Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 14

World Development, Vol. 24, No. 6, pp.

1119-I 132, 1996


Pergamon Copyright 0 1996 Elsevier Science Ltd
Printed in Great Britain. All rights reserved
0305-750X/96 $15.00 + 0.00
80305-750X(%)000214

Government Action, Social Capital and Development:


Reviewing the Evidence on Synergy

PETER EVANS*
University of California, Berkeley, U.S.A.

Summary. - Instead of assuming a zero-sum relationship between government involvement and


private cooperative efforts, the five preceding articles argue for the possibility of “state-society
synergy,” that active government and mobilized communities can enhance each others’ developmental
efforts. This article draws on these articles to explore the forms and sources of state-society synergy.
I argue that synergy usually combines complementarity with embeddedness and is most easily fostered
in societies characterized by egalitarian social structures ard robust, coherent state bureaucracies.
I also argue, however, that synergy is constructable, even in the more adverse circumstances typical of
Third World countries. Copyright 0 1996 Elsevier Science Ltd

1. INTRODUCTION Generalizations derived from a small number of cases


have to be considered exploratory. Still, common
“State-society synergy” can be a catalyst for devel- themes derived from such a diverse set of analyses
opment. Norms of cooperation and networks of civic certainly must be considered useful clues by those try-
engagement among ordinary citizens can be promoted ing to organized public-private relations more produc-
by public agencies and used for developmental ends. tively as well as warranting further testing by other
Figuring out how such public-private cooperation researchers. Collectively, these articles raise a welter
might flourish more widely should be a priority for of new ideas about how and under what circumstances
those interested in development. The preceding arti- civic actors can more fruitfully engage with public
cles by Lam, Heller, Ostrom, Fox and Burawoy offer institutions in pursuit of developmental ends.
an excellent start on this agenda. This essay tries to
look across the five articles, highlighting some gen-
eral findings that resonate across the different settings 2. STRUCTURE OF SYNERGISTIC RELATIONS
and perspectives of the individual articles. In addition,
I have drawn on some of the other work discussed at Mutually reinforcing relations between govem-
the conference where the original versions of the five ments and groups of engaged citizens can take a vari-
articles were presented. For example, I will make sub- ety of forms. I begin with a simple dichotomy which I
stantial use of Judith Tendler’s forthcoming work on think is useful in clarifying what we mean by synergy
“good government” in Northeast Brazil. - an analytical distinction between complementarity
First, I examine the structure of synergistic rela- and embeddedness. The two concepts not only imply
tions, focusing on the distinction between synergy
based on complementary actions by government and
citizens and synergy based on ties that cross the pub-
lic-private divide (embeddedness). In the second part *I would like to thank all of the participants at the May,
of the essay I explore the social and political circum- 1995 Conference of the Economic Development Working
stances that facilitate the emergence of synergy. How Group, Social Capital and Public Affairs Project for their
extremely useful feedback on an earlier version of this
crucial is the underlying stock of social capital? How
paper, especially Guillermo O’Donnell whose comments at
important is the character of the state apparatus itself? the conference were particularly important in reshaping my
What difference do formal political rules or the over- thinking. My greatest debt is, obviously, to the five authors
all shape of the social structure make? Can synergy be whose papers precede this one. At the same time, I should
constructed in the short run, or does it require histori- make it clear that none of them can be held responsible for
cally deep institutional and normative foundations? the interpretations I have imposed on their work.

1119
1120 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

different forms of synergy but also different connec- neurial behavior from economic elites. The work
tions between the idea of synergy and prior theories of being discussed here suggests that the “rule of law”
relations between public and private institutions. may be even more important as a complement to the
Complementarity is the conventional way of con- efforts of less privileged groups to organize them-
ceptualizing mutually supportive relations between selves. Both Heller and Fox argue that the provision
public and private actors. It suggests a clear division and enforcement of universalistic rules is an invalu-
of labor, based on the contrasting properties of public able organizational resource for the less privileged.’
and private institutions. Governments are suited to Fox underscores the centrality of simple legal norms
delivering certain kinds of collective goods which such as freedom of assembly and association in mak-
complement inputs more efficiently delivered by pri- ing civic organization possible for indigenous peas-
vate actors. Putting the two kinds of inputs together ants. Heller sees “drawing traditionally disenfran-
results in greater output than either public or private chised workers within the purview of the law” as
sectors could deliver on their own. The idea of com- critical to the process of mobilization in Kerala.
plementarity fits nicely with existing paradigms in Conversely, as O’Donnell (1993, p. 1365) has elo-
institutional economics and public administration and quently argued, the destruction of “the state as law” in
forces no rethinking of the public-private divide. many parts of Latin America has led to an “angry
The idea that synergy may be based on “embed- atomization of society” which leaves no space for
dedness,” that is, on ties that connect citizens and self-organization at the bottom.
public officials across the public-private divide, Complementarity based on the public provision of
is more novel. Can networks which trespass the intangibles can also take forms quite independent of
boundary between public and private divide be repos- the provision and enforcement of rules. The creation
itories of developmentally valuable social capital and diffusion of new knowledge by agricultural exten-
rather than instruments of corruption or rent-seeking? sion services is a standard example. More novel exam-
Despite the difficulties it creates for conventional wis- ples of complementarity based on the provision of
dom, the evidence that has been presented in these intangibles are offered by Tendler in her recent (forth-
articles suggests that the permeability of public-pri- coming) work on “good government” in Northeast
vate boundaries must be acknowledged as an Brazil.2 Tendler makes the point that another kind of
inescapable part of many developmentally successful intangible collective good with very large economies
programs. of scale is media publicity. Because media publicity is
Acknowledging embeddedness does not make subject to manifest economies of scale, it is the kind of
analysis of complementarities obsolete. To the con- public good that it makes sense for the state to provide.
trary, complementarity and embeddedness turn out to One of the most important aspects of this complemen-
be mutually supportive. Most concrete cases of syn- tary input was that it enhanced the extent to which
ergy involve combinations of complementarity and government programs were able to combine social
embeddedness. The aim of separating the two is not to capital formation with the delivery of services. In
privilege one over the other, but to get better analytical Ceara’s successful preventive health program, the
purchase on the complexities of synergistic relations. state government’s blitz of positive media publicity
Complementarity is given a new dimension when bolstered the health agents’ sense of “calling” and
social capital is included along with goods and ser- made them more willing to engage in the kind of dif-
vices as a desired outcome of public-private coopera- fuse public service that helped generate new relations
tion. New research on states and the formation of of trust between them and the community. It also
social capital suggests new kinds of complementari- affected the way in which they were viewed by mem-
ties and innovative ways of seeing traditional comple- bers of the community, again increasing the likelihood
mentarities. of relations of trust. Similar effects were observed in
The most universally acknowledged kind of com- the case of agricultural extension workers trying to
plementarity is exemplified in the quote from Nugent organize drought relief. According to Tendler (forth-
(1993) cited in the introduction. Effective states coming, p. 116; see also Tendler and Freedheim,
deliver rule-governed environments which 1994),
“strengthen and increase the efficiency” of local orga-
nizations and institutions. The state’s contribution to As with the health agents, the state government’s actions
[ in promoting a supportive media campaign ] elicit
social capital is general and from a distance.
public-minded behavior by creating a strong sense of
Productive informal ties, like market exchange, “calling” around particular public jobs and civic
require a basic ambience of rule-governed behavior. responsibilities.
The state provides the necessary ambience but public
agencies are not directly linked to societal actors. Complementarity of a more prosaic and tangible
Traditional analysis of the benefits of a rule- variety can also play a significant developmental role.
governed environment - from Weber to Douglass Irrigation is the classic case, in both historical and
North - emphasizes on its role in elicitingv entreme- L contemporary analysis. Contemporary work, how-
GOVERNMENT ACTION. SOCIAL CAPITAL AND DEVELOPMENT 1121

