Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 41

Journal of Economic Literature 2019, 57(1), 3–43

https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20171452

Digital Economics†
Avi Goldfarb and Catherine Tucker*

Digital technology is the representation of information in bits. This technology has


reduced the cost of storage, computation, and transmission of data. Research on digital
economics examines whether and how digital technology changes economic activity.
In this review, we emphasize the reduction in five distinct economic costs associated
with digital economic activity: search costs, replication costs, transportation costs,
tracking costs, and verification costs. (JEL D24, D83, L86, O33, R41)

1.  What Is Digital Economics? economic models change as certain costs


fall substantially and perhaps approach zero.

D igital technology is the representation


of information in bits. This reduces the
cost of storage, computation, and transmis-
We emphasize how this shift in costs can be
divided into five types:

sion of data. Research on digital economics (i) Lower search costs


examines whether and how digital technol-
ogy changes economic activity. (ii) Lower replication costs
Understanding the effects of digital tech-
nology does not require fundamentally new (iii) Lower transportation costs
economic theory. However, it requires a dif-
ferent emphasis. Studying digital economics (iv) Lower tracking costs
starts with the question of “what is differ-
ent?” What is easier to do when information (v) Lower verification costs
is represented by bits rather than atoms?
Digital technology often means that costs Search costs are lower in digital environ-
may constrain economic actions. Therefore, ments, enlarging the potential scope and
digital economics explores how standard quality of search. Digital goods can be rep-
licated at zero cost, meaning they are often
­non-rival. The role of geographic distance
* Goldfarb: University of Toronto and NBER. Tucker: changes as the cost of transportation for dig-
Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of ital goods and information is approximately
Management and NBER. We thank Andrey Fradkin and
Kristina McElheran for helpful comments. We are grate- zero. Digital technologies make it easy to
ful to the Sloan Foundation for its support of the NBER track any one individual’s behavior. Last, dig-
Digitization Initiative, which built the research community ital verification can make it easier to certify
around which this review is based.

Go to https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20171452 to visit the the reputation and trustworthiness of any
article page and view author disclosure statement(s). one individual, firm, or organization in the

3
4 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

digital economy. Each of these cost changes affect prices and price dispersion. They affect
draws on a different set of w ­ ell-established product variety and media availability. They
economic models, primarily search, ­non-rival change matches in a variety of settings, from
goods, transportation cost, price discrimina- labor markets to dating. They have led to an
tion, and reputation models. increase in the prevalence of ­platform-based
Early research tested straightforward mod- businesses, and affected the organization of
els of lower costs. For example, the search some firms.
literature of the late 1990s and early 2000s We next turn to zero replication costs, which
built directly on earlier models by Diamond also affect pricing decisions including the
(1971) and Varian (1980). As we detail below, decision to provide a good for free. This has
empirical work emerged that found some enabled an increase in the provision of public
inconsistencies with the simple models, and goods such as Wikipedia, raising a number of
so richer models and empirical analysis of the new questions about the motivations for pro-
cost reductions developed to take account of viding such goods. Zero replication costs cre-
the subtleties of the digital context. ate challenges with respect to excludability.
Other authors have also emphasized the Copyright can enforce excludability by using
role of lower costs for digital economics the law to overcome the ­non-rival nature of
(e.g., Shapiro and Varian 1998; Borenstein the technology. Consequently, copyright has
and Saloner 2001; and Smith, Bailey, and become increasingly important to a variety of
Brynjolfsson 2001). Ellison and Ellison businesses and a core policy challenge related
(2005) discuss the implications of these lower to digitization.
search and transportation costs for indus- Because the cost of transporting infor-
trial organization with respect to increasing mation stored in bits is near zero, this has
returns, distance, and t­wo-sided markets. changed the role of p ­ lace-based constraints
Since their article, the digital ­economics liter- on economic activity, whether due to costs of
ature has grown to contribute to the econom- physical transportation or policy. Digitization
ics of crime, the economics of public goods, changes the ways governments can control
organizational economics, finance, urban the flow of information, from advertising
economics, labor economics, development restrictions to media blackouts.
economics, health economics, political econ- We then turn to examine a more recent
omy, media economics, public finance, and literature that has identified two other cost
international economics. In this sense, we changes: Tracking and verification costs.
view digital economics as a way of thinking Tracking costs are the costs associated with
that touches many fields of economics. connecting an individual person or firm with
In addition to applying across many fields, information about them. Low tracking costs
these shifts in costs have transformed many enable novel forms of price discrimination as
aspects of the economy. After providing a brief well as new ways to targeting advertising and
history of digital technology and the Internet, other information. At the same time, better
we discuss each of the cost changes associated tracking has made privacy a key issue, gen-
with digitization. In each section, we empha- erating a great deal of research and policy
size the key research questions that have discussion.
driven the area and how they have evolved, We conclude the discussion of cost
and relate them to policy where applicable. changes by detailing changes in verification
We begin with a discussion of the effect costs. The rise of online reputation sys-
of lower search costs, defined as the costs of tems has facilitated trust and created new
looking for information. Lower search costs ­markets. At the same time, such systems are
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 5

i­mperfect, and can serve as platforms for researchers also developed the particu-
fraud or discrimination. lar packet-switching standards that define
We finish by discussing the consequences Internet communication: the Transmission
of digitization for countries, regions, firms, Control Protocol/Internet Protocol (TCP/
and individuals. Digitization has affected IP). The National Science Foundation (NSF)
productivity, trade, the economic role of cit- began managing a network using that proto-
ies, domestic and international outsourcing, col in the 1980s, building a reliable infra-
consumer surplus, and how people spend structure that was relatively easy to adopt but
their leisure time. also restricted to researchers.
Privatization occurred between 1990 and
1995, leading to the modern commercial
2.  Digital Technology: A Brief History
Internet. The commercial Internet diffused
The history of modern computing begins quickly, with universities playing a key role
not with the Internet, but in 1945 with the in the diffusion process (Goldfarb 2006).
commercialization of technologies developed There was ­ near-universal availability and
during World War II (Ceruzzi 2003). These widespread adoption in the United States
first machines focused on rapid calculation by 2000 (Greenstein 2000).1 Over time, new
with little capacity for storing and retrieving technologies have been layered on top of
information. By the early 1950s, magnetic the basic TCP/­IP-based Internet, including
core memories enabled efficient digital infor- browsers, search engines, online shopping,
mation storage and perhaps the first real social networks, mobile communications
non-arithmetical benefit of representing
­ protocols, security standards, customer rela-
information in bits emerged: the lower mar- tionship management systems, and many
ginal cost of reproducing information. Over others. These technologies and others have
time, storage technology, software, and hard- enabled increased collection and use of data.
ware improved so that information processing During this process, there has been an
and reproduction became widespread. The open question of who should control vari-
software and hardware industries grew rap- ous aspects of commercial Internet activity,
idly (Ceruzzi 2003 and Campbell-Kelly 2004). given this historical context of decentral-
Limited communication between ization. Standards are often agreed upon
computers limited their effect on the through committees with representatives
economy. It was with the rise of the from industry and academia. Such standards
Internet—and with it, ­ low-cost, commer- have an influence on which technologies
cial, c­ omputer-to-computer communica- are widely adopted (Rysman and Simcoe
tion—that the representation of information 2008). Therefore, standards setting creates
in bits began to have a measurable effect winners and losers. Simcoe (2012) examines
on multiple markets. This rise was built on the incentives in standards development for
key inventions developed through US mili- one such standard-setting organization, the
tary funding in the 1960s and 1970s (Hafner Internet Engineering Task Force, demon-
and Lyon 1996 and Greenstein 2015). For strating that the commercialization of the
example, the Defense Advanced Research Internet slowed standards development due
Projects Agency (DARPA) funded the inven-
tion of packet switching, which breaks down
1 This rapid speed of diffusion proved useful for identi-
a long message into shorter messages that
fication in the empirical papers examining the effect of the
can be sent through the network and then Internet on regions, firms, and individuals that we discuss
reassembled upon receipt. ­DARPA-funded in the penultimate section.
6 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

to competing commercial interests. Given Therefore, a key theme in the history of


their importance, control of hardware and digital technology is a tension between open-
software standards has been controversial. ness and control. As we discuss below, this
Echoing this question of control, the tension is at the center of much of the digital
earlier literature on the economics of the policy literature with respect to copyright,
Internet focused on pricing the sending of privacy, and discrimination.
information and how it varies with intercon-
nection, competition, and the nature of the
3.  Reduction in Search Costs
content (­MacKie-Mason and Varian 1994).
In other words, there is a question about Search costs are the costs of looking for
the role of Internet service providers in con- information. Every information-gathering
trolling access. Laffont et al. (2003) empha- activity therefore involves search costs. The
sized how the need for interconnection can basic idea with respect to digital economic
affect prices and welfare. This literature activity is that it is easier to find and compare
emphasized network effects and the chal- information about potential economic trans-
lenges of interconnection (Cremer, Rey, and actions online than offline.
Tirole 2000; Besen et al. 2001; Laffont et al. At the beginning of the commercial
2001; and Caillaud and Jullien 2003). Internet, there was much discussion among
As data transmission became a key aspect economics researchers around how a dra-
of digital technology, the question of net matic reduction in search costs might trans-
neutrality has become a central research form the economy by reducing prices, price
and policy focus. Net neutrality means that dispersion, unemployment, vacancies, and
an Internet service provider should treat all inventories. Alan Greenspan argued that the
data in the same way; regardless of the con- information and communications technology
tent provider or content, companies cannot (ICT) revolution would reduce the severity
pay an Internet service provider to have of business cycles.2 The consequences of low
faster speeds. The net neutrality debate asks search costs were discussed in financial mar-
whether Internet service providers should kets (Barber and Odean 2001), labor markets
exercise control over content. Put differently, (Autor 2001), and retail markets (Borenstein
net neutrality is the norm that Netflix pays the and Saloner 2001 and Bakos 2001). The ideas
same to send a gigabyte of data to one of their in these papers have their roots in the early
customers as a small startup would pay to search literature, which modeled search
send data to the same customer. Internet ser- costs as the costs of gathering information
vices have had a historic norm of net neutral- (Stigler 1961, Diamond 1971, and Varian
ity, though this has been challenged in recent 1980). Reflecting this early focus and solid
years by Internet service providers and policy base of economic understanding, the liter-
makers in the United States and globally. The ature on the effects of lower digital search
net neutrality literature therefore empha- costs is more established than the other parts
sizes the role of the connection intermediary of the digital economics literature.
(Economides and Hermalin 2012; Bourreau,
Kourandi, and Valletti 2015; Choi, Jeon, and
Kim 2015; and Goetz 2017). As shown by Lee
and Wu (2009) and Greenstein, Peitz, and 2 “Information technology has doubtless enhanced
Valletti (2016), the particulars of the model the stability of business operations,” Federal Reserve
Chairman Alan Greenspan, February 26, 1997, testimony
matter, and the costs and benefits of net neu- before Congress. https://www.federalreserve.gov/board-
trality depend on the specific setting. docs/hh/1997/february/testimony.htm.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 7

3.1 Are Prices and Price Dispersion Lower and shipping policies. Firms with higher qual-
Online? ity may develop stronger brands and there-
Low search costs make it easier for con- fore command higher prices (Waldfogel and
sumers to compare prices, putting downward Chen 2006).
pressure on prices for similar products. This Firms selling products can also shape the
should reduce both prices and price disper- search process. When consumers search, they
sion. Brynjolfsson and Smith (2000) compare assess multiple dimensions of information:
prices of books and CDs at four ­Internet-only price, quality, reputation, shipping fees, time
retailers, four offline retailers, and four to delivery, color, etc. Lynch and Ariely (2000)
“hybrid” retailers who had both online and demonstrate this for online wine purchasing
offline stores. They identified twenty books in a laboratory. If price was available on the
and twenty CDs, half of which were best- first page, consumers focused on price. If con-
sellers and half of which were randomly sumers needed to click further to learn the
selected among titles popular enough to be price, other attributes became more import-
sold in most offline stores. They showed that ant for purchase decisions. Fradkin (2017)
online prices for these items were substan- shows that the details of the search process
tially lower than offline prices. Relatively low matter in the context of short-term accommo-
online prices have been shown in a variety of dation platform Airbnb. Structural estimates
other settings, including insurance (Brown of the cost of an extra click in the consumer
and Goolsbee 2002), automotive products search process suggest they are larger than
(Scott Morton, Zettelmeyer, and S ­ ilva-Risso might be supposed (Honka 2014 and De Los
2001), and airlines (Orlov 2011). Santos, Hortacsu, and Wildenbeest 2012).
However, though prices may be lower, This means that consumers stop searching
substantial price dispersion remains. sooner than predicted by models that assume
Brynjolfsson and Smith (2000) show this search costs close to zero.
in their o­nline–offline retail study. Baye, In the presence of search costs, and mul-
Morgan, and Scholten (2004) use evidence tiple dimensions of information, firms can
from thousands of products and prices partly choose which information has the low-
to document large and persistent online est search costs. Ellison and Ellison (2009a)
price dispersion. Orlov (2011) finds that demonstrate that computer memory chip
the Internet increases the intrafirm disper- retailers attract customers with low prices
sion of airline prices, but had no effect on at an online price comparison website, and
interfirm price dispersion. By contrast, the then show customers other (typically higher
development economics literature measur- quality and higher margin) products once
ing the effect of mobile phones on commod- they arrive. Using data from eBay, Dinerstein
ity prices suggests that lower search costs et al. (2018) emphasizes how the design of
reduced price dispersion (Jensen 2007; Aker the search algorithm on eBay affects mark-
2010; and Parker, Ramdas, and Savva 2016). ups charged by eBay sellers. More directly,
Given evidence of the persistence of price Hossain and Morgan (2006) show that online
dispersion online, research turned to explore sellers often hide shipping fees until the final
why price dispersion does not disappear. Of purchase page. Blake et al. (2018) shows a
course comparison of online products does similar phenomenon in the information
not always compare ­apples to apples. In com- revealed in ticket prices at an online ticket
paring book prices, the book may be the same, platform.
but the retailer is different. Different retailers Therefore, while prices have fallen,
offer different quality, shopping experiences, price dispersion has persisted. The initial
8 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

­ redictions of low price dispersion missed


p sold to everyone, while niche products are
the point that search costs are endogenous, sold through long-tail retailers. The increase
and so firms can manipulate the search pro- in tails at the right and left of the distribution
cess in order to sustain higher margins and comes at the cost of products in the middle.
prices. The degree to which search costs generate
more or less variety depends on the search
3.2 How Do Low Search Costs Affect
process endogenously chosen by the firm.
Variety?
Recommendation engines are a key aspect
Low search costs may mean that it is easier of the online search process. Fleder and
to find rare and niche products (Yang 2013). Hosanagar (2009) demonstrate this, show-
In this case, digital search might lead to an ing that algorithms that emphasize “people
increase in the proportion of sales going to who bought this also bought” move the sales
products that are relatively rarely purchased, distribution toward superstars. If many peo-
a phenomenon dubbed “the long tail” by ple buy Harry Potter, this recommendation
Anderson (2006). Using data from a retailer engine will recommend Harry Potter to
with both online and offline channels, everyone else. In contrast, if the algorithm
Brynjolfsson, Hu, and Simester (2011) doc- emphasizes “people who bought this dis-
ument that the variety of products available, proportionately bought,” relatively unusual
and purchased, online is higher than offline. items that demonstrate niche tastes will be
Low search costs may facilitate discovery of sold. Empirically, Tucker and Zhang (2011)
relatively unknown products (Zhang 2018).3 document that popularity information
Low search costs could also generate has asymmetrically large effects for niche
superstar effects (Rosen 1981). If there are products.
vertically differentiated products and the Popularity information affects sales in
marginal cost of production is zero, then general. Many online platforms sort items
homogeneous consumers will all agree by popularity and feature popularity prom-
which product is best and buy it. Consistent inently, reducing search costs for this type
with this, Goldmanis et al. (2010) show that of information. Showing such popularity
the Internet initially led to a relative increase information affects purchase behavior not
in the number of large offline bookstores and only in retail, but also online lending (Zhang
travel agencies. and Liu 2012) and online investing (Agrawal,
Bar-Isaac, Caruana, and Cunat (2012)
­ Catalini, and Goldfarb 2015).
explain how superstar and long-tail effects The effect on welfare of this change in
may result from a reduction in search costs. variety is not obvious, and so it has been
If products are both vertically and horizon- the subject of a rich discussion in the liter-
tally differentiated, a reduction in search ature. Lower search costs that lead people
costs may lead to an equilibrium where the to buy the products that more closely match
most popular and highest-quality products their preferences should increase welfare.
are produced in high enough quantity to be Consistent with this, Brynjolfsson, Hu, and
Smith (2003) show that increased variety
3 In addition to search costs, variety may increase
increases consumer surplus.
because digital technologies can make inventory systems At the same time, improvements in wel-
more efficient, meaning firms can hold millions of prod- fare may be small. The increase in matching
ucts, especially for digital goods that have no physical pres- of products to preferences is, by definition,
ence. People may also be less inhibited from purchasing
nonstandard items when purchasing on a screen, rather marginal. The new products offered are the
than from a human (Goldfarb et al. 2015). products on the margin of being produced.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 9

