Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 28

Article

Progress in Human Geography


2014, Vol. 38(2) 221–247
‘Socialism with Chinese ª The Author(s) 2013
Reprints and permission:

characteristics’: Uneven sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav


DOI: 10.1177/0309132513476822
phg.sagepub.com
development, variegated
neoliberalization and the dialectical
differentiation of state spatiality

Kean Fan Lim


University of British Columbia, Canada

Abstract
While ‘neoliberalization’ is increasingly used to conceptualize concrete realities of China’s economic
development, it is not employed in dialectical relation with China’s prevailing developmental ideology –
‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’. This paper offers a fresh framework and research agenda from which
to examine this relation. It argues that neoliberalization across China is a variegated process, formed and
fractured by actually existing uneven state spatiality and the Communist Party of China’s (CPC) ostensibly
contradictory historicization of a Marxian socialist end-state. How neoliberalization works simultaneously in/
through multiple sites in China and consequently reproduces the CPC’s ideological legitimacy has become a
theoretically significant question for research on geographical political economy.

Keywords
cross-scalar sociospatial dialectic, geographical political economy, ideology, ‘nationally strategic new areas’,
socialism with Chinese characteristics, uneven development, variegated neoliberalization

We must integrate the universal truth of Marxism G20 counterparts that their respective govern-
with the concrete realities of China, blaze a path ments adopt current account deficit or surplus
of our own and build a socialism with Chinese targets of less than 4% of GDP. This proposal
characteristics – that is the basic conclusion we drew an intriguing response from China’s Vice-
have reached after reviewing our long history.
Foreign Minister Cui Tiankai: ‘The artificial set-
(Deng, 1982: n.p.)
ting of a numerical target cannot but remind us of
[P]erhaps the most interesting aspect of neoliber- the days of a planned economy’ (Bloomberg,
alization arises out of the complex interplay of 2010). At one level, Cui was probably offering
internal dynamics and external forces. (Harvey, a witty counterpoint: indeed, it was China that
2005a: 177) had operated as – and some might argue it still

I Introduction Corresponding author:


Department of Geography, University of British Columbia,
In November 2010, the United States (US) Trea- 1984 West Mall, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z2, Canada.
sury Secretary Timothy Geithner proposed to his Email: keanflim@geog.ubc.ca
222 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

is – a centrally planned economy. On closer read- (p. 10). In China, however, the increasing influ-
ing, however, there might be a more profound ence of neoliberal logics within Chinese policy-
underlying meaning to Cui’s remarks that exem- making circles is entwined with – if not sub-
plifies a scalar differentiation within the Chinese sumed under – the national strategy to actualize
state apparatus’s politico-economic ideology: ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’. For this
freedom of financial and commodity flows across reason, the apparent willingness of Chinese
the global economy is strongly preferred, while policy-makers to embrace the logic of a self-
the notion of ‘a planned economy’ at this scale regulatory ‘free’ market at the global scale does
– led by a hegemonic US government that heavily not – or, indeed, cannot – translate into a whole-
influences the terms of market exchange – is sale adaptation of neoliberal logics at the national
deemed an undesirable barrier to capital accumu- scale. Taking the constitutive role of this ‘situ-
lation. This outlook strongly suggests China is ated phenomenon’ into account, this paper raises
not unlike what Harvey (2005a: 64) terms a ‘neo- an equally plausible proposition: geographically
liberal state’, within which ‘the freedom of busi- variegated neoliberalization, driven and cush-
nesses and corporations (legally regarded as ioned by the Chinese state, could function as the
individuals) to operate within [an] institutional precondition of/for a historicized totality known
framework of free markets and free trade is as ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’.
regarded as a fundamental good’. Juxtaposed The subsequent discussion aims to achieve
against this outlook, however, is the fact that the two interrelated objectives. First, it explains
Communist Party of China (CPC) continues to why ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’ is
weave socialist principles – in particular what not an absolute entity that can be neatly period-
Deng Xiaoping (1982) refers to as the ‘universal ized and packaged into a geographically uni-
truth of Marxism’1 – through its domestic socio- form ‘variety of capitalism’ (pace Hall and
economic policies. This apparent contradiction Soskice, 2001); neither does this ideological
raises a theoretically significant question that vision reflect, in spatial practice, received
remains unaddressed in politico-economic stud- notions of the ‘capitalist developmental state’.
ies of China: what is the function of neoliberaliza- Rather, China’s contemporary socialistic evolu-
tion in the CPC’s quest to secure ‘common tion is expressed through different sociospatial
affluence’ (gongtong fuyu) within/for a ‘harmo- forms, in tandem with variegated modes of neo-
nious society’ (hexie shehui)? liberal regulation. The inclusion of neoliberal
To address this question, it is necessary first to logics in politico-economic governance neces-
understand that neoliberalization in and through sitates a recurring series of territorialized rein-
Chinese state space does not occur in a post- stitutionalization (cf. Brenner et al., 2010).
ideological vacuum. Neoliberalization, as Zhang This proactive reorganization of state space is
and Ong (2008: 10) observe, has taken on the aimed at directing new capital investments into
appearance of ‘an inexorable process that renders poorer areas (particularly in the western inte-
all national spaces intelligible or commensurable rior) while sustaining, at the same time, the rates
in accord with predetermined universal norms’. of capital accumulation in more affluent coastal
This perception of inexorability in turn engen- city-regions. Through ameliorating the pro-
dered formalistic conceptualizations in the social nounced interprovincial income disparities,2 the
sciences that ‘assess whether particular nation- CPC’s primary policy intention is to obviate the
states are more or less ‘‘neoliberal’’ in terms of emergence of sociospatial crises that may desta-
a preconceived collection of attributes’, assess- bilize its control over the national political
ments that ‘tend to give short shrift to the role economy. Territorialized reinstitutionalizations
of situated phenomena in shaping outcomes’ thus do not simply function as economic tools
Lim 223

that deepen the application of market logics; principles in relation to highly varied domestic
they are social countermovements that pre- sociospatial contexts; the (neoliberal) institu-
empt revolutionary ruptures that could poten- tional guidelines of the ‘Washington Consensus’;
tially become, in Marxian terms, new ‘locomo- and the profit-maximizing strategies of TNCS –
tives’ that power historical evolution. now including many Chinese state-owned enter-
Second, the paper presents a fresh conceptual prises (SOEs) – that determines the ‘Chinese
framework and research agenda that examines characteristics’ of what Deng conceives as the
how the external pressures to reshape Chinese ‘universal truth of Marxism’.4
economic geographies paradoxically negate The paper will be organized in three parts. Sec-
and fortify the CPC’s similarly paradoxical tion II places the growing global-scale hegemony
approach to create ‘Chinese characteristics’ to of neoliberalism in relation to China’s post-1949
complement ‘the universal truth of Marxism’ politico-economic development. The sociospatial
(after all, if Marxian ‘truth’ is really ‘universal’, expressions that emerge from the dialectical
would it be necessary to place it in relation to fusion of socialistic policies with neoliberal logics
unique characteristics?). The proposed frame- in China will be presented in section III. Strategies
work and agenda explore how the selective dif- emergent at two scales over the past decade – the
ferentiation of state spatiality in relation to delineation of three cross-provincial regional
actually existing sociospatial inequality – an developmental programmes and six intra-urban
emergent process this paper identifies as ‘nationally strategic’ new areas – are fore-
‘decentralization as centralization’ (yidianweiz- grounded as theoretically significant research
hong) – works to legitimize the CPC’s grasp on platforms. The section explains how these strate-
politico-economic power. It does appear, gies are symptomatic of the sociospatial tensions
indeed, that the Marxian ‘locomotives’ that that arise from earlier rounds of selective neoliber-
power history in and through China are being alization. The importance of examining varie-
geo-institutionally reconfigured to power a gated neoliberalization as a sociospatial function
timeless engine – that engine is the CPC. of ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’ – and,
To foreground the theoretical significance of more crucially, as pre-emptory geo-institutional
this reconfiguration process, this paper argues leaps that consolidate the CPC’s state power – is
that China’s economic transformations must be re-emphasized in the conclusion.
conceptualized as a cross-scalar sociospatial
dialectic. This dialectic is defined and expressed
as the dynamic interplay of ostensibly opposi- II The (im)possibility of totalizing
tional processes, originating in and/or occurring neoliberalization
at different geographical scales, within a spa-
tially delimited social formation (e.g. the popula-
1 Neoliberalization as
tion living within a city-region). ‘Socialism with neo-developmentalism?
Chinese characteristics’, as will be argued, is a The global system of capitalism is constituted
geographic tension: the permeation of (puta- by a cyclical process of boom (resulting in over-
tively) non-socialist practices (e.g. increasing accumulation) and bust (resulting in massive
privatization of production, the growing role of devaluation). This tendency is intensified fol-
financialization, expanding industrialization and lowing the dollar’s de-link with gold in 1971,
the concomitant proleterianization of farmers, which precipitated a rapid and colossal increase
etc.) fuse dynamically with the quest for a class- in short-term global financial flows, mostly for
less and prosperous society across Chinese state speculative purposes rather than to fund trade
space.3 It is this threefold placement of socialistic and foreign direct investments (FDIs). The
224 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

quest for a reduction of geographical barriers to territory and as the driver of transnational finan-
financial flows and trade, in conjunction with cial flows through its independent ability to
what is now known as the new international implement monetary policy, remains a central
division of labour (Fröbel et al., 1980), contrib- generator and mediator of neoliberalizing strate-
uted to the contemporary hegemony of ‘neoli- gies. This point was obscured by the post-1989
beralism’, a political-economic governance euphoria in advanced capitalist economies, nota-
ideology that (1) entails individual states to bly by neoliberal proponents in the Anglophone
effect market-like rule to protect private prop- world. Writing just after the collapse of the Soviet
erty and ownership rights regardless of citizen- Union and the publication of Francis Fukuyama’s
ship, and (2) minimizes, if not eradicates, (1992) highly influential ‘end of history’ thesis,
‘price-distortions’ through the abolishment of Johnson (1993: 63) laments that ‘[t]he seeming
regulations that impede market access for pri- victory of the state-as-referee conception has
vate individuals. given American social science in particular an
The principal and most influential proponent ethnocentrism and an ideological quality that
of neoliberal reason is arguably the late Univer- seem to have erased all Western memory of
sity of Chicago economist Milton Friedman (see the state from Plato’s Republic to Hobbes’s
Crouch, 2011; Klein, 2007; Peck, 2010). Once Leviathan’. A keen believer in how economic
concretized as a developmental ideology, neoli- activities are inextricably entwined with the
beralism became an engine set off to shape eco- ‘guiding hand’ of the ‘plan rational’ state, John-
nomic policies. While the ideology was put into son (1982) is unconvinced that the putative ‘free
practice – with the participation of Friedman market’ could self-regulate for the common good.
and his allied economists known as the ‘Chi- Japan’s post-war economic development, to
cago Boys’ – with mixed success in South Johnson, was propelled by the industrial policies
America in the 1970s, it came to historical pro- of what is now widely known as the ‘capitalist
minence worldwide through the policies of developmental state’.
Margaret Thatcher (Prime Minister of the UK, While China’s developmental approach –
1979–1990) and those of Ronald Reagan (Pres- particularly the enlargement of domestic spaces
ident of the USA, 1981–1989). Friedman for market exchange after 1978 – appears simi-
advised both leaders. Interestingly, Deng lar to Johnson’s (1982) conceptual prototype,
Xiaoping, another of Thatcher’s contemporaries key differences are observed through two criti-
and then newly appointed leader of China, also cal geographical perspectives (pace Beeson,
received a crash course from Friedman in 1980, 2009; Xia, 2000). First, at the national level, the
but the Deng administration opted not to go presupposition of the ‘developmental state’ as
down the path of Latin American economies ‘capitalist’ overlooks a crucial function of the
by selling off state-owned assets and opening state apparatus – its capacity to rescale capital
up the entire national territory to the transna- allocation and the accumulation process to
tional flows of capital. For this reason, China’s ameliorate uneven economic-geographical
national-scale developmental trajectory is an development. The state apparatus and its socio-
apposite arena from which to theorize how neo- economic policies are assessed by developmen-
liberalism works as a flexible developmental tal state theorists at the national level without
ideology that generates geographically varie- ascertaining the redistributive intents and
gated impacts. effects of spatial strategies implemented at the
As is now clear, a national state apparatus, in subnational scales (cf. Brenner, 2004; section
its integrated position as the absolute sovereign III.2). National-level capital redistribution takes
power over social formations within state two forms in China: direct form, through the
Lim 225