ever, adds the positive impact on social capital forma- ates much more efficiently and effectively that the one
tion as one of the important byproducts of comple- Lam studied earlier in Nepal,3 but it is certainly not an
mentarity. This perspective extends the standard instance of “hands off’complementarity. Lam’s work
analysis of public goods to include the possibility that confirms Moore’s earlier assessment (1989, p. 1748,)
provision of such goods, in addition to facilitating pri- that “enmeshment” in the form of a “dense network of
vate production of conventional goods (crops in this social relationships which exist among IA staff and IA
case), may also contribute to “enhancing farmers’ members” is the key to the system’s effectiveness at
capability and willingness to relate to, and to work the local level. According to Moore (1989, p. 1742),
with, one another” (Lam, 1994, p. 288). Efficient pro- “IA’s are overwhelmingly staffed by people who were
vision of the tangible main facilities and channels born in the locality, have lived there all their lives,
have the intangible consequence of making it more and, in many cases also farm there.” Therefore, “IA
worthwhile for farmers to organize themselves. Other staff are so much part of local society that they can
kinds of tangible complementarities can also stimulate neither escape uncomfortable censure if they are seen
social capital formation. In Fox’s discussion of to be conspicuously performing poorly, nor ignore
“reformists” and peasant organizations in rural representations made to them by members.”
Mexico, one of the state’s contributions to “scaling- Lam’s account further spells out the multifaceted
up” peasant social capital is simply providing trans- set of ties which bind together local public officials
portation so that peasants from different local areas and local farmers.4 His analysis makes clear the extent
can get together. to which those who make their careers the local field
Looking at these examples, it is clear that comple- offices rely on the experience and local knowledge of
mentarity is not just about government providing the farmers to allocate water among the fields, to carry
inputs that its scale and bureaucratic organizations out local operations and maintenance, and to provide
allows it to provide more effectively and leaving it to the voluntary labor and voluntary monetary “chip-ins”
citizens to do the rest. Complementarity supports day- which “were important sources of resources for irriga-
to-day interaction between public officials and com- tion management at the local level.” At the same time,
munities, which is in turn essential to organizing com- local farmers depend on their public sector counter-
plementarity. In addition to promoting social capital parts. The local field station is responsible for inte-
formation in civil society, complementarity supports grating local needs into the overall plan for the entire
embeddedness irrigation association and, even more important, for
Embeddedness complicates the analysis of syn- making sure that the promised water is actually deliv-
ergy. If synergy depends on day-day public private ered to the local area. Farmers and local officials are
interactions and the norms and loyalties that build up engaged in a shared project aimed at making sure that
around them, then its institutional forms become more enough water reaches their area at the right time.
complex. Unfortunately for analytic simplicity, how- There is a division of labor but it among a set of tightly
ever, embeddedness appears to be just as common a connected individuals who work closely together to
feature of synergy as complementarity. achieve a common set of goals.
Again, irrigation provides a nice way to start. In Once again, Tendler’s work in Northeast Brazil
Lam’s earlier (1994) analysis of Nepal, comple- reinforces the insights gained from East Asian irriga-
mentarity without the intrusion of public officials at tion systems. The health care program she describes in
the local level seemed to be the ideal. Farmers needed Cearh epitomizes the way in which embeddedness
inputs that they could not supply themselves in order plays a role in the success of public programs.
to make it worth their while to organize and it was Creating new ties between 7,000 newly hired health
also helpful if the state provided intangible collective agents and their communities was the key to the health
goods in the form of legal recognition of local farmers program’s success. Starting out in a civic climate in
groups. The state was useful as long as it kept out which people were reluctant to even open their doors
of the day-to-day operation of irrigation systems at to anyone working for the government? the new
the local level. Direct involvement of the state- health agents made building relations of trust between
bureaucracy in the operations of local systems under- themselves and their “clients” a central part of their
cut the development of the collective institutions that jobs. To this end, they even helped with mundane
farmer-managed systems depended on and reduced household tasks without direct relation to health (e.g.
the likelihood of effective water delivery. The cooking or cutting a baby’s hair). According to
lesson seemed to be that the state can help most by Tendler (forthcoming, p. 76), “they saw their clients
providing inputs that local people cannot provide for not only as subjects whose behavior they wanted to
themselves and then maintaining a “hands-off’ stance change, but as people from whom they wanted respect
with regard to activities that are within the scope of and trust.” Not surprisingly, the health agent’s
local action. approach generated reciprocal attitudes, with clients
Lam’s article here on Taiwan presents a very dif- describing them as “true friends.” Individual ties
ferent kind of story. Taiwan’s irrigation system oper- helped generate in turn a generalized commitment to
1122 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the community. Tendler reports (forthcoming, p. 73) state corporatism” which Burawoy , following Oi, sees
that, “health agents took on, of their own accord, com- as underpinning China’s surprising rates of rural
munity-wide activities meant to reduce public health industrial growth, depends on a set of local ties which
hazards - in addition to their job of visiting house- bind local state officials and nascent entrepreneurs
holds.” As one health agent put it, “I was ready to around a joint-project of rural industrialization. Oi
leave and look for a job in Sio Paulo, but now I love notes that in most of the localities where she has done
my job and I would never leave - I would never fieldwork, “it is the local party bosses - the first party
abandon my community .” secretary of the county, township or village - who
In Tendler’s description of Ceara’s health cam- are at the helm of the drive for economic develop-
paign, as in Lam’s description of the Taiwanese irri- ment” (Oi, 1992, p. 124). Not only are the ties between
gation system, social capital is formed by making local enterprise managements and local officials
some who are part of the state apparatus more thor- important, but also the web of relations that allows
oughly part of the communities in which they work. local officials to work through officials and agencies
The networks of trust and collaboration that are cre- in the central state apparatus to gain access to credit
ated span the public/private boundary and bind state and scarce raw materials that local entrepreneurs need
and civil society together. Social capital inheres, not (Oi, 1992,~~. 120-121).
just in civil society, but in an enduring set of relation- The central role of ties that cross public-private
ships that spans the public-private divide. boundaries in China’s “transition” success story
The interweaving of ties across the public/private echoes the pivotal role of embeddedness in the biggest
divide to create developmentally effective social cap- capitalist success story of the 20th century - the
ital can even characterize what are usually thought of transformation of the economies of East Asia from
as institutions rooted strictly in civil society, like low-productivity agrarian backwaters to the most
Grameen Banks. In May 1992, a Grameen Bank-type rapidly growing industrial economies in the world.
rotating credit association was begun in the environs Even the official World Bank interpretation (1993)
of Ho Chi Minh City. Participation was limited to poor concedes that state/society linkages played a central
households and 95% of the participants were women. role in this “East Asian Miracle.” Institutional
They used the loans for working capital in petty trad- descriptions of East Asian industrialization, from
ing ventures (e.g., selling vegetables) or to buy equip- Johnson’s (1982) classic work on Japan to Amsden
ment for craft production (e.g., sewing machines). The (1989) and Wade (1990) on the East Asian newly
loans had a substantial impact on the women’s income industrializing countries (NICs) paint a picture of
earning capacity and the reported repayment rate on dense networks that span public/private boundaries.
the loans was an astonishing lOO%.h From Okimoto (1989) to the World Bank (1993), ana-
Such results are not, of course, unusual for lysts stress the dense networks of ties that connect
Grameen Bank-type projects.7 What makes this pro- state agencies and private capital. From joint busi-
ject interesting and relevant to the analysis of synergy ness-government “deliberation councils” to “the maze
is that it was organized by the Institute of Economic of intermediate organizations and informal policy net-
Research (IER), an agency of the city government of works where much of the time consuming work of
Ho Chi Minh City (with support from an international consensus formation takes place” (Okimoto, 1989, p.
nongovernment organization). The IER enlisted the 155), it is social capital built in the interstices between
support of the people’s committees (local govem- state and society that keeps growth on track. This pro-
ment) in the villages covered by the scheme but con- fusion of concrete ties between officials in organiza-
tinued to provide training and technical support. The tions such as Taiwan’s Industrial Development
local village secretaries provided the organizational Bureau, Japan’s MITI, or Korea’s Ministry of
skills and energy that actually got the project rolling. Communications and those who manage private
The organization of the individual credit groups industrial corporations generates in turn a “joint pro-
depended on pre-existing ties (friends, relatives, etc.) ject” of industrial transformation (Evans, 1995).
but the initial organization of the scheme as we11 as its In these archetypal capitalist successes, as in
organization and administration depended on the China’s would-be market economy, the social capital
interaction of local government staff and officials and that is most critical to the outcome is formed once
their relationships with the local women who became again in networks that are neither public nor private
members and group leaders. Adding concrete ties but fill the gap between the two spheres.* Far from
across the state-society boundary to pre-existing kin being a pattern that emerges only when the state
and friendship ties helped transform traditional ties develops ties to the less privileged or during the tran-
into developmentally effective social capital. sition from nonmarket to market-based economic
Embeddedness is not just a feature of developmen- relations, synergy based on embeddedness is the
tally effective relations between public agencies and essence of the most important contemporary instances
the powerless. It is even more pervasive in successful of market success.
projects that join the state with elite actors. The “local The centality of embeddedness to synergy across a
GOVERNMENT ACTION, SOCIAL CAPITAL AND DEVELOPMENT 1123