The superstar effects may be marginal rela- polarization of digital content because the
tive to the consumers who bought products increase in polarization is largest for demo-
in the middle because they were unwilling to graphic groups with the least Internet usage.
pay search costs. For example, Ershov (2017) Polarized media may be less concentrated,
shows that a reduction in search costs in the generating incentives for niche sources to
mobile app market reduced average product intentionally mislead. Allcott and Gentzkow
quality. On balance, however, it also shows (2017) show that false news stories about the
that the increase in variety led to a substan- 2016 presidential election were shared tens
tial increase in overall welfare despite the of millions of times, though they demon-
incremental nature of the new products. strate the fake news was unlikely to have
Aguiar and Waldfogel (2016) suggest that changed the election outcome. Long before
this marginal argument misses the substan- the attention to fake news in the 2016 elec-
tial uncertainty about product quality for tion, Antweiler and Frank (2004) examined
many information goods. In the context how anonymous, and potentially misleading,
of music, they show that several songs and online investing advice affects stock prices.
musicians that seem marginal ex ante ended Low search costs—in the absence of a reli-
up having substantial sales. Therefore, by able quality filter—meant that this informa-
enabling such music to get produced, digital tion could be more easily found and shared.
markets led to a large change in the relative Low online search costs have also trans-
sales of products. Uncertainty in the process formed the way academic research is con-
meant better and more music was created. sumed. McCabe and Snyder (2015) show
A great deal of attention has focused on that JSTOR led to an increase in citations
the increase in variety in consumption of of included articles at the expense of others.
media in particular. The Internet might also Search costs fell, but because they fell more
enable people to only read information that for some articles than others, it changed the
reflects their narrow viewpoint; despite the nature of attention to specific articles and
variety, there is no need to search widely. ideas. More starkly, Ellison (2011) argues
The latter idea has been emphasized by Cass that peer review may be in decline because
Sunstein as an “echo chamber” (Sunstein of low online search costs. In particular, he
2001). Consistent with the idea of wide vari- shows that ­high-profile researchers do not
ety available but consumption in echo cham- need to rely on academic journals to dissem-
bers, Greenstein and Zhu (2012) examine inate their ideas. They can post online and
the bias of Wikipedia and show that, while, people will find their work. In other words,
on aggregate Wikipedia has become less similar to the superstar effect in products,
politically biased (toward Democrats) over low search costs combined with thousands
time, the bias of articles has not changed of research articles benefit the superstar
much. Instead, the political bias has mainly researchers.
dropped because of the arrival of new, rela-
3.3 How Do Low Search Costs Affect
tively ­right-wing articles.
Matching?
By contrast, Gentzkow and Shapiro (2011)
show that Internet media consumption is Reduced search costs facilitate exchange
more varied than offline media consumption. more generally, often enabled by large dig-
Therefore, in this context, low search costs ital platforms. Dana and Orlov (2014) show
lead to increased variety. Boxell, Gentzkow, that airlines are better able to fill to c­ apacity.
and Shapiro (2017) argues that the Internet Ellison et al. (2014) show that online buy-
is unlikely to be responsible for increased ers are better able to find the specific books
10 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

they want. Kroft and Pope (2014) find online much of the research takes a market design
search through Craigslist decreased rental perspective. For example, Cullen and
­
apartment and home vacancies (though Farronato (2016) examine an online mar-
they measure no effect on unemploy- ketplace that matches buyers and sellers of
ment). Anenberg and Kung (2015) show domestic tasks, such as cleaning, moving,
that online search enabled the rise of a and simple home repair. They emphasize the
market for ­truck-based mobile restaurants challenges in growing both the demand and
(“food trucks”). To the extent that the liter- supply sides with respect to variation in the
ature emphasizing matching is distinct from quantity of buyers and sellers over time, econ-
search, the matching literature emphasizes omies of scale in matching, and geographic
that both sides of the market engage in the density. A key result is that demand fluctua-
search process. tions in this ­two-sided market lead to changes
Related to the above ideas, low search in quantity supplied rather than changes in
costs are likely to increase the quality of prices. Similarly, Hall, Kendrick, and Nosko
matches between buyers and sellers, firms (2016), Farronato and Fradkin (2018), and
and workers, etc. The labor economics lit- Zervas, Proserpio, and Byers (2017) also show
erature has emphasized that the Internet that the responsiveness in quantity supplied
should reduce unemployment and vacancies. to changes in demand conditions is a key
Kuhn and Skuterud (2004) find no effect of aspect of ­peer-to-peer platforms (specifically,
Internet job search on employment. Kuhn Uber and Airbnb). Low search costs provide
and Mansour (2014) revisit the analysis sev- market demand information that enables sup-
eral years later with updated data and find ply to enter the market when needed.
that individuals that used the Internet in job
3.4 Why Are Digital ­Platform-based
search were indeed more likely to match to
Businesses So Prevalent?
an employer.
The reduced costs of search have led to the Platforms are intermediaries that
development of online “peer-to-peer” plat- enable exchange between other players.
forms dedicated to facilitating matching. The Digitization has led to an increase in the
variety of such online matching markets is prevalence of platform businesses, even
extraordinary: workers and firms, buyers and beyond the p ­ eer-to-peer platforms discussed
sellers, investors and entrepreneurs, vacant above. Most of the major technology firms
rooms and travelers, charities and donors, can be seen as ­platform-based businesses.
dog walkers and dog owners, etc. Several of For example, Apple provides hardware and
these markets have been dubbed the “shar- software platforms for others to build appli-
ing economy” because people are able to use cations around. Google provides platforms
unused objects or skills better. Most “sharing for bringing together advertisers and poten-
economy” platforms are not sharing in the tial buyers.
sense learned by kindergarteners: custom- As highlighted in Jullien (2012), there are
ers typically pay for the “shared” services. two main reasons digital markets give rise to
Horton and Zeckhauser (2016) emphasize platforms. First, platforms facilitate match-
that many of these markets are driven by ing. In particular, as in the sharing economy
an unused capacity for durable goods. Low platforms, they provide a structure that can
search costs enable such unused capacity to take advantage of low search costs to create
be filled more efficiently. efficient matches. Often platforms serve as
In a review of the ­ peer-to-peer mar- intermediaries between buyers and sellers, as
kets literature, Einav et al. (2018) note that highlighted in Nocke, Peitz, and Stahl (2007)
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 11

and Jullien (2012). In the context of a central ­ istance. On the other hand, Garicano (2000)
d
role of matching, a rich theory literature has also shows that ­ low-cost communication
arisen that examines competition and pricing could decrease centralization by enabling
strategy in such platform businesses, with an ­front-line employees to access information
emphasis on the importance of indirect net- previously only available to senior employ-
work effects (for example Baye and Morgan ees at headquarters. A variety of papers have
2001, Caillaud and Jullien 2003, Weyl 2010, explored nuances in this trade-off within
Hagiu and Jullien 2011, and de Corniere organizations, emphasizing the importance
2016). of the particular technology studied.
Second, platforms increase the efficiency Bloom et al. (2014) test this theory directly,
of trade. They do this through lower search using data on European and American
costs as well as other aspects of digitization manufacturing firms to show that informa-
that we discuss below: low reproduction and tion technology is a centralizing force and
verification costs. Hagiu (2012) emphasizes communication technology is a decentral-
how software platforms enable application izing force. Acemoglu et al. (2007) also dis-
providers to serve a large number of cus- cuss the decentralizing role of information
tomers quickly, with the only requirement technology. For example, Forman and van
that the application serve some particular Zeebroeck (2012) shows that digital commu-
customer need, reproduce at zero cost, and nication increases in research collaboration
rely on the platform and the other applica- across establishments within an organization.
tions to serve other needs. Interoperability Baker and Hubbard (2003) examines the
is therefore a key aspect of platforms. There effect of ­on-board computers on asset own-
is a large literature on the topic, as reviewed ership in the trucking industry. They empha-
in Farrell and Simcoe (2012). A key contri- size tracking costs more than search costs
bution of this literature is the emphasis on and find that aspects of o­ n-board comput-
the strategic nature of decisions on interop- ing that improve monitoring pushed truck-
erability and standards (Rysman and Simcoe ing firms to more ownership of trucks while
2008 and Simcoe 2012). A related set of aspects of ­on-board computing that improve
questions examines whether market partic- real-time location information pushed
­
ipants will “­multi-home” and use multiple trucking firms to less ownership of trucks.
platforms (Rochet and Tirole 2003, Rysman Therefore, while adoption of digital tech-
2007, Halaburda and Yehezkel 2013). nology led to improved efficiency, the effect
on organization of the firm in equilibrium
3.5 How Do Low Search Costs Affect the
depends on the nature of the technology
Organization of the Firm?
and how its specific features affect trade-offs
­Lucking-Reiley and Spulber (2001) discuss between competing tensions at the bound-
several hypotheses with respect to the effect ary of the firm. McElheran (2014) examines
of the Internet on firm structure in terms of the decision to centralize or delegate IT
the role of online intermediaries and vertical adoption decisions within firms. Firms with
integration. This literature emphasizes infor- a greater need for integrated processes (dig-
mation flow generally, in which search is one ital or otherwise) delegate less. Forman and
key type of information flow. Garicano (2000) McElheran (2013) show that this tendency is
shows that ­low-cost digital information flow mitigated by the ease with which IT enables
could increase ­ centralization by enabling coordination across firms, so that disintegra-
headquarters, and organizational leaders, tion of the firm boundary can be seen as an
to understand better what is happening at a extreme form of delegation.
12 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

In addition to the effect on the domes- be shared without diminishing the original
tic boundaries of the firm, the reduction in information.
search costs (combined with the reduction In the absence of deliberate legal or tech-
in verification costs discussed below) has nological effort to exclude, bits can be repro-
also led to an increase in international hiring duced by anyone—not just the producing
and outsourcing. While international out- firm—at near zero cost without degrading
sourcing is not a new phenomenon (Leamer the quality of the initial good. As Shapiro and
2007), the recent rise of digital international Varian (1998, p. 83) put it, the Internet can
labor market platforms suggests a different be seen as a “giant, out of control copying
avenue for international hiring. Agrawal, machine.”
Lacetera, and Lyons (2016) show that online Nevertheless, the economics of zero mar-
platforms with standardized information dis- ginal cost, n
­ on-rival goods can shift things in
proportionately benefit workers from devel- favor of producers, consumers, or both. In a
oping countries. The objective information static model, as marginal costs fall the poten-
available online, combined with the ability to tial surplus rises, and so the welfare effect
send the output of the work (typically infor- depends on the final price and associated
mation such as data or software code) for free deadweight loss. The final price and dead-
over long distance helps workers who are far weight loss depend on legal and technological
from the buyer. Such online labor markets tools for exclusion (Cornes and Sandler 1986),
have several important challenges. Using which relate to the ability to track behavior—
data from online labor markets, Lyons (2017) the subject of a later section. In this section,
shows that c­ ross-cultural international teams we emphasize that the underlying technology
can be less productive because of commu- enables firms and governments to make a
nication challenges. Relatedly, Ghani, Kerr, choice not to exclude. This can allow individ-
and Stanton (2014) show that employers in uals to enjoy the full benefits of the ­non-rival
the Indian diaspora are more likely to hire nature of ­information-based goods.
Indians online.
4.1 How Can N ­ on-Rival Digital Goods Be
Priced Profitably?
4.  The Replication Cost of Digital Goods
The n­ on-rival nature of digital goods has
Is Zero
led to questions of how to structure pric-
The key shift in the production function ing of a large variety of n­ on-rival ­zero-cost
is not that digital goods have a marginal cost goods, should a producer choose to charge.
of zero. Simple microeconomic models with Bundling occurs when two or more products
zero marginal cost are not so different from are sold together at a single price (Shapiro
models with positive marginal cost. The and Varian 1998, Choi 2012). Bundling
demand curve slopes downward and firms models have a long history in economics.
price where marginal revenue equals zero. Stigler (1964) and Adams and Yellen (1976)
Instead, a key distinction between goods note that a sufficient condition for price dis-
made of atoms and goods made of bits is that crimination benefit of bundling arises when
bits are n
­ on-rival, meaning that they can be consumers have negatively correlated pref-
consumed by one person without reducing erences. Some people may value an action
the amount or quality available to others. A movie at $10 and a romance at $2. Others
common analogy for n ­ on-rival goods is that may value the romance at $10 and the action
just as one person can start a fire without movie at $2. Selling the bundle at $12 yields
diminishing another’s fire, information can higher profits than selling the action and
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 13

romance movies separately. The challenge of ­non-rival public digital goods are open-
for firms is to identify such negative correla- source software and Wikipedia. Both cases
tions in preferences to identify when bun- involve a deliberate decision not to exclude,
dling will increase profits. and applying established models is somewhat
Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999, 2000) rec- less straightforward than the bundling models
ognize that, under certain assumptions, with highlighted in the preceding subsection.
enough goods and independent preferences, Lerner and Tirole (2002) ask why software
this challenge is overcome. Furthermore, developers would freely share their code with
the ­non-rival nature of information goods no direct payment. They emphasize two core
means that large numbers of information benefits from open source that do not appear
goods can be bundled without substantially in standard models of public goods. For
increasing costs. Therefore, a simple and individual developers, providing high-qual-
useful insight on the economics of n ­ on-rival ity open-source code is a way to signal their
information goods is that it will sometimes skills to potential employers. For companies,
be optimal to bundle thousands of digital improving the quality of open source software
products together. may allow them to sell other services that
Chu, Leslie, and Sorensen (2011) use an are complementary to open-source software
empirical example to show that the intuition (such as hardware or consulting services)
of Bakos (1999) applies to relatively small at a premium. Underlying these core bene-
numbers of goods in the bundle. There are fits is the ­non-rival nature of the code: digi-
also strategic reasons to bundle because it can tal distribution through the Internet means
reduce competition (Carbajo, de Meza, and that (high-quality) open-source contributions
Seidmann 1990). When bundling has zero can be widely adopted. The literature on the
marginal cost, such strategic considerations economics of open source that followed has
can become particularly relevant (Carlton, largely supported their hypotheses of career
Gans, and Waldman 2010; Choi 2012). concerns and complementarity (Johnson
Despite the extensive theory work, it is only 2002; Bitzer and Schroder 2005; Mustonen
recently that empirical examples of such mas- 2005; Lerner, Pathak, and Tirole 2006; Henkel
sive bundles appeared in the literature, in the 2009; Xu, Nian, and Cabral 2016).
form of subscription services such as Netflix Wikipedia represents a different import-
for video and Spotify and Apple Music for ant context for the puzzle of why people
music. Aguiar and Waldfogel (2018) show that contribute to digital public goods. Zhang and
Spotify displaces sales but it also displaces Zhu (2011) emphasize social benefits related
“piracy,” or the downloading of music without to breadth of readership. In the context of
permission from the copyright holder. They Chinese-language Wikipedia, they show that
estimate that the reduction in sales and the users care about audience size, and decrease
increase in legal music consumption balance contributions when part of the audience is
each other so that Spotify appears to be reve- blocked due to Chinese government policy.
nue neutral in the ­2013–15 time period. Consistent with this idea of a social benefit,
Aaltonen and Seiler (2016) and Kummer,
4.2 What Are the Motivations for Providing
Slivko, and Zhang (2015) together provide
Digital Public Goods?
evidence for a virtuous circle in which more
Information providers can deliberately editing leads to more views and more views
decide not to exclude. It is somewhat of a lead to more editing. Contributions are likely
puzzle why private actors would choose to related to the interests of the contributors:
create public goods. Two prominent examples Wikipedia leaned sharply Democratic early
14 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

on and has gradually become more neutral (Gordon and Loeb 2002 and G ­ al-Or and
(Greenstein and Zhu 2012). Ghose 2005), especially if costly investments
Nagaraj (2016) suggests the potential for in data security also are a public good.
government sponsorship of digital public While digital technology creates public
goods. He finds that open mapping infor- goods, zero marginal cost of production can
mation led to a substantial increase in min- also create public bads, such as spam (Rao
ing activity, particularly for smaller firms and Reiley 2012) and online crime (Moore,
with fewer resources. Therefore, open data Clayton, and Anderson 2009). These have
enabled a wider set of participants to succeed. led to policy responses such as the US
More generally, the ­non-rivalrous nature Controlling the Assault of Non-Solicited
of digital technology could enable consum- Pornography And Marketing Act of 2003
ers and workers in developing countries to (CAN-SPAM). Another example of digital
access the same information as people in spam is junk telephone calls, the automation
developed countries, conditional on having of which has been enabled by digital technol-
access to the Internet. In the context of edu- ogies. Petty (2000) and Varian, Wallenberg,
cation, Kremer, Brannen, and Glennerster and Woroch (2005) evaluate the role of the
(2013) argue that information technology can federally sponsored “Do Not Call” list in pre-
improve pedagogy in the developing world. venting potentially intrusive direct sales calls
Underlying their argument is an emphasis and find positive effects.
on ­non-rival, ­non-excludable digital informa- That said, the economics of such bads
tion, and the public ­Internet-based posting are relatively straightforward. In contrast,
of educational materials. Correspondingly, the more challenging policy question for
Acemoglu, Laibson, and List (2014) empha- ­non-rival digital goods is whether the gov-
sizes that digital education will lead to a more ernment should intervene through copyright
equal distribution of educational resources. policy to enforce excludability despite the
There are, however, situations in which ­non-rival nature of the goods.
welfare may decrease because of a decision
4.3 How Do Digital Markets Affect
not to exclude digital goods from wide-
Copyright Policy?
spread copying. The decision not to exclude
­non-rival goods can reduce the incentives to As the Internet first diffused in the late
produce information goods, a subject we dis- 1990s, copyrights of music (and text) were
cuss below in the context of copyright pol- often ignored as people freely posted copy-
icy. It can also create negative externalities. righted goods online. Because of the ­non-rival
For example, Acquisti and Tucker (2014) nature of digital information, one posted
show that policies that mandate “open data” copyrighted item could be useful to millions
by government may lead to data leakages of people, potentially replacing sales. At the
(or privacy breaches) that affect individ- same time, music industry revenue began to
uals’ ­welfare offline. Openness, almost by fall (Waldfogel 2012a) and this was widely
definition, implies a reduction in privacy. blamed on changes brought by the Internet.
Relatedly, Acquisti and Gross (2009) show Optimal enforcement of copyright has
that using public data online makes it pos- therefore been a key focus of the digital eco-
sible to predict an individual’s social security nomics literature. The early work focused
number. This feeds back, in general, to the on the revenue consequences of free online
idea that while n ­on-excludability may be copying. This was referred to as “­file sharing”
attractive in principle, it can lead to ques- to those who believe it should be allowed,
tions of appropriate data security practices and as “piracy” by those who didn’t. The
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 15

direct effect of free online copying of media so quality rose. Results are similar in ­movies
is that revenues from the sale of copies of (Waldfogel 2016) and books (Waldfogel and
that media fall. At the same time, revenues Reimers 2015). This contrasts with the eco-
could rise if the free copies are merely sam- nomic history literature, which suggested that
pled and consumers buy what they like (Peitz copyright alone could increase the quality of
and Waelbroeck 2006). Revenues could also creative output (Giorcelli and Moser 2016).
rise for complementary goods like live per- In addition to affecting incentives to inno-
formances (Mortimer, Nosko, and Sorensen vate, digital challenges to copyright protec-
2012). Finally, revenues could rise if the free tion may affect incentives to build on prior
copies are limited to developing markets for work. Williams (2013) demonstrates this
products with network effects (Takayama point in a different intellectual property
1994). Empirically, though a small num- context and shows that intellectual property
ber of studies have found positive effects protections limit f­ollow-on innovation in

Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf 2007), most gene sequencing. Heald (2009) shows that
studies have found that free online copy- copyrighted music is less used in the movies
ing reduces revenues in music (Rob and than ­non-copyrighted music. Nagaraj (2018)
Waldfogel 2006, Zentner 2006, Liebowitz shows that copyright protection of old sports
2008, and Waldfogel 2010), in video (Rob and magazines reduces the quality of Wikipedia
Waldfogel 2007; Liebowitz and Zentner 2012; pages decades later. This phenomenon is
Danaher, Smith, and Telang 2014b; Danaher not unique to the digital context. Biasi and
and Smith 2014; and Peukert, Claussen, and Moser (2018) show that eliminating copy-
Kretschmer 2017), and in books (Reimers rights of German books during World War II
2016). This echoes a ­ non-digital historical led to a substantial increase in US scientific
literature (Li, MacGarvie, and Moser 2015; output, measured by PhDs in mathematics
and MacGarvie and Moser 2015) suggesting and patents that cited the German books.
a continuity between policy governing digital Another challenge for copyright policy
technologies and earlier policies. driven by the shift in costs of replication is that
How does copyright affect the creation of it has made it easier for other firms to repli-
new works? This is a more difficult research cate digital content and attempt to aggregate
question, as it requires some attempt to it. This practice has been particularly preva-
measure counterfactual quality and quan- lent in the news media, where policy makers
tity of goods had copyright law not existed have been encouraged to take action to pro-
(Varian 2005; Waldfogel 2012b; and Danaher, tect the interests of the newspapers that actu-
Smith, and Telang 2014b). Waldfogel (2012a) ally originated this news content. However,
addresses this challenge using two measures in general the work in economics that has
of music quality: historical “best albums” lists evaluated the effect of these aggregators has
and usage information over time. In both been to emphasize that such aggregation pro-
cases, he shows that the quality of music motes more exploration, rather than neces-
began to decline in the early 1990s and sarily cannibalizing content (Calzada and Gil
stopped declining after the arrival of free forthcoming; Chiou and Tucker 2017; Athey,
online copying in 1999. Why did quality rise Mobius, and Pal 2017).
despite declining revenue? He argues that Overall, copyright law is more import-
simultaneously with the decline in revenue ant in digital markets because goods can be
came a decline in the cost of producing and copied at zero cost. Stricter enforcement of
distributing music. Digitization affected the copyright appears to increase revenue to the
supply side as well as the demand side, and copyright holder, increase some incentives
16 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

by potential copyright holders to innovate, 5.1 Does Distance Still Matter If


but reduce incentives by others to build Transportation Costs Are Near Zero?
on copyrighted work. Nevertheless, the
literature also shows that, despite ease of Low transportation costs for information
copying, digitization has not killed creative mean that the cost of distribution for digital
industries because production and distribu- goods approaches zero and the difference in
tion costs have fallen and because the tech- cost of nearby and distant communication
nology has caught up to facilitate copyright approaches zero.
enforcement. The potential implications of low transpor-
tation costs have been explored in the popular
press. Cairncross (1997) suggests that this fall
5.  Lower Transportation Costs
in the costs of transporting information would
Related to replication being costless, the lead to a “death of distance.” Isolated indi-
cost of transporting information stored in viduals and companies would be able to plug
bits over the Internet is near zero.4 Put dif- into the global economy. Rural consumers
ferently, the cost of distribution for digital would benefit by having access to the same
goods approaches zero and the difference in set of digital products and services as every-
the cost of nearby and distant communica- one else. There would be a global diffusion of
tion approaches zero. knowledge. Friedman (2005) identifies sev-
In addition, digital purchasing technol- eral of the same themes in predicting a “flat
ogies have reduced transportation costs. world,” in which businesses anywhere could
Consumers buy physical goods online, partic- plug into the global supply chain and produce.
ularly when offline purchasing is costly or dif- Being in the United States would not confer
ficult (Goolsbee 2000; Forman, Ghose, and a meaningful advantage relative to India.
Goldfarb 2009; and Brynjolfsson, Hu, and Both Cairncross and Friedman suggested the
Rahman 2009). Furthermore, Pozzi (2013) potential arrival of a global culture, in which
shows that consumers also use online shop- everyone everywhere would consume the
ping to overcome the transportation costs of same information, an idea with its roots in
carrying things from the store. In this way, the McLuhan (1964). This idea is implicit in the
Internet facilitates stockpiling, allowing peo- trade model of Krugman (1979): countries
ple to buy in bulk when a discount appears consume the same goods as transport costs
because delivery means there is no need to approach zero. Rosenblat and Mobius (2004)
carry the large quantity of items purchased. formalize some of these ideas in a different
Therefore, for information, digital goods, context, using a network model of collabora-
and physical goods, transportation costs are tion in which long distance collaboration rises
lower online. but coauthor similarity in other dimensions
(such as field of research) also rises.
4 While transportation costs could be positive and even
A less extreme question than “Is distance
high due to network congestion, in practice this has not dead?” is “Does distance matter more or less
been an issue. Early on, such network congestion was a than it used to?” The most definitive answer
key focus of the literature. For example, one of the first to that question comes from Lendle et al.
volumes on Internet economics, Mcknight and Bailey
(1998), has several articles on congestion pricing. This (2016). They compare ­ cross-border sales
early literature on backbone competition and congestion on eBay with international trade data. They
ended up influencing our understanding of the economics demonstrate that, while distance predicts
of net neutrality discussed above (Cremer, Rey, and Tirole
2000; Laffont et al. 2001; Besen et al. 2001; and Laffont both online and offline trade flows, distance
et al. 2003). matters substantially less on eBay.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 17