reallocation of fiscal revenue by the central gov- demands of the neoliberally oriented ‘Washing-
ernment, and indirect form, through state spatial ton Consensus’.5 A focus on China’s state spatial
strategies that designate where SOEs’ capital strategies over the past decade, specifically how
investments and FDIs are (al)located. The sec- these strategies accommodate and/or reignite
ond redistributive form occurs because the pre- neoliberalizing impulses in relation to the global
determined socialist goal of ‘Common economy, would thereby offer a more incisive
Affluence’ impels the Chinese state to ensure platform from which to theorize the develop-
capital flows and fixity are as balanced as possi- mentalist orientation of the CPC.
ble across state space (more in section III). This approach begins with the presupposition
Second, the conceptualization of developmen- that state intervention drives and cushions the
tal statism is not extended dialectically to the global-scale neoliberalization process. If the mar-
global scale to show how they exist in tension with ket is self-regulatory anywhere, there should not
other states that advocate the construction of a be macroeconomic intervention at the intra- and
self-regulatory global ‘free’ market. It is not inad- interstate levels. As the aforementioned ‘Geithner
vertent that Japan’s economic development stag- Proposal’ indicates, neoliberalization is an impos-
nated after a currency appreciation agreement (the sibility without proactive state intervention. It is
Plaza Accord) was signed in September 1985. even plausible that states are inherently anti-
Similarly, the economy of South Korea – another market because they do not believe in self-
state commonly held to be an exemplary develop- regulating markets in the first place; what counts
mental state – spun into crisis in 1997–1998 after as ‘markets’ – and, indeed, as ‘free’ markets – to
its government believed transnational financial individual states is thus open to interpretation.
market liberalization would enhance the Peck (2010) sums up this dialectic incisively:
performance of domestic Korean firms. Over the
last decade, the relevance of the developmental Neoliberalism . . . has only ever existed in
‘impure’ form, indeed can only exist in messy
state concept vis-a-vis intensifying neoliberaliz-
hybrids. Its utopian vision of a free society and
ing processes is increasingly called into question
free economy is ultimately unattainable. Yet
(see, inter alia, Beeson and Islam, 2005; Glass- the pristine clarity of its ideological apparition,
man, 1999; Low, 2004). The rationale of this the free market, coupled with the endless
critical evaluation is clear: the ability of these frustrations borne of the inevitable failure to
economies’ ‘national champions’ (e.g. Toyota, arrive at this elusive destination, nevertheless
Samsung) to shift and/or stretch production net- confer a significant degree of forward momentum
works overseas – and hence the need for ‘free’ on the neoliberal project. Ironically, neoliberal-
market access to foreign product and labour ism possesses a progressive, forward-leaning
markets – has intensified global-scale neoliberali- dynamic by virtue of the very unattainability of
zation. While this phenomenon appears at first its idealized destination. (Peck, 2010: 7,
glance to be analogous to China’s recent ‘Go emphases in original)
Abroad’ (zouchuqu) developmental approach (to Put another way, then, neoliberalism as a
be elaborated in section III), the ideological basis totalizing ideology exemplifies what Žižek
is distinct in the Chinese context: China’s devel- (1989) calls a ‘social fantasy’; it is a represen-
opmentalist orientation, bound a priori within tational imaginary that is able to sustain its
Marxian temporal parameters and a single-party hegemonic existence because of its very onto-
political system (see section II.2), necessitates the logical impossibility:
proactive differentiation of state involvement in
economic activities at different scales (now [T]he stake of social-ideological fantasy is to con-
including the global scale) to accommodate the struct a vision of society which does exist, a
226 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

society which is not split by an antagonistic divi- (p. 19). Wade (2003) succinctly describes this
sion, a society in which the relation between its ‘twisting’ in his critical discursive analysis of
parts is organic, complementary . . . The notion the ‘Washington Consensus’:
of social fantasy is therefore a necessary counter-
part to the concept of antagonism: fantasy is pre- What [it] does not include are proactive industrial
cisely the way the antagonistic fissure is masked. policies to nurture new industries and new tech-
In other words, fantasy is a means for an ideology nologies and to diffuse innovations to established
to take its own failure into account in advance. industries – that might have the unwanted conse-
(Žižek, 1989: 142, emphases in original) quence of raising the competitive pressure on
industries in the industrialized countries. This is
It is arguably this ‘social fantasy’ of a free market definitely not on today’s development agenda.
utopia that masks an ‘antagonistic fissure’ – i.e. Indeed, words like ‘technology’, ‘national inno-
the primacy placed on the incessant exploitation vation system’, ‘entrepreneurship’, ‘competi-
of uneven economic-geographical development tiveness’, and ‘universities’ are conspicuously
(hereafter uneven development) under the rubric missing from the thinking of development organi-
of state-endorsed market ‘laws’ rather than more zations like the World Bank and the bilateral
benign and holistic socioeconomic development donors. So too are words like ‘distribution of
(cf. Harvey, 2005b; Polanyi, 1944; Smith, 1984). power’, ‘elite capture’, ‘trade unions’, and even
Indeed, neoliberalization is co-constituted in ‘freedom of association’. The poor are to be lifted
practice by what Marx calls ‘primitive accumula- up by supplying them with missing assets and by
gaining the knowledge with which to manage
tion’, a systematic process by which elites
them better, not through their own engagement
(politicians and capitalists) consolidate their in collective action. Thus lifted up, they will be
power through expropriating assets from the as good-natured as the sheep they tend. (Wade,
people (notably farmland and free access to 2003: xliv)
natural resources), in turn compelling the masses
to commodify their labour power (triggering What Wade (2003) does not address in his oth-
the ‘proletarianization’ process, in Marxian erwise incisive critique is the conspicuous
determination). absence of different ideological terminologies
The more successful the primitive accumula- (and the consequent policies that emerged due
tion process, the broader the pool of ‘industrial to different ideological moorings) such as
reserve army’. This outcome, which suppresses ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’. This
wages and deepens uneven development, leads absence in itself reflects what Gibson-Graham
Harvey (2005a: 19) to interpret neoliberaliza- (1996) call ‘capitalocentrism’, a situation in
tion ‘as a utopian project to realize a theoretical which:
design for the reorganization of international
capitalism or as a political project to re- other forms of economy (not to mention noneco-
establish the conditions for capital accumula- nomic aspects of social life) are often understood
tion and to restore the power of economic primarily with reference to capitalism: as being
fundamentally the same as (or modeled upon)
elites’. The notion of utopianism, Harvey adds,
capitalism, or as being deficient or substandard
‘primarily worked as a system of justification
imitations; as being opposite to capitalism; as
and legitimation for whatever needed to be done being the complement of capitalism; as existing
to achieve this goal. The evidence suggests, in capitalism’s space or orbit. (Gibson-Graham,
moreover, that when neoliberal principles clash 1996: 6)
with the need to restore or sustain elite power,
then the principles are either abandoned or Indeed, there seems to be an implicit conces-
become so twisted as to be unrecognizable’ sion in Wade’s comment that these develop
Lim 227

mental discourses have come to represent the realize, in Marxian determination, a proletar
eternal-cum-ecumenical new normal; that ‘uto- ian-led socialist mode of production across the
pianism’ is now strictly defined by neoliberal country thereafter. This led to a second contra-
parameters. Perhaps, in the heady days of the diction: a socialist epoch first emerged before
early 1990s, neoliberal policy-makers in it had the opportunity to develop its existential
Washington forgot about their Beijing counter- preconditions (through the capitalist mode of
parts’ resolute resolve to contextualize the ‘uni- production). Following an extensive review of
versal truth of Marxism’ across (and possibly historical resources, Li (2006: 64–65) explains
beyond) Chinese state space. how Joseph Stalin, the former leader of the
Soviet Union and a fervent advocate of policy
radicalism in the 1920s and 1930s, advised Chi-
2 China after 1949: (already) living in nese policy-makers in 1948 to keep the eco-
different times nomic status quo of China unchanged should
The CPC’s attempt to resolve developmental they emerge victorious in the civil war with the
contradictions in the contemporary conjuncture Nationalists. Gradualism, rather than radical-
foregrounds – and is arguably undergirded by – ism, was the recommended developmental
a unique interpretation of a major tenet of Marx- approach to socialist transformation. It was
ian historical materialism, namely, how ‘modes arguably because of Stalin’s advice – which
of production’ succeed one another chronologi- took into account the economic-geographical
cally through social revolution. The ultimate foundations that the CPC inherited – that
socioeconomic end-state of Marxian historical Mao (1949) initially decided to engage capital-
evolution is an upper-stage ‘socialist mode of ists in his quest to build a socialist mode of
production’ – communism – ruled directly by the production:
proletariat, with the state functioning in a faded
capacity. Much has been written on this classic China’s private capitalist industry, which occu-
prediction over the last century, and the aim of pies second place in her modern industry, is a
force which must not be ignored. Because they
this paper is not to review this extensive litera-
have been oppressed or hemmed in by imperial-
ture. Rather, this paper explores a dialectical
ism, feudalism and bureaucrat-capitalism, the
phenomenon not fully addressed by received national bourgeoisie of China and its representa-
historical-materialist conceptualizations of tives have often taken part in the people’s demo-
China: it is Chinese policy-makers’ simultaneous cratic revolutionary struggles or maintained a
affirmation and negation of Marxian historical neutral stand. For this reason and because China’s
materialism that drives the reinstitutionalization economy is still backward, there will be need, for
of state space in China. a fairly long period after the victory of the revolu-
This spatial dialectic evolved in three ways. tion, to make use of the positive qualities of urban
First, former CPC Chairman Mao Zedong’s and rural private capitalism as far as possible, in
attempt to introduce ‘socialism’ to a newly uni- the interest of developing the national economy.
fied China (which essentially was a territorial (Mao, 1949: n.p.)
patchwork of diverse economies) in itself con- That gradualism was soon abandoned. This
tradicted Marx’s formulation: it was the weak third contradiction was induced by the CPC’s
(rather than strong, as Marx determined) and aforementioned a priori historicization of ‘new
geographically uneven existence of the capital- China’ as socialist. Rather than dismiss this act
ist mode of production that provided both the as an ideological tool to disguise reality, this
conditions for the successful CPC-led revolu- paper argues that a priori historicization
tion prior to 1949 and the obstacles to fully becomes precisely the central driver of Chinese
228 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