range of different settings is undeniable, but none of farmers and local irrigation staff in Taiwan delivered
this negates the importance of complementarity. sewers to urban neighborhoods in Northeast Brazil,
Instead, this multiplicity of examples should be taken Irrigation systems, like sewers, are characterized
as a reminder that even the most obvious division of by complement&y as well as embeddedness. The role
labor must be sustained by shared orientations and of embeddedness in the Taiwanese case has already
concrete interactions among the actors involved. A been highlighted; the importance of complementarities
better sense of how complementarity and embedded- needs to be underlined as well Dams, reservoirs and
ness can come together is the key to understanding other “lumpy collective goods” provided by state
synergy. agencies that are quite separate from the embedded
Embeddedness and complementarity are not com- Irrigation Associations. As Lam points out, one of the
peting conceptions of synergistic relations but are reasons for Taiwan’s success is that, in contrast to
themselves complementary. A few examples will suf- South Asian irrigation systems, it has left responsibil-
fice to make the point. “Coproduction” which forms ity for the construction of major irrigation projects in
the conceptual framework for both Lam and Ostrom’s the hands of a separate organization, so that operation
analysis, sets out the interdependence of complemen- and maintenance do not become “stepchildren” in a
tarity and synergy most clearly.9 In the coproduction construction-dominated bureaucracy. Here again,
model, complementarity creates a basis for productive Lam’s analysis parallels that of Moore (1989, p. 1741)
interaction, but without embeddedness the potential who notes that, “The key feature is the institutional
for mutual gain is hard to realize. separation of major irrigation construction, which is
As Ostrom’s production functions (Figures 1 and the responsibility of national agencies, from routine
2) show graphically, complementarity is the essential maintenance and operation of irrigation systems.”
prerequisite of coproduction. When public agents and Even in the maintenance and operation of the sys-
citizens have sufficiently different (but equally neces- tem, there is clear recognition of the complementari-
sary) kinds of inputs, they can produce more effi- ties between the what public agencies can do and what
ciently by combining their efforts than by either pro- self-organized citizens can do. The bureaucratic hier-
ducing everything privately or everything publicly. archy constructs the overall plan of water delivery
Complementarity is the precondition for coproduc- (after the basic inputs of information have been con-
tion. Without complementarities there would be few structed jointly by local offtcials and farmers). The
incentives (other than rent-seeking) for trying to orga- organization of the system recognizes that trying to
nize collective actions across the public-private have local communities settle on an overall plan
divide. Nevertheless, production functions convey would lead to a cumbersome, ineffectual political
only the complementarity half the coproduction story. process in which local communities were forced to
The embeddedness half of the story comes across only make decisions involving the unfamiliar circum-
in concrete examples. stances of other areas. By the same token, state offi-
Ostrom’s sewer condominium case illustrates the cials do not infringe on the role of the water guards at
point. Complementarity was clear. The technology of the village level or become involved in micro-level
producing trunk sewer lines was beyond the collective allocational decisions among farmers. To do so would
efforts of local neighborhoods, so neighborhoods had stretch even the very well-organized Irrigation
to rely on government to produce trunk lines. By the Association bureaucracies beyond their capacity, and
same token, public sector fiscal problems put the they still would not be able to replicate the efficiency
resources necessary to deliver the entire system out of of community initiatives. Everyone realizes that even
reach of the government. Without citizen collabora- local officials with long tenure in a particular area can-
tion the full network would not be built. This, how- not replicate the local knowledge (social as well as
ever, is only the complementarity half of the story. topographical) of the water guards and irrigation
Complementarity created the potential for synergy but group leaders. In sum, intimate interconnection and
not the organizational basis for realizing the potential. intermingling among public and private actors is com-
Embeddedness in the form of direct involvement of bined with a well-defined complementary division of
the public officials was a key component in getting labor between the bureaucracy and local citizens,
citizen efforts organized and sustaining citizen mutually recognized and accepted by both sides.
involvement. The organizational “start-up costs” of Tendler’s health campaign is yet another example of
setting up neighborhood meetings, explaining options complementarity combined with embeddedness. The
and mediating conflicts required substantial time and Ceara state government’s media campaign was a very
effort on the part of public officials. Likewise, once useful complementary input, but without the thou-
the sewer systems were constructed, monitoring and sands of day-to-day interactions between health-care
maintenance required continuous face to face interac- workers and community members to give it substance,
tion between an on-going, familiar set of public the media campaign would have been fruitless. If the
agency staff and collaborating neighborhoods. In government had limited its role to the provision of the
short, a relationship very much like the one that unites complementary input and assumed that local citizens
1124 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