The digital economic literature has empha- retailers went online first. In their review
sized what factors influence the extent to of the literature on o­nline–offline compe-
which distance still matters. tition, Lieber and Syverson (2012) provide
As Lemley (2003) notes, “No one is ‘in’ some additional evidence that offline options
cyberspace” (p.  523). Therefore, offline affect online purchasing. Similarly, in the
options matter. Balasubramanian (1998) digital media context, evidence suggests that
examines the importance of offline options online media consumption substitutes for,
using a circular city/Salop (1979) model with and is replacing, offline media consumption
the cost of using the direct retailer as con- (Wallsten 2013 and Gentzkow 2007).
stant for all locations, but the cost of using the In addition to the offline option, the fact
stores located around the circle dependent on that tastes are spatially correlated also mat-
transportation costs. The model shows that ters for the persistent role of distance. Blum
the benefit of a direct (online) retailer will be and Goldfarb (2006) examine the interna-
largest for those who live far from an offline tional Internet surfing behavior of about
retailer. Forman, Ghose, and Wiesenfeld 2,600 American Internet users, and demon-
(2008) provide evidence to support this strate that Internet surfing behavior is con-
model, demonstrating that when a Walmart or sistent with the w ­ ell-established empirical
Barnes & Noble opens offline, people substi- finding in the trade literature that bilateral
tute away from purchasing books on Amazon. trade decreases with distance (Overman,
A number of other studies also demonstrate Redding, and Venables 2003; Anderson and
how offline retail affects online purchasing. van Wincoop 2004; and Disdier and Head
Related models include Loginova (2009) and 2008). In other words, even for a product
Dinlersoz and Pereira (2007), which examine with zero shipping costs (visiting websites),
the role of loyalty to the offline store in driv- people are more likely to visit websites from
ing the more price sensitive customers online. nearby countries than from faraway coun-
Empirically, Brynjolfsson, Hu, and Rahman tries. This relationship between distance
(2009) show that online sales at a women’s and website visits is much higher in taste-de-
clothing retailer are lower from places with pendent categories (and loses statistical
many offline women’s clothing stores. This significance in the ­non-taste-dependent cat-
effect is driven by the more popular prod- egories). Distance matters because it prox-
ucts that are likely to be available in a typical ies for taste similarity. Alaveras and Martens
offline store. Choi and Bell (2011) shows that (2015) replicates this core result using much
online sales of niche diaper brands are higher richer data on website visits by users in a large
in places where they are unlikely to be avail- number of countries. Sinai and Waldfogel
able offline. Goolsbee (2001), Prince (2007), (2004) also shows that highly populated areas
and ­Duch-Brown et al. (2017) all show sub- produce more content, and that because
stitution between online and offline sales tastes are spatially correlated in the sense
of personal computers. Gentzkow (2007) that people are more likely to consume local
demonstrates substitution between the media than distant media, people in highly
online and offline news in Washington DC. populated areas are particularly likely to go
Seamans and Zhu (2014) and Goldfarb and online. This geographically specific nature
Tucker (2011a, 2011d) demonstrate substitu- of tastes is also reflected in the consumption
tion between online and offline advertising. of digital goods such as music (Ferreira and
Gertner and Stillman (2001) show how chan- Waldfogel 2013) and content (Gandal 2006).
nel conflict interacts with vertical integration Quan and Williams (2018) demonstrate that
and show that vertically integrated apparel accounting for spatial correlation in tastes
18 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

reduces the estimated ­ consumer surplus and Douglas (2009) shows that s­ame-city
from increased online variety by 30 percent. sales on eBay and MercadoLibre (a Brazilian
In addition to offline choices and spa- electronic commerce platform) are dis-
tially correlated tastes, another factor that proportionately high, likely because some
explains the continuing role of distance is the products are observed and delivered in
presence of social networks. Much online person. Furthermore, Forman, Ghose, and
behavior is social, and social networks are Wiesenfeld (2009) shows that Americans fol-
highly local (Hampton and Wellman 2003). low the online product recommendations of
Therefore, while zero transportation costs others who live near them.
of information mean that you can commu-
5.2 Can Policy Constrained by Geographic
nicate with anyone anywhere in the world
Boundaries Shape Digital Behavior?
for the same price, the vast majority of most
people’s email comes from those who either Early work worried that the Internet could
live at the same home or work in the same undermine local regulation and national sov-
building. Gaspar and Glaeser (1998) specu- ereignty (Castells 2001). The results of some
late that because of the spatial correlation of research is consistent with this idea: Online
social networks, the Internet may be a com- sales have been higher where the differ-
plement to cities. More efficient commu- ence between online and offline tax rates is
nication would be especially important for highest (Goolsbee 2000, Ellison and Ellison
those who communicate frequently. In other 2009b, Anderson et al. 2010, and Einav et al.
words, though the relative costs of communi- 2014). When local regulation prohibits offline
cation fall more for distant communication, advertising, similar online advertising is more
the overall importance of local communica- expensive (Goldfarb and Tucker 2011e)
tion might mean that cities benefit most. and more effective (Goldfarb and Tucker
Agrawal and Goldfarb (2008) provide 2011a). This substitution suggests that online
some evidence in support of this hypothe- and offline markets should be considered
sis by showing that as new universities con- together in the context of antitrust (Goldfarb
nected to a 1980s I­ nternet-like network, they and Tucker 2011f; Brand et al. 2014).
increased their collaboration rate with those At the same time, regulation can mean
already connected. The biggest change in that users experience the Internet differ-
collaboration rates were for c­ o-located uni- ently in different locations. At the extreme,
versities in different quality tiers. The paper regulation can prohibit certain content,
emphasizes the likely local social networks making the experience of using the Internet
of researchers in the same city. Looking at different across locations. Zhang and Zhu
online “crowdfunding” of music, Agrawal, (2011) examine the effect of the blocking
Catalini, and Goldfarb (2015) provide further of Wikipedia in China in October 2005 on
evidence of the importance of local social the motivations of others outside China to
networks by showing that musicians’ early contribute. Therefore, a key online website
funding tends to come from local supporters was available in some places and not others.
who the musicians knew prior to joining the More generally, some countries regularly
crowdfunding platform. As a musician gains block access to certain websites, changing
prominence on the website, the later fund- the nature of the Internet across locations.
ing often comes from distant strangers. Regulation can also change what users
Finally, in the absence of the improve- find available across locations. Copyright
ments in verification discussed below, trust policy leads to variation in the availability
is easier locally. Hortacsu, Martinez-Jerez, and consumption of media across locations
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 19

(­Gomez-Herrera, Martens, and Turlea 2014; Bailey, and Brynjolfsson 2001; and Bakos
Chiou and Tucker 2017; Athey, Mobius, and 2001). Even fi ­rst-degree price discrimina-
Pal 2017; and Calzada and Gil forthcoming). tion seemed like it might become more than
Privacy policy leads to different advertising a theoretical curiosity.
and different website success (Goldfarb and One form of price discrimination that has
Tucker 2011d and Tucker 2015). Trademark received a great deal of attention in the the-
policy leads to different search experiences ory literature on digital markets is behavioral
(Chiou and Tucker 2012 and Bechtold and price discrimination (see Fudenberg and
Tucker 2014). ­Villas-Boas 2007, 2012 for reviews). This lit-
Therefore, when regulation does not erature emphasizes that the low cost of col-
reach into the online sphere, the zero trans- lecting digital information makes it easier for
portation costs of information in the online companies to ­ price discriminate based on
channel generate a disproportionate benefit an individual’s past behavior. The research
of online information in regulated contexts. builds on a large price discrimination liter-
However, when regulation does reach the ature that does not specifically emphasize
online sphere, it can have a substantial effect digital markets (Hart and Tirole 1988; Chen
on the nature of the Internet across locations. 1997; Fudenberg and Tirole 2000). Broadly,
the research explores the benefits and costs of
identifying previous customers for monopolies
6.  Lower Tracking Costs
(­Villas-Boas 2004) and competing firms (Shin
The first three drops in costs, those asso- and Sudhir 2010; Chen and Zhang 2011).
ciated with search, replication, and distance, Fudenberg and ­Villas-Boas (2012) summarize
were well discussed in the early digital eco- this literature to conclude that under monop-
nomics literature. However, the importance oly, firms benefit from the additional informa-
of the lowering of the next two costs we tion, but under competition the information
discuss, tracking and verification, has only may increase the intensity of competition.
become clear in the last decade. Furthermore, the benefits of the information
Digital activity is easily recorded and stored. to a monopoly may lead consumers to strate-
In fact, many web servers store information gically withhold information. In other words,
automatically, and firms have to make a delib- consumers become ­privacy sensitive (Taylor
erate decision to discard data. Reductions 2004; Acquisti and Varian 2005; Hermalin
in tracking costs enable personalization and and Katz 2006). In the opposite direction,
the creation of ­one-to-one markets, leading rules that restrict the flow of information hurt
to renewed interest in established economic firms’ ability to price discriminate and there-
models with asymmetric information and dif- fore may leave some consumers unwilling to
ferentiated products such as price discrimina- buy at the offered prices (Taylor and Wagman
tion, auctions, and advertising models. 2014; Kim and Wagman 2015).
Another form of price discrimination that
6.1 Do Lower Tracking Costs Enable Novel
has received attention in the digital eco-
Forms of Price Discrimination?
nomics literature is versioning. Bhargava
The ability to use digital technologies to and Choudhary (2008) provide a model of
track individuals enables personalized mar- versioning when variable costs are zero. Fay
kets. Several economists recognized this and Xie (2008) explore versioning based on
potential for digital price discrimination probabilistic selling. For example, airlines
as the Internet commercialized in the late and hotels offer low-price versions of their
1990s (Shapiro and Varian 1998; Smith, products on Priceline.com, in which there is
20 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

buyer uncertainty about the specific product for personalized pricing of goods online, it
being bought. is perhaps a surprise that for many of these
Empirical support for digital price dis- goods, consumers face a price of zero (Evans
crimination is limited, despite the rich 2009). Therefore, perhaps the most striking
theoretical discussion of the potential for effect of the creation of low online tracking
personalized pricing. For example, version- costs has not been to use personalized pro-
ing is a basic form of t­hird-degree price files to charge different consumers different
discrimination that precedes most digital prices, but instead to show these different
markets (Maskin and Riley 1984; Deneckere consumers more appropriate, relevant, and
and McAfee 1996; Corts 1998; Fudenberg profitable advertising.
and Tirole 1998). Rao (2015) provides exper- Variants of these ideas appear in a rich the-
imental support for the value of versioning ory literature on t­wo-sided markets, empha-
digital products, demonstrating that online, sizing the digital context (Baye and Morgan
limited-time “rentals” can increase profits 2001; Anderson and de Palma 2009, 2013;
by segmenting high- and low-value con- White 2013; Athey, Calvano, and Gans 2018).
sumers. Despite the ease of even this most Baye and Morgan (2001) demonstrate that
straightforward form of price discrimina- an information intermediary will price low
tion, Shiller and Waldfogel (2011) argue that to consumers, while charging advertisers a
digital firms may not be versioning, or more high enough price that some choose not to
generally p ­ rice discriminating, as much as participate. Anderson and de Palma (2009)
would be optimal. In particular, they puz- and Athey, Calvano, and Gans’s (2018) papers
zle over the surprisingly uniform nature of each model consumer attention as scarce
pricing for digital music. They argue that and explore advertiser competition for that
uniform pricing of music appears to lead to attention. Athey, Calvano, and Gans (2018)
­lower-than-optimal profits for firms, but do emphasize that if an advertiser wants to send
not provide a clear answer to this puzzle. a message to a customer offline, they need to
While there is evidence of broad versioning rely on noisy signals based on media demo-
of online media (Chiou and Tucker 2013; graphics. In contrast, online targeting tech-
Lambrecht and Misra 2017), the theoreti- nology is such that an advertiser can target
cal literature on digital price discrimination a particular consumer. In the presence of
seems to be ahead of the empirical work and multiple media outlets and ­multi-homing by
of firm practices. While there is evidence of consumers, the equilibrium outcome is that
first-degree price discrimination in higher online advertising prices can be much lower
education (Waldfogel 2015), the only online than offline advertising prices even though the
research example we found is Dube and online advertising is in fact more useful to the
Misra (2017), who demonstrate the feasibil- advertiser. However, Gentzkow (2014) argues
ity and profitability of targeting many prices that the price of attention is not lower online
to different customers of an online service than offline, which challenges this prediction.
based on a large number of characteristics. Perhaps because of these forces, many
of the largest online companies—in
6.2 Why Has There Been a Shift in
terms of revenues, profits, and users—are
Academic Emphasis from Personalized
­advertising-supported. ­Low-cost tracking
Pricing to Personalized Advertising?
means that what distinguishes online adver-
Given the emphasis of the theoretical lit- tising from offline advertising is that it is tar-
erature on the ease and practicality of behav- geted (Goldfarb and Tucker 2011b, Goldfarb
ioral price discrimination and the potential 2014). This difference is highlighted in
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 21

­ odels that explore competition between


m wasted. Simonov, Nosko, and Rao (2018) use
online and offline advertising (Athey and data from Microsoft’s Bing search engine
Gans 2010, Bergemann and Bonatti 2011, to show that the results for eBay may be
and Johnson 2013). Athey, Calvano, and driven by the strength of eBay as a partic-
Gans (2018) and Levin and Milgrom (2010) ularly ­well-known brand. Less ­well-known
use very different models to demonstrate that advertisers seem to benefit from search
better targeting may not help online media. advertising.
Athey, Calvano, and Gans (2018) show that While much better than prior ways to mea-
improved tracking can increase competition sure advertising effectiveness, there are still
between media outlets. Levin and Milgrom substantial challenges. Correlational research,
(2010) show that too much targeting can lead even with detailed data, typically yields inac-
to insufficient competition among advertisers curate measures of advertising effects because
for the user attention sold by a monopolist the ­signal-to-noise ratio for advertising’s effect
media firm. on sales is low (Lewis, Rao, and Reiley 2015;
This better targeting has led to a thriving Gordon et al. 2016). Furthermore, even with
literature that measures advertising effec- experiments, advertising effects are subtle rel-
tiveness. Because ad messages are sent to ative to the variance in purchase behavior, and
individuals in bits (rather than broadcast so studies need to be highly powered (Lewis
through billboards and newspapers), it is and Rao 2015).
relatively easy to identify consumers that see A large literature also emphasizes the
ads, to randomize which consumers see ads, role of targeting as a distinct and important
and even to track those consumers through feature of online advertising. Goldfarb and
purchase. Until recently, this was very diffi- Tucker (2011c) shows that targeted banner
cult, and so there were few studies that could advertising is effective, but only as long as
deliver credible empirical measures of adver- it does not take over the screen too much.
tising effectiveness. Low tracking costs make Targeting works when subtle, in the sense
it relatively easy to run field experiments that it has the biggest effect on plain banner
online, and large scale field experiments ads, relative to how it increases the effective-
have been the focus of the recent literature. ness of other types of ads. Lambrecht and
Research on online advertising effec- Tucker (2013) and Tucker (2012a) demon-
tiveness has been largely conducted by strate the effectiveness of other types of
research economists working with indus- online advertising targeting.
try. For example, Lewis and Reiley (2014) As noted above, online media support
use a field experiment on 1.6 million Yahoo their business by selling scarce consumer
customers that connects online advertis- attention to advertisers. New technologies
ing to offline department store sales. They are emerging that allow consumers to block
find that online advertising increases offline advertising online. Such ad blocking may
sales in a department store. Blake, Nosko, reduce revenues and, perhaps counterintu-
and Tadelis (2017) show that in many cases, itively, increase the quantity of ads shown
search engine advertising—the key reve- to those without ad blockers (Anderson
nue generator for Google—does not work. and Gans 2011). In a test of these ideas,
In particular, they demonstrate with a large Shiller, Waldfogel, and Ryan (2018) use
field experiment at eBay that consumers data on ad blocking and website visits to
will often click on the “organic” link anyway show that widespread use of ad blockers
and navigate to the advertiser’s page. They may decrease the quality of websites on the
argue that much search engine advertising is ­advertising-supported Internet.
22 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