economic-geographical development to the vision of China, and more so than conventional


present day. To reapply Žižek’s (1989: 142; wisdom would have us believe. There was no
cf. section II.1) conceptualization, the goal of place in Mao’s vision of a socialist economy for
ideology is not to conceal a reality that is ‘less market forces or a private economy (Li, 2006:
illusory’ or ‘more real’; rather – in a manner 186–187).
akin to the ‘end of history’ undertones of the The rolling series of contradictions generated
neoliberal doctrine that automatically view by the socialistic historicization of China from
non-compliant entities as ‘anomalies’6 – it con- 1949 thus exemplifies the paradoxical interpre-
structs the ‘social fantasy’ that is the social real- tation of Marxian historical materialism by Chi-
ity, and the primary ideological concern is how nese policy-makers. On one hand, the temporal
to address the ‘antagonistic fissure’ that threa- logic of historical evolution is indeed what
tens this new reality. Deng made it to be – a ‘universal truth’. It was,
For this reason, the declaration of a socialist as aforementioned, through a decisive round of
epoch in China became at once a social totality revolution in 1949 that Mao launched a socialist
and a spatial process. The political act of epoch in/for China, following which he fortified
Marxian temporal framing produced its own the ‘superstructure’8 (i.e. new social institutions
socioeconomic necessity and geographical con- and ideas) to cement state-society relations.
tingency: to be in and of a socialist epoch, it Addressing the geographical contingency asso-
would be necessary to launch socioeconomic ciated with socialistic historicization, on the
policies that were aligned to Marxist-Leninist other hand, would prove to be a greater chal-
principles, but this alignment was (and still is) lenge. Under the Mao administration, the neces-
a contingent process – its success depended on sary push for sociospatial egalitarianism was
whether socialist ideals and policies can be paradoxically built upon the contingency it
smoothly implemented across a highly disparate sought to extinguish – uneven development.
and geographically uneven national social for- As such, Whyte (2005: 6) correctly problema-
mation. It was this eagerness to accelerate the tizes the conventional account that portrays
transposition of ‘social fantasy’ into reality Deng Xiaoping as trading off social equality for
(i.e. universalize the Marxist-Leninist model economic efficiency: this account ‘diverts atten-
of socialism across Chinese state space) that led tion from other features of the stratification sys-
Mao Zedong to turn to Stalin’s Short Course7 tem of Mao-era China, many of which were
for guidance (Li, 2006). The outcome – which decidedly not egalitarian either in intent or con-
unfortunately generated catastrophic conse- sequences’. Rather, Whyte adds:
quences – was radical economic Stalinization
in the immediate years following the establish- in China the combination of virtually total sup-
ment of ‘new China’: pression of markets in favor of bureaucratic allo-
cation as well as of voluntary changes in
Between 1950 and 1953, Mao consciously and residence and employment makes the dominance
deliberately sought to repeat Stalin’s actions of one’s bureaucratic location rather than one’s
between 1921 and 1925 as described in the Short individual human capital or other social back-
Course. Mao almost literally relied upon this ground traits (and one’s resulting ‘market posi-
work as a do-it-yourself handbook for building tion’) much greater as a general rule. (Whyte,
socialism. Mao’s general line, which summarized 2005: 6)
Stalin’s basic ideas on how to build socialism,
became a mini handbook for building socialism Uneven development, quite clearly, remained
in China in the 1950s. He was more radical than the ‘antagonistic fissure’ throughout the Mao-
most other Chinese leaders in pursuing a Stalinist era socialistic quest (cf. Fan, 1995; Wei, 1999).
Lim 229

Recent social-scientific research shows how effects of neoliberal governance be circum-


‘Mao’s invisible hand’ – e.g. socioeconomic vented? Second, what are the roles of sociospa-
foundations laid during the Mao era, the hukou tial revolutions – the aforementioned Marxian
(household registration) institution that under- ‘locomotives of history’ that power the shift
girds rural-urban differentiation, geographically from capitalism to socialism – in a ‘once-and-
sensitive ‘adaptive governance’ – continues to for-all revolutionalized’ China? The present
extend deep into the Chinese political economy answer to these questions appears as such: any
(e.g. Chan and Buckingham, 2008; Heilmann sociospatial revolution arising from dissatisfac-
and Perry, 2011; Kueh, 2008; Lin, 2006). As tion with capitalistic exploitation could endan-
outgoing Chinese President Hu Jintao empha- ger the CPC’s rein on politico-economic
sizes in his valedictory speech at the 18th Party power, and, as a consequence, these sociospatial
Congress, Mao’s Marxian historicization of ruptures would either be pre-empted or sup-
China as a priori socialist has not effaced the pressed (cf. Wang, 2009). This pre-emptive
contingent determinants of an advanced social- necessity is arguably why Chinese Premier Wen
ist stage: Jiabao underscored, in his 2011 annual televised
press conference, that ‘reforms’ (gaige) – not
We must be soberly aware that China is still in revolutions (geming) – are ‘the eternal flames
the primary stage of socialism and will long of history’ (CCTV, 2011, author’s transcription;
remain so. This basic condition of China has not cf. Perry, 2007; Su, 2011).
changed; nor has the principal problem in our Hu and Wen’s comments, this paper argues,
society, that is, how we can meet the ever-
are historic; they effectively marked the CPC’s
growing material and cultural needs of the peo-
ple with backward social production; nor has conclusive interpretation of Marxian historical
China’s international position as the largest materialism. The future of ‘socialism with Chi-
developing country in the world. (Global Times, nese characteristics’ is now; socialism in China
2012) is the evolving present, driven in motion by see-
mingly contradictory neoliberalizing impulses
Hu’s point that ‘the basic condition of China has and the CPC’s ‘eternal’ reforms (which, because
not changed’ offers an interesting historical of neoliberalization, now has a growing global
reconnection of China’s post-1978 reforms with reach). The discursive substitution of ‘revolu-
the period immediately following the 1949 tion’ with ‘reform’ strongly suggests that the
establishment of ‘new China’: through the rein- Chinese state apparatus’s primary political goal
troduction of the profit-motive in domestic eco- is existential timelessness. To achieve this, it
nomic practices; the dovetailing of transactional must do everything it can to pre-empt the emer-
practices with that of the global economy, gence of revolutionary ruptures across state
particularly following China’s entry into the space. Yet, precisely because Deng’s govern-
WTO in 2001; and the willingness to permit ment decided against Mao-styled geo-economic
proletarianization through relaxing rules on insulation, it became increasingly difficult for the
domestic population movement, China’s post- Chinese state to draw a coherent sociospatial
1978 reforms can be construed as reapplying reform blueprint for the entire country. The
Mao’s initial approach to accommodate the pre-emptory process is thus predicated on rela-
capitalist mode of production in the transition tional geo-institutional differentiation: tailored
to advanced socialism. However, the need to to actually existing economic-geographical con-
negotiate neoliberal logics within a socialist texts across and beyond Chinese state space, the
developmental stage raises two further questions. CPC’s economic reforms – beginning first with
First, how would the potentially exploitative four Special Economic Zones in southeastern
230 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

China (Shantou, Shenzhen, Xiamen and Zhuhai) growth – China’s GDP growth rate averaged
in 1980, and, over the past decade, through an *10% annually between 1979 and 2011 – and
expanding series of ‘nationally strategic new uneven economic-geographical development.
areas’ across the country – are evidently intended This phenomenon has its roots in Deng Xiaop-
to produce locomotives of contemporary and ing’s willingness to accept uneven economic-
future flows, fixity and redistribution of capital. geographical development as a trade-off for
A more incisive theorization of the Chinese opening Chinese borders to transnational capital
state’s ‘authoritarian resilience’ thus needs to flows. The spatial expression of Deng’s eco-
incorporate the selective and seemingly con- nomic policies was guided by a distinct geogra-
tradictory spatialization of neoliberal logics phical theory – the ‘ladder step’ approach (tidu
for socialism (cf. Nathan, 2003). So long as lilun). This approach delineated Chinese state
China remains an integral component of the spatiality into three economic belts: the eastern
(neoliberalizing) global system of capitalism, (coastal), central, and western. Deng gave one
it is clear that a Marxian-styled socialist mode belt (the eastern seaboard) the priority in
of production can never be a spatiotemporal ascending the development ‘ladder’. He
straightjacket. Stressing ‘the impossibility of assumed that the fruits of development in the
fully formed totalities’ within states, Jones and ‘first mover’ belt would diffuse downwards to
Jessop (2010: 1122–1123, emphases in origi- other rungs of the ladder (see Fan, 1995; Wang
nal) argue that analyses of contemporary states and Hu, 1999). In a 1988 speech entitled ‘Two
should instead theorize ‘coherence and inco- Big Pictures’ (liangge dajü), Deng summed up
herence, zones of stability and instability, his time-oriented theoretical approach to
deferrals and displacements’. As Figure 1 illus- economic-geographical development:
trates, the inherent geographical incoherence
of capital fixity and flows in and through China the coastal area must accelerate its opening up to
enable this broad region of 200 million people to
makes it imperative to theorize ‘socialism with
first develop, from which it will stimulate even
Chinese characteristics’ as processes that better development in the interior. This is a matter
simultaneously involve neoliberal initiatives that involves a big picture. The interior must
to create bigger, self-regulatory and borderless understand this big picture. (Deng, 1993: 277–
‘free markets’ and redistributive mechanisms 278; author’s translation from Mandarin)
that ensure capital investments flow to less
developed regions. These processes resulted Deng, however, identified an equally impor-
in the (re)production of uneven economic geo- tant ‘big picture’, which entailed people in the
graphies, a development arguably turned on coastal provinces to reciprocate the state’s
its head by the CPC through a rolling series decision to first implement reforms in their
of strategic territorial (re)institutionalizations provinces by accepting the subsequent redistri-
over the past decade. bution of accumulated value accruing from
economic liberalization for the development
of the interior:
III Chinese socialism as a upon attaining a certain level of development, the
geographic tension coastal areas are requested to give more energy to
1 Neoliberalization in and through Chinese assist in the development of the interior, this is
also a ‘big picture’ . . . It is an obligation for eco-
state space nomically advanced areas to help those that are
Post-Mao reforms in China have been associ- more backward, and it is also a major policy.
ated simultaneously with fast-paced economic (Deng, 1993: 277–278; author’s translation)
Lim 231

The CPC as driver of Neoliberalizing impulses


‘socialism with Chinese Driven by still-active
characteristics’ Integrates “Washington Consensus”
Commitment to the Aim to reduce tariffs and
“universal truth of Marxism” augment unencumbered
Commitment to socio- access to potential markets
Negates
spatial egalitarianism for TNCs
(Deng, 1993) Absolute belief in the
Promise of ‘Common virtues of the privatization
Affluence’ of economic activities

Reaffirms/ Enlivens/
Revises (Re)produces through Encumbers
strategic (re)institutionalization

New institutional developmental arenas


Gradually phases out the ‘Ladder step’ developmental approach
Three major cross-provincial regional programs launched since 1999
Six ‘nationally-strategic new areas’ launched, five of them since
2006 (ref. Table 2)
Unique geo-economic integration policies with extra-border Chinese
economies since 2003, namely Hong Kong, Macau & Taiwan
(through CEPAs & ECFA, respectively)

Figure 1. ‘Socialism with Chinese characteristics’ as a cross-scalar sociospatial dialectic.

