Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 14

C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

Private
Profits and
Socialized Risk

Investment banks are highly


levered and undercapitalized,
thanks in part to regulatory rules
that lowered capital requirements.
So argues David Einhorn, who also
contends that value-at-risk (VaR)
is a flawed model that encourages
excessive risk-taking and that
rating agencies have done a poor
job of analyzing bank balance
sheets.Aaron Brown (see pg. 19)
cautions that too much capital can
be dangerous, explains why VaR is
useful and defends the track
record of regulators.

10 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2


few weeks ago, the financial world was present- do: maximize employee compensation. Investment banks

A ed with the imminent failure of a publicly trad-


ed entity called Carlyle Capital Corporation.
You see, it had leveraged itself more than 30 to
one. The press scoffed about what kind of
insanity this was. Who in their right mind
would take on such leverage?
The fact was that the Carlyle portfolio consisted of gov-
ernment agency securities. Historically, after treasuries,
these have been among the safest securities around.
pay out 50% of revenues as compensation. So, more lever-
age means more revenues, which means more compensation.
In good times, once they pay out the compensation,
overhead and taxes, only a fraction of the incremental rev-
enues fall to the bottom line for shareholders. Shareholders
get just enough so that the returns on equity are decent.
Considering the franchise value, the nonrisk fee-generating
capabilities of the banks and the levered investment result,
in the good times the returns on equity should not be
Carlyle’s strategy was to take relatively safe securities that decent — they should be extraordinary. But they are not,
generate small returns and, through the magic of leverage, because so much of the revenue goes to compensation.
create medium returns. Given the historical safety of the The banks have also done a wonderful job at public rela-
instruments, Carlyle and its lenders tions. Everyone knows about the 20% incentive fees in the
judged 30 times leverage to be hedge fund and private equity industry. Nobody talks
appropriate. One could check the about the investment banks’ 50% compensation structures,
backward-looking volatility and which have no high-water mark and actually are exceeded
come to the same conclusion. in difficult times in order to retain talent.
Of course, the world changed,
and the models didn’t work. The Trouble with VaR
Carlyle’s investors lost most of their The second question is, how do the investment banks justi-
investment and the world, with fy such thin capitalization ratios? And the answer is, in
normal 20-20 hindsight, has part, by relying on flawed risk models, most notably value-
learned that investment companies David at-risk (VaR). VaR is an interesting concept. The idea is to
with 30 times leverage are not safe. Einhorn
It didn’t take long for investors to
realize that the big investment banks sport similar leverage. In
fact, the banks count things such as preferred stock and sub- Investment banks pay out 50% of
ordinated debt as equity for calculating leverage ratios. If
those are excluded, the leverage to common equity is even revenues as compensation. So, more
higher than 30 times.
And I’ll tell you a little secret: these levered balance leverage means more revenues,
sheets hold some things that are dicier than government
agency securities. They hold inventories of common stocks
which means more compensation.
and bonds. They also have various loans that they hope to
securitize. They have pieces of structured finance transac-
tions. They have derivative exposures of staggering notion- tell how much a portfolio stands to make or lose 95% of
al amounts and related counterparty risk. They have real the days or 99% of the days or what have you. Of course,
estate and private equity. if you are a risk manager, you should not be particularly
The investment banks claim that they are in the “mov- concerned how much is at risk 95% or 99% of the time.
ing” business rather than the “storage” business, but the You don’t need to have a lot of advanced math to know
very nature of some of their holdings suggests that this is that the answer will always be a manageable amount that
not true. And they hold this stuff on tremendously levered will not jeopardize the bank.
balance sheets. A risk manager’s job is to worry about whether the bank
is putting itself at risk in the unusual times — or, in statisti-
Origins of Levered Balance Sheets cal terms, in the tails of distribution. Yet, VaR ignores what
The first question to ask is, how did this happen? The happens in the tails. It specifically cuts them off. A 99%
answer is that the investment banks outmaneuvered the VaR calculation does not evaluate what happens in the last
watchdogs, as I will explain in detail in a moment. As a 1%. This, in my view, makes VaR relatively useless as a risk
result, with no one watching, the management teams at the management tool and potentially catastrophic when its use
investment banks did exactly what they were incentivized to creates a false sense of security among senior managers and

GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS 11


C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

watchdogs. This is like an airbag that works all the time, on many of them for the same reason. This is why in recent
except when you have a car accident. periods the investment banks had quarterly write-downs
By ignoring the tails, VaR creates an incentive to take that were many times the firmwide modelled VaR.
excessive but remote risks. Consider an investment in a
coin-flip. If you bet $100 on tails at even money, your VaR Ratings: Flawed Opinions from
to a 99% threshold is $100, as you will lose that amount Understaffed Agencies
50% of the time, which obviously is within the threshold. Which brings us to the third question, what were the watch-
In this case, the VaR will equal the maximum loss. dogs doing? Let’s start with the credit rating agencies. They
Compare that to a bet where you offer 127 to 1 odds have a special spot in our markets. They can review non-
on $100 that heads won’t come up seven times in a row. public information and opine on the creditworthiness of the
You will win more than 99.2% of the time, which investment banks. The market and the regulators assume
exceeds the 99% threshold. As a result, your 99% VaR is that the rating agencies take their responsibility to stay on
zero, even though you are exposed to a possible $12,700 top things seriously. When the credit crisis broke last sum-
mer, one of the major agencies held a public conference call
to discuss the health of the investment banks.
The gist of the rating agency perspective was, “Don’t
Everyone knows about the 20% worry.” The investment banks have excellent risk controls,
and they hedge their exposures. The initial reaction to the
incentive fees in the hedge fund and credit crisis basically amounted to “everyone is hedged.” A
few weeks later, when Merrill Lynch announced a big loss,
private equity industry. Nobody that story changed. But initially, the word was that every-
talks about the investment banks’ one was hedged. Securitization had spread the risk around
the world, and most of the risk was probably in Asia,
50% compensation structures, Europe, Dubai or at the bottom of the East River. The
banks were in the “moving” business, not the “storage”
which have no high-water mark and business, so this was no big issue. I wondered whether any-
one saying this had actually looked at the balance sheets.
actually are exceeded in difficult Of course, this raised the following question: how did
times in order to retain talent. everyone hedge and who were the counterparties holding
the bag? I pressed star-1 during the conference call and
asked the rating agency analyst how everyone hedged the
massive apparent credit risks on the balance sheets. The
loss. In other words, an investment bank wouldn’t have analyst responded that the rating agency had observed
to put up any capital to make this bet. The math whizzes enormous trading volumes on the Chicago Mercantile
will say it is more complicated than that, but this is the Exchange (“the Merc”) in recent days.
basic idea. The Merc offers products that enable one to hedge inter-
Now we understand why investment banks held enor- est rate risk, not credit risk. I called the rating analyst back
mous portfolios of “super-senior triple A-rated” whatever. to discuss this in greater depth. At first he told me that you
These securities had very small returns. However, the risk could hedge anything on the Merc. When I asked how to
models said they had trivial VaR, because the possibility of hedge credit risk there, he was less familiar. I came to sus-
credit loss was calculated to be beyond the VaR threshold. pect that the rating agency analyst viewed his role as one to
This meant that holding them required only a trivial restore confidence in the system, which the rating agency
amount of capital, and a small return over a trivial amount call did do for a while, rather than to analyze risk.
of capital can generate an almost infinite revenue-to-equity I later had an opportunity to meet a recently retired senior
ratio. VaR-driven risk management encouraged accepting a executive at one of the large rating agencies. I asked him how
lot of bets that amounted to accepting the risk that heads his agency went about evaluating the creditworthiness of the
wouldn’t come up seven times in a row. investment banks. By then, Merrill had acknowledged large
In the current crisis, it has turned out that the unlucky losses, so I asked him what the rating team found when it
outcome was far more likely than the backtested models went to examine Merrill’s portfolio in detail.
predicted. What is worse, the various supposedly remote He answered by asking me to refocus on what I meant by
risks that required trivial capital are highly correlated; you “team.” He told me that the group covering the investment
don’t just lose on one bad bet in this environment, you lose banks was only three or four people and they have to cover