would provide the appropriate responses without the must constrain the possibility of constructing syner-
involvement of public sector workers in the construc- gistic relations. The question remains: how much
tion of a set of reinforcing ties, the campaign would room is left for agency?
almost certainly have failed. In order to assess the relative weight of endow-
In the end, the analytical distinction between com- ments and constructability, I begin with a look of the
plementarity and embeddedness is useful primarily in role of endowments of social capital in civil society,
that it reminds us to look for both elements. There may then move to a focus on administrative structures and
be cases in which synergy is created solely on the basis the question of whether robust, efficacious bureaucra-
of complementarity. Or, though this seems even less cies constitute prerequisites for synergy. I then turn to
likely, cases where synergy is built around network politics and social structure and the ways in which
connections which do not involve complementarity. political regimes and the basic patterns of interest con-
Nonetheless, the best way to understand synergy is as a flicts in society impinge on the possibility of synergy.
set of public/private relations built around the integra- Finally, I return to the issue of constructability and
tion of complementarity and embeddedness. whether we can point to any “soft technologies” of
This preliminary description of the forms of syn- institutional change that enhance the possibilities for
ergy is useful in thinking about how synergy works in joint projects that bring together government and civil
practice, but it does not illuminate the social and polit- society in the short run.
ical conditions that make synergy possible in the first Endowments ofsocial capital are obviously crucial
place. To explore the origins of synergistic relations it to synergy. Putnam’s (1993a) original analysis of the
is necessary to look more broadly at the circumstances Italian case suggested that stocks of social capital
under which synergy has emerged, searching for com- accumulated over long periods of time (perhaps hun-
monalities across different contexts. dreds of years) were the crucial ingredient in creating
the “virtuous circle” in which civic engagement nur-
tured good government and good government in turn
3. CONTEXT AND CONSTRUCTION IN fostered civic engagement. The question remains
THE CREATION OF SYNERGY whether in most Third World settings the requisite
social capital is in such short supply as to exclude the
The most basic issue in analyzing the origins of possibility of synergy or whether the norms and net-
synergistic relations is the question of endowments works that characterize “normal” Third World com-
versus constructability. Does the possibility of syn- munities constitute sufficiently fertile ground for the
ergy depend primarily on sociocultural endowments construction of developmental projects that span the
that must be taken as givens? Or, can the application public-private divide. The cases analyzed here sug-
of imaginative organizational arrangements or institu- gest that prior endowments of social capital are not the
tional “soft technologies” produce synergy over rela- key constraining factor. The limits seem to be set less
tively brief periods of time? If synergy is an outcome by the initial density of trust and ties at the micro level
that depends on the prior existence of social and cul- and more by the difficulties involved in “scaling up”
tural patterns historically rooted in particular cultures micro-level social capital to generate solidary ties and
and societies then it may well be out of reach for most social action on a scale that is politically and econom-
groups. A “constructability” perspective is more opti- ically efficacious.
mistic. Synergy becomes a latent possibility in most Starting once again with Taiwan’s irrigation sys-
contexts, waiting to be brought to life by the institu- tem, it is hard to make the argument that the system’s
tional entrepreneurship. Optimistic assumptions, pre- unusual efficiency derives from historically excep-
cisely because they are attractive, must be approached tional levels of social capital in Taiwanese rural com-
skeptically. Assuming constructability if endowments munities. Lam is quite explicit about this, saying
are really the key would only produce failure and frus- “farmers in Taiwan do not stand out as having
tration. Nonetheless, if possibilities for construction unusual levels of trust and solidarity.” This is not to
exist, they should be exploited. say that solidary community ties are irrelevant to the
The most obvious endowment that might set limits local functioning of the irrigation system. Water
on synergy is the stock of social capital within civil guards and imgation group leaders could not perform
society, but there are others. The relevant properties of their functions in the absence of supportive commu-
government institutions may take decades or genera- nity norms. The point is rather that such community
tions to change, in which case they are best considered norms are probably no stronger in Taiwan than they
as endowments. Likewise, basic, hard-to-change fea- are in Nepal, where irrigation is a much more prob-
tures of the social structure, like the degree of inequal- lematic affair.
ity, may put synergy out of reach for certain societies. The same argument applies even more strongly
The possibility of synergy might be also precondi- to the Northeast of Brazil, which is the site of
tioned on the prior existence of particular kinds of both Ostrom’s and Tendler’s examples of synergy.
political regime. Singly or in combination such factors Neither Tendler’s rural communities nor the city
GOVERNMENT ACTION. SOCIAL CAPITAL AND DEVELOPMENT 1125

neighborhoods in Recife that are the site of Ostrom’s 162-163). The second, (CONASUPO) was even more
sewer condominiums are known as historically excep- surprising in its effects: “For one to two million of
tional repositories of civic engagement. Ethnographic Mexico’s most impoverished rural people, the food
descriptions suggest that the Northeast Brazil is as councils [created by CONASUPO] were among the
prone to conflict and suspicion as most areas of the first genuinely mass-based, regionwide representative
Third World. Nor, for that matter, did exceptional organizations of any kind” (Fox, 1994, p. 165). The
endowments of social capital appear to play a role in third cycle [PRONASOL] continued the process of
the successful Vietnamese Grameen-type bank men- “‘objective alliance’ between social movements and
tioned earlier. In all of these cases, cooperative patterns reformists” (Fox, 1994, p. 165) through which
of interaction among friends, kin or neighbors no doubt reformist social programs “offered political and eco-
antedate and facilitate particular instances of synergy, nomic resources that fostered the consolidation of
but the stock of social capital is not exceptional. growing representative and autonomous social orga-
Heller makes the point more forcefully. Disputing nizations” (Fox, 1994, p. 177)
analyses which see Kerala’s extraordinary levels of Fox’s reformists in the state apparatus support and
contemporary mobilization as the result of the area’s transform mobilized groups in civil society much in
historic “proliferation of community associations,” the same way (if not as thoroughly and unreservedly)
Heller argues that traditional associations based on as party activists and their government allies did in
caste and community ties could never have produced Kerala. Rural Mexico is not, however, Kerala. While
the kind of developmental transformation that Kerala parts of the state were “coproducing” autonomous
has experienced. In fact, as he points out the natural associations of rural peasants, other parts of the state
outcome of a “vigorous civil society rooted in inter- were working with rural elites to suppress the same
ests bounded by parochial loyalties” is not develop- organizations. Reformists were always engaged in an
ment but the kind of “demand overload’ that has been implicit or explicit struggle against politically author-
such a crippling problem for India as a whole. itarian groups within the state apparatus and their pri-
Kerala’s tradition of caste and community activism vate allies. The state of Chiapas offered a parlicularly
provided a useful foundation for subsequent mobiliza- telling example. Threatened by the state reforms in the
tion, but in order to produce the results that were National Indigenous Institute (INI), “ the governor
achieved the activist tradition had to be harnessed to a jailed three top IN1 officials on trumped-up charges of
more universalistic set of identities. Translating social fraud.” Seeing their state allies in jail, “Autonomous
ties from engines of parochial loyalties into vehicles indigenous organizations marched to defend them”
for more encompassing forms of organization was the (Fox, 1994,~~. 175-176).
real key to synergy. None of these examples negate the importance of
Fox places the strongest emphasis on historical micro-level social capital in the construction of
endowments of social capital, noting that “the overall synergy. Ties among friends and neighbors based on
degree of survival of horizontal community organiza- trust and rooted in everyday interactions are essential
tion and norms of reciprocity in indigenous Mexico is foundations. Without them there would be nothing
quite remarkable.” Nevertheless, Fox, like Heller, to build on. The key point is that such ties seem to be
emphasizes that the key problem is not social capital a resource that is at least latently available to most
at the level of local communities but rather “scaling- Third World communities. Based on these cases, it
up” such personal and community ties to form organi- seems reasonable to argue that if synergy fails to
zations that can be developmentally efficacious. To be occur, it is probably not because the relevant neigh-
politically effective, Fox argues, autonomous peasant borhoods and communities were too fissiparous and
organizations have to have a regional scope, bringing mistrustful but because some other crucial ingredient
internally solidary communities together with a broad was lacking.
set of other villages who share similar interests. The most obvious candidate for the missing ingre-
As in Heller’s case, Fox points to the role of state dient is a competent, engaged set of public institu-
actors in translating local networks into developmen- tions. If synergy can regularly emerge out of commu-
tally relevant “scaled-up” organizations. Just as in nities that seem quite ordinary in terms of their stock
Kerala, “reformists” within the state apparatus were of social capital, but governments vary dramatically in
crucial to the process of translating parochial loyalties terms of their ability to act as counterparts in the cre-
into more encompassing forms of organization. Fox ation of developmentally effective civic organiza-
recounts an iterative pattern of interaction between tions, then perhaps the limits to synergy are located in
state social policy initiatives and social mobilization. government rather than in civil society. Fox’s
Each round brought higher levels of popular mobiliza- Mexican case shows that even a somewhat schizo-
tion. In the first case (PIDER) state-sponsored rural phrenic government apparatus can occasionally pro-
development organizations “successfully organized duce instances of synergy, but the character of the
peasant protest against regional bosses for broader state apparatus may still be the weak link in the gener-
distribution of credit and fertilizer” (Fox, 1994, pp. ation of synergistic relations.
1126 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Government organizations vary fundamentally attention has been paid to the traditional Weberian
across countries in ways which shape the possible requisites of bureaucratic organization. Public institu-
forms of state-society relations. The nature of the con- tions are characterized by traditional Weberian fea-
nection is, however, less obvious than it might appear. tures such as meritocratic recruitment, good salaries,
There are at least two competing perspectives on what sharp sanctions against violations of organizational
kind of government organization makes for the most norms and solid rewards for career-long performance.
effective relations between state and society. Some Corruption is still common, but it has not been
analyses focus on the importance of corporately allowed to overwhelm the joint public-private project
coherent Weberian bureaucracies in making sure that of industrialization.
embeddedness does not degenerate into clientelism Cases in which traditional bureaucratic forms are
(e.g., Evans, 1995). Others focus on the importance of vehicles for synergy must, of course, be juxtaposed
decentralization and opening up bureaucratic hierar- with the more familiar story in which bureaucracy is
chies to inputs from below. There is support for both the enemy of both social capital and development.
perspectives in the material considered here and some Ostrom’s story of Nigerian primary education is a
hints as to how the two views might be reconciled. paradigmatic example, so much so that it worth
Undoubtedly, the absence of coherent, dependable breaking down this case of “anti-synergy” into its
public institutions makes synergy harder. Burawoy’s constituent elements. To begin with, there is no com-
analysis of the demise of the woodworking conglomer- plementary. Bereft of resources itself, the state pro-
ate in Komi illustrates the point. The demolition of the vides little in the way of tangible support local public
Russian state left the woodworkers of Komi without institutions. To make matters worse, bureaucratic
an effective public sector countetpartrO Consequently, organization, instead of being used as the rationale
self-organization moved in the opposite direction from for a liberating hierarchical division of labor, as in the
the trajectory that Heller reports from Kerala. Divisive Taiwanese case, is interpreted as demanding a uni-
interests prevailed and the gains from interdependency form, simplistic application of inflexible rules which
were ignored. Whatever social capital existed in the leave no room for initiative or imagination on the part
prior woodworking conglomerate was dissipated and of either local officials or their counterparts in civil
individual companies were left to the mercy of global society. This kind of bureaucracy eliminates the pos-
commodity markets. The Chinese case makes the con- sibility of synergy.
verse point. While Russia’s government was dissolv- On reflection, this crude exercise of bureaucratic
ing into disarray, China’s retained sufficient coherence power is, like the absence of material benefits, an
to purposefully restructure the system of incentives at indication of the state’s poverty - in this case its
the local level in a way that promoted self-organization organizational poverty. Uniformity is the simplest
and entrepreneurship. rule; constructing the kind of intricate interplay of
The civic advantages of having a coherent govem- hierarchy and latitude that characterizes a Taiwanese
ment bureaucracy are conveyed even more clearly in irrigation association requires much more capacity
Lam’s analysis of Taiwanese irrigation. A tightly and sophistication. The overcentralized Nigerian edu-
organized and quite traditional bureaucratic hierarchy cation ministry actually demonstrates the same lesson
provides a supportive carapace for the self-organiza- as the East Asian cases. Robust, sophisticated public
tion of the farmers. The robustness of government institutions are an advantage both in the formation of
organization gives the farmers confidence that the local social capital and in the pursuit of developmen-
higher levels of the apparatus will in fact deliver the tal ends, not because they are instruments of centaliza-
water they have been promised and increases the tion but because they are capable of formulating more
incentive for forward-looking cooperation at the local nuanced ways of distributing power and therefore of
level. At the same time, a well worked-out hierarchi- supporting decentralization and openness to local self-
cal division of labor within the bureaucracy leaves organization.
farmers and local officials free to work out their prob- Another aspect of the Taiwan/Nigeria contrast
lems as the local level without interference from takes the analysis down a different road. Alongside
above. the question of bureaucratic structures and rules there
The importance of robust bureaucratic structures is is the question of public sector attitudes. Ostrom sug-
amplified in analyses of East Asian industrialization. gests that one of the reasons public bureaucracies are
When individual officials are enmeshed in a set of ineffective is that “Public sectors typically rely on
close relations with elites who command vast private incentive systems that send very weak signals about
resources, attractive opportunities for rent-seeking are performance to staff. ..” Put another way, many public
inevitable. Unless such opportunities are constrained bureaucracies give public sector workers little reason
by powerful internal norms and a dependably reward- to pay attention to the people they are serving. While
ing system of longterm career benefits, corruption is the articles I am drawing on here do not contain much
indeed likely to become the prime consequence of direct evidence on the attitudes of public sector staff
embeddedness.lr In the East Asian cases, careful toward the communities they work withJ2 gross
GOVERNMENT ACTION. SOCIAL CAPITAL AND DEVELOPMENT 1127