As is now well documented, Deng’s decision to enterprises in its territory as if it were a diversi-
gradually integrate Chinese state space into the fied business corporation’. The corporatization
global economy produced colossal changes in of decentralized governance manifests itself at
the flows, fixity and redistribution of capital the macro level through land-use changes: local
over the past three decades. With deeper eco- state cadres try to enrol prime agricultural land
nomic integration, the place-specific contradic- into (urbanizing) circuits of capital, in turn pro-
tions of market-oriented development have ducing a ‘great urban transformation’ at signif-
concomitantly become more pronounced (cf. icant social and environmental costs (Harney,
section I; The Economist, 2011; Wang, 2008). 2009; He and Wu, 2009; Hewitt, 2008; Lin,
All the major coastal city-regions, such as 2009a; Tsing, 2010).
Shenzhen and Guangzhou in the Pearl River An expanding literature reveals how primi-
Delta and Suzhou and Shanghai in the Yangtze tive accumulation – a distinct precondition and
River Delta, have generated significant infla- expression of neoliberalization (see section
tionary pressures on wage-costs, consumer II.1) – has become a prevalent driver of eco-
goods and real estate. A cause of this inequality nomic development in China. Looking at trans-
was arguably the emergence of what Oi (1992: formations in the Shanghai rural landscape,
101–102) refers to as ‘local corporatist states’, Buck (2007) shows how primitive accumulation
each of which ‘coordinates economic is related to the subsumption of labour to capital.
232 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

Lin (2009b: 441) highlights how major city gov- linked economic actors will remain integral to the
ernments in Guangdong province ‘scaled up’ their ‘socialist market economy’:
development policies through the ‘forceful
annexation of suburban cities and counties’. We should unwaveringly consolidate and develop
While Webber (2008a, 2008b) believes there are the public sector of the economy; allow public
economic and non-economic logics that underpin ownership to take diverse forms; deepen reform
of state-owned enterprises; improve the mechan-
the primitive accumulation process, Walker
isms for managing all types of state assets; and
(2006: 1) views the violent captures of rural space
invest more of state capital in major industries and
and resources, which have triggered ‘a tidal wave key fields that comprise the lifeline of the econ-
of peasant protest’ over the past two decades, as a omy and are vital to national security. We should
clear reflection of ‘gangster capitalism’ at work. thus steadily enhance the vitality of the state-
Against these varied interpretations of the causes owned sector of the economy and its capacity to
and implications of primitive accumulation across leverage and influence the economy. (President
China, one pattern is clear: Deng’s (1993: 64) fear Hu Jintao; Global Times, 2012)
that post-1978 Chinese social formations would
split into distinct ‘haves’ and ‘have-nots’ (liangji At first glance, this state-economy entwine-
fenhua) was certainly not unfounded. ment, also construed as ‘centrally managed
Indeed, as neoliberalization across China capitalism’ and ‘state neoliberalism’ (Lin,
intensifies, the concomitant exacerbation of 2011; So and Chu, 2012), logically makes it eas-
uneven development has meant that, if Deng’s ier for the Chinese state to implement a develop-
(1993: 277–278) injunction to balance out socio- mental agenda oriented towards sociospatial
economic disparities is to remain valid, the defer- egalitarianism. Not only does the CPC retain a
ment of socialistic development in time is high degree of autonomy over the nascent pri-
insufficient per se; something must be done to vate capitalist class, it has co-opted this class
change space. One key challenge must be taken into its governance orbit (for the rationale of this
into consideration, however: China’s public and co-option, see Dickson, 2008). As such, it is
private economic sectors intermesh in place- able to strongly influence national economic
specific ways that are probably not found else- development through direct orders and/or
where. To be sure, private capital investments moral suasion. However, the strong state control
have become more important in China’s domestic over the economy sacrifices another form of
economy and, over the past three years, rules have autonomy characteristic of effective ‘capitalist
been relaxed to permit foreign venture capitalists developmental states’: it is difficult, if not
to operate within China. But one characteristic impossible, for the Chinese state bureaucracy
stays unchanged: the major economic actors to be autonomous from the corporate strategies
within the Chinese economy remain the SOEs.9 of SOEs (cf. Evans, 1995). The situation
Interrelated to the SOEs’ economic practices is becomes more complicated as the majority of
a sprawling state-controlled financial system. SOEs are affiliated with local governments,
As Walter and Howie (2011) explain, complex each of which pursues its own developmental
off-budget arrangements, SOE borrowings and a agenda and which may in turn destabilize
non-convertible exchange rate sustain a financial Deng’s vision of even development. To draw
system that looks increasingly internationalized from Howell’s (2006: 274) observation, post-
but remains undergirded by older arrangements 1978 China has evolved into a ‘polymorphous
that directly affect the allocation of domestic cap- state’, within which exists ‘a deeper process of
ital. Also, to take the CPC’s recent indication as a state fragmentation that fosters contradictory
guide, the intertwined activities of Chinese state- and complex patterns of state behaviour’.
Lim 233

As Figure 1 shows, these ‘contradictory and and effected through the ‘Washington Consen-
complex patterns of state behaviour’ can be seen sus’ – has, in a most intriguing twist, become the
through the Chinese government’s selective sine qua non of China’s socialistic development
endorsement of neoliberalization at the global (cf. Figure 1).
and subnational scales. At the global level, the The Chinese state’s global-scale endorse-
central government’s push for global free trade ment of neoliberal logics generated new vulner-
and investments is accompanied by its staunch abilities, however. After the US government
refusal to succumb to US-led pressures to alter announced its plan to launch a second round
its fixed exchange rate regime, an arrangement of ‘quantitative easing’ in November 2010, the
which ensures China-based producers enjoy Chinese Vice Finance Minister Zhu Guangyao
propitious terms of trade and economic stability expressed immediate concerns about this inter-
(cf. Broz, 2002; Lim, 2010). Indeed, well- vention by the US government in global money
capitalized China-based firms, particularly the markets:
national sovereign wealth fund (China Invest-
ment Corporation) and large SOEs (e.g. As a major reserve currency issuer, for the
CNOOC and SINOPEC), need the ‘freedom’ United States to launch a second round of
quantitative easing at this time, we feel that
at the global scale if they are to expand into new
it did not recognize its responsibility to stabi-
markets and successfully fulfil the state’s ‘Go lize global markets and did not think about
Abroad’ market expansion programme. The the impact of excessive liquidity on emerging
launch of this programme – which Gonzalez- markets. (Reuters, 2010)
Vicente (2011) identifies as an extra-territorial
expression of ‘state entrepreneurialism’ – was The presupposition of Zhu’s concern – that
primarily due to the large overaccumulation10 national governments should not intervene
of US dollars under China’s fixed exchange rate excessively in international money markets –
system (Lim, 2010; Nolan, 2012). Given the US is paradoxical, to be sure, since the fixed-rate
government’s preferred post-subprime crisis yuan is in itself a calculated act of state interven-
strategy of printing and injecting dollars into tion. What is more significant in Zhu’s com-
money markets (known as ‘quantitative eas- ments is the acknowledgement that Chinese
ing’), China’s surplus capital stock needs to be macroeconomic strategizing has become
quickly and regularly reinvested to preclude increasingly susceptible to the interventionist
future devaluation. Chinese firms launching policies of other economies (cf. the point raised
outward FDI – which surged from US$2.7 bil- earlier about states being inherently anti-‘free’
lion in 2002 to US$60.07 billion in 2011 (China markets), an ironic aspect which could affect its
Daily, 2012a) – would thus benefit directly from future ability to reinvest overaccumulated
less regulatory barriers imposed by foreign domestic capital (in dollars and/or yuan) abroad
states and/or supranational institutions. This (cf. Nolan, 2012).
quest for unfettered market access overseas is Vis-a-vis this global-scale vulnerability, the
arguably the main reason why China joined the importance and urgency of crafting capital
WTO in 2001 and, more importantly, willingly accumulation opportunities from within Chi-
became bound to the WTO’s goal of reducing nese state space became more pronounced.
barriers to market access at the global scale.11 While the Chinese state has been cautious in its
Contrary to popular zero-sum conceptions of ‘down-scaling’ of neoliberal logics in order to
Sino-US relations, then, US (neoliberal) hege- preclude further sociospatial inequality, it
mony is in fact not unwelcomed by the Chinese appears increasingly keen to overcome the lim-
state. If anything, US hegemony – expressed itations of this ‘down-scaling’ process. Indeed,
234 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

it now appears to be in the interests of the Chi- 2010; see section III.2). This cross-scalar,
nese state to differentiate the institutionalization process-oriented approach potentially generates
of neoliberal governance logics at the subna- two contributions. First, the geographically tar-
tional scale in order to produce new (re)invest- geted fusion of socialist principles with ‘free’
ment opportunities for global circulatory market principles – which produces a new series
capital (of which it is now an integral part; cf. of sociospatial tensions – in and through China
Figure 1). The emergence of Chinese state space underscores the conceptual futility of framing
as a relational and reflexive entity (in relation to China as a ‘variety of capitalism’ or ‘develop-
neoliberal ideology) in turn reinforces Peck’s mental state’. Nor is it useful, as has become the
(2010: 10, emphasis in original) observation norm in the social scientific and business studies
that neoliberalization is a process that ‘denotes literature, to construe China as a coherent entity
the form of state/economy relations, not a linear that is ‘transitioning’ towards a ‘market econ-
path towards a purely free-market state’. As omy’, as if time will ensure a totalizing market-
Wang Hui (2009) puts it, state-capital co-evolu- ization of social life (pace Coase and Wang,
tion is fundamental to the post-1978 neolibera- 2012; Lardy, 2012; Wang, 2003; cf. Nonini,
lization in/of China: 2008). If there is any ‘transition’, it is Deng
Xiaoping’s promise that ‘Common Affluence’
Chinese neoliberalism has at times expressed its will come after some people ‘get rich first’; that
contradictions with the state in an anti-political an advanced socialist totality is, since 1949,
(or anti-historical, or even anti-socialist – in its already in the making (see section II.2).
traditional sense) way. But these oppositions
Through reinforcing the ability to shield Chi-
seem incapable of really concealing neoliberal-
nese sociospatial formations from the very pro-
ism’s intimate connections with state-directed
economic policy. For neoliberalism, in truth, cess – neoliberalization – it allows and
relies . . . upon its inherent links to the state. (selectively) endorses, the CPC has begun chan-
(Wang, 2009: 19) nelling new capital investments to less devel-
oped areas, particularly the western interior.
A fruitful way to extend these insights would be This process is inherently dialectical: on one
to assess neoliberalization in and through China hand, the Chinese state apparatus – directly
as an ideologically premeditated and geographi- through its macroeconomic and spatial strate-
cally variegated dialectic: this process is gies and indirectly through its aforementioned
entwined with the socialistic approach to over- arsenal of SOEs – appears to be producing a dif-
come actually existing uneven development by ferentiated pattern of reinstitutionalization to
strategically reproducing uneven development embed ‘free market’ logics and produce spatio-
(see Figure 1). Recently a nascent literature has temporal fixes for targeted investments, while,
begun to shine analytical light on state rescaling on the other hand, it simultaneously negates
strategies in China (Li and Wu, 2012; Ong, some of these logics (in the name of ‘rebalan-
2004; Smart and Lin, 2007; Su, 2012). To cing’ economic-geographical development)
simultaneously broaden and narrow the investi- through broadening and deepening state invol-
gation of territorial rescaling, this paper argues vement in economic practices within the tar-
that it is useful to push forth empirically sub- geted spatiotemporal fixes (cf. Deng, 1993:
stantiated theorizations of how state space is 277–278). An analysis of variegated neolibera-
(re)institutionalized by the CPC at the intra- lization in and through China could thus begin
urban scale and strategically patterned at the from the place-specific intersections of
national scale to accommodate and/or negate politico-economic processes that originate from
neoliberalizing impulses (cf. Brenner et al., and flow across different scales, namely (a) the
Lim 235

