Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 5

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) represents an important breakthrough in finance theory.

It was developed independently by Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), Treynor and Black, and built
on preparatory portfolio work by Markowitz (1952) and Tobin.

It is a straightforward, yet elegant model that relates an asset’s expected return to its risk. The
CAPM is one of the key concepts in modern finance and thoroughly researched by academics. It
is widely used by financial managers and analysts to establish required rates of return and the cost
of capital for different types of investments and finance decisions.

The CAPM draws on a particular classification of risk: (i) systematic (or market) risk, which is the
tendency of a stock to move together with the general stock market, and (ii) non-systematic risk,
which reflects firm-unique factors. The former type is also called “non-diversifiable risk,” the latter
“diversifiable risk.” By holding a large number of stocks and other assets, investors can eliminate
firm-specific risk factors. Because of asset diversification, the standard deviation of a portfolio is
often less than the standard deviation of the individual assets in the portfolio. Although
diversification can eliminate firm-specific risk, it cannot eliminate overall market risk. For an
efficiently designed and diversified portfolio the only relevant risk that remains is systematic risk.
Hence, CAPM’s core idea is that investors can expect a reward for a particular investment’s
contribution to the risk of a portfolio with higher rewards (returns) for investments that have a
larger element of non-diversifiable risk. However, no reward can be expected for exposure to risks
that can be easily diversified away.

The capital asset pricing model is based on simplifying assumptions, of which can be
expressed as follows: The first assumption is that Invest or purpose is the maximizing of
expected utility from final wealth. Second, all investors have homogeneous expects about the
risk/reward trade-offs in the market. The third assumption is that Information simultaneously and
freely available to all investors and investors can’t be affected stock prices by buying and selling
stock. The fourth assumption is that Taxes, transaction costs, there is no limit to short sell
or other market constraints. Investors are considered to maintain diversified portfolios, as
the market does not reward investors for bearing diversifiable risk. Consequently, the CAPM
implies that if a security’s beta is known, it may to calculate the parallel expected return. The
relationship is known as the Security Market Line (SML) equation and the measure of systematic
risk in the CAPM is called Beta.
The formula for CAMP is
E (Ri) = Rf +βj (E(Rm) - Rf
But CAPM can be modified to include size premium and specific risk. This is important for
investors in privately held companies who often do not hold a well-diversified portfolio. The
equation is similar to the traditional CAPM equation “with the market risk premium replaced by
the product of beta times the market risk premium:”

E (Ri) = Rf + (RPm) +RPs+ RPu

“where:
E(Ri) is required return on security i
Rf is risk-free rate
RPm is general market risk premium
RPs is risk premium for small size
RPu is risk premium due to company-specific risk factor

In the CAPM, the key variable is the beta coefficient, which measures the degree of market risk.
It reflects the change in an asset’s return in response to a change in the overall market return. It is
thus a (relative) measure of volatility. The beta for an individual asset is estimated on the basis of
historical data, using regression analysis of the returns of the asset in a particular period against
the returns of a suitable market return. For future applications, therefore, the beta and the required
return should only be regarded as estimations.
In the freely competitive financial markets described by CAPM, no security can sell for long at
prices low enough to yield more than its appropriate return on the SML. The security would then
be very attractive compared with other securities of similar risk, and investors would bid its price
up until its expected return fell to the appropriate position on the SML. Conversely, investors
would sell off any stock selling at a price high enough to put its expected return below its
appropriate position. The resulting reduction in price would continue until the stock’s expected
return rose to the level justified by its systematic risk.
(An arbitrage pricing adjustment mechanism alone may be sufficient to justify the SML
relationship with less restrictive assumptions than the traditional CAPM. The SML, therefore, can
be derived from other models than CAPM.2)

One perhaps counterintuitive aspect of CAPM involves a stock exhibiting great total risk but very
little systematic risk. An example might be a company in the very chancy business of exploring
for precious metals. Viewed in isolation the company would appear very risky, but most of its total
risk is unsystematic and can be diversified away. The well-diversified CAPM investor would view
the stock as a low-risk security. In the SML the stock’s low beta would lead to a low risk premium.
Despite the stock’s high level of total risk, the market would price it to yield a low expected return.