differences are. evident. In Kerala there is a strong Before accepting unreservedly the idea that politi-
identification of party and state offtcials with their cal competitiveness enhances synergy, some caveats
constituents. In the East Asian cases constituents are are in order. First, in order for political competition
also important. Lam reports that “the image that to have positive effects, it must be constrained by
farmers are the boss of the IA is very clear in the minds mutually accepted ground rules that channel political
of IA offtcials. The importance of private sector entre- energies into efforts at mobilization or attempts to
preneurs to the bureaucrats that worked with them in convince the citizenry of governmental efficacy.
creating the East Asian miracles goes without saying. Second, there is an interaction between the adminis-
In Ostrom’s discussion of Nigerian primary education, trative issues discussed above and the consequences
on the other hand, bureaucratic behavior radiates indif- of political competition. Incentives derived from
ference. Finally, in Fox’s Mexico, it is clear that, in the political competition are hard to actualize without an
eyes of a large number of state officials, non-elite con- adequate administrative infrastructure. Finally, the
stituents are the enemy. This range of attitudes is not incentives generated by political competition are not
just a reflection of differences in administrative struc- necessarily the most salient factor in motivating
tures or governmental competence. It is a reminder that specific efforts to “coproduce” particular goods or
we cannot analyze synergy without considering ques- services. I will start with the motivations of public
tions of politics and interests. sector workers and work back to the question of
Politics and interests often get relegated to the “rules of the game ,”
background in discussions of social capital. Most dis- At least in the cases examined here, the public sec-
cussions implicitly assume a group, relatively homo- tor workers who build the social and organizational
geneous in terms of its interests, whose members must infrastructure of synergy “on the ground” appear more
overcome collective action problems in order to real- motivated by a desire to realize their own organiza-
ize their shared interests. Shared norms of trust and tional objectives than by an interest in preserving the
cooperation are a means of overcoming the collective standing of a particular party or faction. The satisfac-
action problems. If a community is riven by conflict- tions of the Brazilian engineer that designed the con-
ing interests, the nature and meaning of social capital dominium sewer idea were technocratic rather than
becomes more complicated. political. Tendler’s health care workers, extension
The idea of synergy, as it has been developed to agencies and small business consultants did not see
this point, implicitly takes the assumption of homoge- the payoff to their efforts as justified primarily by their
neous interests further by assuming that public sector impact on the interests of a particular political faction.
actors share interests with their constituents. In fact, The technocrats in Japan’s MIT1 or Taiwan’s
the degree to which interests are shared across the Industrial Development Bureau could hardly be more
public-private divide varies substantially from case to different from Tendler’s health agents but they share a
case and plays a central role in determining the poten- relative disinterest in contributing to the political
tial for synergy. Introducing the question of conflict- advantage of particular political factions.
ing interests raises in turn the question of whether con- None of this is to say that political competition
flicts are fought out in open political competition or conveys no benefits to public officials and organiza-
contained by repression. Political regimes no less than tions trying, for whatever reason, to deliver services.
bureaucratic structures condition the possibility of Political competitiveness is useful first of all because
synergy and social capital formation. The question of it contributes to a climate in which citizens count. The
political competition is the best place to begin the dis- effective delivery (or coproduction) of public services
cussion. is only valued if citizens reactions make a difference
In the cases reviewed here, political competitive- in the eyes of government leaders. In short, political
ness seems to have a salutary effect on possibilities for competition helps mitigate what the Ostrom calls
synergy. Heller emphasizes the centrality of persistent “signals problem” that has already been mentioned.
political competitiveness in sustaining the commit- Finally, political competition is important because it
ment of parties (whether in or out of government) to helps check the ability of individual members of the
mobilization and the construction of encompassing eliter to interfere with efforts to foster social capital
organizations among subordinate groups. Tendler among the less privileged.
emphasizes the connection between the reinitiation of Just as the presence of engaged public agencies
democratic elections in Brazil and the government of may allow synergy to proceed in concrete cases inde-
Cearii’s new-found enthusiasm for building connec- pendently of incentives generated by political compe-
tions with common citizens. Even in the Taiwanese tition, the positive possibilities that flow from political
case, Lam argues that, despite one-party rule at the competitiveness are likely to be sterile if public insti-
national level, political competitiveness (among fac- tutions are organizationally incapable of delivering
tions) is quite pervasive at the local level and helps to what people need. Post-soviet Russia allows more
generate pressure on the IA’s to remain responsive to political competition than China, but the ineffectual
the interests of local communities. Russian state provides no dependable vehicle to
1128 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