Table 1. China’s 10 economic challenges, identified in the proposal of the 12th Five-Year Plan.
Number Economic challenge
1 Increasing constraints of resource environments
2 Relationship between investment and consumption is unbalanced
3 Income distribution gap widened
4 Scientific and technical innovation capacity remains weak
5 Asset structure is unsatisfactory
6 Thin and weak agricultural foundation
7 Lack of coordination in urban-rural development
8 Co-existence of contradictory economic structure and employment pressures
9 Apparent increase in social contradictions
10 Persistent structural and systemic obstacles to scientific development
Source: Suggestions on the 12th Five-Year Plan by the Communist Party of China (p. 3, Mandarin document; NDRC,
2011). Author’s compilation and translation.

global economy, (b) the nation state, (c) individ- insofar as a national political economy is posi-
ual provinces and (d) prefectures and counties. tioned vis-a-vis the global system of capitalism,
Space, as section III.2 shows, is not an epiphe- modification to/in state space is at once contin-
nomenon when it comes to the interplay gent and necessary:
between neoliberalizing dynamics and the
developmental parameters of ‘socialism with The restructuring of state spatiality rarely entails
Chinese characteristics’ – its role is central. the complete dissolution of entrenched political
geographies . . . [it] is uneven, discontinuous, and
unpredictable: it is best conceived as a layering
process in which newly emergent state spatial
2 China’s new ‘national strategy’ of/for projects and state spatial strategies are superim-
socialism: decentralization-as- posed upon entrenched morphologies of state spa-
centralization? tial organization. Thus conceived, the spatiality of
In the build-up to the 12th Five-Year Plan state power is at once a presupposition, a medium,
and a product of the conflictual interplay between
(2011–2015), China’s central government can-
inherited geographical parcelizations of state
didly acknowledged the gamut of current chal- space and emergent political strategies intended
lenges engendered by the market-oriented to instrumentalize, restructure, or transform the
reforms and development of the past three latter towards particular sociopolitical ends.
decades, one of which is uneven development (Brenner, 2004: 107, emphases in original)
(see Table 1). The analysis of ‘state spatial stra-
tegies’, which Brenner (2004: 94) defines as the Indeed, neoliberalizing processes reshape and
use of ‘political strategies oriented towards the reproduce variegated central-local relations
reproduction, modification, or transformation across China that in turn redefine – or poten-
of inherited frameworks of state spatial interven- tially de-legitimize – the material expressions
tion at various scales’, offers a fertile launchpad of ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’.
from which to understand how Chinese policy- Interestingly, vis-a-vis problems engendered
makers turn the challenges of uneven by the penetration of market logics within the
economic-geographical development into strate- Chinese political economy, the CPC’s primary
gic advantage. As Brenner (2004) observes, policy response in the past decade – under the
236 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

leadership of Hu Jintao – has not been to media began to discuss province-specific eco-
eradicate these logics. On the contrary, a two- nomic development policies in relation to the
pronged approach is adopted: (1) to enhance broader regional strategy (e.g. how the urbani-
neoliberalization overseas through an expansio- zation of capital and labour power in Chongqing
nist geo-economic strategy (as discussed is connected to and helps drive the Great West-
above); and (2) to test out more spatially delim- ern Development programme). Developing
ited regulatory experimentations domestically regional consciousness is important as individ-
that enhance the targeted absorption of global ual provincial governments have been working
capital flows on one hand and ease the domestic disparately, particularly since the early 1990s,
problems of uneven geographical development and interprovincial (and, by extension, interur-
on the other. That these experimentations inevi- ban) collaboration has proved very difficult
tably form and fracture spatial hierarchies offers (author’s personal communications with Chi-
glimpses of the dialecticism of China’s macro nese urban planners, 2012). Intriguingly, the
spatial logic of development (see Figure 1): the delineation of three major regions of develop-
quest for national-level sociospatial egalitarian- ment bears striking similarity to Mao’s ‘Three
ism in relation to pressures for global free trade Front’12 spatial developmental approach in the
and capital flows entails domestic regulatory mid-1960s (cf. Li and Wu, 2012); the key differ-
differentiation that in turn enlivens global- ence is that these regions’ developmental
scale neoliberalization – the process repeats programmes are to be crafted with their respec-
itself. tive positions in the global capitalist – rather
The domestically variegated regulatory than geopolitical – system in mind.
experiments – which remain undertheorized in Geographically targeted (re)institutionaliza-
the social-scientific literature – are currently tions were and are expected to be implemented
evident at two scales: cross-provincial regions at the intra-urban level, with six ‘nationally stra-
and intra-urban economic zones. Proactive tegic new areas’ (guojia zhanlüe xinqu) identi-
cross-provincial spatial planning only became fied as bordered zones within selected cities to
more prominent in the decade following 1999, ‘move first, experiment first’ (xianxing xian-
during which the Chinese state launched three shi). The ‘new area’ concept is actually not
broad regional development programmes, novel, although its scale of implementation has
namely the Great Western Opening Up (xibu widened considerably since 2006 (see Table 2).
dakaifa), the Northeast Revitalization (dongbei Following the success of the first four Special
zhenxing) and the Rise of the Central (zhongbu Economic Zones in the provinces of Guangdong
jueqi). While fiscal monies have been redistrib- and Fujian, the world-renowned Pudong New
uted to the provinces involved to launch Area in Shanghai was approved for develop-
concrete developmental projects, these pro- ment in 1990, and has since been transformed
grammes entailed no specific institutional into a city-regional ‘motor’ of China’s eco-
(re)formulations at the provincial level (for a nomic growth. This intra-urban (re)institutiona-
detailed overview, see Li and Wu, 2012; Liu lization was not extended elsewhere in China
et al., 2012). The more crucial goal of these pro- for 14 years until the Binhai industrial region
grammes appears to be the production of cross- adjacent to the northeastern city of Tianjin was
provincial geographical imaginations. This designated China’s second ‘nationally strategic
goal is to materialize through a discursive- new area’ in 2006. From 2009 to 2012, four
ideological strategy: the name of each pro- more ‘new areas’ were demarcated. Two ‘new
gramme began to be included in individual areas’ are in the western interior, namely Liang-
provinces’ policy documents, while the mass jiang New Area in the city of Chongqing and
Lim 237

Table 2. China’s ‘nationally strategic new areas’, 1990–2012.


Area Concise overview
Shanghai Pudong  The oldest of the new areas, initiated for development in 1990; probably the
most widely known worldwide.
 Now the national base of many TNCs and big domestic firms; a major financial
centre; as well as a major global seaport. Plans underway to launch China’s first
free trade zone (a ‘mini Hong Kong’) in 2013.
 It is arguably the success of this new area that led China’s central government to
formulate similar spatial strategies in other cities.
Tianjin Binhai  Relatively established; was already a designated industrial development zone for
several years when it was ‘upgraded’ to zone of ‘national strategic significance’ in
2006.
 Since the institutional redesignation, perhaps the most high-profile develop-
ment has been the establishment of Airbus’s first non-EU assembly facility.
 Tianjin has also become a zone of financial innovations. GDP growth per annum
has regularly hit or exceeded 20% since 2007. The development of this area is,
surprisingly, not covered in much of the social science literature to date.
Chongqing Liangjiang  Officially unveiled as ‘new area’ in June 2010.
 Planning commenced several years before, during the 2006–2010
developmental phase.
 Like Binhai, the area around Chongqing has experienced industrialization in the
past decade. It is the first inland nationally strategic new area.
 The primary developmental aim is to redirect more capital flows to the western
region, as part of China’s ‘Great Western Opening Up’ strategy. Current plans
are to develop high value-added manufacturing capacities and deepening firms’
production chains in the region, as well as to experiment with ambitious
reforms to enhance social welfare.
 The inclusion of social reforms alongside industrialization strategies has
highlighted the tensions associated with socialistic development in
contemporary China.
Zhejiang Zhoushan  Approved for development in July 2011; located off the coast of Ningbo, in
Archipelago Zhejiang province.
 Designated to boost the development of China’s ‘oceanic economy’ and ‘land-
ocean integration’ (luhai tongchou), it is an intriguing site from which to examine
the commodification of aquatic nature.
Gansu Lanzhou  Approved for development in August 2012; located in the arid and mountainous
northwestern interior.
 Integral to the ‘Great Western Opening Up’ strategy: designated to absorb
manufacturing industries relocating from coastal provinces.
Guangzhou Nansha  Approved for development in September 2012; located at the centre of the
Pearl River Delta, just south of Guangzhou, in between two other specially
designated zones, Hengqin (in Zhuhai) and Qianhai (in Shenzhen).
 An integral part of the Guangdong-Hong Kong-Macau economic development
agreement to enhance the regional integration of the Pearl River Delta (PRD)
metropolitan region (yuegangao yitihua).
 Aids in the industrial restructuring and upgrading of the PRD as lower-end man-
ufacturing activities relocate due to cost pressures.
 Expected to experiment in policies regarding China’s financial reforms (jingai)
and integration of labour markets between Guangdong province and the
Hong Kong and Macau SARs.
Source: Author’s compilation.
238 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