12 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2


all of the banks. So they have no team to send to Merrill for a The purpose of the new rule was to reduce regulatory
thorough portfolio review. He explained that the agency costs for broker-dealers by allowing large broker-dealers to
doesn’t even try to look at the actual portfolio, because it use their own risk management practices for regulatory
changes so frequently that there would be no way to keep up. purposes. According to the SEC’s website, very large bro-
I asked how the rating agencies monitored the balance ker-dealers had the opportunity to volunteer for additional
sheets so that when an investment bank adds an asset, the oversight and confidential disclosure to the SEC and, in
agency assesses a capital charge to ensure that the bank exchange, would be permitted to qualify for “the alterna-
doesn’t exceed the risk for the rating. He answered that tive capital computation method.”
they don’t and added that the rating agencies don’t even While the SEC did not say that the alternative capital
have these types of models for the investment banks. computation method would increase or decrease the capital
I then asked what they do look at. He told me they look requirements, the rule says that “deductions for market
mostly at the public information — basic balance sheet and credit risk will probably be lower under the alternative
ratios, pretax margin and the volatility of pretax margin. method.” Obviously, since this appears to be the carrot
They also speak with management and review management offered to accept additional supervision, and I believe that
risk reports. And, of course, they monitor VaR. all of the largest broker-dealers have elected to participate,
I was shocked by this, and I think that most market partic- I think it is reasonable to speculate that the rule enabled
ipants would be surprised as well. While the rating agencies brokers to lower their capital requirements.
don’t actually say what work they do, I believe the market Under this new method, the broker-dealer can use
assumes that they take advantage of their exemption from “mathematical modelling methods already used to manage
Regulation FD to examine a wide range of non-public mater-
ial. A few months ago, I made a speech where I said that rat-
ing agencies should lose the exemption to Regulation FD, so According to the SEC’s website,
that people would not over-rely on their opinions.
The market perceives the rating agencies to be doing very large broker-dealers had the
much more than they actually do. The agencies themselves
don’t directly misinform the market, but they don’t dis- opportunity to volunteer for addi-
abuse the market of misperceptions — often spread by the
rated entities — that the agencies do more than they actual-
tional oversight and confidential
ly do. This creates a false sense of security, and in times of disclosure to the SEC and, in
stress, this actually makes the problems worse. Had the
credit rating agencies been doing a reasonable job of disci- exchange, would be permitted to
plining the investment banks — which unfortunately hap-
pen to bring the rating agencies lots of other business —
qualify for “the alternative capital
then the banks may have been prevented from taking computation method.”
excess risk and the current crisis might have been averted.
The rating agencies remind me of the department of
motor vehicles: they are understaffed and don’t pay enough their own business risk, including VaR models and scenario
to attract the best and the brightest. The DMV is scary, but analysis for regulatory purposes.” It seems that the SEC
it is just for mundane things like driver’s licenses. Scary allowed the industry to adopt VaR as a principal method of
does not begin to describe the feeling of learning that there calculating regulatory capital.
are only three or four hard-working people at a major rat- Unfortunately, it gets worse. In the new rule, the SEC also
ing agency judging the creditworthiness of all the invest- said, “We are amending the definition of tentative net capi-
ment banks; the agency, moreover, does not even have its tal to include securities for which there is no ready market.
own model for evaluating creditworthiness. …This modification is necessary because … we eliminated
the requirement that a security have a ready market to qual-
Insufficient Capital Requirements ify for capital treatment using VaR models.” Without the
The second watchdog to talk about is the SEC. In 2004, the modification, the “no ready market” securities would have
SEC instituted a rule titled, “Alternative Net Capital been subject to a 100% deduction for capital purposes.
Requirements for Broker-Dealers That Are Part of Is it any wonder, then, that over the last few years the
Consolidated Supervised Entities.” In hindsight, as you will industry has increased its holdings of no ready market
see, an alternative name for the rule might have been the securities? In the rule itself, the SEC conceded, “… inclu-
“Bear Stearns Future Insolvency Act of 2004.” sion in net capital of unsecured receivables and securities

GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS 13


C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

that do not have a ready market under the current net capi- probability that a large broker-dealer could go bust.
tal rule will reduce the liquidity standards.”
These adjustments reduced the amount of required capi- The Fall of Bear Stearns
tal to engage in increasingly risky activities. The SEC esti- I don’t know what effect the new rules had on Bear Stearns.
mated at the time the rule was proposed that the broker- The information the broker-dealers provide the SEC to show
dealers taking advantage of the alternative capital compu- their compliance with these regulatory capital requirements
tation would realize an average reduction in capital deduc- is confidential. It would be interesting to know how ade-
tions of approximately 40%. From my reading, the final quately capitalized Bear and other large broker-dealers
rule appears to have come out even weaker, suggesting that would have been under the rules as they existed before 2004.
the capital deductions may have been reduced even further. In response to this possible regulatory failure,
Obviously, since the rule was implemented, the broker- Christopher Cox, the SEC chairman, said recently that this
dealers have modified their balance sheets to take advan- current voluntary program of SEC supervision should be
tage of it. They have added lots of exposure to low-return made permanent and mandatory. Reuters reported that
bonds with credit risk perceived to be beyond the VaR Cox said that the current value of the SEC supervisory pro-
threshold, and they have added more no ready market gram “can never be doubted again.”
securities — including whole loans, junior pieces of struc- Rather than looking at its own rules — which permitted
tured credit instruments, private equity and real estate. increased leverage, lower liquidity, greater concentrations
If this wasn’t enough, the 2004 rule also changed what of credit risk and holdings of no ready market securities —
counts as capital: “In response to comments received, the the SEC is conducting an investigation to see if any short-
Commission has expanded the definition of allowable capi- sellers caused the demise of Bear by spreading rumors.
tal … to include hybrid capital instruments and certain Of course, Bear didn’t fall because of market rumors. It
deferred tax assets,” the SEC explained. fell because it was too levered and had too many illiquid
The rule also permits the inclusion of subordinated debt assets of questionable value and at the same time depended
in allowable capital. The SEC permitted this because subor- on short-term funding. With the benefits of the reduced
dinated debt “has many of the characteristics of capital.” I capital requirements and reliance on flawed VaR analysis,
find this one particularly amazing; apparently, it doesn’t Bear — like the other investment banks — increased its risk
actually have to be capital. For everyone else except the profile over the last few years.
broker-dealers, subordinated debt is leverage. The commis- While VaR might make sense to the quants, it has led to
sion considered but stopped short of allowing the broker- risk-taking beyond common sense. If Bear’s only business
dealers to count all long-term debt as capital. was to have $29 billion of illiquid, hard-to-mark assets,
In reading through the rules and the SEC’s response to supported by its entire $10.5 billion of tangible common
comment letters, it seems that the SEC made concession equity, in my view, that by itself would be an aggressive
after concession to the large broker-dealers. I won’t bore investment strategy. However, as of November 2007, that
you by describing how the rule eased the calculations of sliver of equity was also needed to support an additional
counterparty risk, maximum potential exposures and mar- $366 billion of other assets on Bear’s balance sheet.
gin lending or how the rule permitted broker-dealers to When Bear’s customers looked at the balance sheet and
assign their own credit ratings to unrated counterparties. also noticed the increased cost of buying credit protection on
My impression of this is that the large broker-dealers con- Bear, they had to ask themselves whether they were being
vinced the regulators that the dealers could better measure compensated for the credit risk and counterparty risk in
their own risks, and with fancy math, they attempted to show doing business with Bear. Many decided that they weren’t and
that they could support more risk with less capital. I suspect did the prudent thing to protect their own capital by curtail-
that the SEC took the point of view that these were all large, ing their exposure. Bear suffered a classic “run on the bank.”
well-capitalized institutions, with smart, sophisticated risk
managers who had no incentive to try to fail. Consequently, Perils of a Reverse-Robin Hood System
they gave the industry the benefit of the doubt. When I came up with the title for this discussion, it was
In the cost-benefit analysis of the rule, on the benefit before Bear Stearns failed. I was going to point out that we
side, the SEC estimated the “value” to the industry by tak- were developing a system of very large, highly levered,
ing advantage of lower capital charges to earn additional undercapitalized financial institutions — including the
returns. In the “cost” part of the analysis, the SEC carefully investment banks, some of the large money center banks,
analyzed the number of hours and related expense of the the insurance companies with large derivatives books and
monitoring and documentation requirements, as well as IT the government-sponsored entities (GSEs). I planned to
costs. It did not discuss the cost to society of increasing the speculate that regulators believe all of these are too big to

16 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2


fail and would bail them out if necessary. Even so, the crisis deepened. So now they have introduced
The owners, employees and creditors of these institu- the “Big Gulp,” also known as the Bear Stearns bailout, and
tions are rewarded when they succeed, but it is all of us — an alphabet soup of extraordinary measures to support the
the taxpayers — who are left on the hook if they fail. This current system. If that doesn’t turn the markets, they are
is called private profits and socialized risk. Heads, I win. threatening the financial equivalent of having the water utili-
Tails, you lose. It is a reverse-Robin Hood system. ties substitute Coke for water throughout the system.
In any case, with the actual failure and subsequent In early April, Ben Bernanke told Congress that he hopes
bailout of Bear Stearns — and regardless of what our lead- that Bear Stearns is a one-time thing. In the short-term, it
ers told Congress last week, it is a bailout under any defini- might be. If market participants accept as an article of faith
tion — I am shifting the subject of this talk from a potential that the Fed will bail them out, it reinforces risk-taking
bailout to the real, live thing. without the need for credit analysis. As night follows day, it
Some would say that it wasn’t a bailout, because the is certain that in the absence of tremendous government
shareholders, including the risk-taking employees, lost most regulation, this bailout will lead to a new and potentially
of their money, so they were properly punished and the sys- bigger round of excessive risk-taking. If Mr. Bernanke is
tem is intact. However, the problem is that we don’t have an unlucky, the payback may come later in this cycle; if he is
equity bubble. (In fact, the equity markets seem to be func- lucky, it will come in the next cycle.
tioning fine, with a good number of excellent companies at Since the government is now on the line for the losses, there
reasonable valuations.) What we do have is a credit bubble, is a strong public interest in increased supervision, which
and the Bear Stearns bailout has reinforced the excessive should result in dramatically higher capital requirements for
risk-taking and leverage in that arena. Specifically, the the major players. Additionally, regulators should consider
bailout preserved the counterparty system. The government dismantling the counterparty system so that the market can
appears to have determined that the collapse of a single sig- survive the failure of a big player. One step could be to require
nificant player in the derivatives market would cause so the posting of all derivative trades, clearing them through a
much risk to the entire system that it could not be permitted central system and regulating margin requirements.
to happen. In effect, the government appears to have guar-
anteed virtually the entire counterparty system. Lehman Brothers vs. Bear Stearns:
The message is that if you are dealing with a major player A Quick Comparison
— anyone in the “too big to fail” group — you don’t have to Finally, I’ll offer a few words about Lehman Brothers.
worry about that player’s creditworthiness. In effect, your (Greenlight Capital is short the stock.) Lehman’s manage-
risk is with the US Treasury. The government does not want ment is charismatic and has almost cult-like status. It gets
customers of the next Bear Stearns to have to evaluate its tremendously favorable press for everything from handling
creditworthiness, find it lacking and determine that exposure the 1998 crisis to supposedly hedging in this crisis to not
needs to be curtailed, creating a run on another bank. playing bridge while the franchise implodes.
From a balance sheet and business mix perspective,
The Bailout Impact Lehman is not that materially different from Bear Stearns.
The next question is whether the bailout was a good idea. Lehman entered the crisis with a huge reliance on US fixed
It really comes down to Coke vs. water. If you are thirsty, income, particularly mortgage origination and securitiza-
you have choices. Coke tastes better and provides an imme- tion. It is different from Bear in that it has greater exposure
diate sugar rush and caffeinated stimulus, while quenching to commercial real estate and its asset management franchise
thirst. Water also quenches thirst, but it isn’t as stimulating. did not blow up. Incidentally, neither Bear nor Lehman had
It purifies your body. It doesn’t make you fat and is much enormous on-balance-sheet exposure to CDOs.
better for your long-term health. At the end of November 2007, Lehman had Level 3
One of the things I have observed is that American finan- assets and total assets of about 2.4 times and 40 times its
cial markets have a very low pain threshold. Last fall, with tangible common equity, respectively. Even so, at the end of
the S&P 500 only a few percent off its all-time high prices January 2008, Lehman increased its dividend and autho-
after a multi-year bull market, certain TV commentators rized the repurchase of 19% of its shares. In the quarter
and market players were having daily tantrums demanding ended in February, Lehman spent over $750 million on
that the Federal Reserve System (“the Fed”) give them the share repurchases, while growing assets by another $90 bil-
financial equivalent of Coke. Other parts of the world lion. I estimate Lehman’s ratio of assets to tangible com-
endure much greater swings in equity values without mon equity to have reached 44 times.
demanding relief from central planners. There is good reason to question Lehman’s fair value cal-
The Fed responded by providing liquidity and lower rates. culations. It has been particularly aggressive in transferring

GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS 17


C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

mortgage assets into Level 3. Last year, Lehman reported its have come to regret them.
Level 3 assets actually had $400 million of realized and Lehman wants to concentrate on long investors; in fact,
unrealized gains. Lehman has more than 20% of its tangi- it went to great lengths to tell the market that it sold all of
ble common equity tied up in the debt and equity of a single its recent convert issue to long-only investors. Putting aside
private equity transaction — Archstone-Smith, a real estate the fact that some of the clearing firms have told us that
investment trust (REIT) purchased at a high price at the end this wasn’t entirely true, companies that fight short sellers
of the cycle. Lehman does not provide disclosure about its in this manner have poor records. The same goes for com-
valuation, though most of the comparable company trading panies that publicly ask the SEC to investigate short selling,
prices have fallen 20-30% since the deal was announced. as Lehman has done. There is good academic research to
The high leverage in the privatized Archstone-Smith would support my view on this point.
suggest the need for a multibillion-dollar write-down. As I have studied Lehman for each of the last three quar-
Lehman has additional large exposures to Alt-A mort- ters, I have seen the company take smaller write-downs
gages, CMBS and below-investment-grade corporate debt. than one might expect. Each time, Lehman reported a
Our analysis of market transactions and how debt indices modest profit and slightly exceeded analyst estimates that
performed in the February quarter would suggest Lehman each time had been reduced just before the public
could have taken many billions more in write-downs than it announcement of the results. That Lehman has not report-
did. Lehman has large exposure to commercial real estate. ed a loss smells of performance smoothing.
Lehman has potential legal liability for selling auction-rate Given that Lehman hasn’t reported a loss to date, there is
securities to risk-averse investors as near cash equivalents. little reason to expect that it will any time soon. Even so, I
What’s more, Lehman does not provide enough trans- believe that the outlook for Lehman’s stock is dim. Any
parency for us even to hazard a guess as to how they have deferred losses will likely create an earnings headwind
accounted for these items. It responds to requests for going forward. As a result, in any forthcoming recovery,
improved transparency grudgingly, and I suspect that Lehman might underearn compared to peers that have been
greater transparency on these valuations would not inspire more aggressive in recognizing losses.
market confidence. Further, I do expect the authorities to require the broker-
Instead of addressing questions about its accounting and dealers to de-lever. In my judgment, a back-of-the-envelope
valuations, Lehman wants to shift the debate to where it is calculation of prudent reform would require 50-100% cap-
on stronger ground. It wants the market to focus on its liq- ital for no ready market investments; 8-12% capital for
uidity. However, in my opinion, the proper debate should what the investment banks call “net assets”; 2% capital for
be about Lehman’s asset values, future earning capabilities the other assets on the balance sheet; and an additional
and capital sufficiency. charge that I don’t know how to quantify for derivative
In early April, Lehman raised $4 billion of new capital exposures and contingent commitments.
from investors, thereby spreading the eventual problems Only tangible equity, not subordinated debt, should
over a larger capital pool. Given the crisis, the regulators count as capital. On that basis, assuming that Level 3 assets
seem willing to turn a blind eye toward efforts to raise capi- are a good proxy for no ready market investments —
tal before recognizing large losses; this holds for a number assigning no charge for the derivative exposure or contin-
of other troubled financial institutions. gent commitments and assuming its asset valuations are
The problem with 44 times leverage is that if your assets fairly stated — Lehman, based on its November balance
fall by only a percent, you lose almost half the equity. sheet, would need $55-$89 billion of tangible equity, which
Suddenly, 44 times leverage becomes 80 times leverage and would be a three- to-five-fold increase.
confidence is lost. It is more practical to raise the new So what do I expect to happen? I just finished a book on
equity before showing the loss. Hopefully, the new Allied Capital and the lack of proper and effective regula-
investors understand what they are buying into, even tory oversight. Based on my book and the current regulato-
though there probably isn’t much discussion of this ry environment, the pessimistic side of me says that regula-
dynamic in the offering memos. Some of the sovereign tors will probably decide to send me a subpoena and send
wealth funds that made these types of investment last year Lehman a Coke. ■

✎ DAVID EINHORN is the president and founder of Greenlight Capital, a long-short value-oriented hedge fund. Since its inception in 1996,
Greenlight has generated a greater than 25% annualized net return for its partners. Einhorn is the chairman of Greenlight Capital Re, Ltd.
(Nasdaq: GLRE), and serves on the boards of the Michael J. Fox Foundation for Parkinson’s Research and Hillel: The Foundation for Jewish
Campus Life. Einhorn is the author of Fooling Some of the People All of the Time:A Long Short Story (Wiley, May 2008).