“deliver the goods.” Individual state officials have no the source of sharp conflicts around the management
reason to believe either that their efforts will produce of irrigation.
the intended effects, or that producing the intended Kerala post-land reform is also exceptionally egal-
effects will be rewarded by their superiors. In short, itarian. This point has been made repeatedly with
without an effective administrative apparatus, the respect to agriculture. Heller extends it to industry. He
more positive orientation toward citizens associated points out that one of the things that makes industrial
with political competition is hard to translate into relations in Kerala exceptional is that the vast gap that
results. in the rest of India separates the organized sector from
The rules of the game issue is perhaps most impor- the informal sector has been largely closed in Kerala.
tant caveat with regard to political competition. As Gaps among different categories of workers within
Fox underscores, entrenched elites (inside and outside each sector have also been substantially narrowed. In
of government) are likely to interpret increased politi- such a context, generalized mobilization and the con-
cal competitiveness as a threat and respond with struction of synergistic relations with the state flour-
repression. Without that quintessential complemen- ish, in sharp contrast to the rest of India where, as
tary good - the rule of law, - private thugs and offi- Heller puts it, “A fragmented and dependent labor
cial means of repression commandeered for particu- movement has spawned atomized and disaggregated
laristic ends become the principal tools of political strategies and...labor management relations in general
competition. Unless force and corruption can be made have become increasingly chaotic and ungovernable.”
marginal to the repertoire of competitive strategies, These cases replicate on a societal scale what is
increased political competition has perverse effects. also true in microcosm in the more specific studies of
Once again, Kerala provides a nice counterpoint to Ostrom and Tendler. The societal context of Northeast
rural Mexico. In Mexico the official means of Brazil is starkly inegalitarian, but the groups which
violence are routinely diverted to pursue essentially become organized and connected to state initiatives in
private ends. In Kerala, despite the anti-Communist the examples offered by Ostrom and Tendler share
bias of the national government of India, the Indian similar circumstances and problems. In Tendler’s
state was unwilling to allow Kerala’s landlords to rural communities and Ostrom’s urban neighbor-
commandeer the official means of violence to coun- hoods, the constituencies involved share relatively
teract mobilization. Class warfare was fought on the homogenous interests with respect to the problems
terrain of ideology and organization, which meant they are trying to solve.13
positive spillovers for both social capital formation To the extent that egalitarian social structures
and synergy. facilitate synergy, social structure may be an impor-
The forms and nature of political competition tant obstacle to constructing synergistic relations,or at
depend, of course, not only on the effective normative least in constructing such relations with subordinate
context but also on the nature of underlying social groups. Unfortunately, rural Mexico is more typical
conflicts. Looking at the cases under review here, it is than rural Taiwan or Kerala. In most Third World
clear that a relative equality of circumstances is an countries, the interests of the privileged intrude funda-
advantage, not just in building social capital, but also mentally on relations between the state and less privi-
in creating societal foundations for synergistic rela- leged groups. The ways in which public officials deal
tions with the state. From Taiwan to Kerala, relatively with elites and the conflicting interests that separate
egalitarian social structures are as much of an advan- elites from the rest of the citizenry have to be factored
tage for synergy as is political competitiveness. into the equation.
Taiwan enjoys, of course, one of the lowest Gini In rural Mexico, Fox sees the state apparatus as
indexes in the Third World and its rural sector is generally allying itself with private elites at the
internally more egalitarian than the overall society. expense of the peasantry. What needs to be explained
Building solidary organizations oriented toward then is why, even in this class-divided society, there
increasing output in an agricultural sector “mainly are so many significant exceptions in which state
comprised of small family-owned farms” where actors ally themselves with subordinate groups. Why
landlords have “virtually disappeared” (Lam), is a are there “reformists” who foster social capital forma-
qualitatively different task than trying to do the same tion among the oppressed, not just in opposition to the
thing in rural Mexico where large landowners domi- interests of landowners, but at some risk to their own
nate an excluded peasantry. There are economically positions within the government?
advantaged “local notables” in Taiwanese farming To begin with, state actors interested in changing
communities, but their income and status do not the status quo need allies in civil society. For public
derive from controlling the land or labor of their officials who harbor visions of changing the societies
neighbors. Instead, they are likely to see their neigh- they govern, building synergistic ties with subordinate
bors as a potential political base. Lam contrasts this groups may be the best way of circumventing the
situation with the typical South Asia context where power of entrenched elites. Conversely, ties to the
divisions between rich and poor agriculturalists are state give communities that are powerless new lever-
GOVERNMENT ACTION. SOCIAL CAPITAL AND DEVELOPMENT 1129

age in their conflicts with local elites. Fox (1992) lays social structures depend on people’s perceptions of
out this possibility in his discussion of the “sandwich themselves and their neighbors and that these perceg
strategy,” in which reformists within the state appara- tions are malleable. Social identities are constructed
tus and autonomous civic organizations outside it ally and reconstructed on a regular basis and can be recon-
with each other in a mutual struggle against local structed in ways that enhance prospects for synergy.
defenders of the status quo both inside and outside of This possibility lies at the heart of the kind of “scaling-
the state apparatus. Tendler describes an analogous up” process that Fox and Heller emphasize. In Mexico,
dynamic. In Ceara, “reformists” at the level of state villagers who define their interests in terms of defend-
government gave public sector workers and citizens in ing traditional land rights against infringements by
local communities leverage to counter the power of neighbors in adjacent villages can also see themselves
local political bosses. as peasants who need to cooperate with other commu-
Ties to the less privileged are attractive for another nities in order to defend themselves against landown-
related reason. For “normal” Third World states that ers and the impersonal forces of commodity markets.
lack the kind of powerful, autonomous bureaucracies In Kerala, members of particular subcastes and reli-
that enabled East Asian industrializers to create syner- gious communities can also see themselves as landless
gistic ties with entrepreneurial groups, clientelistic laborers who need to unite across caste and community
capture is the natural consequence of tight public-pri- boundaries in order to get out from underneath the
vate ties involving elites. Ties with the poor and pow- indignities of feudal patron-client relations. New defi-
erless are much less threatening to the institutional nitions of identity and interest have to be built on new
integrity of state organizations. Indeed it might be experiences and interaction, but they can be con-
argued that one of the prime advantages of mobilizing structed in years rather than decades or centuries.
ordinary citizens is that mobilization helps balance the The second aspect of constructability worth under-
inevitable ties with elites and thereby protects the scoring is that “soft technologies” of organizational
integrity of the state as an institution. design can have large effects. Tendler’s careful analy-
Overall, looking at the political and social struc- sis of the “spill over” effects of the methods used in
tural factors positively associated with synergy is recruiting agents for Cearl’s heath care program is an
somewhat discouraging. If egalitarian societies with excellent case in point (Tendler, forthcoming; see also
robust public bureaucracies provide the most fertile Tendler and Freedheim, 1994). The intricate ways in
ground for synergistic state-society relations, most of which hierarchy and latitude are combined in
the Third World offers arid prospects. Since highly Taiwanese irrigation authorities offer a more complex
inegalitarian social structures presided over by fragile, illustration of how organizational details make a dif-
fragmented government apparatuses are the general ference. One simple example of the importance of
rule, it is no wonder that most studies of state-society organizational form is the choice between keeping
relations abound in negative examples. Having begun staff in the same local area or transferring them. In
by rejecting the pessimistic proposition that only areas India frequent shifts were instituted with the intention
with exceptional endowments of social capital would of insulating the irrigation bureaucracy and ended up
be able to enjoy the benefits of synergy, I seem to have creating a pervasive system of corruption (see Wade,
fallen into an equally pessimistic appraisal based on a 1985). In Taiwan, insulation was secured by other
different set of arguments. The conclusion seems means so that permanent placement of local staff
bleak given the relatively optimistic cases from which could be used to enhance embeddedness in local com-
it is derived. It is time to reassess the idea of con- munities.14
structability. Does it still seem possible that synergy Finally, constructing synergy can begin with sim-
can be constructed out of small-scale changes imple- ple redefinitions of problems. Ostrom’s sewer exam-
mented in relatively compressed periods of time, even ple is a fine case in point. The innovative organiza-
in adverse environments? tional form of the sewer condominium depended first
Constructability looks less out of reach if we focus of all on reconceptualizing “sewers” as consisting of
on the content of particular synergistic successes. two different, complementary kinds of construction.
They suggest that even when the social and political From there it was possible to formulate a set of syner-
context is inauspicious, creative cultural and organi- gistic relations based on “coproduction.” To take
zational innovations can still produce results. another, very different, example, a key element in
Sometimes building synergy depends on transforming allowing synergistic relations of “local state corpo-
established worldviews. Sometimes it involves intro- ratism” to emerge in China was the fiscal redefinition
ducing innovative “soft technologies” at the organiza- of local governments as the residual claimants on
tional level. Sometimes it involves simply rethinking increases in local profits.
the nature of the problem that a government agency is The effects of specific innovations are not context-
trying to address. Any of these strategies can make free. Anyone who plucks what appears to be a very
synergy constructable. effective sot3 technology out of the setting where it
The first cornerstone of constructability is that was developed and inserts it in a different sociopoliti-
1130 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