Lanzhou New Area, which overlaps the city of existing economic-geographical positioning
the same name in Gansu province. The other within national state space, China’s ‘nationally
two are located along the coast, namely strategic new areas’ are intended to be more
Zhoushan Archipelago New Area, based off- competitive at the global scale. In other words,
shore in Zhejiang province, and Nansha New unevenness is harnessed by the central govern-
Area, strategically positioned between two spe- ment, with the place-specific competitive
cialized new zones (Hengqin, in Zhuhai, and impulses directed outwards to the global econ-
Qianhai, in Shenzhen) in the Pearl River Delta. omy. Each designated ‘nationally strategic new
It appears that several more of these ‘nationally area’ could thus become a central competitive
strategic new areas’ will be identified across the node for the country because its positional
country in the coming years (Xinhua, 2012). importance has been ‘scaled up’ to the global
The unfolding of this seemingly patterned level. Decentralization, in this regard, trans-
development raises two major research ques- poses into a new form of centralization that pro-
tions. (1) What does it mean, in both ideological pels and reproduces China’s ‘socialist market
and practical terms, to speak of a place as economy’.
‘nationally strategic’? (2) If a place is ‘strategic’ At the national level, the Chinese central
in the ‘national’ sense, what is the ‘national government’s emergent decentralization-as-
strategy’? centralization strategy transcends dichotomous
To arrive at an understanding of what a conceptualizations of politico-economic centra-
‘national strategy’ of economic development lization and decentralization. Putting into prac-
might look like, it would be helpful to begin tice the power to reconfigure national state
with the pre-existing state spatial form of the space, the central government appears to be
contemporary conjuncture. This brings to ques- effecting a more balanced domestic allocation
tion the causal effect of economic-geographical of capital (and, by extension, labour power).
unevenness. The last decade of high economic This in turn reinforces its control over local
growth has been based on what Chinese presi- practices that may deviate from national goals.
dent Hu Jintao terms ‘unbalanced, uncoordi- Furthermore, as one planner in China remarked,
nated and unsustainable development’ (Global ‘whenever the central government launches a
Times, 2012). A national strategy thus inevita- project, many people at the local level automat-
bly builds on – and attempts to change – this ically respond with much fervour. There is no
uneven spatiality. A critical examination of how problem getting people [at the local scale] to
actually existing uneven geographies comple- do things’ (personal communication, Beijing,
ment one another offers useful insights on how 2012; author’s translation). This insight
the CPC addresses and absorbs the contradic- strongly suggests how interprovincial and inter-
tory pressures associated with global economic city competition have not devalued perceptions
integration. So long as the targeted zones of of the central government’s importance; rather,
reinstitutionalization are ascertained to be relations with the central government are highly
‘nationally strategic’, the spatial logic goes valued because it is through the central govern-
beyond that of interurban competitiveness. ment that a locality ‘jumps scale’ and, almost
These ‘new areas’ are possibly designated to instantly, assumes a propitious economic-
circumvent – if not overturn – the oft- geographical position globally. The formation
debilitating, race-to-the-bottom competition by and evolution of the ‘nationally strategic new
local governments (see section III.1; cf. Howell, areas’ thus brings into focus a new central-
2006). Thus fortified with new (centrally local dynamic that shows, on closer reading,
approved) institutions tailored to their pre- how ‘developmentalism’ is constituted in and
Lim 239

through Chinese state space (cf. Beeson, 2009; ‘new area’ and how these policies are discur-
Howell, 2006). sively (re)presented. It is certain that the desig-
There are three interrelated dimensions to nation of an intra-urban area as ‘nationally
the emergent decentralization-as-centralization strategic’ would be accompanied by a fresh set
dynamic, namely politics, policy and practical- of policies. The primary aim of policy analysis
ity. First, the act of redrawing administrative is to ascertain how new regulatory processes
boundaries involves cross-scalar spatial poli- and parameters – particularly how they facili-
tics. The identification and designation of ‘new tate market exchange and/or more extensively
areas’ takes place in what Peck and Theodore involve private producers in the organization
(2010: 169) refer to as ‘fields of power’. These of everyday social life – differ from the pre-
‘fields’ are intersections of ‘adaptive connec- existing ones. If the new policies are designated
tions, deeply structured by enduring power rela- to ‘move first, experiment first’, how long these
tions and shifting ideological alignments’; they experiments last and whether they are retained
foreground the ‘intrinsic politics to the policy or discontinued become further points of
transfer process’ (p. 169). Given that the Chi- inquiry. Apart from policy content, a correlated
nese state apparatus is a heterogeneous entity research focal area is the discursive justification
within which exist different perspectives on of the new policies and the statistics that are
development (see, for example, Kuhn, 2010; made public. To follow newly appointed Chi-
McGregor, 2010), it is expected that the spatial nese President Xi Jinping’s (Nanfang Ribao,
politics will play out before and after the ‘new 2012) philosophy that ‘empty talk harms the
areas’ are designated ‘nationally strategic’. It nation, practical work leads to national flourish’
is currently unclear what kind of central-local (kongtanwuguo, shiganxingbang), public dis-
relations lead to the choice of a location as courses and statistics are critical materials
‘nationally strategic’ while others are passed against which evaluations of policy rationale
over. The decision-making process could be and effectiveness in the new areas can be made.
totally top-down, with provincial policy- Specifically, discourses by policy-makers offer
makers having little influence, or it could be another avenue to explore how market-
an outcome of aggressive lobbying of the cen- oriented reforms (e.g. the ‘financial reforms’,
tral government by provincial and metropolitan or jingai, to be launched in Nansha New Area
policy-makers. Ascertaining the nature of this and two other zones in the Pearl River Delta; see
process is methodologically challenging, to be Table 2) are to nurture a socialist mode of pro-
sure, as it is hard to penetrate policy-making cir- duction. At the theoretical level, the integrated
cles (especially at the central level) to obtain focus on new policy contents and their accompa-
first-hand data, but there might be alternative nying political discourses facilitates an investiga-
sources of information (e.g. interviews with tion of how ‘deepening neoliberalization’ –
senior members of enterprises, local urban plan- which Brenner et al. (2010: 209) define as the ‘the
ners, reporters) from which solid inferences growing interdependence, inter-referentiality and
could be made. Given that the potential outcome co-evolution of market-oriented reform efforts
of this research approach is a clearer under- among territorial jurisdictions, spatial scales and
standing of the macro spatial logic underpinning policy fields’ – plays out in and through the
the CPC’s strategies to actualize ‘socialism with ‘nationally strategic new areas’ vis-a-vis endur-
Chinese characteristics’, it is certainly worth ing socialist principles.
trying. This leads to the third interrelated dimen-
The next research focal point is a critical sion – practicality. The objective of combining
assessment of the policies introduced in each market-deepening reforms with socialist ideals
240 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

within the ‘new areas’ is not to produce nation- of (market-oriented) productive forces and
wide institutional homogeneity; the aim is to place-based social relations.
engender patterned variants of developmental
permutations that, working in tandem, help to
IV Conclusion: from the
propel the entire political economy. Indeed, the
concentration of processes in the ‘new areas’ are geographically impossible to the
not random; the act of ‘bordering’ – and the new geographically inevitable?
policies implemented within the bordered
zones – are deliberately crafted to create a driving In contemporary China, only socialism with Chi-
nese characteristics can develop China, benefit
effect towards a macro potentiality (in China’s
people and revitalize the nation. (Xi Jinping,
context, a ‘Harmonious Society’ constituted by
newly appointed Chinese president; China Daily,
balanced, coordinated and sustainable develop- 2012b)
ment). This said, there is every possibility that the
desired actuality will not materialize; that these Every child in China is schooled in the ‘univer-
spaces will constantly remain spaces of socialist sal truth of Marxism’ from the moment s/he
potential, in need of reintervention. Put another attends primary school. Despite China’s dee-
way, the processes emerging in and through the pening integration into the global system of
‘new areas’ are purposive and propulsive, but not capitalism, the central importance of Marxism
definitely transformative. is such that it remains enshrined in the national
In summary, the geo-institutional differentia- education law: ‘In developing the socialist edu-
tion of ‘nationally strategic new areas’ in China cational undertakings, the state shall uphold
is the latest round of spatial reconfiguration Marxism-Leninism, Mao Zedong Thought and
aimed at resolving tensions arising from neolib- the theories of constructing socialism with Chi-
eral and socialist practices. Yet it must be nese characteristics as directives and comply
emphasized that these strategies are deontologi- with the basic principles of the Constitution’
cal; they provide a preview of emergent sites (Chapter 1, Article 3).13 However, the ways in
and, by extension, the macro spatial logic of which Marx’s ‘universal truths’ now co-exist
development. Corresponding to what Lefebvre and co-evolve in China with neoliberalism, the
(1991: 33) terms ‘spaces of representation’, they reigning global governance ideology, receives
are notional determinations that designate what almost no focus. While the curriculum admir-
spaces should become in order to be fully ‘real’. ably espouses the virtues of sociospatial egali-
The primary underlying link between these stra- tarianism, the concrete realities of socialism in
tegies is the role of the state as a producer and China are shaped by capitalistic demands – the
mediator of neoliberal logics; through formulat- majority of which originate from the SOEs and
ing geographically differentiated regulations of/ foreign investors – that in turn produce varie-
for capital accumulation and then directly gated sociospatial consequences. Specifically,
participating in the actualization of these differ- it is not clear how neoliberalization in and
entiated spaces through SOE investments, through China – which, according to Marxian
Chinese policy-makers essentially aim to create logic, has already moved beyond the capitalist
different ‘spatial fixes’ for transnational capital mode of production (see section II.2) – fortifies
flows, driven by both private firms and SOEs. and fractures simultaneously the putatively
This is proactively leavened by the twofold ‘universal’ status of Marxian logics (cf. Deng,
redistribution of state finance and the power to 1982). This paper is an attempt to add concep-
make mistakes (shicuoquan). These new state tual clarity to this ideological interpenetration
spaces in China are hence tentative amalgams through a critical geographical perspective.
Lim 241

‘Socialism with Chinese characteristics’ ‘antagonistic fissure’ – uneven development


demands but simultaneously defies geographical (cf. Žižek, 1989: 142). This ‘antagonistic fis-
definition. The selective institutional differentia- sure’ is, interestingly, what Deng sought to
tion of state spatiality and the concomitant defer to the future as he put into practice the
accommodation of neoliberal logics epitomize ‘ladder step theory’ of economic-geographical
a seemingly unending cause-effect relationship. development in the early 1980s (cf. section
While the Chinese state’s decision to actively III.1). Evidence over the past decade suggests,
(re)produce economic-geographical unevenness however, that the CPC is ready to make even
within its territory may, at first glance, suggest development a prominent spatial issue. Its ratio-
neoliberalization has gained further traction in nale is not surprising: to follow Žižek (1989:
China, this decision must be assessed as a 143), the key to identifying and overcoming
dynamic, place-specific negotiation of what ideological limitations is ‘to detect, in a given
appear to be oppositional forces (i.e. socialism ideological edifice, the element which represents
and neoliberalism). The unfolding of this nego- within it its own impossibility’. For the CPC to
tiation in and through Chinese state space offers get closer to its goal (i.e. ‘socialism with Chinese
distinct contextual springboards to theorize what characteristics’) while it simultaneously nego-
Brenner et al. (2010: 211) call ‘the uneven devel- tiates the pressures of neoliberalization, this
opment of neoliberalization, and the neoliberali- ‘element’ has to be uneven development (see
zation of regulatory uneven development’. These Table 1; Deng, 1993).
springboards potentially challenge an increas- That uneven development would become the
ingly pervasive interpretation of China’s devel- prominent source of China’s socialistic
opment as a triumph of neoliberalism over advancement was unimaginable during the Mao
socialism/communism; as ‘neoliberalism with era (and possibly today); as China deepens its
Chinese characteristics’ (pace Coase and Wang, integration within the global system of capital-
2012; Harvey, 2005a; cf. Ma, 2009; Nonini, ism, however, this phenomenon has become a
2008). geographical inevitability. ‘If capitalism sur-
Challenging this interpretation involves vives through uneven development . . . if capit-
addressing two distinct but crosscutting ques- alism is uneven development, then, surely, we
tions. (1) Has neoliberalism really become the need to search out an adequate theoretical
ideology par excellence in China, or has it framework to encompass this fact’ (Harvey,
become a precondition of socialist/communist 2005b: 88, emphasis in original). Increasingly
development? (2) If there really is ‘neoliberal- central to the evolution of the contemporary
ism with Chinese characteristics’, (how) are global system of capitalism (and its prevailing
these ‘Chinese characteristics’ socialist in prac- governance ideology, neoliberalism) and yet
tice? As this paper has argued, it is more apposite simultaneously striving to enhance a histori-
to interpret variegated neoliberalization as a pre- cized socialist totality, China presents a contex-
condition of – rather than an alternative to – tually rich but contradiction-ridden arena from
‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’ because which to ‘search out’ this theoretical frame-
the production of a ‘socialist market economy’ work. Taking up and extending Harvey’s
entails a deepening structuring of everyday social (2005b) cue, this paper has proposed a concep-
life within China around market exchange on one tual framework that takes, as its basis, ‘socialism
hand and the Chinese state’s consolidation- with Chinese characteristics’ as a geographic ten-
cum-expansion of SOEs’ economic influence sion. The actualization of this historicized end-
on the other. Section II.1 has shown how neoli- state is encumbered by the ‘antagonistic fissure’
beralization is intrinsically undergirded by an that is uneven development, yet it is this
242 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