This article is a reprint of a speech given April 8, 2008, at Grant’s Spring Investment Conference

18 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2


Counterpoint:
Capital Inadequacy By Aaron Brown

agree with David Einhorn that the financial dealer sys- later is less adequate. Basel I treated every asset like a loan,

I tem is undercapitalized, and I think he has identified the


important links in the chain: management incentives,
financial regulation and risk management. However, I
have different views about each of those, and put them
together in a different order. Therefore, it makes sense
to me to start at the end, with his recommendation for
“prudent reform”:

“50-100% capital for no ready market investments; 8-


which made it impossible to treat derivatives. Basel II treats
every asset like a derivative, and loans are easy to fit into
that. Unfortunately, Basel II also requires more assump-
tions, flaws that can lead to disaster. Still, I prefer assump-
tions, which might be right and can be revised as circum-
stances change, to embedded contradictions, which cannot
be either.
One point I concede immediately: David Einhorn is a far
better equity analyst than I am. If he tells you what he thinks
12% capital for ... net assets; 2% capital for all other assets of a Lehman common stock investment, no one should con-
on the balance sheet; and an additional charge that I don’t sider asking my opinion. My portfolio consists of low-cost
know how to quantify for derivative exposures and contin- index funds and stock I received as compensation (all from
gent commitments.” overleveraged financial firms, but not including Lehman),
which I hold out of loyalty rather than calculation. So I’m
This, of course, is Basel I, the standard created in 1988 not going to touch the question of whether Lehman is over-
and put into law in 1992. Basel I had five buckets from 0% leveraged from the standpoint of shareholders.
(for home country sovereign debt) to 8% (for corporate
debt), with an add-on for the notional amount of deriva- Building a Better Basel
tives. The prudent reform proposal has about 50% higher On the other hand, I suspect I
capital levels (based on a quick estimate applying both know more about the nuts and
rules to Lehman’s 2007 balance sheet) and different cate- bolts of calculating risk-sensitive
gories, but the principles are the same. capital levels for big financial insti-
There were three problems with Basel I, all of which tutions. I’ve done it for four of
apply to prudent reform as well. First, everything in a them, and I know a lot of the peo-
bucket had the same capital charge, which encouraged ple who did it for the rest. Twenty
institutions to fund the riskiest things in each bucket and years ago, I looked at Basel I and
ignore the safest things. The most notorious example was Aaron quit my job as head of mortgage
the 0% charge for sovereign risk, which encouraged over- securities to become an advocate
Brown
exposure to emerging markets. This distorted markets and for what came to be called VaR.
led to excessive risk-taking. How could I have been so stu-
Second, Basel I did not encourage risk management. In pid as to help develop a “useless” and “potentially cata-
most cases, hedging a risk — except for certain nearly per- strophic” measure that, to quote Mr. Einhorn, is “like an
fect hedges — increased rather than decreased the capital air bag that works all the time, except when you have a car
charge. Two assets had the same capital charge whether accident”? It wasn’t for lack of alternatives. There were all
they were highly correlated or negatively correlated. Some sorts of candidates for a risk-sensitive measure in those
major risks, like counterparty credit in an era when over- days, including ones that looked deep in the tails. VaR has
the-counter transactions were rarely collateralized, did not only one virtue, but it was enough to win out over all the
appear at all. At a higher level, there was no requirement to others. VaR is observable.
monitor risk, nor to report it to regulators, nor to disclose VaR is defined as the loss amount such that there is a
it to investors. specified probability (e.g., 1%) that the loss from a portfo-
Finally, under Basel I, derivatives and commitments are lio at a specified future time (say, close of business tomor-
afterthoughts. This was inadequate in 1988, and 20 years row) will be greater than the VaR amount, assuming fixed

GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS 19


C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

positions and normal markets. You evaluate VaR by back- day VaR has to operate for about three years before you
test; you compute it every night on the portfolio, and check trust it. A 99.97% one-year VaR, which some people use
the next day how much that fixed portfolio would have for economic capital, requires 26,000 years for the same
gained or lost (this is not the same as the actual gain or loss level of confidence. That makes deep tail VaR a matter of
if there is trading during the day). You check that the loss faith and assumptions, not something you can observe with
exceeds VaR on 1% of the days (plus or minus expected reasonable statistical certainty over a moderate time inter-
statistical variation) and test that the break days are both val. Moreover, assumptions like fixed positions and normal
independent in time and independent of market factors markets make VaR far less relevant over longer periods at
(most importantly, the level of the VaR). smaller probabilities.
VaR is only as good as its backtest. When someone Most important, some days have undefined losses due
shows me a VaR number, I don’t ask how it is computed, I to events like market closures, extreme liquidity events,
legal uncertainties and so forth. And however careful you
are, there is some chance your VaR estimate is significantly
misstated due to data or calculation errors (including those
VaR is only as good as its backtest. induced by rogue traders and embezzlers and third-party
crooks). These might happen two or three times a decade,
When someone shows me a VaR about 0.1% of the time. VaR excludes these days, which is
reasonable in a 99% measure. But in a 99.9% measure,
number, I don’t ask how it is com- you would be excluding as many days as you had VaR
puted, I ask to see the backtest. If I breaks, making the number pretty useless; 99.97% is
entirely pointless.
think I could make money betting
New and Improved!
either side at 100 to 1 on whether A once-popular alternative to VaR, which has enjoyed a
or not a break will occur tomor- resurgence among academics but not practitioners, is
expected shortfall (ES) — defined as how far you expect to
row, I disregard the VaR. If anyone go beyond VaR, given that you exceed it. ES has some
desirable mathematical properties and tells you more about
argues with me, I challenge them to the tail than VaR. However, expected loss, conditional or
take my bet over the next year. unconditional, is not observable because there is always the
possibility of a small-probability, large-impact event that is
missing from historical data. Standard deviation, which
depends on the square of P&L movements, is even more
ask to see the backtest. If I think I could make money bet- sensitive to this problem.
ting either side at 100 to 1 on whether or not a break will Another alternative is to consider maximum loss within
occur tomorrow, I disregard the VaR. If anyone argues with the VaR interval. But this is hard to define with securities
me, I challenge them to take my bet over the next year. trading in different markets and time zones. You can esti-
Also, it’s essential that VaR is actually calculated before the mate it with a parametric model, but you have to trust your
start of trading. That means there will be errors: mis- model; you can’t prove the results with transactions.
booked trades, missing feeds, stale prices and other prob- Useful numbers are compromises between what we
lems. The noise from these errors has to be included in want to know and what we can measure well. VaR can be
VaR, because they are real risks. measured better than alternatives, but what does it tell us?
If you report a $50 million VaR, then revise it to $200 It’s not the worst-case loss: in fact, we expect to lose more
million after a $150 million loss, you did nothing useful than VaR two or three times a year. Sometimes people
and I don’t trust either the original or the revised number. I assume that a multiple of VaR, say three times VaR, is a
want to see a VaR backtest based on the actual values pub- good almost-worst-case number. This is a terrible assump-
lished before the start of the period they reference. tion on both theoretical and empirical grounds.
Hypothetical backtests based on scrubbed data are suspect, VaR is a tool of risk management, not risk measure-
and tests with after-the-fact corrections to the VaR for data ment. For one thing, putting in a VaR system always leads
or processing errors are worthless. to tremendous improvements in information systems and
Why not go deeper into the tails? Because you won’t communication within a firm and always turns up some
have enough data for convincing validation. A 99% one- important surprises. You could throw away the final num-