cal context is running a risk. Nonetheless, contexts are institutional basis for realizing it. Most examples of
not immutable. Specific innovations depend on con- synergy involve concrete ties connecting state and
text for their effects, but they also change the contexts society which make it possible to exploit comple-
in which they are introduced. The effectiveness of menu&ties. Norms of trust built up from intimate
Kerala’s Industrial Relations Committees (IRCs) interaction are not restricted to relations within civil
depended on the preexisting context of labor relations, society. People working in public agencies are closely
but IRCs also helped change that context in a way that embedded in the communities they work with,
enabled Kerala to take better advantage of the human creating social capital that spans the public-private
and social capital it had amassed over the years. Even divide.
if contextual properties of different settings remain Pre-existing endowments of social capital are
unchanged, they may still be sufficiently similar to valuable resources in the construction of synergistic
make organizational innovations transplantable. relations, but they do not appear to be the decisive
Ostrom notes, for example, that the effectiveness of scarcity. Communities that enjoy the benefits of syn-
condominium sewer systems is not confined to ergy do not necessarily enjoy exceptional prior
Northeast Brazil but has transplanted well to Kenya, endowments of social capital. More crucial in practice
Paraguay and Indonesia. There is every reason to is the question of “scaling up” existing social capital
believe that synergy is constructable. The trick is to to create organizations that are sufficiently encom-
temper the optimism inherent in a constructability per- passing to effectively pursue developmental goals.
spective with the legitimate pessimism of contextual A competitive political system helps overcome
constraint. Small-scale successes can be achieved barriers to synergy, as long as the means of competi-
even in divided societies without robust public institu- tion are constrained by some set of mutually recog-
tions; generalizing them is more difficult. Even in nized rules. Egalitarian social structures and robust
small-scale efforts, it would be foolish to ignore bureaucracies also facilitate its emergence. The rarity
adverse sociopolitical circumstances. Still, prudence of this combination of circumstances in the Third
should not be an excuse for paralysis. In the end, World does not, however, make joint state-society
ignoring the evidence of returns to enterprising and projects unattainable chimeras. Small-scale successes
imaginative efforts to construct synergy is probably a are constructable even within broader contexts that are
worse mistake than underestimating the sociopolitical adverse. Even in class-divided societies suffering
obstacles to be overcome. under disorganized, authoritarian governance, innov-
ative institutional tactics can foster synergy on a lim-
ited scale.
4. CONCLUSION The vision of synergy that has been presented here,
however preliminary, has strong implications for both
The value of synergistic strategies is evident. theory and practice. Theoretically, it reinforces the
Creative action by government organizations can fos- call for an approach to development that is framed in
ter social capital; linking mobilized citizens to public the broadest institutional terms. Nothing else will cap-
agencies can enhance the efficacy of government. The ture the complicated interactions among social identi-
combination of strong public institutions and orga- ties, informal norms and networks and formal organi-
nized communities is a powerful tool for develop- zational structures that are involved creating synergy.
ment. Better understanding of the nature of synergistic For explanations of development to continue to
relations between state and society and the conditions exclude such institutional factors because they do not
under which such relations can most easily be con- lend themselves to “well-behaved growth models” is
structed should become a component of future theo- inexcusable. Synergy is too potent a developmental
ries of development. tool to be ignored by development theories. Like
Synergy usually consists of a combination of com- social capital, it magnifies the socially valued output
plementarity and embeddedness. Active citizens are that can be derived from existing tangible assets
hamstrung unless their governments dependably sup- but requires minimal material resources in its own
ply them with inputs that they cannot produce on their creation.
own. These range from lumpy tangible products such On the practical side, this analysis implies that
as dams to essential intangibles such as the rule of law. those interested in fomenting social capital, even
Citizens contribute local knowledge and experience among groups that are normally excluded and
that would be prohibitively costly for outsiders to oppressed, should not automatically assume that “the
acquire. As the beneficiaries of the final product com- state is the enemy.” The state may often be the enemy,
munity members can also contribute their time at but only in exceptional circumstances is it monolithi-
implicit wages that public employees should not be cally the enemy. Even in relatively authoritarian
forced to match. These obvious complementarities regimes, alliances with “reformists” within the state
provide a potential basis for synergy. Comple- can offer resources to popular organizations that are
mentarities create the potential but do not provide an unavailable anywhere else. The implications for
GOVERNMENT ACTION, SOCIAL CAPITAL AND DEVELOPMENT 1131

“reformists” working with or inside governments are, research on positive cases. There are many innovative
as we would expect, complementary. The image of the efforts that cross “the great public-private divide,” but
good bureaucrat - carefully insulated from con- they are scattered. Innovators in one area are likely to
stituents - has its usefulness, but openness to the role be unaware of similar efforts elsewhere. Systematic
of the “coproducer,” whether of sewer systems or investigation and comparison of cases across diverse
social capital, may the best way to increase effective- sectors and contexts would be a boon to those in
ness and ultimately the best way to preserve the search of “soft technologies” to apply to concrete
integrity of increasingly besieged public institutions. problems. Research has an important role to play in
Finally, there are implications for researchers. diffusing the idea that synergy is a real possibility for
While is it always fun and often useful to expose the Third World countries trying to enhance the welfare
perfidies of public sector actors, this kind of news is of their citizens.
already in oversupply. What is needed is more