unevenness that enlivens both the Chinese state is how this central planning is reconfigured
and, indeed, the ‘Washington Consensus’ (see through the dialectical differentiation of Chi-
section III.1). While it cannot be determined a nese state spatiality and the variegated adapta-
priori whether the Chinese state’s ‘move first, tion of neoliberal logics across different
experiment first’ policies in the strategically scales. Rather than allow private, non-state
reinstitutionalized areas will succeed, it is, iro- capitalists to shape uneven development in an
nically, this potential for failure that justifies ad hoc and potentially socially debilitating man-
new rounds of geographically variegated insti- ner (which in turn foments conditions for social
tutional experimentations. Every round of insti- revolutions), the inclusion of private capitalists
tutional experimentation is, indeed, an in the CPC and the central government’s tight
exemplification of a Beckettsian ‘try again, fail grip over the national capital account (which
again, fail better’ spirit. concentrated a huge amount of foreign currency
In an interesting twist, it could be China’s reserves in Beijing) creates colossal leverage for
‘national strategy’ of state-driven policy experi- the CPC to shape the domestic and (increas-
mentations, rather than TNCs operating sepa- ingly) global allocation of financial investments
rately from and against national governments, (the allocative power applies, to a lesser extent,
that cause what Crouch (2011) terms ‘the to the flows and fixity of Chinese labour power
strange non-death of neoliberalism’. Aided by as well). This leverage helps to pre-empt socio-
its national monetary policy and a strong ‘invi- economic crises intrinsic to neoliberalization
sible hand’ over SOEs’ corporate strategies, and, by extension, sustains the CPC’s sociopoli-
CPC-driven territorial reconfigurations reflect tico legitimacy. As such, the production of
the paradoxical integration of uneven regulatory economic-geographical unevenness is, in the
development as an intrinsic driver of its multi- Chinese context, not what Myrdal (1957: 26)
scalar ‘eternal reforms’. A new research chal- refers to as a ‘historical accident’; it is not an
lenge for geographical political economy, outcome of the abstract laws of transnational
then, is to understand how sociospatial contra- capital and labour flows; rather, it is an ideolo-
dictions in China are transposed, through geo- gically driven, institutionally differentiated and
institu-tional differentiation, into new develop- inevitably recursive spatial tool that generates
mental preconditions in relation to the global pre-emptory territorial leaps towards an as-
(neoliberalizing) context (cf. Figure 1; Table yet-unknown future known as ‘socialism with
2). Specifically, the challenge is to ascertain Chinese characteristics’.
how – or, indeed, whether – uneven develop-
ment can be transposed from a developmental
effect to a developmental source. The empirical Acknowledgements
outcomes of the recursive cause-effect relation- I have benefited tremendously from the comments
ship between actually existing uneven develop- of Jamie Peck, Henry Yeung and Xiaobo Su on ear-
lier drafts of this paper. My sincere gratitude also
ment and state spatial strategies are of
goes to the anonymous referees for providing very
significance because, as aforementioned, it
insightful feedback, and to Professor Noel Castree
remains unclear how market-based regulations for his encouraging comments and editorial
and practices can fulfil the CPC’s integrated assistance. All responsibility for the arguments
socialist goal of ‘Common Affluence’ and ‘Har- presented in this paper remains solely mine. Over
monious Society’. the two years it took to transpose thoughts into text,
What is clear, for now, is that the days of a the support from Stephanie Lim, my dearest wife,
centrally planned economy are not over in has been the proverbial still point of the turning
China. The major difference from the Mao era world – thank you.
Lim 243

Funding II). As such, this paper argues that a multiscalar con-


This research received no specific grant from any ceptualization of China’s economic development
funding agency in the public, commercial, or not- offers a more incisive understanding and critique of its
for-profit sectors. ongoing, dialectical quest for a ‘socialist market
economy’.
4. The end-state of this pursuit is inevitably imaginary
Notes because no one, arguably even policy-makers within
1. While the existence of ‘universal’ truths in Marxism the top echelons of the Chinese state apparatus, knows
remain moot per se, three characteristics are certainly what the (geographical) form of ‘socialism with Chi-
not ‘universalized’ by Karl Marx and Frederick nese characteristics’ looks like. However, this imagin-
Engels: (1) the design of a Marxist state apparatus that ary is inherently material (rather than idealistic and/or
holds power over the proletariat within the contempo- illusory) because it is shaped by concrete geohistorical
rary international system of nation states; (2) the spe- events and, in turn, engenders direct impacts on socio-
cific temporal moment when this state apparatus economic policies implemented in and beyond China
hands over power absolutely to the proletariat; and (see sections II and III).
(3) strategies to address recurring uneven economic- 5. Originally coined in 1989 by the economist John Wil-
geographical development. As such, it is arguable that liamson, the ‘Washington Consensus’ describes 10
the ‘Chinese characteristics’ that accompany the puta- common policy prescriptions shared by the World
tive ‘universal truths’ of Marxism are these three con- Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the
tingent characteristics: precisely because these US Treasury Department for then-floundering Latin
characteristics are contingent, there is a degree of pol- American economies. These prescriptions were pro-
icy flexibility for the CPC to justify its existence as the free market, particularly the call for market-
leader of the Leninistic ‘dictatorship of the proletar- determined currency exchange rates, the privatization
iat’, and by extension, to use state space strategically of state enterprises, and the abolition of regulations
to further legitimize the perenniality of a one-party that impede market entry. Williamson has since been
governance system. at pains to distance his conceptualization from neoli-
2. The need to redress economic-geographical inequal- beralism, but fails to convince, given that the 10 pre-
ity, as recent statistics suggest, is pressing: the average scriptions are indeed integral to the three
income in 2010 of a resident in the province-level cit- institutions’ approach to development since the
ies of Shanghai, Beijing and Tianjin is at least five 1990s (cf. Harvey, 2005a; Peck, 2010).
times more than a resident in the three provinces with 6. This arguably came to a head in the lead up to the 2012
the lowest per capita GDP, namely Yunnan, Gansu US Presidential Election. Both presidential candidates
and Guizhou (The Economist, 2011). A report by the – Barack Obama and Mitt Romney – engaged in vig-
Chinese Household Finance Survey Center of Cheng- orous ‘China bashing’ in many of their campaign
du’s Southwestern University of Finance and Eco- speeches (see CNN, 2012).
nomics put China’s 2010 Gini coefficient at 0.61, 7. The Short Course was a collection of Stalin’s thoughts
which, according to World Bank figures, is substan- on and approaches to be socialist; it was compulsory
tially above the average of 0.44 for all countries reading in the Soviet Union between 1938 and 1956.
(Caixin Online, 2012). 8. As it became increasingly clear that a primary focus on
3. Contrary to the Marxian dialectical method, the scale- economic strategies was not yielding desired results,
sensitive approach in this paper does not predetermine Mao (1977: 130) began to critique Stalin’s policies
‘primary’ and ‘secondary’ contradictory forces: forces in 1961, placing particular emphasis on the impor-
may contradict one another at one scale and combine tance of central state power: ‘Commodity exchange
complementarily at another. For instance, full-blown laws governing value play no regulating role in our
neoliberalization contradicts the CPC’s aim to pro- production. This role is played by planning, by the
duce a domestic ‘socialist market economy’, but is great leap forward under planning, by politics-in-
in fact necessary to support the continued expansion command. Stalin speaks only of the production rela-
of the Chinese economy at the global scale (see section tions, not of the superstructure, nor of the relationship
244 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

between superstructure and economic base . . . Stalin References


mentions economics only, not politics.’ This emphasis Beeson M (2009) Developmental states in East Asia: A
arguably continues to undergird the CPC’s govern- comparison of the Japanese and Chinese experiences.
ance of the Chinese political economy today. Asian Perspective 33(2): 5–39.
9. Of China’s Top 500 Enterprises for 2011 (based on Beeson M and Islam I (2005): Neo-liberalism and East
2010 revenue), 316 are SOEs (guoqi), while 184 are Asia: Resisting the Washington Consensus. The Jour-
privately owned (minqi). SOE-ownership is differen- nal of Development Studies 41(2): 197–219.
tiated by place: they are either central government- Bloomberg (2010) China says Fed must explain bond-
owned (zhongyang qiye) or provincial government- buying or endanger recovery. Bloomberg 5 November.
owned (difang guoqi). While there is an increase in the Available at: http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2010-
number of minqi (from 169 in 2009), it is important to 11-05/china-says-u-s-fed-must-explain-bond-buying-
note that the top 38-ranked are SOEs, while the first or-endanger-global-confidence.html.
minqi to make the ranking – Huawei – was placed Brenner N (2004) New State Spaces: Urban Governance
39th. For the full list and a series of discussions (pub- and the Rescaling of Statehood. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
lished in Mandarin), see Sina.com (2011). This inter- versity Press.
esting information points to two potential research Brenner N, Peck J and Theodore N (2010) Variegated neo-
directions: (1) how the Chinese state continues to liberalization: Geographies, modalities, pathways. Glo-
influence domestic and global economic growth bal Networks 10(2): 182–222.
through the SOEs; and (2) the extent to which private Broz JL (2002) Political system transparency and mone-
enterprises are allowed to wield influence in the tary commitment regimes. International Organization
domestic economy. 56(4): 861–887.
10. In September 2012, the People’s Bank of China held Buck D (2007) The subsumption of space and the spatiality
approximately US$3.3 trillion in foreign exchange of subsumption: Primitive accumulation and the transi-
reserves. tion to capitalism in Shanghai, China. Antipode 39(4):
11. The dialecticism of this process is evident when 757–774.
viewed from the angle of the WTO. Through accept- Caixin Online (2012) China’s Gini Index at 0.61, University
ing a member state (China) that wants to ‘play the eco- Report Says. Caixin Online 11 December. Available at:
nomic game’ partly on its own ideological terms, the http://english.caixin.com/2012-12-10/100470648.html.
WTO has generated its own contradictory element CCTV (2011) China’s Premier Wen Jiabao meets press.
within itself. The question for the WTO is arguably CCTV 14 March. Available at: http://english.cntv.cn/
not whether it should have admitted China, but special/2011twosessions/wen_press/index.shtml.
whether the development of its member economies, Chan KW and Buckingham W (2008) Is China abolishing
increasingly integrated with the Chinese economy, the hukou system? The China Quarterly 195: 582–606.
can be sustained without subjecting (at least) some China Daily (2012a) China foreign investment boom to
Chinese investment and trading policy-making pro- continue. China Daily 31 May.
cesses within its regulatory realm. Both parties thus China Daily (2012b) VP stresses socialism with Chinese
produce and face tensions by virtue of becoming a part characteristics. China Daily 25 July.
of the other. CNN (2012) Obama, Romney’s ‘China bashing’ grates
12. In view of potential geopolitical threats from different Chinese netizens. CNN 22 October. Available at:
directions (the Soviet Union in the north, Vietnam and http://www.cnn.com/2012/10/22/world/asia/china-us-
the USA in the southeast and east, respectively), Mao debates-comments/index.html.
Zedong’s government decided in 1964 to designate Coase R and Wang N (2012) How China Became Capital-
China’s coastal belt as a ‘first front’ of defence, and ist. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
the southwestern interior as the ‘third front’. All areas Crouch C (2011) The Strange Non-Death of Neoliberal-
in between are categorized as the ‘second front’. ism. Cambridge: Polity.
13. The full text of the Education Law of the People’s Deng X (1982) Opening speech at the twelfth national con-
Republic of China can be accessed here: http://www. gress of the Communist Party of China, 1 September.
china.org.cn/english/education/184669.htm. Reproduced by People’s Daily. Available at: http://
Lim 245

