has been significant, Taiwan’s knowledge dif- 251–278.
fusion pivot, semiconductor and electronics industries, Eaton, J., Kortum, S., 1999. International technology diffusion: the-
are essentially built on the leverage effect from ITRI, ory and measurement. International Economic Review 40 (3),
including diffusion of R&D manpower and technology. 537–570.
Ellison, G., Glaeser, E., 1997. Geographic concentration in US man-
Another aspect of the Taiwan case is that the increase ufacturing industries: a Dartboard approach. Journal of Political
in patenting rates reflects a genuine increase in innova- Economy 105 (5), 889–927.
tive capacity, a point that cannot be sustained in the case Evenson, R., 1993. Patents, R&D, and Invention Potential: Inter-
of the advanced countries, where much of the recent national Evidence. Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and
increase in patenting rates is tactical (or strategic) in Fifth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association,
May 1983, pp. 463–468.
nature, and does not necessarily reflect enhancements Furman, J.L., Porter, M.E., Stern, S., 2002. The determinants of
in innovative capacity (Hall and Ziedonis, 2001). Thus, national innovative capacity. Research Policy 31, 899–933.
the reliance on patenting rates as a proxy for innovative Furman, J., Stern, S., 2002. Climbing atop the shoulders of
activity works well for the latecomer country Taiwan, giants: the impact of institutions on cumulative research.
whereas it is less well-defined in some of the advanced Working Paper. Available at: http://people.bu.edu/furmab/
Institutions&Cumulative Research - Furman Stern 10 02.pdf.
countries. Gerschenkron, A., 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Per-
A final contribution of this study is that it raises spective. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cam-
new questions. Why are some latecomer countries more bridge, MA.
innovative than others? How does the involvement of Goh, K.S., 1996. The technology ladder in development: the Singa-
the public sector relate to the performance of national pore case. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature 10 (1), 1–12.
Gregersen, B. (Ed.), 1992. National Systems of Innovation: Towards
innovative capacity? When will IP turn to a significant a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning. Pinter Publish-
and positive effect on innovation activity of latecomer ers, London UK.
countries, and to what extent will that affect national Griliches, Z., 1990. Patent statistics as economic indicators: a survey.
innovative capacity? While the reliance on patenting Journal of Economic Literature 28 (4), 1661–1707.
rates as a proxy for innovative activity works well Hagedoorn, J., Cloodt, M., 2003. Measuring innovative performance:
is there an advantage in using multiple indicators? Research Pol-
for the latecomer country, such as Taiwan, one should icy 32, 1365–1379.
consider whether the high level of patent self-citation Hall, B.H., Ziedonis, R.H., 2001. The patent paradox revisited: an
biases the assessment of national innovative perfor- empirical study of patenting in the U.S. semiconductor indus-
mance. Future research on these questions and others try, 1979–1995. RAND Journal of Economics 32 (1), 101–
will lead to a better understanding of how national inno- 128.
Hobday, M., 1994. Export-led technology development in the four
vative capacity is established in latecomer countries. dragons: the case of electronics. Development and Change 25
(2), 333–361.
Hu, A.G.Z., 2003. Multinational corporations, patenting, and
knowledge flow: the case of Singapore. METIA Confer-
References ence 2003. Singapore Management University. Available at:
http://www.business.smu.edu.sg/metia/programme/paper.htm.
Hu, A.G.Z., Shin, J., 2002. Climbing the technology ladder: chal-
Amsden, A.H., 1998. Editorial: bringing production back in
lenges facing Singapore in a globalized world. In: Hui, W.T.,
–understanding government’s economic role in late industrial-
Koh, A.T., Rao, Bhanoji, Lim, K.L. (Eds.), The Singapore Econ-
ization. World Development 25 (4), 469–480.
omy in the 21st Century: Issues and Strategies. McGraw-Hill
Amsden, A.H., Chu, W.W., 2003. Beyond Late Development: Tai-
Publisher, London.
wan’s Upgrading Policies. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
M.-C. Hu, J.A. Mathews / Research Policy 34 (2005) 1322–1349 1349

Hu, A.G.Z., Jaffe, A.B., 2001. Patent citations and international national Journal of Technology Management 22 (5/6), 455–
knowledge flow: the cases of Korea and Taiwan, NBER Working 479.
Paper 8528. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mathews, J.A., 2002. The origins and dynamics of Taiwan’s R&D
MA. consortia. Research Policy 31 (4), 633–651.
ITRI, 2002. Annual Report. Taiwan: Industrial Technology Research Mathews, J.A., Cho, D.S., 2000. Tiger Technology: The Creation of
Institute. Available at: http://www.itri.org.tw/eng/sitemap.jsp. the Semiconductor Industry in East Asia. Cambridge University
Jaffe, A., Trajtenberg, M., 2002. Patents, Citations & Innovations: Press, Cambridge.
a Window on the Knowledge Economy. The MIT Press, Mas- Neely, A., Hii, J., 1999. The innovative capacity of firms. Report
sachusetts Institute of Technology. commissioned by the Government Office for the East of England.
Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., 1998. International knowledge flows: Centre for Business Performance. Judge Institute of Management
evidence from patent citations. Economics of Innovation and Studies, University of Cambridge.
New Technology 8, 105–136. Nelson, R. (Ed.), 1988. Institutions Supporting Technical Change
Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., Henderson, R., 1993. Geographic in the United States. Technical Change and Economic Theory.
localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent Printer Publishers, London, UK.
citations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 434, 577– Nelson, R. (Ed.), 1993. National Innovation Systems: A Comparative
598. Analysis. Oxford University Press, New York.
Jones, C., 1995. R&D based models of economic growth. Journal of Patel, P., Pavitt, K., 1994. National innovation systems: why they
Political Economy 103, 739–784. are important, and how they might be measured and compared.
Jones, C., 1998. Introduction to Economic Growth. WW Norton & Economic Growth. Economic Inquiry 33 (4), 571–591.
Co., New York. Pallent, J., 2001. SPSS Survival Manual. SPSS Inc., Chicago, USA.
Jones, C., 2002. Sources of U.S. economic growth in a world of ideas. Pavitt, K.,1988. Uses and abuses of patent statistics. In: van Raan,
American Economic Review 92 (1), 220–239. A.F.J. (Ed.), Handbook of Quantitative Studies of Science Policy.
Jung, S.C., Imm, K.-Y., 2002. The patent activities of Korea and Tai- North-Holland, Amsterdam.
wan: a comparative case study of patent statistics. World Patent Porter, M.E., 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Free
Information 24 (4), 303–311. Press, New York.
Kanwar, S., Evenson, R., 2001. Does intellectual property protec- Porter, M.E., 1998. Clusters and competition: new agendas for com-
tion spur technological change? Center Discussion Papers 831, panies, governments and institutions. In: Porter, M. (Ed.), On
Economic Growth Center, Yale University. Competition. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Kim, L., 1997a. The dynamics of Samsung’s technological learn- Rausch, L.M., 1995. Asia’s New High-Tech Competitors: An SRS
ing in semiconductors. California Management Review 39 (3), report. National Science Foundation, NSF 95-309.
86–100. Romer, P.M., 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of
Kim, L., 1997b. Imitation to Innovation: The Dynamics of Korea’s Political Economy 98 (5 (pt. 2)), 71–102.
Technological Learning. Harvard Business School Press, Boston. Schmookler, J., 1966. Invention and Economic Growth. Harvard Uni-
Kortum, S., 1997. Research, patenting, and technological change. versity Press, Cambridge, MA.
Econometrica 65 (6), 1389–1419. Soete, L., 1987. The impact of technological innovation on interna-
Lall, S., 2003. Indicators of the relative importance of IPRs in devel- tional trade patterns: the evidence reconsidered. Research Policy
oping countries. Research Policy 32 (9), 1657–1680. 18, 101–130.
Lanjouw, J.O., Schankerman, M., 1999. The quality of ideas: measur- Soete, L., Wyatt, S., 1983. The use of foreign patenting as an inter-
ing innovation with multiple indicators. NBER Working Paper nationally comparable science and technology output indicator.
No. 7345. Scientometrics 5 (January), 31–54.
Liu, S.J., 2001. Competing in the knowledge game: intellectual prop- Suarez-Villa, L., 1990. Invention, inventive learning, and innovative
erty rights. In: Chang, C.Y., Yu, P.L. (Eds.), Made by Taiwan: capacity. Behavioral Science 35 (4), 290–310.
Booming in the Information Technology Era. World Scientific Suarez-Villa, L., Hasnath, S.A., 1993. The effect of infrastructure
Publishing. on innovation: Innovative capacity and the dynamics of public
Lundvall, B.A., 1988. Innovation as an interactive process: from user- construction investment. Technological Forecasting and Social
producer interaction to the national system of innovation. In: Change 44 (4), 333–358.
Dosi, G. (Ed.), Technical Change and Economic Theory. Printer Trajtenberg, M., 1990. Patents as indicators of innovation. In: Eco-
Publishers, London, UK. nomic Analysis of Product Innovation. Harvard University Press,
Mansfield, E., 1986. Patents and innovation: an empirical study. Man- Cambridge, MA.
agement Science 32, 173–181. Trajtenberg, M., 1999. Innovation in Israel 1968–1997: a compar-
Maskus, K.E., 2000. Lessons from studying the international eco- ative analysis using patent data. NBER Working paper 7022.
nomics of Intellectual Property Rights. Caslon Analytics Intel- National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
lectual Property Guide. UNIDO, 2002.
Mathews, J.A., 2001. National systems of economic learning: the World Bank, 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and
case of technology diffusion management in East Asia. Inter- Public Policy. The World Bank, Washington, DC.

Вам также может понравиться