6.3 Why Are Online Goods and Services This idea also appears in Varian (2010), which
Often Sold by Auction? describes the benefits of ­computer-mediated
transactions with respect to decentralized
The rise of online advertising, along with price discovery, and therefore more finely
i­ndividual-level tracking technologies, has based price discrimination. While auctions
created a difficult pricing problem: how can for goods (rather than advertising) still exist
a firm choose prices for thousands of adver- online, Einav et al. (2017) show that goods
tisements that might be priced differentially auctions are in decline as online markets
to millions or even billions of customers? As have matured. The prominent role of auc-
economists have ­ long-recognized, auctions tions in economic theory means that a sep-
are a particularly useful tool for price discov- arate literature has used the digital setting
ery. Consequently, digital markets typically as a context to test ­long-established theory.
use auctions to determine prices for adver- This research, pioneered by L ­ ucking-Reiley
tising. Auctions are also used to price some (1999), is not about digital markets per se, but
other goods. uses the digital context to inform a broader
Originally, advertising on Yahoo!’s search theory literature (Roth and Ockenfels 2002,
page in the 1990s was priced according to Bajari and Hortacsu 2003, and Einav et al.
a standard rate. Goto.com’s insight—that 2018).
an auction could leverage the fact that the
6.4 How Do Digital Markets Affect Privacy
value of advertising depended on the search
Policy?
term—led to a new way to price discrimi-
nate in advertising. Rather than price for the Low tracking costs have led to a renewed
search page, price could be at the level of interest in the economics of privacy, as high-
the search term. Google and Bing’s ad auc- lighted by a recent review in this journal
tions run on this insight. A large literature (Acquisti, Taylor, and Wagman 2016).
has arisen to develop auction formats for this In general, the economics literature on
context (Varian 2007; Edelman, Ostrovsky, privacy, both offline and online, grapples
and Schwarz 2007; Levin and Milgrom 2010; with the question of how privacy should be
Arnosti, Beck, and Milgrom 2016). Today, treated in terms of the consumers’ utility
advertising auctions, particularly for display function. Should economists treat privacy as
advertising, often take into account addi- an intermediate good—that is, a good whose
tional information provided by online track- value simply lies in the way it can moderate
ing technologies, such as websites visited in the achievement of another good—or as a
the past and products observed. final good—that is, a good that should be
Less related to tracking costs, online auc- enjoyed and valued for its own sake (Farrell
tions have also been used for price discovery 2012)? Much p ­ olicy making is grounded on
for goods, most notably on eBay. An early the idea that privacy is a final good where a
review of the auction literature is provided in distaste for others intruding on or gathering
Ockenfels, Reiley, and Sadrieh (2006). They knowledge about an individual’s personal
emphasize that the transactions costs of con- domain is valid as a driver of an individual’s
ducting and participating in auctions are utility. However, much of the theoretical lit-
lower in the digital context. Furthermore, erature analyzes privacy as an intermediate
many digital goods are not standardized in good because of the implications for per-
the sense that buyer valuations vary over sonalized pricing that are discussed above
time and location, and so the price discovery (Taylor 2004, Acquisti and Varian 2005,
function of the auction is particularly useful. Hermalin and Katz 2006).
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 23

Privacy regulation can affect the nature and medicine technologies: regulations that gave
distribution of economic outcomes (Goldfarb consumers control over disclosures enhanced
and Tucker 2012a). Edelman (2009) and adoption, but regulations that imposed con-
Lenard and Rubin (2009) emphasize that sent requirements decreased adoption.
there is a ­trade-off between the use of online Privacy regulation puts a cost on tracking
customer data to subsidize z­ ero-price goods information flows. The welfare effects of
and advertising performance. Goldfarb and these costs may be ambiguous.
Tucker (2011d) show that European privacy First, there may be ­ knock-on effects to
regulation that restricted online tracking led industry structure from privacy regulation.
to a substantial decline in the effectiveness of Campbell, Goldfarb, and Tucker (2015) show
online advertising in Europe. Johnson (2014) that because privacy regulations typically
estimates the financial effect of privacy pol- require firms to persuade their consumers
icies on the online display ad industry, sug- to give consent, which in turn imposes a cost
gesting that an ­opt-in policy or a tracking ban on the consumer, small firms and new firms
would reduce welfare substantially, though are disproportionately affected because it is
an ­ opt-out policy would have little effect. harder for them to obtain consent under the
Johnson’s paper is very useful for under- regulation.
standing the effect on publishers (rather than Second, welfare complications of privacy
advertisers) of privacy regulation. policies are also hard to assess due to a pri-
Kim and Wagman (2015) show that regula- vacy paradox, where consumers state an affin-
tion of sharing financial information increased ity for privacy, but then act in ways that are
defaults on loans during the financial crisis. not consistent with this stated preference.
Miller and Tucker (2009, 2011) show that Athey, Catalini, and Tucker (2017) provide
US healthcare privacy regulation reduced some evidence about the extent to which
hospital adoption of electronic medical small incentives, distracting information,
records, leading to worse health outcomes. and small navigation costs can lead to a gap
On a more positive note in favor of privacy, between stated privacy preferences and actual
Tucker (2014) shows that ­firm-implemented behavior. Furthermore, assessing the value
privacy controls designed to encourage con- of privacy is complicated for many reasons,
sumers’ perceptions of control can actually including that privacy preferences for the
enhance the performance of online adver- same individual change over time (Goldfarb
tising. Tucker (2012b) compares this result and Tucker 2012b).
with work that suggests there may be bene- Third, much of the work in the econom-
fits from addressing consumer privacy con- ics of privacy has understandably focused
cerns, building on research that illustrates on questions relating to industrial organi-
how perceptions of control influence privacy zation, there are also implications of digital
concerns in general (Brandimarte, Acquisti, technologies and privacy for the economics
and Loewenstein 2012). of national security. In addition to improving
In general, the precise nature of privacy the ability of firms to track consumers, digital
protection can be expected to matter a lot for technology allows government c­ rime-fighting
the direction of innovation: it is not a matter of agencies to track a broad swathe of the
a simple binary choice to have privacy protec- population. Marthews and Tucker (2014)
tion or not. This is emphasized in Miller and show that increasing consumer awareness
Tucker’s (2018) work, which shows that differ- of government data use leads to increased
ent types of privacy protections had very dif- ­privacy-protecting behavior among consum-
ferent effects on the ­adoption of p­ ersonalized ers in their interactions with firms.
24 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

7.  Reduction in Verification Costs past buyers and sellers are posted for future
market participants to see. The marketplace
The reduction in tracking costs has also that has received the most attention in the
led to a reduction in costs associated with the literature is eBay. As mentioned above, one
verification of identity and reputation. This reason eBay has received so much attention
was not anticipated by the early literature by economists is that it provided a useful set-
in economics because the earliest reporting ting to test auction theory. Another reason
on the Internet suggested that it would be relates to reputation mechanisms. eBay rec-
a vehicle for anonymity—“On the Internet, ognized the challenges of getting people to
nobody knows you’re a dog.”5 Furthermore, buy from strangers whom they will not meet
in addition to tracking cost falling, digital in person (Resnick and Zeckhauser 2002 and
technologies have also made it easier to verify Livingston 2005). To address this issue, they
identity and also create a digital reputation. built, and continually adapted and improved,
In the absence of such technologies, a a ratings system. The effectiveness and
­long-standing solution for firms to provide development of this ratings system has been
credible information about quality was to the subject of hundreds of papers in econom-
develop a reputation in the form of a brand ics and management. For example, Ba and
(Tadelis 1999, Smith and Brynjolfsson 2001, Pavlou (2002) shows how a ratings system
and Waldfogel and Chen 2006). However, can enable trust in the absence of repeated
digital markets involve thousands of small interactions. A number of papers empirically
players. Furthermore, these small players demonstrate that ­ better-rated sellers have
can be unfamiliar to potential customers. higher prices and higher revenues (Melnik
Einav et al. (2017) estimate that 88 percent and Alm 2002, Livingston 2005, Houser and
of online Visa transactions are with a mer- Wooders 2005, a­nd Lucking-Reiley et al.
chant that the customer does not visit offline. 2007). Cabral and Hortacsu (2010) demon-
Alternative mechanisms to ­ brand-based strates differences between positive and
reputations are needed. The literature on negative feedback, emphasizing how the rat-
verification costs builds on economic mod- ings system acts as a disciplining force in the
els of reputation, exploring when the expe- marketplace in which sellers with low ratings
riences of previous buyers and sellers can exit from eBay’s platform.
enable market exchange in the presence of Therefore, the original emphasis of the
asymmetric information about quality and reputation literature was as a platform for
trustworthiness. This emphasis on repu- establishing trust in ­long-distance transac-
tation models distinguishes the literature tions. Dellarocas (2003) recognizes early on
on verification costs from the literature on that the application of these feedback mech-
tracking costs, which emphasizes price dis- anisms was not limited to online exchange.
crimination, advertisement targeting, and Instead, Dellarocas argued that such mech-
other forms of personalization. anisms would enable a variety of market
activities, both online and offline. As long as
7.1 How Do Online Reputation Systems
incentives to deviate are not too high, such
Facilitate Trust?
systems can provide credible quality signals
The most common such mechanism is an in a variety of settings (Dellarocas 2003 and
online rating systems in which ratings from Cabral 2012).
One key application is to provide informa-
tion on product quality. Rather than enhance
5 The New Yorker on July 5, 1993. information about a particular seller, ratings
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 25

can inform consumers about the best prod- the ability to more securely and easily
ucts available within a platform. It might make p ­ ayments. This is demonstrated by
be in the platform’s interest to provide such Economides and Jeziorski (2017), who
information so that consumers are directed show the power of using mobile devices
to the highest-quality products. Comparing to digitally verify identity in Tanzania.
changes in reviews on Amazon relative to They show that this power enables the use
Barnes & Noble, Chevalier and Mayzlin of mobile payments networks to transfer
(2006) demonstrate that positive reviews money to others, but also, equally impor-
lead to higher sales. tantly, to transport money over short dis-
More recently, the literature has focused tances. People appear to deposit cash after
on how online tools reduce verification costs work, walk home, and then pick up the cash
in offline settings. Luca (2011) shows how at home. The verification system enables
online restaurant reviews on Yelp affect easy deposits and withdrawals, thereby
restaurant demand, particularly for indepen- reducing the risk of robbery. Digital ver-
dent restaurants. Overall, his results suggest ification, in the form of DNA databases,
that Yelp led to a decrease in the share of has also been shown to reduce crime
chain restaurants relative to independents. (Doleac 2017).
Hollenbeck (2018) finds a similar result for As technology improves, verification may
hotels. continue to become easier. Researchers
It is easier to establish an online reputa- have speculated that the blockchain is a
tion using online reputation mechanisms, promising technology for reducing veri-
but the mechanisms for damaging that rep- fication costs further (Catalini and Gans
utation in the form of consumer complaints 2016). Blockchain is a technology that
have also become easier. Historically, com- combines insights from game theory and
plaints were registered with letters, and then cryptography to enable the exchange of
calls into call centers. Social media enables value between two distant untrusting par-
rapid widespread communication of com- ties without the need for an intermediary.
plaints to both the firm and a wider audi- Transaction attributes, or information on
ence. Gans, Goldfarb, and Lederman (2016) the agents involved, can be cheaply veri-
use data from Twitter to explore ideas on the fied if stored on a distributed ledger. This
relationship between market power and con- means that trust in an intermediary could
sumer voice first sketched out in Hirschman be replaced by trust in the underlying code
(1970). They show that consumers are more and rules that define how the network can
likely to voice their complaints via Twitter in reach agreement. Currently, most of the lit-
locations where airlines have a higher share erature on blockchain technologies focuses
of flights. In turn, airlines are more likely on specific applications of the technology
to respond to consumers in these markets. such as cryptocurrencies (Böhme et al. 2015
Tucker and Yu (2017) show some positive and Catalini and Tucker 2017). However,
effects of digital technologies, in that the if blockchain technologies achieve the
use of mobile apps to receive complaints promise highlighted in Catalini and Gans
can actually advantage less-educated con- (2016), then we might see a diverse liter-
sumers who are more likely to suffer from ature emerge over the next few years on
employee–consumer discrimination in the
­ the consequences of l­ow-cost verification—
treatment of their complaints. and the associated changing role for inter-
A benefit of improved online verifica- mediaries—across a variety of empirical
tion procedures for individuals has been settings.
26 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

7.2 Is There a Role for Policy in Reducing e­ xamining worker and firm behavior on an
Reputation System Failures? online labor market. They show that new
workers benefit from affiliating themselves
Given the important role of such systems with an agency.
in generating demand, it is perhaps unsur- The platforms also work to improve their
prising that the economics literature has reputation systems. Fradkin, Grewal, and
focused on questioning when reputation sys- Holtz (2017) document two experiments
tems fail. Often the failures relate to incom- made at Airbnb with this aim: offering
plete ability to verify the person doing the monetary incentives to submit reviews and
rating online. One type of failure relates to implementing a simultaneous review pro-
a selection bias: not all consumers provide cess to reduce strategic reciprocity. Hui et
ratings. Nosko and Tadelis (2015) show evi- al. (2016) show, in the context of eBay, that
dence of such a selection bias, in which buy- platforms benefit by having both reputation
ers with a bad experience do not bother to systems and regulations to expel bad actors.
rate the seller. They instead stop buying from In each of these cases, it has been the pri-
any sellers on the platform into the future. vate sector that has reduced these reputa-
Poor service by a seller therefore creates an tion system failures. To the extent that there
externality. The failure of the reputation sys- has been a role for policy, it has been in the
tems hurts the platform, rather than the indi- enforcement of contracts and prevention of
vidual seller. Another type of failure relates fraud. At this point, the literature does not
to direct manipulation of the ratings by the point to a specific digital policy with respect
firms or their competitors. Mayzlin, Dover, to reputation systems failures.
and Chevalier (2014) and Luca and Zervas One aspect of policy related to verification
(2016) show evidence of manipulation, in is the nature of intellectual property tools
which firms seem to give themselves high rat- such as trademarks. Trademarks allow cus-
ings while giving low ratings to their compet- tomers to verify whether a brand is indeed
itors. This evidence of manipulation suggests the brand it claims to be. Chiou and Tucker
that ratings systems alone are insufficient. (2012) and Bechtold and Tucker (2014) doc-
The challenges of ratings systems were ument that, online, consumers use trade-
recognized relatively early in the digital eco- marks to search ­proactively. The trademark
nomics literature. Consider the market for therefore serves two purposes: it verifies
collectible baseball cards. When buyer and identity and it provides a path to search for
seller are in the same place, the buyer can related products. Trademark policy needs to
inspect the quality of the card in the store. be narrow enough to facilitate search related
They can look for rips, folds, or frayed edges. to trademarks, but broad enough to ensure
Online, quality is hard to assess. Jin and Kato that such search does not sow confusion on
(2006) provide evidence of fraud in these brand identity.
markets. They show that the online reputa-
7.3 How Do Digital Markets Affect
tion system is insufficient in many ways. In a
­Antidiscrimination Policy?
companion paper (Jin and Kato 2007), they
show how a professional grading industry A second policy issue driven by changes
grew to help solve the information asym- in verification relates to discrimination. If
metry between buyers and sellers online. people were indeed truly anonymous on
Stanton and Thomas (2016) shows the the Internet, then there could be no direct
value of online intermediaries in ­providing discrimination. However, the drop in ver-
information beyond platform ratings by
­ ification costs and the ability to identify an
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 27

i­ ndividual and also their characteristics the suitability of employees. They find con-
makes discrimination possible (and poten- siderable use of social networking sites for
tially low cost) in a digital environment. ­potentially discriminatory purposes. Similar
The question, then, for policy makers is results have been found in a variety of other
whether there is something unique to the online contexts (Pope and Sydnor 2011 and
online setting that requires additional regu- Edelman and Luca 2014).
lation beyond existing a­ ntidiscrimination law. Both online and offline, discrimination
One area where this is hotly debated is in the is prevalent. Open questions remain as to
use of algorithms to parse data and auto- whether discrimination is more prevalent
mate the allocation of resources and decision online or offline, and as to whether policies
making. This is investigated in Lambrecht aimed at reducing online discrimination spe-
and Tucker (forthcoming), which shows that cifically will reduce discrimination overall,
algorithms may lead to apparently discrim- or simply push discrimination into another
inatory outcomes for innocent reasons. In setting.
particular, they show that ads for STEM edu-
cation are disproportionately shown to men
8.  Consequences of Digitization for
by online algorithms because advertising to
Economic Actors
men is less expensive overall than advertising
to women, and so advertisers who are indif- As people spend more time consuming
ferent to gender end up showing their ads to digital media and buying products online,
men more often. and as business and government increasingly
Broadly, on the one hand, while tracking use digital technology, it suggests a broader
is easier, such tracking may focus on dimen- question: how does storing information in
sions that are legally and morally less contro- bits rather than atoms affect welfare? As
versial, such as preferences rather than race. search, reproduction, transportation, track-
If digital transactions mean that gender and ing, and verification costs fall, has that had
race information is not revealed, then dis- an effect on the economy?
crimination may fall. Morton, Zettelmeyer, Broadly, the literature has tackled this
and Silva-Risso (2003) show that Internet question in four different ways: ­country-level
car purchasing reduces gender- and effects, ­ region-level effects, ­ firm-level
­race-based price discrimination. Cullen and effects, and ­consumer-level effects.
­Pakzad-Hurson (2017) show that a reduc-
8.1 ­Country-level Effects
tion of privacy of wages in online platforms
decreases pay differences across workers The macroeconomic productivity litera-
(though it also reduces average pay). ture with respect to Internet technology has
On the other hand, if gender, race, or its roots in the Solow (1987) claim that “you
other sensitive information is revealed, it is can see the computer age everywhere but in
possible that, in the absence of other infor- the productivity statistics.” This “productiv-
mation, discrimination is high. For example, ity puzzle” persisted for many years. A large
Ayres, Banaji, and Jolls (2015) and Doleac growth accounting literature has arisen to
and Stein (2013) show that sellers receive examine this puzzle and measure the overall
lower prices when a black hand is shown with effect of digital technologies on the econ-
the item than when a white hand is shown. omy. While we view this literature as beyond
Acquisti and Fong (2013) present the results the scope of this article, Jorgenson, Ho, and
of a field experiment to study how employers Stiroh (2008) and Bloom et al. (2010) both
use information on social networks to filter summarize it to suggest that there was a
28 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