In conclusion, The CAPM’s key outcome – a required return – represents thus a market-based
opportunity “cost” that reflects risk similar to the asset under scrutiny. Well-known alternative
financial models to estimate this return include the Gordon Constant-Growth Model ,which
focuses on a firm’s dividends; the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (Ross, 1976), which uses multiple
economic factors instead of the market portfolio; to explain expected returns.
REFERENCES

1. ADLER M. and B. DUMAS (1983), “International Portfolio Selection and Corporation


Finance: A Synthesis”, Journal of Finance, n° 38, pp. 925-84.
2. ADLER M. and QI R. (2003), “Mexico’s Integration into the North American Capital
Market”, Emerging Economic Review, 4, pp. 91-120.
3. Arouri , M. E.-H. and Nguyen, D. K. . (2010). Time-Varying Characteristics of Cross-
Market Linkages with Emperical Application to Gulf Stock Markets. Managerial Finance,
36(1), 57-70.
1. Arouri, M. Nguyen, D.K. and K. Pukthuanthong (2012) “An international CAPM for
partially integrated markets: Theory and empirical evidence” Journal of Banking and
Finance, 36, 2473-2493.
2. BAILEY W. and JAGTIANI J. (1994), "Foreign ownership restrictions and stock prices in
the Thai capital market", Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 36(1), pp. 57-87.
3. BASAK S. (1995), “A general equilibrium model of portfolio insurance”, Review of
Financial Studies, 8, pp. 1059–1099.
4. Basak, S., Chabakauri, G., 2010. Dynamic Mean-Variance Asset Allocation. Review of
Financial Studies 23, 2970-3016.
5. BEKAERT G. and C. HARVEY (1995), “Time Varying World Market Integration”,
Journal of Finance, 50(2), pp. 403-44.
6. BEKAERT G. and HARVEY C. (2003),” Emerging Markets Finance”, Journal of
Empirical Finance, 10, pp. 3-55.
7. BEKAERT G., HARVEY C. and LUMSDAINE R. (2002), “ The Dynamics of Emerging
Market equity Flows”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 21 :3, pp. 295-350.
8. Bell D. (1995), “Risk, return and utility”, Management Science, 41(1), pp. 23-30.
9. BHATTACHARYA U. and DAOUK H. (2002),“The World Price of Insider Trading”,
Journal of Finance, 57, pp. 75-108.
10. BLACK F. (1974), “International Capital Market Equilibrium with Investment Barriers”,
Journal of Financial Economics, 1, pp. 337-352.
11. BROUNENE D., DE JONG A. and K. KOEDIJK (2004), “Corporate finance in Europe:
Confronting theory with practice”, Financial Management, 33(4), pp. 74-101.
12. CARRIERI F, ERRUNZA V. and HOGAN K. (2007), “Characterizing World Market
Integration through Time”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42(4), pp. 915-
940.
13. Charles A. (2010), “The Day-of –the-week Effects on the Volatility: The Role of the
Asymmetry”, European Journal of Operational Research, 202, pp. 143-152.
14. Chortareas, G., Kapetanios, G., 2009. Getting PPP right: Identifying mean-reverting real
exchange rates in panels. Journal of Banking & Finance 33, 390-404.
15. CLARK, E.; JOKUNG, O.; Kassimatis, K. (2011), “Making inefficient market indices
efficient”, European Journal of Operational Research, 209(1), pp. 83-93.
16. COOPER I. and KAPLANIS E. (2000), “Partially Segmented International Capital Market
Integration Budgeting”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 43, pp. 287-307.
17. Cumming, D., Johan, S., Li, D., 2011. Exchange trading rules and stock market liquidity.
Journal of Financial Economics 99, 651-671.
18. DE SANTIS G. and GERARD B. (1997), “International Asset Pricing and Portfolio
Diversification with Time-Varying Risk”, Journal of Finance 52, pp. 1881-1912.
19. DRAGOTA, V. and MITRIC, E. (2004), “Emergent capital markets` efficiency: The case
of Romania”, European Journal of Operational Research, 155, pp. 353–360.
20. DURNEV A., MORCK R. and YEUNG B. (2004), “Value Enhancing Capital Budgeting
and Firm-Specific Stock Returns Variation,” Journal of Finance, 59(1), pp. 65-105.

Вам также может понравиться