english.peopledaily.com.cn/dengxp/vol3/text/c1010. Hewitt D (2008) Getting Rich First: Life in a Changing


html. China. London: Vintage.
Deng X (1993) Deng Xiaoping wenxuan [Deng Xiaoping’s Howell J (2006) Reflections on the Chinese state. Develop-
Selected Works], Volume 3. Beijing: People’s Publish- ment and Change 37(2): 273–297.
ing House. Johnson C (1982) MITI and the Japanese Miracle. Stan-
Dickson B (2008) Wealth Into Power: The Communist ford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Party’s Embrace of China’s Private Sector. Cambridge: Johnson C (1993) Comparative capitalism: The Japanese
Cambridge University Press. difference. California Management Review 35(4):
Evans P (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Indus- 51–67.
trial Transformation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univer- Jones M and Jessop B (2010) Thinking state/space incom-
sity Press. possibly. Antipode 42(5): 1119–1149.
Fan CC (1995) Of belts and ladders: State policy and Klein N (2007) The Shock Doctrine: The Rise of Disaster
uneven regional development in post-Mao China. Capitalism. New York: Metropolitan Books.
Annals of the Association of American Geographers Kueh YY (2008) China’s New Industrialization Strategy:
85(3): 421–449. Was Chairman Mao Really Necessary? Cheltenham:
Fröbel F, Heinrich J and Kreye O (1980) The New Interna- Edward Elgar.
tional Division of Labor. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni- Kuhn RL (2010) How China’s Leaders Think: The Inside
versity Press. Story of China’s Reform and What This Means for the
Fukuyama F (1992) The End of History and the Last Man. Future. Singapore: Wiley.
New York: Avon Books. Lardy N (2012) Sustaining China’s Economic Growth
Gibson-Graham JK (1996) The End of Capitalism (As We after the Economic Crisis. Washington, DC: Peter G.
Knew It): A Feminist Critique of Political Economy. Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Oxford: Blackwell. Lefebvre H (1991) The Production of Space. Oxford:
Glassman J (1999) State power beyond the ‘territorial Blackwell.
trap’: The internationalization of the state. Political Li H (2006) Mao and the Economic Stalinization of China,
Geography 18(6): 669–696. 1949–1953. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.
Global Times (2012) Full text of Hu Jintao’s report at 18th Li Y and Wu F (2012) The transformation of regional gov-
Party Congress, 18 November. Available at: http:// ernance in China: The rescaling of statehood. Progress
www.globaltimes.cn/content/744879.shtml. in Planning 78: 55–99.
Gonzalez-Vicente R (2011) The internationalization of the Lim KF (2010) On China’s growing geo-economic influ-
Chinese State. Political Geography 30: 402–411. ence and the evolution of variegated capitalism. Geo-
Hall PA and Soskice D (eds) (2001) Varieties of Capital- forum 41: 677–688.
ism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Lin C (2006) The Transformation of Chinese Socialism.
Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
Harney A (2009) The China Price: The True Cost of Chi- Lin GCS (2009a) Developing China: Land, Politics, and
nese Competitive Advantage. London: Penguin. Social Conditions. Abingdon: Routledge.
Harvey D (2005a) A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Lin GCS (2009b) Scaling-up regional development in glo-
Oxford: Oxford University Press. balizing China: Local capital accumulation, land-
Harvey D (2005b) Spaces of Neoliberalization: Towards a centred politics and reproduction of space. Regional
Theory of Uneven Geographical Development. Wies- Studies 43(3): 429–447.
baden: Franz Steiner Verlag. Lin N (2011) Capitalism in China: A centrally managed
He S and Wu F (2009) China’s emerging neoliberal urban- capitalism (CMC) and its future. Management and
ism: Perspectives from urban redevelopment. Antipode Organization Review 7(1): 63–96.
41(2): 282–304. Liu W, Jin F Liu Y, et al. (2012) 2011 Zhongguo Quyu Faz-
Heilmann S and Perry EJ (eds) (2011) Mao’s Invisible han Baogao. Beijing: Shangwu Yinshuguan.
Hand: The Political Foundations of Adaptive Govern- Low L (ed.) (2004) Developmental States: Relevancy,
ance in China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Redundancy Or Reconfiguration? New York: Nova
Asia Center. Science Publishers.
246 Progress in Human Geography 38(2)

Ma LJC (2009) Viewpoint: China’s authoritarian capital- September. Available at: http://finance.sina.com.cn/
ism: Growth, elitism and legitimacy. International focus/2011zgqy500q.
Development Planning Review 31(1): i–xii. Smart A and Lin GCS (2007) Local capitalisms, local citi-
McGregor R (2010) The Party: The Secret World of Chi- zenship and translocality: Rescaling from below in the
na’s Communist Rulers. New York: HarperCollins. Pearl River Delta Region, China. International Journal
Mao Z (1949) Report to the second plenary session of the of Urban and Regional Research 31(2): 280–302.
seventh central committee of the Communist Party of Smith N (1984) Uneven Development: Nature, Capital and
China, 5 March. Available at: http://www.marxists. the Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell.
org/reference/archive/mao/selected-works/volume-4/ So AY and Chu Y (2012) The transition from neoliberal-
mswv4_58.htm. ism to state neoliberalism in China at the turn of the
Mao Z (1977) Selected Works. Volume 5. Beijing: Foreign twenty-first century. In: Chang K, Fine B and Weiss
Languages Press. L (eds) Developmental Politics in Transition: The Neo-
Myrdal G (1957) Economic Theory and Underdeveloped liberal Era and Beyond. Basingstoke: Palgrave Mac-
Regions. London: Gerald Duckworth. millan, 166–187.
Nanfang Ribao (2012) Xi Jinping kaocha Guangdong: Su X (2011) Revolution and reform: The role of ideology
Zaiyici qiangdiao ‘kongtanwuguo, shiganxingbang’. and hegemony in Chinese politics. Journal of Contem-
Nanfang Ribao 13 December. porary China 20(69): 307–326.
Nathan AJ (2003) Authoritarian resilience. Journal of Su X (2012) Rescaling the Chinese state and regionaliza-
Democracy 14(1): 6–17. tion in the Great Mekong Subregion. Review of Interna-
National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) tional Political Economy 19: 501–527.
(2011) Zhonggong Zhongyang guanyu zhiding guomin The Economist (2011) All the parities in China. The Econ-
jingji he shehui fazhan di shierge wunian guihua de jia- omist 24 February.
nyi. Available at: http://www.ndrc.gov.cn/125gh.pdf. Tsing Y (2010) The Great Urban Transformation: Politics
Nolan P (2012) Is China Buying the World? Cambridge: of Land and Property in China. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
Polity. versity Press.
Nonini DM (2008) Is China becoming neoliberal? Critique Wade R (2003) Governing the Market: Economic Theory
of Anthropology 28(2): 145–176. and the Role of Government in East Asian Industriali-
Oi JC (1992) Fiscal reform and the economic foundations zation, second edition. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni-
of local state corporatism in China. World Politics versity Press.
45(1): 99–126. Walker KLM (2006) ‘Gangster capitalism’ and peasant
Ong A (2004) The Chinese axis: Zoning technologies and protest in China: The last twenty years. Journal of Pea-
variegated sovereignty. Journal of East Asian Studies sant Studies 33(1): 1–33.
4: 69–96. Walter C and Howie F (2011) Red Capitalism: The Fragile
Peck J (2010) Constructions of Neoliberal Reason. New Financial Foundation of China’s Extraordinary Rise.
York: Oxford University Press. Singapore: Wiley.
Peck J and Theodore N (2010) Mobilizing policy: Models, Wang H (2003) The historical origin of Chinese ‘neoliber-
methods, and mutations. Geoforum 41: 169–174. alism’. The Chinese Economy 36(4): 3–42.
Perry EJ (2007) Studying Chinese politics: Farewell to rev- Wang H (2009) The End of the Revolution: China and the
olution? The China Journal 57: 1–22. Limits of Modernity. London: Verso.
Polanyi K (1944) The Great Transformation: The Political Wang S (2008) The political economy of spatial inequality
and Economic Origins of Our Times. Boston, MA: Bea- in China. Paper presented at the International WSIR
con Press. 2008, Peter Wall Institute for Advanced Studies, Uni-
Reuters (2010) China ratchets up pressure after Fed move. versity of British Columbia, Canada.
Reuters 8 November. Available at: http://www.reuters. Wang S and Hu A (1999) The Political Economy of
com/article/2010/11/08/us-china-economy-world- Uneven Development: The Case of China. New York:
idUSTRE6A70XO20101108. M.E. Sharpe.
Sina.com (2011) Top 500 Enterprises of China Release Webber M (2008a) Primitive accumulation in modern
Conference and China Corporations Summit, 3 China. Dialectical Anthropology 32(4): 299–320.
Lim 247

Webber M (2008b) The places of primitive accumula- Xia M (2000) The Dual Developmental State: Develop-
tion in rural China. Economic Geography 84(4): ment Strategy and Institutional Arrangements for Chi-
395–421. na’s Transition. Aldershot: Ashgate.
Wei YD (1999) Regional inequality in China. Progress in Xinhua (2012) Pandian: Zhongguo 20nian she 6ge guojiaji
Human Geography 23(1): 49–59. xinqu huopi shijian, dingwei yilan. Xinhua 11 October.
Whyte MK (2005) Rethinking equality and inequality in Available at: http://news.xinhuanet.com/local/2012-
the PRC. Paper presented at the 50th anniversary con- 10/11/c_123810467.htm.
ference for the Fairbank Center for East Asian Zhang L and Ong A (2008) Privatizing China: Socialism
Research, Harvard University, 9–11 December. Avail- from Afar. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
able at: http://www.wcfia.harvard.edu/sites/default/ Žižek S (1989) The Sublime Object of Ideology. London:
files/1068__MKW_rethinkingequality.pdf. Verso.
Copyright of Progress in Human Geography is the property of Sage Publications, Ltd. and its
content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the
copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email
articles for individual use.

Вам также может понравиться