­ ost-1995 productivity surge that was largely


p direct effect of the Internet find a decrease
driven by digital technology investment and in the role of distance in trade (Freund and
usage. Weinhold 2004, Clarke 2008, Lendle et al.
Still, measuring the productivity shifts is 2016, and Hui forthcoming), while other
difficult. Haltiwanger and Jarmin (2000) lay papers identify other weaker forces moving
out several of the anticipated challenges in in the ­ opposite direction. Consistent with
measuring the effect of the digital economy: an effect of easy international communica-
service industry output, data on digital tech- tion on trade, Gorodnichenko and Talavera
nology spending, price deflators, et cetera. (2017) show that exchange rate p ­ ass-through
A key challenge relates to intangible capital is faster online.
(Corrado and Hulten 2010), which has been
8.2 ­Region-level Effects
found to affect productivity measurement
in both the United States and the United Another question is the extent to which
Kingdom (Corrado, Hulten, and Sichel the Internet has led to redistribution of
2009; and Marrano, Haskel, and Wallis economic benefits within countries and, in
2009). Soloveichik (2010) takes on this mea- particular, between cities and rural areas.
surement challenge and identifies about $65 Gaspar and Glaeser (1998) notes that digi-
billion in intangible capital related to books, tal communication could be a substitute or a
movies, music, and television. complement to cities. Overall, the literature
A different stream of work on c­ ountry-level suggests that the biggest beneficiaries of dig-
effects examines how digital communication ital technologies and data have been in large
may affect trade flows for digital and physi- urban areas. The prime early beneficiaries of
cal goods. Freund and Weinhold (2004) pro- online media were in urban areas because the
vide suggestive evidence that the Internet highest quality online content was produced
increased trade in physical goods due to a in urban areas. This might be one reason
reduction in the cost of international com- why Savage and Waldman (2009) find that
munication. The asynchronous nature of urbanites have higher willingness to pay for
email communication may be particularly broadband. Eichengreen, Lafarguette, and
important for reducing the cost of commu- Mehl (2016) show that efficient electronic
nication across many time zones (Borenstein communication in foreign exchange mar-
and Saloner 2001). ­ Gomez-Herrera, kets led to an increase in offshore currency
Martens, and Turlea (2014) suggest, how- trading and the consequent agglomeration
ever, that this increase may disproportion- of currency markets in London and a small
ately benefit ­ English-language countries. number of other major financial centers.
Several of the papers highlighted earlier in Forman, Goldfarb, and Greenstein (2012)
this review demonstrate that the Internet shows that wealthy cities were the primary
facilitated trade in digital services (Blum beneficiaries of the business Internet.
and Goldfarb 2006, Alaveras and Martens The mechanism through which cities
2015, and Lendle et al. 2016), and this might appear to have benefited has been shown
lead to offshoring of certain jobs (Tambe to depend on agglomeration effects, par-
and Hitt 2012). While there is some debate ticularly with respect to skilled workers in
about whether distance matters less over- local labor markets. Forman, Goldfarb, and
all than it did prior to the diffusion of the Greenstein (2005, 2008) show that Internet
Internet (Leamer 2007, Cristea 2011, and adoption by businesses is higher in cities and
Krautheim 2012), our reading of the liter- in large companies but the advantage associ-
ature is that those papers that focus on the ated with being in a city or a large company
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 29

are substitutes for each other. This indicates direct link from digital technology adop-
the importance of agglomeration effects. tion and usage to productivity growth at the
Dranove et al. (2014) finds similar results for firm level. By using micro data and various
hospitals. econometric techniques to address selec-
In contrast to the above work, there is tion, omitted variables bias, and simultaneity,
some evidence that Internet adoption has this literature has found that digital tech-
some benefits for isolated individuals and nology adoption and usage does enhance
rural areas. Autor (2001) and Gaspar and productivity. However, the story is not as
­
Glaeser (1998) speculated that the Internet simple as it seems at first. Only some types
might reduce the need for ­ task-specific of firms experience improved productivity.
workspace, thereby increasing the preva- Various factors enhance or mitigate this rela-
lence of “telecommuting” and reducing the tionship, including organizational change,
need for home and work to be nearby. Kolko skills, geography, regulation, firm size and
(2012) shows that broadband disproportion- age, and the potential for spillovers and/or
ately benefited people in low density areas network externalities.
in terms of employment, though the over- Reviews by Brynjolfsson and Saunders
all effect is small. Furthermore, while the (2010) and Draca, Sadun, and Van Reenen
primary result in the Sinai and Waldfogel (2009) conclude that ICT adoption and
(2004) study cited above is that urban areas usage increase firm performance. This con-
have higher quality Internet content, they clusion is driven by a large number of papers
also show that isolated individuals consume and a variety of settings. The correlation
disproportionately more Internet news. For between IT and productivity is even stronger
example, blacks in white neighborhoods con- when ICT investment is modeled with a lag
sume more Internet news. Finally, Forman, (Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2003).
Goldfarb, and Greenstein (2005) show that There are also specific case studies on the
basic Internet technologies have (perhaps effects of ICT on productivity. Baker and
disproportionately) benefited rural and iso- Hubbard (2004) show that ICT improved
lated cities. productivity in trucking. Jin and McElheran
Overall, two forces are at play. (2017) show improved productivity in manu-
Agglomeration effects mean that cities dispro- facturing. Agrawal and Goldfarb (2008) show
portionately benefit. Low-cost communica- that BITNET increased academic produc-
tion, however, can benefit the geographically tivity at ­middle-tier universities. In health
isolated. In any particular context, the overall care, Athey and Stern (2002) show that ICT,
result depends on the balance between these in the form of Enhanced 911, improved
forces. Generally, the more difficult the tech- emergency response; Miller and Tucker
nology is to use, the more likely that agglom- (2011) and McCullough, Parente, and Town
eration effects dominate. (2016) show that electronic medical records
(EMRs) improve patient outcomes; Dranove
8.3 ­Firm-level Effects
et al. (2014) show that EMRs reduce hospital
As noted above, the growth accounting costs in the presence of complementary skills
literature has suggested a compelling link but not otherwise; and Lee, McCullough,
between digital technology investments and and Town (2013) show that EMRs increase
productivity growth at the country level; hospital productivity.
however, causal inference is difficult with Bloom, Sadun, and Van Reenen (2012)
­macro-level measurement. There is a large use a ­ large-scale ­
multi-country ­ firm-level
and growing literature that documents a panel database on ICT and productivity.
30 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

Their database contains 19,000 firms in thir- 8.4 ­Consumer-level Effects


teen EU countries over eleven years, plus
a smaller panel of US firms over the same Measurements that focus on productivity
time period. They conclude that ICT does or national income accounts do not measure
increase productivity, though they find con- consumer surplus. To the extent that much
siderable heterogeneity in this effect across of the most valuable content online is free,
countries and type of firm. They emphasize measures of productivity and GDP may miss
the importance of ­ organizational capital, a potential increase in consumer surplus
showing that US multinationals operating driven by the Internet (Scott and Varian 2015;
in the United Kingdom experienced the Brynjolfsson, Eggers, and Gannamaneni
same productivity miracle as U ­S-based 2017; Greenstein and McDevitt 2011; and
establishments. In contrast, other multi- Goolsbee and Klenow 2006). With time use
nationals (and other firms) in the United data, Wallsten (2013) demonstrates that we
Kingdom did not. The title communicates are spending an increasing proportion of our
the idea well: “Americans do I.T. better.” leisure time online, substituting for offline
They argue that US firms are organized in leisure (including television), and to a lesser
way that allows them to use ICT more effi- extent work and sleep. Also with time use
ciently. This essential role of organizational data, Goolsbee and Klenow (2006) estimate a
capital and organizational structure in mak- consumer surplus of $3,000 per ­person-year
ing productive use of ICT investments is a in 2005. Goldfarb and Prince (2008) shows
recurring theme elsewhere in the literature that this effect is heterogeneous. Overall,
(Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson, and Hitt 2002; rich educated Americans are more likely to
Brynjolfsson and Saunders 2010; Garicano adopt and therefore, overall consumer sur-
2010; Tambe, Hitt, and Brynjolfsson 2012; plus disproportionately goes to the wealthy.
and Brynjolfsson and McElheran 2016). At the same time, conditional on adoption,
In addition to change in the organiza- lower-income people spend more time
­
tional structure, the most effective use of online. Therefore, among adopters, con-
advanced ICT also involves “coinvention,” sumer surplus (at least relative to overall con-
the process of adapting ICT to the organi- sumption) is higher for ­lower-income people.
zation’s needs (Bresnahan and Greenstein Many studies arrive at specific estimates of
1996). Such process innovation is easiest for the consumer surplus from ­Internet-related
firms in places that have a pool of local ICT technologies. Greenstein and McDevitt
expertise to draw on (Forman, Goldfarb, and (2011) measures the consumer surplus
Greenstein 2008; and Dranove et al. 2014). associated with broadband diffusion at $4.8
This of course reflects the extensive litera- to $6.7 billion between 1999 and 2006.
ture on ­ skill-biased technological change, Brynjolfsson and Oh (2012) estimate the con-
which is long and beyond the scope of this sumer surplus from free online services to be
review. As reviewed in Acemoglu and Autor close to $100 billion. Cohen et al. (2016) esti-
(2012), given that prior generations of IT are mate billions of dollars in consumer surplus
­skill-biased, it is perhaps unsurprising that from the UberX car service alone.6
use of the Internet to enhance productivity
is also ­skill-biased. Correspondingly, in the
context of the Internet, Akerman, Gaarder, 6 Greenstein and Nagle (2014) estimate an intangible
and Mogstad (2015) provide evidence that benefit of digitization distinct from consumer surplus: the
value of open source. It shows that open source software
broadband diffusion in Norway dispropor- Apache generates at least $2 billion in unmeasured bene-
tionately benefited skilled workers. fits to the US economy.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 31

Brynjolfsson, Eggers, and Gannamaneni costs. We have identified five such costs:
(2017) provide perhaps the most compre- search, reproduction, transportation, track-
hensive estimate of the consumer surplus ing, and verification. These themes inform
of the Internet by using (incentive compat- our understanding of the nature of digital
ible) choice experiments. For example, in economic activity, and of the interaction
one study, they asked people how much they between digital and n ­ on-digital settings.
would need to be paid in order to not have In defining the scope of this article, we
access to Facebook for a month. They then drew boundaries. For example, we did
implemented the result by actually block- not discuss work on ­ skill-biased technical
ing their respondents’ access to Facebook in change. Because ­skill bias is not primarily
exchange for p­ ayment. They estimate a value driven by the storage of information in bits,
of Facebook of about $750 per user per year, and because there are several other reviews
or $18 billion for the United States. They of that literature, we instead refer to Katz and
also generated u ­ ser-level survey estimates of Autor (1999), Acemoglu (2002), Goldin and
the consumer surplus from other free online Katz (2008), and Acemoglu and Autor (2012).
services such as search engines ($16,000 per Similarly, we limit the discussion of the digi-
user per year) and online video ($900 per tal technology growth accounting literature,
user per year). referring the reader to Jorgenson, Ho, and
Before concluding, it is important to rec- Stiroh (2008) and Bloom et al. (2010). We
ognize that there are other, perhaps negative, also limited our discussion on three topics
changes to overall welfare that may result that have already received reviews in the
from shifts in Internet consumption that Journal of Economic Literature: privacy
are not captured by these surplus measures. (Acquisti, Taylor, and Wagman 2016), online
Belo, Ferreira, and Telang (2014) show a auctions (Bajari and Hortacsu 2004), and
reduction in grades associated with schools telecommunications pricing and universal
adopting broadband, perhaps because online service (Vogelsang 2003).
games distracted students. Bhuller et al. This overview highlights that changes
(2013) argue that Internet diffusion may have to economic behavior that result from the
increased sex crime, likely due to increased change of costs inherent in the digital con-
consumption of pornography (not because text are not as obvious as basic economic
of reporting or matching between offenders models might imply. Key open questions
and victims). Similarly, Chan, Ghose, and remain with respect to each of the cost
Seamans (2016) suggest an increase in racial changes highlighted. Further, other catego-
hate crimes associated with the Internet, and ries of costs may shift downwards as digital
Falck, Gold, and Heblich (2014) suggest that technology evolves.
Internet availability reduces voter turnout in
elections. References

Aaltonen, Aleksi, and Stephan Seiler. 2016. “Cumula-


tive Growth in User-Generated Content Production:
9.  Conclusions Evidence from Wikipedia.” Management Science 62
(7): 2054–69.
Across a variety of fields, economists Acemoglu, Daron. 2002. “Technical Change, Inequal-
examine how digital technologies change ity, and the Labor Market.” Journal of Economic Lit-
economic activity. While these papers often erature 40 (1): 7–72.
Acemoglu, Daron, Philippe Aghion, Claire LeLarge,
have different perspectives and cite different John Van Reenen, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2007.
literatures, a core theme is that digitization “Technology, Information, and the Decentralization
has reduced a number of specific economic of the Firm.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122
32 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

(4): 1759–99. Media and Fake News in the 2016 Election.” Journal
Acemoglu, Daron, and David Autor. 2011. “Skills, Tasks of Economic Perspectives 31 (2): 211–36.
and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Anderson, Chris. 2006. The Long Tail: Why the Future
Earnings.” In Handbook of Labor Economics: Vol- of Business Is Selling Less of More. New York:
ume 4B, edited by David Card and Orley Ashen- Hyperion.
felter, 1043–171. Amsterdam and Boston: Elsevier, Anderson, Eric T., Nathan M. Fong, Duncan I.
North-Holland. Simester, and Catherine E. Tucker. 2010. “How Sales
Acemoglu, Daron, David Laibson, and John A. List. Taxes Affect Customer and Firm Behavior: The Role
2014. “Equalizing Superstars: The Internet and the of Search on the Internet.” Journal of Marketing
Democratization of Education.” American Economic Research 47 (2): 229–39.
Review 104 (5): 523–27. Anderson, James E., and Eric van Wincoop. 2004.
Acquisti, Alessandro, and Christina M. Fong. 2013. “Trade Costs.” Journal of Economic Literature 42
“An Experiment in Hiring Discrimination via Online (3): 691–751.
Social Networks.” Unpublished. Anderson, Simon P., and André de Palma. 2009. “Infor-
Acquisti, Alessandro, and Ralph Gross. 2009. “Pre- mation Congestion.” RAND Journal of Economics 40
dicting Social Security Numbers from Public Data.” (4): 688–709.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106 Anderson, Simon P., and André de Palma. 2013.
(27): 10975–80. “Shouting to Be Heard in Advertising.” Management
Acquisti, Alessandro, Curtis Taylor, and Liad Wagman. Science 59 (7): 1545–56.
2016. “The Economics of Privacy.” Journal of Eco- Anderson, Simon P., and Joshua S. Gans. 2011. “Plat-
nomic Literature 54 (2): 442–92. form Siphoning: Ad-Avoidance and Media Content.”
Acquisti, Alessandro, and Catherine Tucker. 2014. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 3 (4):
“Guns, Privacy, and Crime.” Unpublished. 1–34.
Acquisti, Alessandro, and Hal R. Varian. 2005. “Condi- Anenberg, Elliot, and Edward Kung. 2015. “Informa-
tioning Prices on Purchase History.” Marketing Sci- tion Technology and Product Variety in the City: The
ence 24 (3): 367–81. Case of Food Trucks.” Journal of Urban Economics
Adams, William James, and Janet L. Yellen. 1976. 90: 60–78.
“Commodity Bundling and the Burden of Monop- Antweiler, Werner, and Murray Z. Frank. 2004. “Is All
oly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 (3): 475–98. That Talk Just Noise? The Information Content of
Agrawal, Ajay, Christian Catalini, and Avi Goldfarb. Internet Stock Message Boards.” Journal of Finance
2015. “Crowdfunding: Geography, Social Networks, 59 (3): 1259–94.
and the Timing of Investment Decisions.” Journal of Arnosti, Nick, Marissa Beck, and Paul Milgrom. 2016.
Economics and Management Strategy 24 (2): 253–74. “Adverse Selection and Auction Design for Internet
Agrawal, Ajay, and Avi Goldfarb. 2008. “Restructuring Display Advertising.” American Economic Review
Research: Communication Costs and the Democ- 106 (10): 2852–66.
ratization of University Innovation.” American Eco- Athey, Susan, Emilio Calvano, and Joshua S. Gans.
nomic Review 98 (4): 1578–90. 2018. “The Impact of Consumer Multi-homing on
Agrawal, Ajay, Nicola Lacetera, and Elizabeth Lyons. Advertising Markets and Media Competition.” Man-
2016. “Does Standardized Information in Online agement Science 64 (4): 1574–90.
Markets Disproportionately Benefit Job Applicants Athey, Susan, Christian Catalini, and Catherine Tucker.
from Less Developed Countries?” Journal of Inter- 2017. “The Digital Privacy Paradox: Small Money,
national Economics 103: 1–12. Small Costs, Small Talk.” Massachusetts Institute of
Aguiar, Luis, and Joel Waldfogel. 2018. “As Streaming Technology Sloan Research Paper 5196-17.
Reaches Flood Stage, Does it Stimulate or Depress Athey, Susan, and Joshua S. Gans. 2010. “The Impact
Music Sales?” International Journal of Industrial of Targeting Technology on Advertising Markets and
Organization 57: 278–307. Media Competition.” American Economic Review
Aguiar, Luis, and Joel Waldfogel. 2016. “Digitization, 100 (2): 608–13.
Copyright, and the Welfare Effects of Music Trade.” Athey, Susan, Markus Mobius, and Jeno Pal. 2017.
University of Minnesota Working Paper. “The Impact of News Aggregators on Internet News
Aker, Jenny C. 2010. Digitization from Markets Near Consumption: The Case of Localization.” Stanford
and Far: Mobile Phones and Agricultural Markets in University Technical Report 3353.
Niger.” American Economic Journal: Applied Eco- Athey, Susan, and Scott Stern. 2002. “The Impact of
nomics 2 (3): 46–59. Information Technology on Emergency Health Care
Akerman, Anders, Ingvil Gaarder, and Magne Mogs- Outcomes.” RAND Journal of Economics 33 (3):
tad. 2015. “The Skill Complementarity of Broadband 399–432.
Internet.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 130 (4): Autor, David H. 2001. “Wiring the Labor Market.”
1781–824. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (1): 25–40.
Alaveras, Georgios, and Bertin Martens. 2015. “Inter- Ayres, Ian, Mahzarin Banaji, and Christine Jolls. 2015.
national Trade in Online Services.” Joint Research “Race Effects on eBay.” RAND Journal of Economics
Centre Working Paper on Digital Economy 2015-08. 46 (4): 891–917.
Allcott, Hunt, and Matthew Gentzkow. 2017. “Social Ba, Sulin, and Paul A. Pavlou. 2002. “Evidence of the
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 33

Effect of Trust Building Technology in Electronic for Information Goods?” Management Science 54
Markets: Price Premiums and Buyer Behavior.” MIS (5): 1029–35.
Quarterly 26 (3): 1–26. Bhuller, Manudeep, Tarjei Havnes, Edwin Leuven,
Bajari, Patrick, and Ali Hortaçsu. 2003. “The Win- and Magne Mogstad. 2013. “Broadband Internet: An
ner’s Curse, Reserve Prices, and Endogenous Entry: Information Superhighway to Sex Crime?” Review of
Empirical Insights from eBay Auctions.” RAND Economic Studies 80 (4): 1237–66.
Journal of Economics 34 (2): 329–55. Biasi, Barbara, and Petra Moser. 2018. “Effect of Copy-
Bajari, Patrick, and Ali Hortaçsu. 2004. “Economic rights on Science: Evidence from the U.S. Book
Insights from Internet Auctions.” Journal of Eco- Republication Program.” National Bureau of Eco-
nomic Literature 42 (2): 457–86. nomic Research Working Paper 24255.
Baker, George P., and Thomas N. Hubbard. 2003. Bitzer, Jürgen, and Philipp J. H. Schröder. 2005.
“Make versus Buy in Trucking: Asset Ownership, “Bug-Fixing and Code-Writing: The Private Provi-
Job Design, and Information.” American Economic sion of Open Source Software.” Information Eco-
Review 93 (3): 551–72. nomics and Policy 17 (3): 389–406.
Baker, George P., and Thomas N. Hubbard. 2004. Blake, Thomas, Chris Nosko, and Steven Tadelis. 2015.
“Contractibility and Asset Ownership: On-Board “Consumer Heterogeneity and Paid Search Effec-
Computers and Governance in U.S. Trucking.” tiveness: A Large-Scale Field Experiment.” Econo-
Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (4): 1443–79. metrica 83 (1): 155–74.
Bakos, Yannis. 2001. “The Emerging Landscape for Blake, Thomas, Sarah Moshary, Kane Sweeney, and
Retail E-Commerce.” Journal of Economic Perspec- Steven Tadelis. 2018. “Price Salience and Product
tives 15 (1): 69–80. Choice.” National Bureau of Economic Research
Bakos, Yannis, and Erik Brynjolfsson. 1999. “Bundling Working Paper 25186.
Information Goods: Pricing, Profits, and Efficiency.” Bloom, Nicholas, Mirko Draca, Tobias Kretschmer,
Management Science 45 (12): 1613–30. and Raffaella Sadun. 2010. “The Economic Impact
Bakos, Yannis, and Erik Brynjolfsson. 2000. “Bundling of ICT.” London School of Economics Centre for
and Competition on the Internet.” Marketing Sci- Economic Performance Final Report.
ence 19 (1): 63–82. Bloom, Nicholas, Luis Garicano, Raffaella Sadun, and
Balasubramanian, Sridhar. 1998. “Mail versus Mall: A John Van Reenen. 2014. “The Distinct Effects of
Strategic Analysis of Competition between Direct Information Technology and Communication Tech-
Marketers and Conventional Retailers.” Marketing nology on Firm Organization.” Management Science
Science 17 (3): 181–95. 60 (12): 2859–85.
Bar-Isaac, Heski, Guillermo Caruana, and Vicente Bloom, Nicholas, Raffaella Sadun, and John Van
Cuñat. 2012. “Search, Design, and Market Struc- Reenen. 2012. “Americans Do IT Better: US Mul-
ture.” American Economic Review 102 (2): 1140–60. tinationals and the Productivity Miracle.” American
Barber, Brad M., and Terrance Odean. 2001. “The Economic Review 102 (1): 167–201.
Internet and the Investor.” Journal of Economic Per- Blum, Bernardo S., and Avi Goldfarb. 2006. “Does the
spectives 15 (1): 41–54. Internet Defy the Law of Gravity?” Journal of Inter-
Baye, Michael R., and John Morgan. 2001. “Infor- national Economics 70 (2): 384–405.
mation Gatekeepers on the Internet and the Com- Böhme, Rainer, Nicolas Christin, Benjamin Edelman,
petitiveness of Homogeneous Product Markets.” and Tyler Moore. 2015. “Bitcoin: Economics, Tech-
American Economic Review 91 (3): 454–74. nology, and Governance.” Journal of Economic Per-
Baye, Michael R., John Morgan, and Patrick Schol- spectives 29 (2): 213–38.
ten. 2004. “Price Dispersion in the Small and in the Borenstein, Severin, and Garth Saloner. 2001. “Eco-
Large: Evidence from an Internet Price Comparison nomics and Electronic Commerce.” Journal of Eco-
Site.” Journal of Industrial Economics 52 (4): 463–96. nomic Perspectives 15 (1): 3–12.
Bechtold, Stefan, and Catherine Tucker. 2014. “Trade- Bourreau, Marc, Frago Kourandi, and Tommaso Val-
marks, Triggers, and Online Search.” Journal of letti. 2015. “Net Neutrality with Competing Internet
Empirical Legal Studies 11 (4): 718–50. Platforms.” Journal of Industrial Economics 63 (1):
Belo, Rodrigo, Pedro Ferreira, and Rahul Telang. 2014. 30–73.
“Broadband in School: Impact on Student Perfor- Boxell, Levi, Matthew Gentzkow, and Jesse M. Shapiro.
mance.” Management Science 60 (2): 265–82. 2017. “Greater Internet Use is Not Associated with
Bergemann, Dirk, and Alessandro Bonatti. 2011. Faster Growth in Political Polarization among US
“Targeting in Advertising Markets: Implications for Demographic Group.” Proceedings of the National
Offline versus Online Media.” RAND Journal of Eco- Academy of Sciences 114 (40): 10612–17.
nomics 42 (3): 417–43. Brand, Keith, Martin Gaynor, Patrick McAlvanah,
Besen, Stanley, Paul Milgrom, Bridger Mitchell, and David Schmidt, and Elizabeth Schneirov. 2014.
Padmanabhan Srinagesh. 2001. “Advances in Rout- “Economics at the FTC: Office Supply Retailers
ing Technologies and Internet Peering Agreements.” Redux, Healthcare Quality-Efficiencies Analysis, and
American Economic Review 91 (2): 292–96. Litigation of an Alleged Get-Rich-Quick Scheme.”
Bhargava, Hemant K., and Vidyanand Choudhary. Review of Industrial Organization 45 (4): 325–44.
2008. “Research Note—When is Versioning Optimal Brandimarte, Laura, Alessandro Acquisti, and George
34 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