20 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2


ber and still reap great benefit from the improvements gates 99% of the data to be handled by rote, so that risk
forced by the discipline of publishing a VaR number on managers can focus on the 1% that matters. My rule of
time every day and passing backtests. Just as anyone can be thumb for financial businesses is that no plausible scenario,
a great investor at a cocktail party, but not when you look either hypothetical or based on history, should result in a
at three-year Sharpe ratios, anyone can be a risk expert, loss more than 10 times 99% one-day VaR. If it does,
until you demand rigorous statistical evidence. You only either the business plan should be adjusted or that scenario
learn from models that sometimes surprise you. should be hedged or the VaR should be increased.
It also makes sense to use VaR on the trading desk and If foreseeable events can cause losses more than 10 times
in the executive suite. In 1988, a trader was less likely to the size of what you can assign accurate probability esti-
have a PhD in physics than to have been kicked out of ele- mates to, you have no idea if your business has a positive
mentary school for running a craps game in the principal’s expected value. You can’t manage what you can’t measure.
office after school. But anyone who could add up the spots People will be afraid to take risks up to the VaR point,
on two dice could understand that his losses exceeded because exceeding VaR can lead to uncontrollable losses.
your published VaR estimate three times in the last 300 Timidity will hurt profits, which means you have less
trading days. reserve to survive the surprises. Half of risk management is
Today, it’s a safe assumption that at least one member of persuading people to take more risk the 99% of the time
the executive committee of a big financial institution has it’s safe to do so, half is surviving the other 1%.
some derivative pricing experience — but even the former Of course, when the surprises occur, they will not be the
treasury salespeople and investment bankers could under- plausible scenarios you envisioned. They might be much
stand a graph with a line showing VaR over the last year, worse. But the discipline of preparing for what you can
points showing the daily P&L, with 1% of the points foresee greatly improves your chances of dealing success-
below the line. VaR was the first true communication fully with what actually happens.
between bank executives and traders.
VaR of the Jungle
VaR is like a fence built around a village in the jungle.
There are all kinds of dangers in the jungle: tigers,
Just as anyone can be a great snakes, poisonous plants, swamps, unfriendly humans
investor at a cocktail party, but and other things you don’t know about. The fence is
built in a relatively safe place, and remaining dangers
not when you look at three-year inside the fence are cleared out. We collect lots of statisti-
cal data about dangers in the village; we notice problems
Sharpe ratios, anyone can be a quickly and fix them.
But people spend 1% of their time outside the fence,
risk expert, until you demand rig- where dangers are both greater and less well-known. If
orous statistical evidence.You only people disappear in the jungle, we don’t know if they were
eaten by a tiger or stuck in a swamp or if they just decided
learn from models that some- to find a new home. So we don’t have the kind of data we
need either to evaluate or to fix problems.
times surprise you. The first decision of risk management is where to build
the fence. Inside, we have a well-defined population and
lots of observations, so we can monitor risk with statistics
VaR defines a perimeter. Inside the VaR limit, we have and adjust it through rules. Outside, we have to rely on
plenty of data to optimize decisions. Outside the VaR limit, anecdotes and imagination, knowing both have many
we cannot rely on data. Instead, we use other things to errors. We equip people leaving the village with defenses
judge risk. We look at longer-term history and other mar- against known dangers and general-purpose survival gear.
kets to guess what might happen, knowing the compar- And we wish them good luck.
isons are not exact. We think about plausible extreme sce- It would be foolish to use any extrapolation of statistics
narios, and we concentrate on the things VaR ignores. collected inside the fence to predict things outside it.
What if, for example, markets are not normal? What if Statistics collected outside are noisy and sparse and are
trading exacerbates losses? What if the losses occur over a fatally flawed by survivorship bias (the dangers we hear
shorter or longer period than the VaR horizon? What if about are the ones that people survived). In my friend
P&L does not measure the real risk? The VaR point rele- Nassim Taleb’s (another VaR-hater) terms, inside the fence

GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS 21


C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

is Mediocristan, outside is Extremistan. Tools that work in capital equal to worst-case loss. Capital does not protect
one place are useless in the other. against all risks.
I’m not talking about the VaR you find in the “risk man- The classic example is more cash in the vault doesn’t pro-
agement” section of “management’s discussion and analy- tect against the danger of the vault being robbed. Physical
sis” of the financial statements. That considers only the robbery is not a significant risk for modern financial insti-
market risk of the firm’s trading and portfolio positions tutions, but there are other scenarios in which the more
and usually has an unimpressive backtest. Instead, I mean capital you have, the more capital can be taken away. What
the VaR concept applied to all firm risks: define the risk if the Justice Department goes after top managers, as hap-
precisely enough to specify an observable measure, calcu- pened to Drexel? What if the US government defaults on
late and backtest the measure, then use scenario and stress treasuries, as almost happened in 1995? What if Bear
testing to ensure foreseeable risks are within an order of Stearns had collapsed and frozen all financial institution
magnitude of the observable risk. transfers for a week?
Other risks can be measured in dollars, but plausibly can
scale larger than any reasonable level of capital. If a rogue
trader can cost Societe Generale $7 billion, why can’t the
I’ve argued that capital should be next one cost five or 10 times as much? The 9/11 terrorist
attack caused the stock market to close for a week during
risk-sensitive and that VaR is the which stocks fell 5%, and what financial institution can
hold enough capital to guard against markets being closed
appropriate first step to measure for a month while prices move 25% or 50%?
The simplest view of capital is to consider what happens
risk. Given the VaR, how much cap- if a firm gets into trouble and decides to liquidate. If it can
ital should a bank hold? No multi- sell its assets to repay its liabilities, it can have an orderly
liquidation, with all claimants paid in full. Therefore, capi-
ple of VaR is a safe worst-case loss tal is the excess in value of assets over liabilities, and the
capital requirement should be set such that there is very
estimate. But it’s silly to set capital low probability of a firm going from well capitalized to
equal to worst-case loss. Capital insolvent (negative capital) before a regulator can force liq-
uidation.
does not protect against all risks. Of course, this does not mean that the preferred reaction
to losses is liquidation. If you can liquidate and repay
everyone — that is, if you have positive equity value —
then you have other options, such as raising new capital or
Regulators were wise, not foolish, to allow firms to use selling yourself. If your assets are worth less than your lia-
internal models to estimate risk. The quality of the risk pre- bilities, you are no longer in control of your bank, and
dictions can be judged without looking at the internal some third parties are going to take losses.
workings (the regulators check under the hood as well). No This seems to be what David Einhorn is thinking of with
set of rules could possibly cover the complexities of a mod- his prudent reform proposal. Consistent with the liquida-
ern diversified financial institution, and if they could, they tion view, he wants to count only tangible equity as capital.
would be out of date before they were implemented. That assumes intangible assets are worthless in a liquida-
The regulators offer simpler fixed alternatives for risk- tion: 100% capital for illiquid assets assumes they cannot
challenged institutions, but the top financial institutions all be sold in a liquidation; 50% assumes a steep discount.
invested in Basel II “advanced” approaches. Basel II does An 8% to 12% write-down — about $30 billion to $45
not only require risk estimation for capital adequacy: mod- billion for Lehman — seems to be in the ballpark for the equi-
els and results are reviewed by supervisors and exposed to ty a prime broker would demand to finance the portfolio of
market participants. Lehman’s marketable assets. The collateralized lending assets
are considerably safer: 2% (or about $6 billion) for Lehman
How Much is Enough? seems like a conservative but not absurd potential loss figure.
I’ve argued that capital should be risk-sensitive and that If Lehman meets this standard one month, a regulator can
VaR is the appropriate first step to measure risk. Given the have an appropriate level of confidence that the next month’s
VaR, how much capital should a bank hold? No multiple report will show enough equity cushion for an orderly liqui-
of VaR is a safe worst-case loss estimate. But it’s silly to set dation with full payout to creditors.