NOTES

1. It goes without saying that what often passes for the Report on 1 Year Implementation of the Project ‘Credit-
rule of law in Third World countries is simply the invocation Savings’ in Tan Chanh Hiep Commune Branch” (June
of universalism to mask using the repressive power of the 1994).
state in the interests of the powerful. Nonetheless, even an
flawed approximation of a universalistic rule of law is a 7. See, for example, Shanmugan (1991); Myrada (1992).
potent collective good from the point of view of the power-
less. 8. Indeed the analogies between the market-oriented
socialist version and the established capitalist version is
2. Tendler’s work draws in turn on the research of her striking. Oi (1992: 119), for example, notes that in the local-
students: Amorim (1993). Damiani (1993), Freedheim ities she studied,“The strategy of selective support of certain
(1993) and Ruth Wade (1993). enterprises is reminiscent of Japan’s administrative guid-
ance .”
3. InadditiontoLamseeaIsoMoore(1989,p.l741)who
says that Taiwan’s irrigation system “is widely admired and 9. The concepts of “coproduction” and synergy are very
is perhaps the most efficient in the world.” closely related. Taking about “coproduction” tends to focus
attention on outputs of goods and services, whereas “syn-
4. This kind of embeddedness is, as Thorbecke (1993) ergy” shifts attention more to the social and institutional
points out, a feature of Taiwan’s highly productive agricul- consequences of joint action across the public-private
ture more generally. The farmers’ associations which were a divide. Even in this respect, however, the difference is not
key institutional feature in original efforts to increase agri- clearcut. Fox, for example, talks about “coproduction” of
cultural productivity in Taiwan constituted “a good example social capital.
of a successful GONG0 (a hybrid organization blending
together characteristics of a GOvemment institution and a 10. Burawoy’s description of the coal miners of Vorkuta,
NGO)” (Thorbecke, 1993.p. 597). At theirorigins,tbe farm- on the other hand, show that higher levels of mobilization
ers’ associations were an arm of the government’s Joint can at least partially compensate for the decay of public
Commission for Rural Reconstruction and Development. institutions. The coal miners could not turn the tide of
The associations facilitated the ability of extension agents to “economic involution” but their exceptional levels of mobi-
channel the results of agricultural research to farmers. They lization did slow the pace of decline and give the community
were channels for supervised credit originating in the state more time to adjust.
apparatus as well as enabling joint buying of inputs and sell-
ing of outputs. 11. Unbridled individual maximization is not only detri-
mental to developmental performance but also undermines
5. “Mothers would not answer their knocks on the door, trust and social capital among the sectors of civil society that
or would hide their children when the agent crossed the are connected to the state. Instead of reinforcing the efficacy
doorstep” (Tendler, forthcoming, p. 59). of private sector associations and expanding their scope, it
encourages the primacy of individual ties to particular
6. This description is based on interviews done in Tan bureaucrats and undercuts associational life.
Chanh Hiep Commune, Hoc Mon District in August 1994
with local organizers of the credit scheme and loan recipi- 12. The discussion by Tendler and Freedheim (1994) of
ents plus the information contained in three brief reports health care workers in an exception.
produced by the IBR: “The Poverty Issue in Ho Chi Minh
City and the First Results of the Credit Savings Model” 13. Lack of invidious distinctions between local public
(December 1993); “Preliminary Report on Implementation sector workers and the constitutents of the projects they
of the Project ‘Credit Savings’ for the Poor - First Year - work on may also facilitate synergy. The local irrigation
Tan Chanh Hiep Commune” (May 1994) and “Preliminary officials in Taiwan are more economically secure than the
1132 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

average farmers, but their economic position probably lies agents are definitely the economic and political equals of the
somewhere in between the average farmer and the more people they serve.
affluent members of the communities they deal with. Lam
contrasts their poisition with that of the low-status patrollers 14. Wade (1982) makes the same point in contrasting the
in the South Asian context. Likewise, Tendler’s health organization of irrigation in Korea and India.

REFERENCES

Amorim, M6nica Alves, “Lessons on demand: Order and Oi, Jean, “Fiscal reform and the economic foundations of
progress for small fiis in Ceara, Brazil,” MA Thesis local state corporatism in China,” World Politics Vol.
(Cambridge, MA: Department of Urban Studies and 45,No. 1 (October 1992),pp. 99126.
Planning, MIT, May, 1993). Okimoto, Daniel, Bezween MZTZand the Market: Japanese
Amsden, Alice, Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrial Policy for High Technology, (Stanford, CA:
Zndustrialization (New York: Oxford University Press, Stanford University Press, 1989).
1989). Putnam, Robert, Making Democracy Work: Civic
Coleman, James, Foundations of Social Theory (Cam- Traditions in Modern Ztaly (Princeton, NJ: Princeton
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press [Belknap], 1990). University Press, 1993a).
Damiani, Octavia, ‘Learning from collective experience: Putnam, Robert, “The prosperous community,” American
Successful small farmer associations in northeast Prospect, No. 13 (Spring 1993b),pp. 35-42.
Brazil,” MA Thesis (Cambridge, MA: Department of Shanmugam, Bala, “Socio-economic development through
Urban Studies and Planning, MIT, June, 1993). the informal credit market,” Modern Asian Studies, Vol
Evans, Peter, Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial 25, Part 2 (May, 1991) pp. 209-225.
Transformation (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Tendler, Judith, “Tales of dissemination of small-farm
Press, 1995). agriculture: lessons for institution builders,” World
Fox, Jonathan, The Politics of Food in Mexico: State Power Development, Vol. 21, No. 10 (1993), pp.
and Social Mobifization. (Ithaca, NY: Cornell 1567-1582.
University Press, 1992). Tendler, Judith, Good Government in the Tropics
Fox, Jonathan, “The difficult transition from clientelism to (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, fortb-
citizenship: Lessons from Mexico,” World Politics, Vol. coming).
46,No.2(January 1994),pp. 151-184. Tendler, Judith, “Social capital and the public sector: the
Freedheim, Sarah, “Why fewer bells toll in CearP: Success blurred boundaries between private and public.” (Paper
of community health worker program in Ceara, Brazil.” presented to the American Academy of Arts and
MA Thesis, (Cambridge, MA: Department of Urban Sciences Conference of the Economic Development
Studies and Planning, MIT, June, 1993). Working Group, Social Capital and Public Affairs
Heller, Patrick, “The politics of redistributive development: Project (Cambridge, MA: May, 1995).
State and class in Kerala, India,” PhD dissertation Tendler, Judith and Sara Freedheim, “Bringing Hirschman
(Berkeley, CA: Department of Sociology, University of back in: a case of bad government turned good,” Ms.
California, Berkeley, November 1994). subsequent version published as “Trust in a rent-seeking
Johnson, Chalmers, MZTZ and the Japanese Miracle: the world: Health and government transformed in northeast
Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925-1975 (Stanford, CA: Brazil,” WorldDevelopment, Vol. 22,No. 12 (1994),pp.
Stanford University Press, 1982). 1771-1792.
Lam, Wai Fung, “Institutions, engineering infrastructure, Thorbecke, Erik, “Impact of state and civil institutions on
and performance in the governance and management of the operation of rural markets and nonmarket configura-
irrigation systems: The case of Nepal,” PhD dissertation tions,” World Development, Vol 21, No. 4 (1993). pp.
(Bloomington, IN: School of Public and Environmental 591-605.
Affairs and Department of Political Science, Indiana Wade, Robert, Irrigation andAgricultural Politics in South
University, 1994). Korea (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1982).
Moore, Michael P., “The fruits and fallacies of neoliberal- Wade, Robert, “The market for public office: Why the
ism: The case of irrigation,” World Development, Vol. Indian state is not better at development,” WorZd
17,No. 11 (1989),pp. 1733-1750. Development,Vol. 13,No.4(1985),pp.467497.
Myrada. The Myrada Z?xperience: Alternative Management Wade, Robert, Governing the Market: Economic Theory
Systems for Savings and Credit of the Rural Poor. and the Role of Government in Taiwan’s
(Bangalore, India: Myrada, 1992). Industrialization (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Nugent, Jeffrey B., “Between state, market and households: Press, 1990).
A neoinstitutional analysis of local organizations and Wade, Ruth, “Dry solutions for drought relief: Institutional
institutions,” World Development, Vol. 21, No. 4 innovations in relief delivery in Ceara, Brazil,” MA
(1993) pp. 623-632. Thesis (Cambridge, MA: Department of Urban Studies
O’Donnell, Guillermo, “On the state, democratization and and Planning, MIT, June, 1993).
some conceptual problems: A Latin American view with World Bank The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and
glances at some postcommunist countries,” World Public Policy (A World Bank Policy Research Report)
Development, Vol. 21, No. 8 (1993),pp. 1355-1369. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).

Вам также может понравиться