Loewenstein. 2012. “Misplaced Confidences: Privacy Providers.” RAND Journal of Economics 34 (2):
and the Control Paradox.” Social Psychological and 309–28.
Personality Science 4 (3): 340–47. Cairncross, Frances. 1997. The Death of Distance: How
Bresnahan, Timothy F., Erik Brynjolfsson, and Lorin the Communications Revolution Is Changing Our
M. Hitt. 2002. “Information Technology, Workplace Lives. Cambridge and London: Harvard Business
Organization, and the Demand for Skilled Labor: School Press.
Firm-Level Evidence.” Quarterly Journal of Eco- Calzada, Joan, and Ricard Gil. Forthcoming. “What Do
nomics 117 (1): 339–76. News Aggregators Do? Evidence from Google News
Bresnahan, Timothy, and Shane Greenstein. 1996. in Spain and Germany.” Marketing Science.
“Technical Progress and Co-invention in Computing Campbell, James, Avi Goldfarb, and Catherine Tucker.
and in the Uses of Computers.” In Brookings Papers 2015. “Privacy Regulation and Market Structure.”
on Economic Activity: Microeconomics: 1–78. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 24
Brown, Jeffrey R., and Austan Goolsbee. 2002. “Does (1): 47–73.
the Internet Make Markets More Competitive? Evi- Campbell-Kelly, Martin. 2004. From Airline Reserva-
dence from the Life Insurance Industry.” Journal of tions to Sonic the Hedgehog: A History of the Soft-
Political Economy 110 (3): 481–507. ware Industry. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, Felix Eggers, and Avinash Ganna- Carbajo, José, David de Meza, and Daniel J. Seid-
maneni. 2017. “Using Massive Online Choice Exper- mann. 1990. “A Strategic Motivation for Commodity
iments to Measure Changes in Well-Being.” MIT Bundling.” Journal of Industrial Economics 38 (3):
Working Paper. 283–98.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Lorin M. Hitt. 2003. “Comput- Carlton, Dennis W., Joshua S. Gans, and Michael Wald-
ing Productivity: Firm-Level Evidence.” Review of man. 2010. “Why Tie a Product Consumers Do Not
Economics and Statistics 85 (4): 793–808. Use?” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics
Brynjolfsson, Erik, Yu Hu, and Mohammad S. Rahman. 2 (3): 85–105.
2009. “Battle of the Retail Channels: How Product Castells, Manuel. 2001. The Internet Galaxy: Reflec-
Selection and Geography Drive Cross-Channel Com- tions on the Internet, Business, and Society. Oxford
petition.” Management Science 55 (11): 1755–65. and New York: Oxford University Press.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, Yu Hu, and Duncan Simester. Catalini, Christian, and Joshua S. Gans. 2016. “Some
2011. “Goodbye Pareto Principle, Hello Long Tail: Simple Economics of the Blockchain.” https://papers.
The Effect of Search Costs on the Concentration ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2874598.
of Product Sales.” Management Science 57 (8): Catalini, Christian, and Catherine E. Tucker. 2017.
1373–86. “When Early Adopters Don’t Adopt.” Science 357
Brynjolfsson, Erik, Yu Hu, and Michael D. Smith. (6347): 135–36.
2003. “Consumer Surplus in the Digital Economy: Ceruzzi, Paul E. 2003. A History of Modern Comput-
Estimating the Value of Increased Product Variety at ing, Second edition. Cambridge and London: MIT
Online Booksellers.” Management Science 49 (11): Press.
1580–96. Chan, Jason, Anindya Ghose, and Robert Seamans.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Kristina McElheran. 2016. 2016. “The Internet and Racial Hate Crime: Offline
“The Rapid Adoption of Data-Driven Decision-Mak- Spillovers from Online Access.” MIS Quarterly 40
ing.” American Economic Review 106 (5): 133–39. (2): 381–403.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and JooHee Oh. 2012. “The Atten- Chen, Yongmin. 1997. “Paying Customers to Switch.”
tion Economy: Measuring the Value of Free Digital Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 6
Services on the Internet.” https://aisel.aisnet.org/cgi/ (4): 877–97.
viewcontent.cgi?article=1045&context=icis2012. Chen, Yongmin, and Tianie Zhang. 2011. “Equilibrium
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Adam Saunders. 2010. Wired Price Dispersion with Heterogeneous Searchers.”
for Innovation: How Information Technology Is International Journal of Industrial Organization 29
Reshaping the Economy. Cambridge and London: (6): 645–54.
MIT Press. Chevalier, Judith A., and Dina Mayzlin. 2006. “The
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Michael D. Smith. 2000. “Fric- Effect of Word of Mouth on Sales: Online Book
tionless Commerce? A Comparison of Internet and Reviews.” Journal of Marketing Research 43 (3):
Conventional Retailers.” Management Science 46 (4): 345–54.
563–85. Chiou, Lesley, and Catherine Tucker. 2012. “How Does
Cabral, Luís. 2012. “Reputation on the Internet.” the Use of Trademarks By Third-Party Sellers Affect
In The Oxford Handbook of the Digital Economy, Online Search?” Marketing Science 31 (5): 819–37.
edited by Martin Peitz and Joel Waldfogel, 344–54. Chiou, Lesley, and Catherine Tucker. 2013. “Paywalls
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. and the Demand for News.” Information Economics
Cabral, Luís, and Ali Hortaçsu. 2010. “The Dynamics and Policy 25 (2): 61–69.
of Seller Reputation: Evidence from eBay.” Journal Chiou, Lesley, and Catherine Tucker. 2017. “Content
of Industrial Economics 58 (1): 54–78. Aggregation By Platforms: The Case of the News
Caillaud, Bernard, and Bruno Jullien. 2003. “Chicken Media.” Journal of Economics and Management
& Egg: Competition among Intermediation Service Strategy 26 (4): 782–805.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 35

Choi, Jeonghye, and David R. Bell. 2011. “Preference 2014a. “Piracy and Copyright Enforcement Mech-
Minorities and the Internet.” Journal of Marketing anisms. In Innovation Policy and the Economy,
Research 48 (4): 670–82. Volume 14, edited by Josh Lerner and Scott Stern,
Choi, Jay Pil, Doh-Shin Jeon, and Byung-Cheol Kim. 25–61. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
2015. “Net Neutrality, Business Models, and Inter- Danaher, Brett, Michael D. Smith, Rahul Telang,
net Interconnection.” American Economic Journal: and Siwen Chen. 2014b. “The Effect of Graduated
Microeconomics 7 (3): 104–41. Response Anti-piracy Laws on Music Sales: Evi-
Choi, Tsan-Ming., ed. 2012. Handbook of Newsvendor dence from an Event Study in France.” Journal of
Problems: Models, Extensions and Applications. New Industrial Economics 62 (3): 541–53
York: Springer Science and Business Media. de Cornière, Alexandre. 2016. “Search Advertising.”
Chu, Chenghuan Sean, Phillip Leslie, and Alan American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 8 (3):
Sorensen. 2011. “Bundle-Size Pricing as an Approx- 156–88.
imation to Mixed Bundling.” American Economic De Los Santos, Babur, Ali Hortaçsu, and Matthijs R.
Review 101 (1): 263–303. Wildenbeest. 2012. “Testing Models of Consumer
Clarke, George R. G. 2008. “Has the Internet Increased Search Using Data on Web Browsing and Purchas-
Exports for Firms from Low and Middle-Income ing Behavior.” American Economic Review 102 (6):
Countries?” Information Economics and Policy 20 2955–80.
(1): 16–37. Dellarocas, Chrysanthos. 2003. “The Digitization of
Cohen, Peter, Robert Hahn, Jonathan Hall, Steven Word of Mouth: Promise and Challenges of Online
Levitt, and Robert Metcalfe. 2016. “Using Big Data Feedback Mechanisms.” Management Science 49
to Estimate Consumer Surplus: The Case of Uber.” (10): 1407–24.
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Deneckere, Raymond J., and R. Preston McAfee. 1996.
Paper 22627. “Damaged Goods.” Journal of Economics and Man-
Cornes, Richard, and Todd Sandler. 1986. The Theory agement Strategy 5 (2): 149–74.
of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods, Sec- Diamond, Peter A. 1971. “A Model of Price Adjust-
ond edition. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge ment.” Journal of Economic Theory 3 (2): 156–68.
University Press. Dinerstein, Michael, Liran Einav, Jonathan Levin, and
Corrado, Carol A., Charles Hulten, and Daniel Sichel. Neel Sundaresan. 2018. “Consumer Price Search
2009. “Intangible Capital and U.S. Economic and Platform Design in Internet Commerce.” Amer-
Growth.” Review of Income and Wealth 55 (3): ican Economic Review 108 (7): 1820–59.
661–85. Dinlersoz, Emin M., and Pedro Pereira. 2007. “On the
Corrado, Carol A., and Charles R. Hulten. 2010. “How Diffusion of Electronic Commerce.” International
Do You Measure a ‘Technological Revolution’?” Journal of Industrial Organization 25 (3): 541–74.
American Economic Review 100 (2): 99–104. Disdier, Anne-Célia, and Keith Head. 2008. “The Puz-
Corts, Kenneth S. 1998. “Third-Degree Price Discrim- zling Persistence of the Distance Effect on Bilateral
ination in Oligopoly: All-Out Competition and Stra- Trade.” Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (1):
tegic Commitment.” RAND Journal of Economics 29 37–48.
(2): 306–23. Doleac, Jennifer L. 2017. “The Effects of DNA Data-
Crémer, Jacques, Patrick Rey, and Jean Tirole. 2000. bases on Crime.” American Economic Journal:
“Connectivity in the Commercial Internet.” Journal Applied Economics 9 (1): 165–201.
of Industrial Economics 48 (4): 433–72. Doleac, Jennifer L., and Luke C. D. Stein. 2013. “The
Cristea, Anca D. 2011. “Buyer–Seller Relationships Visible Hand: Race and Online Market Outcomes.”
in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. States’ Economic Journal 123 (572): F469–92.
Exports and Business-Class Travel.” Journal of Inter- Draca, Mirko, Raffaella Sadun, and John Van Reenen.
national Economics 84 (2): 207–20. 2009. “Productivity and ICTs: A Review of the Evi-
Cullen, Zoe, and Chiara Farronato. 2016. “Outsourc- dence.” In The Oxford Handbook of Information and
ing Tasks Online: Matching Supply and Demand Communication Technologies, edited by Chrisanthi
on Peer-to-Peer Internet Platforms.” HBS Working Avgerou, Robin Mansell, Fanny Quah, and Roger
Paper. Siverstone, 100–147. Oxford and New York: Oxford
Cullen, Zoe, and Bobak Pakzad-Hurson. 2017. “Equi- University Press.
librium Effects of Pay Transparency in a Simple Dranove, David, Chris Forman, Avi Goldfarb, and
Labor Market.” Harvard University Working Paper. Shane Greenstein. 2014. “The Trillion Dollar Conun-
Dana, James D., Jr., and Eugene Orlov. 2014. “Internet drum: Complementarities and Health Information
Penetration and Capacity Utilization in the US Air- Technology.” American Economic Journal: Economic
line Industry.” American Economic Journal: Micro- Policy 6 (4): 239–70.
economics 6 (4): 106–37. Dube, Jean-Pierre, and Sanjog Misra. 2017. “Scalable
Danaher, Brett, and Michael D. Smith. 2014. “Gone Price Targeting.” University of Chicago Working
in 60 Seconds: The Impact of the Megaupload Paper.
Shutdown on Movie Sales.” International Journal of Duch-Brown, Néstor, Lukasz Grzybowski, André
Industrial Organization 33: 1–8. Romahn, and Frank Verboven. 2017. “The Impact
Danaher, Brett, Michael D. Smith, and Rahul Telang. of Online Sales on Consumers and Firms: Evidence
36 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

from Consumer Electronics.” International Journal Technology Law 10 (2): 251–64.


of Industrial Organization 52: 30–62. Farrell, Joseph, and Timothy Simcoe. 2012. “Four
Economides, Nicholas, and Benjamin E. Herma- Paths to Compatibility.” In The Oxford Handbook
lin. 2012. “The Economics of Network Neutrality.” of the Digital Economy, edited by Martin Peitz and
RAND Journal of Economics 43 (4): 602–29. Joel Waldfogel, 34–58. Oxford and New York: Oxford
Economides, Nicholas, and Przemyslaw Jeziorski. University Press.
2017. “Mobile Money in Tanzania.” Marketing Sci- Farronato, Chiara, and Andrey Fradkin. 2018. “The
ence 36 (6): 815–37. Welfare Effects of Peer Entry in the Accommoda-
Edelman, Benjamin G. 2009. “Priced and Unpriced tion Market: The Case of Airbnb.” National Bureau
Online Markets.” Journal of Economic Perspectives of Economic Research Working Paper 24361.
23 (3): 21–36. Fay, Scott, and Jinhong Xie. 2008. “Probabilistic Goods:
Edelman, Benjamin G., and Michael Luca. 2014. “Dig- A Creative Way of Selling Products and Services.”
ital Discrimination: The Case of Airbnb.com.” Har- Marketing Science 27 (4): 674–90.
vard Business School Working Paper 14-054. Ferreira, Fernando, and Joel Waldfogel. 2013. “Pop
Edelman, Benjamin G., Michael Ostrovsky, and Internationalism: Has Half a Century of World
Michael Schwarz. 2007. “Internet Advertising and Music Trade Displaced Local Culture?” Economic
the Generalized Second-Price Auction: Selling Bil- Journal 123 (569): 634–64.
lions of Dollars Worth of Keywords.” American Eco- Fleder, Daniel, and Kartik Hosanagar. 2009. “Block-
nomic Review 97 (1): 242–59. buster Culture’s Next Rise or Fall: The Impact of
Eichengreen, Barry, Romain Lafarguette, and Arnaud Recommender Systems on Sales Diversity.” Manage-
Mehl. 2016. “Cables, Sharks and Servers: Technology ment Science 55 (5): 697–712.
and the Geography of he Foreign Exchange Market.” Forman, Chris, Anindya Ghose, and Avi Goldfarb.
National Bureau of Economic Research Working 2009. “Competition between Local and Elec-
Paper 21884. tronic Markets: How the Benefit of Buying Online
Einav, Liran, Chiara Farronato, Jonathan Levin, and Depends on Where You Live.” Management Science
Neel Sundaresan. 2018. “Auctions versus Posted 55 (1): 47–57.
Prices in Online Markets.” Journal of Political Econ- Forman, Chris, Anindya Ghose, and Batia Wiesenfeld.
omy 126 (1): 178–215. 2008. “Examining the Relationship between Reviews
Einav, Liran, Peter J. Klenow, Benjamin Klopack, and Sales: the Role of Reviewer Identity Disclo-
Jonathan D. Levin, Larry Levin, and Wayne Best. sure in Electronic Markets.” Information Systems
2017. “Assessing the Gains from E-Commerce.” Research 19 (3): 291–313.
Unpublished. Forman, Chris, Avi Goldfarb, and Shane Greenstein.
Einav, Liran, Dan Knoepfle, Jonathan Levin, and Neel 2005. “How Did Location Affect Adoption of the
Sundaresan. 2014. “Sales Taxes and Internet Com- Commercial Internet? Global Village vs. Urban
merce.” American Economic Review 104 (1): 1–26. Leadership.” Journal of Urban Economics 58 (3):
Ellison, Glenn. 2011. “Is Peer Review in Decline?” 389–420.
Economic Inquiry 49 (3): 635–57. Forman, Chris, Avi Goldfarb, and Shane Greenstein.
Ellison, Glenn, and Sara Fisher Ellison. 2005. “Lessons 2008. “Understanding the Inputs into Innovation:
about Markets from the Internet.” Journal of Eco- Do Cities Substitute for Internal Firm Resources?”
nomic Perspectives 19 (2): 139–58. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 17
Ellison, Glenn, and Sara Fisher Ellison. 2009a. “Search, (2): 295–316.
Obfuscation, and Price Elasticities on the Internet.” Forman, Chris, Avi Goldfarb, and Shane Greenstein.
Econometrica 77 (2): 427–52. 2012. “The Internet and Local Wages: A Puzzle.”
Ellison, Glenn, and Sara Fisher Ellison. 2009b. “Tax American Economic Review 102 (1): 556–75.
Sensitivity and Home State Preferences in Internet Forman, Chris, and Kristina McElheran. 2013.
Purchasing.” American Economic Journal: Economic “The Digital Reorganization of Firm Boundaries.”
Policy 1 (2): 53–71. Unpublished.
Ellison, Glenn, and Sara Fisher Ellison. 2014. “Match Forman, Chris, and Nicolas van Zeebroeck. 2012.
Quality, Search, and the Internet Market for Used “From Wires to Partners: How the Internet Has Fos-
Books.” Massachusetts Institute of Technology. tered R&D Collaborations within Firms.” Manage-
Ershov, Daniel. 2017. “The Effects of Consumer ment Science 58 (8): 1549–68.
Search Costs on Entry and Quality in the Mobile App Fradkin, Andrey. 2017. “Search, Matching, and the
Market.” University of Toronto Working Paper. Role of Digital Marketplace Design in Enabling
Evans, David S. 2009. “The Online Advertising Indus- Trade: Evidence from Airbnb.” Unpublished.
try: Economics, Evolution, and Privacy.” Journal of Fradkin, Andrey, Elena Grewal, and David Holtz. 2017.
Economic Perspectives 23 (3): 37–60. “The Determinants of Online Review Informative-
Falck, Oliver, Robert Gold, and Stephan Heblich. ness: Evidence from Field Experiments on Airbnb.”
2014. “E-lections: Voting Behavior and the Internet.” MIT Sloan School of Management Working Paper.
American Economic Review 104 (7): 2238–65. Freund, Caroline L., and Diana Weinhold. 2004.
Farrell, Joseph. 2012. “Can Privacy be Just Another “The Effect of the Internet on International Trade.”
Good?” Journal on Telecommunications and High ­Journal of International Economics 62 (1): 171–89.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 37