22 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2


C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

existing shareholders, will rapidly destroy any market


Dynamic Hedging appetite for the stock (nevertheless, people really did try to
A more common view of capital, and a more realistic one exploit the unlimited equity effect, through securities popu-
in my opinion, assumes a going concern and dynamic capi- larly known as “toxic” or “exploding” convertibles).
tal management. The question isn’t what can happen Still, a company that recognizes problems early, main-
before the regulators force a liquidation, but whether man- tains a solid balance sheet and has credibility with investors
agement can raise enough new capital to stay in business. I should be able to raise the equity it needs to continue in
understand why a stockholder, like David Einhorn, would business, even if tangible assets are worth less than liabili-
be suspicious of such a view. Raising capital might take ties. The equity still has going concern and option value in
advantage of the new investors if, as he writes, regulators this situation, and that should be enough to save it.
“turn a blind eye toward efforts to raise new capital before
recognizing large losses.” If this fools investors into over- Loaded for Bear
paying for the new stock, it’s good for the solvency of the
firm and the interests of old shareholders, but bad for the
new shareholders and the market in general.
Now the relevant measure of capital is market capital-
Clearly, the problem wasn’t that
ization, not book-tangible equity. In a highly theoretical Bear was undercapitalized going
analysis, a company should be able to raise new equity cap-
ital up to the existing amount of equity divided by the into the crisis; it’s that Bear manage-
probability of bankruptcy. Let E be the market capitaliza-
tion before selling new equity and p be the probability of
ment chose not to raise significant
bankruptcy. To a first approximation, raising X additional
dollars of equity adds pX to the wealth of creditors (it’s
equity capital long after the prob-
actually less than this, because the equity infusion will lem was obvious to the public.

Consider Bear Stearns, for example. By mid-March 2007,


A company that recognizes prob- HSBC had announced a $10.5 billion write-off from sub-
prime, New Century Financial stock had been suspended
lems early, maintains a solid bal- for bankruptcy concerns and Donald Tomnitz, CEO of the
ance sheet and has credibility with largest US homebuilder, got headlines warning of “huge
subprime losses.” Bear Stearns stock traded at over $150
investors should be able to raise per share ($36 billion market capitalization) for more than
three months after that. The stock took a hit in June 2007,
the equity it needs to continue in when Bear announced bailouts of two of its hedge funds,
but the price was still over $125 per share ($30 billion mar-
business, even if tangible assets are ket cap). Three weeks before Bear failed, the price was
worth less than liabilities. almost $90 per share ($20 billion market cap).
Clearly, the problem wasn’t that Bear was undercapital-
ized going into the crisis; it’s that Bear management chose
not to raise significant equity capital long after the problem
reduce the probability of bankruptcy). Therefore, it adds was obvious to the public. This is not 20/20 hindsight: I
(1-p)X to the equity value of the firm, which becomes E + wrote in October 2007 (not referencing Bear in particular)
(1-p)X. As long as this is greater than X, which is equiva- that banks hit by the crisis were talking about “raising
lent to X < E/p, the company can dilute existing sharehold- enough capital to keep their credit ratings, not the amounts
ers enough to raise X. Better yet, the company can do it needed to reassure their customers.” Of course, many other
again and again, to raise infinite equity capital starting people made similar points.
from any positive market capitalization. This is not intended to be a criticism of the management
Of course, real equity investors do not behave as this theo- of Bear Stearns or any other firm. Perhaps their actions
retical analysis suggests. If there is any suspicion of trouble at were the best for their shareholders — or at least the best
a firm, asking for new equity will depress the stock price — given the information available at the time. Nor is it a criti-
and the repeated need for equity infusions, each one injuring cism of regulators who had to work within their mandates.

24 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2


But the outcome was clearly suboptimal, except possibly ket didn’t suddenly change its mind about the value of Bear
for JPMorgan shareholders. in an orderly liquidation; it lost confidence that Bear had
The lesson learned should not be to make financial insti- the immediate cash on hand to pay day-to-day bills, which
tutions hold more capital in general. A big stack of cash is a self-fulfilling fear. That’s not a capital problem, nor is it
held for disasters is going to be used up; a bigger stack a traditional concern of broker-dealer regulation.
might last longer, but the outcome is the same, only more If a broker-dealer fails but all customers get their cash
expensive. Too much capital insulates the firm from market and securities back in a reasonable amount of time, it used
discipline and leads to waste and sloppiness. It kills return- to be considered a success. You can argue that regulators
on-equity, making investors unwilling to provide additional should have realized months earlier that Bear could not be
capital when the need arises. allowed to fail and forced the firm to raise additional equi-
In poker terms, Wall Street is a tournament with infinite ty capital at that time (assuming that fell within their regu-
rebuys. A good player will survive, even with a short stack, latory authority) — and that such a move, in turn, might
because he or she can always find backers and rebuy. A have sustained market confidence in Bear’s liquidity. But
player with too large a stack will never learn to play, keeps it’s excessive to push the blame back to 2004.
too much at risk on the table and won’t have backers. He I offer my personal opinion that the SEC did not make
or she can only win with an unbroken run of luck. “concession after concession to the large broker-dealers.” I
The proper risk management lesson is to address prob- was there. There was only one SEC and five broker-dealers.
lems early and aggressively, so that they never grow to We cooperated in the effort, so I had a good picture of the
firm-threatening size and block your ability to raise addi- entire process. There was extensive consultation and
tional capital. It’s painful to sell new shares on price review on both sides. In almost all cases, issues were
declines, and you’ll take heat from analysts and existing resolved the right way, sometimes after years of discussion.
shareholders (or, if you manage to hide the bad news until In a few cases, the SEC insisted on unreasonably strict
after the offering, heat from new shareholders). Most of rule; in a few cases, the industry might have gotten away
the time, the precaution will be unnecessary, and you’ll end
up buying back the shares at a higher price. This may or
may not maximize shareholder wealth; I don’t know.
A shareholder with a diversified portfolio might prefer Bear always held more than the
banks to risk failure. But if regulators feel compelled to bail
out losers, they should make firms pay equity-market insur-
regulatory minimum net capital,
ance premiums through creating synthetic puts on their shares. with ratios comfortably over the
Regulatory Defense “well-capitalized” threshold of 10%.
It is not fair to label the SEC’s Basel Capital rule, “Bear
Stearns Future Insolvency Act of 2004.” It’s true that Bear’s
You can argue the regulatory mini-
leverage ratio increased during the period of Consolidated mums are too low or the definition
Supervisory Entity regulation from 27 to 33, but it’s unlike-
ly this was due to reduced capital standards. of capital too lenient, but not that
Bear always held more than the regulatory minimum
net capital, with ratios comfortably over the “well-capital-
Bear took advantage of the low-
ized” threshold of 10%. You can argue the regulatory min-
imums are too low or the definition of capital too lenient,
ered levels and failed as a result.
but not that Bear took advantage of the lowered levels and
failed as a result.
In any event, the amounts were too small to matter for with cutting a corner. But in none of those cases was it a
the events that overtook Bear. With $20 billion of liquidity result of begging or pressure by the broker-dealers. Weak
disappearing in three days, a billion or two extra capital rules were oversights, not concessions. Anyone who con-
would not have helped directly (it might have helped indi- ceives of the size and complexity of the project will not cast
rectly by preventing the run on the bank). stones over a few oversights, all of which can be corrected
Bear was brought down by a crisis in market confidence, with ongoing revision.
not lax regulation. Excessive leverage certainly contributed It’s absolutely true that “dealers could better measure and
to the loss of confidence, but Bear’s leverage was much less monitor their own risks with fancy math” than with old-
than the maximum allowed under the old rules. The mar- style, fixed-percentage-of-notional capital rules. Financial

GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS 25


C O V E R S T O RY : P O I N T / C O U N T E R P O I N T

risk requires fancy math. Math, plain or fancy, is no guaran-


tee against error, but at least you have a chance of getting the
A Quick Rebuttal from David Einhorn right answer. And it’s mostly true that “these were all large,
well-capitalized institutions, with smart, sophisticated risk-
Aaron Brown and I actually agree more than one might
managers who had no incentive to try to fail.” The only
think. He writes, "The VaR point relegates 99% of the
arguable point is “well-capitalized,” and the SEC did not
data to be handled by rote, so risk managers can focus
start by assuming that these institutions had enough capital.
on the 1% that matters." I couldn't agree more. To me,
the normal 99% is portfolio management. Risk manage-
ment is all about the tails, and probably begins about Back to the Start
where VaR ends. Risk management is the airbag that Finally, I end up at David Einhorn’s starting point: leverage
must always work, but only in the multi-sigma event ratios. Comparing Lehman’s leverage ratio to Carlyle Capital
where you have an accident — an event that happens is a great rhetorical point, but it needs some adjustment.
much less often than once in every hundred driving days. Carlyle Capital borrowed on margin, meaning any decline in
Aaron and I have sharply different opinions about the its asset value triggered immediate cash demands from
tolerance for blowups. He equates blowups to needing lenders. I don’t know the margin terms it negotiated, but they
to "rebuy" in a poker tournament. This suggests a will- may have allowed loans to be called or terms changed with
ingness to put capital to such risk — i.e., that it’s an very short notice. Lehman’s borrowings include long-term
acceptable fact of life that, from time to time, investors bonds and loans with more stability than demand financing.
get wiped out or require a bailout. It’s prudent to run a higher leverage ratio if you have time to
This thinking favors the interests of those who benefit address problems and wait out unfavorable markets.
asymmetrically from a high risk tolerance: investment Lehman also has access to more capital sources than
bank employees being paid 50% of revenue or hedge Carlyle Capital. It has more ability to sell stock in public
fund managers earning 20% incentive fees. The victim markets and to arrange private financing. It has strong
is the shareholder who suffers most of the loss when
franchise and going concern values that can be monetized
those inevitable tail events happen. Over the long haul,
through sale or other transactions. It has thousands of peo-
winning investors will be those that preserve most of
ple working to sell its assets, so things illiquid to Carlyle
their capital on the downside and never have to suffer
the permanent dilution and loss from a "re-buy" event. might be liquid for Lehman.
Of course, having "too much" capital, as Aaron Depending on the time of year, Lehman will have up to
writes, might diminish returns on equity to shareholders about $5 billion on its balance sheet accrued for employee
of the big financial institutions. There are three possible bonuses. Its more diversified portfolio is unlikely to suffer
ways to fix that: first, if everyone de-levers to safer lev- losses in all segments at once and is likely to have at least
els, spreads will widen and the cost will be shifted to some liquid securities.
borrowers. Second, institutions can move their business Despite those caveats, it is a sobering thought that a pub-
mix toward non-capital, non-risk taking, fee-based rev- lic fund (hence one that did not have to worry about investor
enue streams. Thirdly, and perhaps unthinkably, the redemptions) holding only AAA vanilla US government
share of revenues allocated for employee compensation agency mortgage-backed securities couldn’t survive at a
could be reduced. leverage ratio significantly lower than the investment banks,
In a paradigm of private profits and private risks, it is which hold much more volatile, complex and illqiuid assets.
acceptable — though maybe not wise — for investors to I have to agree that leverage is too high, especially during a
enter into asymmetric arrangements. However, now credit crunch with unheard-of levels of credit spread.
that we have entered the era of private profits and As a risk manager, I would like to see firms managing
socialized risks, the public has an interest in making sure risk by raising equity capital when risks increase. I would
that the "too big to fail" financial institutions don't do
like to see investors enforcing discipline on the companies
just that.
they own instead of demanding bail-outs. If firms won’t
The taxpayer gets no benefit from the upside of the
raise capital and investors won’t accept pain, then regula-
speculation. As a result, it is in the public interest to insist
tors have no choice but to force leverage down. If every
on capital standards that fully consider the entire range
of outcomes and that don't cut-off the tails. thirsty person demands Coke from the government, the
only sensible solution is to make sure there’s enough water

✎ AARON BROWN is a risk manager at AQR Capital Management and the author of The Poker Face of Wall Street (John Wiley & Sons,
2006). He is also serves on the GRR editorial board and is the former executive director and head of credit risk architecture at Morgan Stanley.
He can be reached at Aaron.Brown@aqr.com.This article expresses the personal opinions of the author, which are not necessarily shared by
his employer or any other entity.

26 GLOBAL ASSOCIATION OF RISK PROFESSIONALS J U N E / J U LY 0 8 I S S U E 4 2

Вам также может понравиться