Friedman, Thomas L.. 2005. The World Is Flat: A Brief ­ argaining in the Broadband Industry.” University of
B
History of the Twenty-First Century. New York: Far- Toronto Working Paper.
rar, Straus and Giroux. Goldfarb, Avi. 2006. “The (Teaching) Role of Univer-
Fudenberg, Drew, and Jean Tirole. 1998. “Upgrades, sities in the Diffusion of the Internet.” International
Tradeins, and Buybacks.” RAND Journal of Econom- Journal of Industrial Organization 24 (2): 203–25.
ics 29 (2): 235–58. Goldfarb, Avi. 2014. “What Is Different about Online
Fudenberg, Drew, and Jean Tirole. 2000. “Customer Advertising?” Review of Industrial Organization 44
Poaching and Brand Switching.” RAND Journal of (2): 115–29.
Economics 31 (4): 634–57. Goldfarb, Avi, Ryan C. McDevitt, Sampsa Samila, and
Fudenberg, Drew, and J. Miguel Villas-Boas. 2007. Brian S. Silverman. 2015. “The Effect of Social Inter-
“Behavior-Based Price Discrimination and Cus- action on Economic Transactions: Evidence from
tomer Recognition.” In Economics and Information Changes in Two Retail Formats.” Management Sci-
Systems, edited by Terrence Hendershott, 377–436. ence 61 (12): 2963–81.
Bingley, UK: Emerald. Goldfarb, Avi, and Jeff Prince. 2008. “Internet Adop-
Fudenberg, Drew, and J. Miguel Villas-Boas. 2012. tion and Usage Patterns Are Different: Implications
“Price Discrimination in the Digital Economy.” for the Digital Divide.” Information Economics and
In The Oxford Handbook of the Digital Economy, Policy 20 (1): 2–15.
edited by Martin Peitz and Joel Waldfogel, 254–72. Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2011a. “Adver-
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. tising Bans and the Substitutability of Online and
Gal-Or, Esther, and Anindya Ghose. 2005. “The Eco- Offline Advertising.” Journal of Marketing Research
nomic Incentives for Sharing Security Information.” 48 (2): 207–27.
Information Systems Research 16 (2): 186–208. Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2011b. “Online
Gandal, Neil. 2006. “Native Language and Internet Advertising.” Advances in Computers 81: 289–315.
Usage.” International Journal of the Sociology of Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2011c. “Online
Language 182: 25–40. Display Advertising: Targeting and Obtrusiveness.”
Gans, Joshua S., Avi Goldfarb, and Mara Lederman. Marketing Science 30 (3): 389–404.
2016. “Exit, Tweets, and Loyalty.” University of Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2011d. “Privacy
Toronto Rotman School of Management Working Regulation and Online Advertising.” Management
Paper 2889388. Science 57 (1): 57–71.
Garicano, Luis. 2000. “Hierarchies and the Organiza- Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2011e. “Search
tion of Knowledge in Production.” Journal of Politi- Engine Advertising: Channel Substitution When
cal Economy 108 (5): 874–904. Pricing Ads to Context.” Management Science 57 (3):
Garicano, Luis. 2010. “Policemen, Managers, Law- 458–70.
yers: New Results on Complementarities between Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2011f. “Substitu-
Organization and Information and Communication tion between Offline and Online Advertising Mar-
Technology.” International Journal of Industrial kets.” Journal of Competition Law and Economics 7
Organization 28 (4): 355–58. (1): 37–44.
Gaspar, Jess, and Edward L. Glaeser. 1998. “Informa- Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2012a. “Privacy
tion Technology and the Future of Cities.” Journal of and Innovation.” In Innovation Policy and the Econ-
Urban Economics 43 (1): 136–56. omy, Volume 12, edited by Josh Lerner and Scott
Gentzkow, Matthew. 2007. “Valuing New Goods in a Stern, 65–89. Chicago and London: University of
Model with Complementarity: Online Newspapers.” Chicago Press.
American Economic Review 97 (3): 713–44. Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2012b. “Shifts in
Gentzkow, Matthew. 2014. “Trading Dollars for Dol- Privacy Concerns.” American Economic Review 102
lars: The Price of Attention Online and Offline.” (3): 349–53.
American Economic Review 104 (5): 481–88. Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 2008. The Race
Gentzkow, Matthew, and Jesse M. Shapiro. 2011. between Education and Technology. Cambridge and
“Ideological Segregation Online and Offline.” Quar- London: Harvard University Press.
terly Journal of Economics 126 (4): 1799–839. Goldmanis, Maris, Ali Hortaçsu, Chad Syverson, and
Gertner, Robert H., and Robert S. Stillman. 2001. Önsel Emre. 2010. “E-Commerce and the Market
“Vertical Integration and Internet Strategies in the Structure of Retail Industries.” Economic Journal
Apparel Industry.” Journal of Industrial Economics 120 (545): 651–82.
49 (4): 417–40. Gomez-Herrera, Estrella, Bertin Martens, and Geo-
Ghani, Ejaz, William R. Kerr, and Christopher Stan- mina Turlea. 2014. “The Drivers and Impediments
ton. 2014. “Diasporas and Outsourcing: Evidence for Cross-Border e-Commerce in the EU.” Informa-
from oDesk and India.” Management Science 60 (7): tion Economics and Policy 28: 83–96.
1677–97. Goolsbee, Austan. 2000. “In a World without Borders:
Giorcelli, Michela, and Petra Moser. 2016. “Copy- The Impact of Taxes on Internet Commerce.” Quar-
rights and Creativity: Evidence from Italian Operas.” terly Journal of Economics 115 (2): 561–76.
Unpublished. Goolsbee, Austan. 2001. “Competition in the C ­ omputer
Goetz, Daniel. 2017. “Competition and Dynamic Industry: Online versus Retail.” Journal of Industrial
38 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

Economics 49 (4): 487–99. ­Cambridge and London: MIT Press.


Goolsbee, Austan, and Peter J. Klenow. 2006. “Valuing Hampton, Keith, and Barry Wellman. 2003. “Neigh-
Consumer Products By the Time Spent Using Them: boring in Netville: How the Internet Supports Com-
An Application to the Internet.” American Economic munity and Social Capital in a Wired Suburb.” City
Review 96 (2): 108–13. and Community 2 (4): 277–311.
Gordon, Brett R, Florian Zettelmeyer, Neha Bhar- Hart, Oliver D., and Jean Tirole. 1988. “Contract Rene-
gava, and Dan Chapsky. 2016. “A Comparison of gotiation and Coasian Dynamics.” Review of Eco-
Approaches to Advertising Measurement: Evi- nomic Studies 55 (4): 509–40.
dence from Big Field Experiments at Facebook.” Heald, Paul J. 2009. “Does the Song Remain the Same?
Unpublished. An Empirical Study of Bestselling Musical Composi-
Gordon, Lawrence A., and Martin P. Loeb. 2002. “The tions (1913–1932) and Their Use in Cinema (1968–
Economics of Information Security Investment.” 2007).” Case Western Reserve Law Review 60 (1):
ACM Transactions on Information and System Secu- 1–46.
rity 5 (4): 438–57. Henkel, Joachim. 2009. “Champions of Revealing—
Gorodnichenko, Yuriy, and Oleksandr Talavera. 2017. The Role of Open Source Developers in Commer-
“Price Setting in Online Markets: Basic Facts, Inter- cial Firms.” Industrial and Corporate Change 18 (3):
national Comparisons, and Cross-Border Integra- 435–71.
tion.” American Economic Review 107 (1): 249–82. Hermalin, Benjamin E., and Michael L. Katz. 2006.
Greenstein, Shane. 2000. “Building and Delivering the “Privacy, Property Rights and Efficiency: The Eco-
Virtual World: Commercializing Services for Inter- nomics of Privacy as Secrecy.” Quantitative Market-
net Access.” Journal of Industrial Economics 48 (4): ing and Economics 4 (3): 209–39.
391–411. Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty:
Greenstein, Shane. 2015. How the Internet Became Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and
Commercial: Innovation, Privatization, and the Birth States. Cambridge and London: Harvard University
of a New Network. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton Press.
University Press. Hollenbeck, Brett. 2018. “Online Reputation Mecha-
Greenstein, Shane, and Ryan C. McDevitt. 2011. “The nisms and the Decreasing Value of Chain Affiliation.”
Broadband Bonus: Estimating Broadband Internet’s Journal of Marketing Research 55 (5): 636–54.
Economic Value.” Telecommunications Policy 35 (7): Honka, Elisabeth. 2014. “Quantifying Search and
617–32. Switching Costs in the US Auto Insurance Industry.”
Greenstein, Shane, and Frank Nagle. 2014. “Digital RAND Journal of Economics 45 (4): 847–84.
Dark Matter and the Economic Contribution of Hortaçsu, Ali, F. Asís Martínez-Jerez, and Jason Doug-
Apache.” Research Policy 43 (4): 623–31. las. 2009. “The Geography of Trade in Online Trans-
Greenstein, Shane, Martin Peitz, and Tommaso Valletti. actions: Evidence from eBay and MercadoLibre.”
2016. “Net Neutrality: A Fast Lane to Understanding American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 1 (1):
the Trade-Offs.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 30 53–74.
(2): 127–50. Horton, John J., and Richard J. Zeckhauser. 2016.
Greenstein, Shane, and Feng Zhu. 2012. “Is Wikipe- “Owning, Using and Renting: Some Simple Eco-
dia Biased?” American Economic Review 102 (3): nomics of the ‘Sharing Economy’.” National Bureau
343–48. of Economic Research Working Paper 22029.
Hafner, Katie, and Matthew Lyon. 1996. Where Wiz- Hossain, Tanjim, and John Morgan. 2006. “. . . Plus
ards Stay Up Late: The Origins of the Internet. New Shipping and Handling: Revenue (non) Equivalence
York: Touchstone, Simon & Schuster. in Field Experiments on eBay.” Advances in Eco-
Hagiu, Andrei. 2012. “Software Platforms.” In The nomic Analysis and Policy 5 (2).
Oxford Handbook of the Digital Economy, edited by Houser, Daniel, and John Wooders. 2006. “Reputation
Martin Peitz and Joel Waldfogel, 59–82. Oxford and in Auctions: Theory, and Evidence from eBay.” Jour-
New York: Oxford University Press. nal of Economics and Management Strategy 15 (2):
Hagiu, Andrei, and Bruno Jullien. 2011. “Why Do 353–69.
Intermediaries Divert Search?” RAND Journal of Hui, Xiang. Forthcoming. “Facilitating Inclusive
Economics 42 (2): 337–62. Global Trade: Evidence from a Field Experiment.”
Halaburda, Hanna, and Yaron Yehezkel. 2013. “Plat- Management Science.
form Competition under Asymmetric Information.” Hui, Xiang, Maryam Saeedi, Zeqian Shen, and Neel
American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 5 (3): Sundaresan. 2016. “Reputation and Regulations:
22–68. Evidence from eBay.” Management Science 62 (12):
Hall, Jonathan, Cory Kendrick, and Chris Nosko. 2016. 3604–16.
“The Effects of Uber’s Surge Pricing: A Case Study.” Jensen, Robert. 2007. “The Digital Provide: Informa-
Unpublished. tion (Technology), Market Performance, and Wel-
Haltiwanger, John, and Ron S. Jarmin. 2000. “Mea- fare in the South Indian Fisheries Sector.” Quarterly
suring the Digital Economy.” In Understanding Journal of Economics 122 (3): 879–924.
the Digital Economy: Data, Tools, and Research, Jin, Ginger Zhe, and Andrew Kato. 2006. “Price,
edited by Erik Brynjolfsson and Brian Kahin, 13–33. ­Quality, and Reputation: Evidence from an Online
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 39

Field Experiment.” RAND Journal of Economics 37 on Wikipedia?” Centre for European Economic
(4): 983–1005. Research Discussion Paper 15-078.
Jin, Ginger Zhe, and Andrew Kato. 2007. “Dividing Laffont, Jean-Jacques, Scott Marcus, Patrick Rey, and
Online and Offline: A Case Study.” Review of Eco- Jean Tirole. 2001. “Internet Peering.” American Eco-
nomic Studies 74 (3): 981–1004. nomic Review 91 (2): 287–91.
Jin, Wang, and Kristina McElheran. 2017. “Economies Laffont, Jean-Jacques, Scott Marcus, Patrick Rey, and
before Scale: Survival and Performance of Young Jean Tirole. 2003. “Internet Interconnection and the
Plants in the Age of Cloud Computing.” Rotman Off-Net-Cost Pricing Principle.” RAND Journal of
School of Management Working Paper 3112901. Economics 34 (2): 370–90.
Johnson, Garrett A. 2014. “The Impact of Privacy Pol- Lambrecht, Anja, and Kanishka Misra. 2017. “Fee or
icy on the Auction Market for Online Display Adver- Free: When Should Firms Charge for Online Con-
tising.” SSRN 233193. tent?” Management Science 63 (4): 1150–65.
Johnson, Justin Pappas. 2002. “Open Source Software: Lambrecht, Anja, and Catherine Tucker. Forthcoming.
Private Provision of a Public Good.” Journal of Eco- “When Does Retargeting Work? Information Spec-
nomics and Management Strategy 11 (4): 637–62. ificity in Online Advertising.” Journal of Marketing
Johnson, Justin Pappas. 2013. “Targeted Advertising ad Research 50 (5): 561–76.
Advertising Avoidance.” RAND Journal of Economics Lambrecht, Anja, and Catherine Tucker. 2018. “Algo-
44 (1): 128–44. rithmic Bias? An Empirical Study into Apparent
Jorgenson, Dale W., Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh. Gender-Based Discrimination in the Display of
2008. “A Retrospective Look at the U.S. Productivity STEM Career Ads.” Management Science.
Growth Resurgence.” Journal of Economic Perspec- Leamer, Edward E. 2007. “A Flat World, a Level Play-
tives 22 (1): 3–24. ing Field, a Small World After all, or None of the
Jullien, Bruno. 2012. “Two-Sided B to B Platforms.” Above? A Review of Thomas L. Friedman’s The
In The Oxford Handbook of the Digital Economy, World Is Flat.” Journal of Economic Literature 45
edited by Martin Peitz and Joel Waldfogel, 161–85. (1): 83–126.
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. Lee, Jinhyung, Jeffrey S. McCullough, and Robert J.
Katz, Lawrence, and David H. Autor. 1999. “Changes Town. 2013. “The Impact of Health Information
in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequality.” In Technology on Hospital Productivity.” RAND Jour-
Handbook of Labor Economics: Volume 3A, edited nal of Economics 44 (3): 545–68.
by Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, 1463–555. Lee, Robin S., and Tim Wu. 2009. “Subsidizing Cre-
Amsterdam and New York: Elsevier: North-Holland. ativity through Network Design: Zero-Pricing and
Kim, Jin-Hyuk, and Liad Wagman. 2015. “Screening Net Neutrality.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23
Incentives and Privacy Protection in Financial Mar- (3): 61–76.
kets: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.” RAND Lemley, Mark A. 2003. “Place and Cyberspace.” Cali-
Journal of Economics 46 (1): 1–22. fornia Law Review 91 (2): 521–42.
Kolko, Jed. 2012. “Broadband and Local Growth.” Lenard, Thomas M., and Paul H. Rubin. 2009. “In
Journal of Urban Economics 71 (1): 100–113. Defence of Data: Information and the Costs of Pri-
Krautheim, Sebastian. 2012. “Heterogeneous Firms, vacy.” Washington, DC: Technology Policy Institute.
Exporter Networks and the Effect of Distance on Lendle, Andreas, Marcelo Olarreaga, Simon Schropp,
International Trade.” Journal of International Eco- and Pierre-Louis Vezina. 2016. “There Goes Gravity:
nomics 87 (1): 27–35. eBay and the Death of Distance.” Economic Journal
Kremer, Michael, Conner Brannen, and Rachel Gel- 126 (591): 406–41.
nnerster. 2013. “The Challenge of Education and Lerner, Josh, Parag A. Pathak, and Jean Tirole. 2006.
Learning in the Developing World.” Science 340 “The Dynamics of Open-Source Contributors.”
(6130): 297–300. American Economic Review 96 (2): 114–18.
Kroft, Kory, and Devin G. Pope. 2014. “Does Online Lerner, Josh, and Jean Tirole. 2002. “Some Simple
Search Crowd Out Traditional Search and Improve Economics of Open Source.” Journal of Industrial
Matching Efficiency? Evidence from Craigslist.” Economics 50 (2): 197–234.
Journal of Labor Economics 32 (2): 259–303. Levin, Jonathan, and Paul Milgrom. 2010. “Online
Krugman, Paul. 1979. “A Model of Innovation, Technol- Advertising: Heterogeneity and Conflation in Mar-
ogy Transfer, and the World Distribution of Income.” ket Design.” American Economic Review 100 (2):
Journal of Political Economy 87 (2): 253–66. 603–07.
Kuhn, Peter, and Hani Mansour. 2014. “Is Internet Lewis, Randall, and Justin M. Rao. 2015. “The Unfa-
Job Search Still Ineffective?” Economic Journal 124 vorable Economics of Measuring the Returns to
(581): 1213–33. Advertising.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 130
Kuhn, Peter, and Mikal Skuterud. 2004. ‘Internet Job (4): 1941–73.
Search and Unemployment Durations.” American Lewis, Randall, Justin M. Rao, and David H. Reiley.
Economic Review 94 (1): 218–32. 2015. “Measuring the Effects of Advertising: The
Kummer, Michael, Olga Slivko, and Michael Zhang. Digital Frontier.” In Economic Analysis of the Dig-
2015. “Economic Downturn and Volunteering: ital Economy, edited by Avi Goldfarb, Shane M.
Do Economic Crises Affect Content Generation ­Greenstein, and Catherine E. Tucker, 191–218. Chi-
40 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

cago and London: University of Chicago Press. “­Economic FAQs about the Internet.” Journal of
Lewis, Randall, and David H. Reiley. 2014. “Online Economic Perspectives 8 (3): 75–96.
Ads and Offline Sales: Measuring the Effect of Marrano, Mauro Giorgio, Jonathan Haskel, and Gavin
Retail Advertising via a Controlled Experiment on Wallis. 2009. “What Happened to the Knowledge
Yahoo!” Quantitative Marketing and Economics 12 Economy? ICT, Intangible Investment, and Britain’s
(3): 235–66. Productivity Record Revisited.” Review of Income
Li, Xing, Megan MacGarvie, and Petra Moser. 2015. and Wealth 55 (3): 686–716.
“Dead Poet’s Property—How Does Copyright Influ- Marthews, Alex, and Catherine E. Tucker. 2014. “Gov-
ence Price?” National Bureau of Economic Research ernment Surveillance and Internet Search Behavior.”
Working Paper 21522. SSRN 2412564.
Lieber, Ethan, and Chad Syverson. 2012. “Online ver- Maskin, Eric, and John Riley. 1984. “Monopoly with
sus Offline Competition.” In The Oxford Handbook Incomplete Information.” RAND Journal of Eco-
of the Digital Economy, edited by Martin Peitz and nomics 15 (2): 171–96.
Joel Waldfogel, 189–223. Oxford and New York: Mayzlin, Dina, Yaniv Dover, and Judith Chevalier.
Oxford University Press. 2014. “Promotional Reviews: An Empirical Investi-
Liebowitz, Stan J. 2008. “Research Note—Testing File gation of Online Review Manipulation.” American
Sharing’s Impact on Music Album Sales in Cities.” Economic Review 104 (8): 2421–55.
Management Science 54 (4): 852–59. McCabe, Mark J., and Christopher M. Snyder. 2015.
Liebowitz, Stan J., and Alejandro Zentner. 2012. “Clash “Does Online Availability Increase Citations? Theory
of the Titans: Does Internet Use Reduce Television and Evidence from a Panel of Economics and Busi-
Viewing?” Review of Economics and Statistics 94 (1): ness Journals.” Review of Economics and Statistics 97
234–45. (1): 144–65.
Livingston, Jeffrey A. 2005. “How Valuable Is a Good McCullough, Jeffrey S., Stephen T. Parente, and Rob-
Reputation? A Sample Selection Model of Internet ert Town. 2016. “Health Information Technology
Auctions.” Review of Economics and Statistics 87 (3): and Patient Outcomes: The Role of Information and
453–65. Labor Coordination.” RAND Journal of Economics
Loginova, Oksana. 2009. “Real and Virtual Competi- 47 (1): 207–36.
tion.” Journal of Industrial Economics 57 (2): 319–42. McElheran, Kristina. 2014. “Delegation in Multi-es-
Luca, Michael. 2011. “Reviews, Reputation, and Rev- tablishment Firms: Evidence from I.T. Purchasing.”
enue: The Case of Yelp.com.” Harvard Business Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 23
School Working Paper 12-016. (2): 225–58.
Luca, Michael, and Georgios Zervas. 2016. “Fake It McKnight, Lee W., and Joseph P. Bailey. 1998. Internet
Till You Make It: Reputation, Competition, and Economics. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.
Yelp Review Fraud.” Management Science 62 (12): McLuhan, Marshall. 1964. Understanding Media: The
3412–27. Extensions of Man. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Lucking-Reiley, David. 1999. “Using Field Experi- Melnik, Mikhail I., and James Alm. 2002. “Does a Sell-
ments to Test Equivalence between Auction For- er’s eCommerce Reputation Matter? Evidence from
mats: Magic on the Internet.” American Economic eBay Auctions.” Journal of Industrial Economics 50
Review 89 (5): 1063–80. (3): 337–49.
Lucking-Reiley, David, Doug Bryan, Naghi Prasad, Miller, Amalia R., and Catherine Tucker. 2009. “Privacy
and Daniel Reeves. 2007. “Pennies from eBay: The Protection and Technology Diffusion: The Case of
Determinants of Price in Online Auctions.” Journal Electronic Medical Records.” Management Science
of Industrial Economics 55 (2): 223–33. 55 (7): 1077–93.
Lucking-Reiley, David, and Daniel F. Spulber. 2001. Miller, Amalia R., and Catherine Tucker. 2011. “Can
“Business-to-Business Electronic Commerce.” Jour- Health Care Information Technology Save Babies?”
nal of Economic Perspectives 15 (1): 55–68. Journal of Political Economy 119 (2): 289–324.
Lynch, John G., and Dan Ariely. 2000. “Wine Online: Miller, Amalia R., and Catherine Tucker. 2018. “Pri-
Search Costs Affect Competition on Price, Quality, vacy Protection, Personalized Medicine, and Genetic
and Distribution.” Marketing Science 19 (1): 83–103. Testing.” Management Science 64 (10): 4648–68.
Lyons, Elizabeth. 2017. “Team Production in Interna- Moore, Tyler, Richard Clayton, and Ross Anderson.
tional Labor Markets: Experimental Evidence from 2009. “The Economics of Online Crime.” Journal of
the Field.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economic Perspectives 23 (3): 3–20.
Economics 9 (3): 70–104. Mortimer, Julie Holland, Chris Nosko, and Alan
MacGarvie, Megan, and Petra Moser. 2015. “Copyright Sorensen. 2012. “Supply Responses to Digital Dis-
and the Profitability of Authorship: Evidence from tribution: Recorded Music and Live Performances.”
Payments to Writers in the Romantic Period.” In Information Economics and Policy 24 (1): 3–14.
Economic Analysis of the Digital Economy, edited by Morton, Fiona Scott, Florian Zettelmeyer, and Jorge
Avi Goldfarb, Shane M. Greenstein, and Catherine Silva-Risso. 2003. “Consumer Information and Dis-
E. Tucker, 357–79. Chicago and London: University crimination: Does the Internet Affect the Pricing of
of Chicago Press. New Cars to Women and Minorities?” Quantitative
MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K., and Hal Varian. 1994. Marketing and Economics 1 (1): 65–92.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 41

Mustonen, Mikko. 2005. “When Does a Firm Support and the Value of Online Retail.” RAND Journal of
Substitute Open Source Programming?” Journal of Economics 49: 877–913.
Economics and Management Strategy 14 (1): 121–39. Rao, Anita. 2015. “Online Content Pricing: Purchase
Nagaraj, Abhishek. 2016. “The Private Impact of Pub- and Rental Markets.” Marketing Science 34 (3):
lic Information: Landsat Satellite Maps and Gold 430–51.
Exploration.” Unpublished. Rao, Justin M., and David H. Reiley. 2012. “The Eco-
Nagaraj, Abhishek. 2018. “Does Copyright Affect nomics of Spam.” Journal of Economic Perspectives
Reuse? Evidence from Google Books and Wikipe- 26 (3): 87–110.
dia.” Management Science 64 (7): 3091–107. Reimers, Imke. 2016. “Can Private Copyright Protec-
Nocke, Volker, Martin Peitz, and Konrad Stahl. 2007. tion Be Effective? Evidence from Book Publishing.”
“Platform Ownership.” Journal of the European Eco- Journal of Law and Economics 59 (2): 411–40.
nomic Association 5 (6): 1130–60. Resnick, Paul, and Richard Zeckhauser. 2002. “Trust
Nosko, Chris, and Steven Tadelis. 2015. “The Limits among Strangers in Internet Transactions: Empirical
of Reputation in Platform Markets: An Empirical Analysis of eBay’s Reputation System.” In The Eco-
Analysis and Field Experiment.” National Bureau of nomics of the Internet and E-Commerce, edited by
Economic Research Working Paper 20830. Michael R. Baye, 127–57. Amsterdam and Boston:
Oberholzer-Gee, Felix, and Koleman Strumpf. 2007. Elsevier, JAI.
“The Effect of File Sharing on Record Sales: An Rob, Rafael, and Joel Waldfogel. 2006. “Piracy on the
Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy High C’s: Music Downloading, Sales Displacement,
115 (1): 1–42. and Social Welfare in a Sample of College Students.”
Ockenfels, Axel, David Reiley, and Abdolkarim Journal of Law and Economics 49 (1): 29–62.
Sadrieh. 2006. “Online Auctions.” National Bureau Rob, Rafael, and Joel Waldfogel. 2007. “Piracy on the
of Economic Research Working Paper 12785. Silver Screen.” Journal of Industrial Economics 55
Orlov, Eugene. 2011. “How Does the Internet Influ- (3): 379–95.
ence Price Dispersion? Evidence from the Airline Rochet, Jean-Charles, and Jean Tirole. 2003. “Platform
Industry.” Journal of Industrial Economics 59 (1): Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of the
21–37. European Economic Association 1 (4): 990–1029.
Overman, Henry G., Stephen Redding, and Anthony Rosen, Sherwin. 1981. “The Economics of Superstars.”
Venables. 2003. “The Economic Geography of Trade, American Economic Review 71 (5): 845–58.
Production and Income: A Survey of Empirics.” In Rosenblat, Tanya S., and Markus M. Mobius. 2004.
Handbook of International Trade, edited by E. “Getting Closer or Drifting Apart?” Quarterly Jour-
Kwan Choi and James Harrigan, 353–87. Malden: nal of Economics 119 (3): 971–1009.
Blackwell. Roth, Alvin E., and Axel Ockenfels. 2002. “Last-Min-
Parker, Chris, Kamalini Ramdas, and Nicos Savva. ute Bidding and the Rules for Ending Second-Price
2016. “Is IT Enough? Evidence from a Natural Auctions: Evidence from eBay and Amazon Auctions
Experiment in India’s Agriculture Markets.” Man- on the Internet.” American Economic Review 92 (4):
agement Science 62 (9): 2481–503. 1093–103.
Peitz, Martin, and Patrick Waelbroeck. 2006. “Why Rysman, Marc. 2007. “An Empirical Analysis of Pay-
the Music Industry May Gain from Free Download- ment Card Usage.” Journal of Industrial Economics
ing—The Role of Sampling.” International Journal of 55 (1): 1–36.
Industrial Organization 24 (5): 907–13. Rysman, Marc, and Timothy Simcoe. 2008. “Patents
Petty, Ross D. 2000. “Marketing without Consent: Con- and the Performance of Voluntary Standard-Set-
sumer Choice and Costs, Privacy, and Public Policy.” ting Organizations.” Management Science 54 (11):
Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 19 (1): 42–53. 1920–34.
Peukert, Christian, Jorg Claussen, and Tobias Kret- Salop, Steven C. 1979. “Monopolistic Competition
schmer. 2017. “Piracy and Box Office Movie Reve- with Outside Goods.” Bell Journal of Economics 10
nues: Evidence from Megaupload.” International (1): 141–56.
Journal of Industrial Organization 52: 188–215. Savage, Scott James, and Donald M. Waldman. 2009.
Pope, Devin G., and Justin R. Sydnor. 2011. “What’s in “Ability, Location and Household Demand for Inter-
a Picture? Evidence of Discrimination from Prosper. net Bandwidth.” International Journal of Industrial
com.” Journal of Human Resources 46 (1): 53–92. Organization 27 (2): 166–74.
Pozzi, Andrea. 2013. “E-commerce as a Stockpiling Scott, Steven L., and Hal R. Varian. 2015. “Bayesian
Technology: Implications for Consumer Savings.” Variable Selection for Nowcasting Economic Time
International Journal of Industrial Organization 31 Series.” In Economic Analysis of the Digital Econ-
(6): 677–89. omy, edited by Avi Goldfarb, Shane M. Greenstein,
Prince, Jeffrey T. 2007. “The Beginning of Online/ and Catherine E. Tucker, 119–35. Chicago and Lon-
Retail Competition and Its Origins: An Application don: University of Chicago Press.
to Personal Computers.” International Journal of Scott Morton, Fiona, Florian Zettelmeyer, and Jorge
Industrial Organization 25 (1): 139–56. Silva-Risso. 2001. “Internet Car Retailing.” Journal
Quan, Thomas W., and Kevin R. Williams. 2018. “Prod- of Industrial Economics 49 (4): 501–19.
uct Variety, Across-Market Demand Heterogeneity, Seamans, Robert, and Feng Zhu. 2014. “Responses to
42 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LVII (March 2019)

Entry in Multi-sided Markets: The Impact of Craig- Tambe, Prasanna, and Lorin M. Hitt. 2012. “Now IT’s
slist on Local Newspapers.” Management Science 60 Personal: Offshoring and the Shifting Skill Composi-
(2): 476–93. tion of the U.S. Information Technology Workforce.”
Shapiro, Carl, and Hal R. Varian. 1998. Information Management Science 58 (4): 678–95.
Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy. Tambe, Prasanna, Lorin M. Hitt, and Erik Brynjolfs-
Cambridge: Harvard Business School Press. son. 2012. “The Extroverted Firm: How Exter-
Shiller, Ben, and Joel Waldfogel. 2011. “Music for a nal Information Practices Affect Innovation and
Song: An Empirical Look at Uniform Pricing and Its ­Productivity.” Management Science 58 (5): 843–59.
Alternatives.” Journal of Industrial Economics 59 (4): Taylor, Curtis R. 2004. “Consumer Privacy and the
630–60. Market for Customer Information.” RAND Journal
Shiller, Ben, Joel Waldfogel, and Johnny Ryan. 2018. of Economics 35 (4): 631–50.
“The Effect of Ad Blocking on Website Traffic and Taylor, Curtis R., and Liad Wagman. 2014. “Consumer
Quality.” RAND Journal of Economics 49: 43–63. Privacy in Oligopolistic Markets: Winners, Losers,
Shin, Jiwoong, and K. Sudhir. 2010. “A Customer Man- and Welfare.” International Journal of Industrial
agement Dilemma: When is It Profitable to Reward Organization 34: 80–84.
One’s Own Customers?” Marketing Science 29 (4): Tucker, Catherine E. 2012a. “Patent Trolls and Tech-
671–89. nology Diffusion.” Paper presented at the Stan-
Simcoe, Timothy. 2012. “Standard Setting Committees: dards, Patents and Innovations Conference, January
Consensus Governance for Shared Technology Plat- 20–21.
forms.” American Economic Review 102 (1): 305–36. Tucker, Catherine E. 2012b. “The Economics of Adver-
Simonov, Andrey, Chris Nosko, and Justin M. Rao. tising and Privacy.” International Journal of Indus-
2018. “Competition and Crowd-Out for Brand Key- trial Organization 30 (3): 326–29.
words in Sponsored Search.” Marketing Science 37 Tucker, Catherine E. 2014. “Social Networks, Person-
(2): 200–215. alized Advertising, and Privacy Controls.” Journal of
Sinai, Todd, and Joel Waldfogel. 2004. “Geography and Marketing Research 51 (5): 546–62.
the Internet: Is the Internet a Substitute or a Com- Tucker, Catherine E. 2015. “Privacy and the Inter-
plement for Cities?” Journal of Urban Economics 56 net.” In Handbook of Media Economics: Volume 1B,
(1): 1–24. edited by Simon P. Anderson, Joel Waldfogel, and
Smith, Michael D., Joseph Bailey, and Erik Brynjolfs- David Stromberg, 541–62. Amsterdam and Boston:
son. 2001. “Understanding Digital Markets: Review Elsevier, North-Hampton.
and Assessment.” In Understanding the Digital Tucker, Catherine E., and Shuyi Yu. 2017. “Technol-
Economy: Data, Tools, and Research, edited by Erik ogy and Inequality: The Role of Mobile Applications
Brynjolfsson and Brian Kahin, 99–136. Cambridge in the Inequality of Treatment of Customer Com-
and London: MIT Press. plaints.” Unpublished.
Smith, Michael D., and Erik Brynjolfsson. 2001. “Con- Tucker, Catherine E., and Juanjuan Zhang. 2011. “How
sumer Decision-Making at an Internet Shopbot: Does Popularity Information Affect Choices? A Field
Brand Still Matters.” Journal of Industrial Economics Experiment.” Management Science 57 (5): 828–42.
49 (4): 541–58. Varian, Hal R. 1980. “A Model of Sales.” American Eco-
Soloveichik, Rachel. 2010. “Artistic Originals as a nomic Review 70 (4): 651–59.
Capital Asset.” American Economic Review 100 (2): Varian, Hal R. 2005. “Copying and Copyright.” Journal
110–14. of Economic Perspectives 19 (2): 121–38.
Solow, Robert M. 1987. “We’d Better Watch Out.” New Varian, Hal R. 2007. “Position Auctions.” International
York Times Book Review, July 12, 36. Journal of Industrial Organization 25 (6): 1163–78.
Stanton, Christopher T., and Catherine Thomas. 2016. Varian, Hal R. 2010. “Computer Mediated Transac-
“Landing the First Job: The Value of Intermediaries tions.” American Economic Review 100 (2): 1–10.
in Online Hiring.” Review of Economic Studies 83 Varian, Hal R., Fredrik Wallenberg, and Glenn Woroch.
(2): 810–54. 2005. “The Demographics of the Do-Not-Call List.”
Stigler, George J. 1961. “The Economics of Informa- IEEE Security and Privacy 3 (1): 34–39.
tion.” Journal of Political Economy 69 (3): 213–25. Villas-Boas, J. Miguel. 2004. “Price Cycles in Markets
Stigler, George J. 1964. “Public Regulation of the Secu- with Customer Recognition.” RAND Journal of Eco-
rities Markets.” Journal of Business 37 (2): 117–42. nomics 35 (3): 486–501.
Sunstein, Cass. 2001. Echo Chambers: Bush v. Gore, Vogelsang, Ingo. 2003. “Price Regulation of Access
Impeachment, and Beyond. Princeton and Oxford: to Telecommunications Networks.” Journal of Eco-
Princeton University Press. nomic Literature 41 (3): 830–62.
Tadelis, Steven. 1999. “What’s in a Name? Reputation Waldfogel, Joel. 2010. “Music File Sharing and Sales
as a Tradeable Asset.” American Economic Review 89 Displacement in the iTunes Era.” Information Eco-
(3): 548–63. nomics and Policy 22 (4): 306–14.
Takeyama, Lisa N. 1994. “The Welfare Implications of Waldfogel, Joel. 2012a. “Copyright Research in the
Unauthorized Reproduction of Intellectual Property Digital Age: Moving from Piracy to the Supply of
in the Presence of Demand Network Externalities.” New Products.” American Economic Review 102 (3):
Journal of Industrial Economics 42 (2): 155–66. 337–42.
Goldfarb and Tucker: Digital Economics 43

Waldfogel, Joel. 2012b. “Digital Piracy: Empirics.” Williams, Heidi L. 2013. “Intellectual Property
In The Oxford Handbook of the Digital Economy, Rights and Innovation: Evidence from the Human
edited by Martin Peitz and Joel Waldfogel, 531–46. Genome.” Journal of Political Economy 121 (1):
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. 1–27.
Waldfogel, Joel. 2015. “First Degree Price Discrimina- Xu, Lei, Tingting Nian, and Luis Cabral. 2016. “What
tion Goes to School.” Journal of Industrial Econom- Makes Geeks Tick? A Study of Stack Overflow
ics 63 (4): 569–97. Careers.” Unpublished.
Waldfogel, Joel. 2016. “Cinematic Explosion: New Yang, Huanxing. 2013. “Targeted Search and the Long
Products, Unpredictability and Realized Quality in Tail Effect.” RAND Journal of Economics 44 (4):
the Digital Era.” Journal of Industrial Economics 64 733–56.
(4): 755–72. Zentner, Alejandro. 2006. “Measuring the Effect of File
Waldfogel, Joel, and Lu Chen. 2006. “Does Informa- Sharing on Music Purchases.” Journal of Law and
tion Undermine Brand? Information Intermediary Economics 49 (1): 63–90.
Use and Preference for Branded Web Retailers.” Zervas, Georgios, Davide Proserpio, and John W. Byers.
Journal of Industrial Economics 54 (4): 425–49. 2017. “The Rise of the Sharing Economy: Estimating
Waldfogel, Joel, and Imke Reimers. 2015. “Storming the Impact of Airbnb on the Hotel Industry.” Journal
the Gatekeepers: Digital Disintermediation in the of Marketing Research 54 (5): 687–705.
Market for Books.” Information Economics and Pol- Zhang, Juanjuan, and Peng Liu. 2012. “Rational Herd-
icy 31: 47–58. ing in Microloan Markets.” Management Science 58
Wallsten, Scott. 2013. “What Are We Not Doing (5): 892–912.
When We’re Online.” National Bureau of Economic Zhang, Laurina. 2018. “Intellectual Property Strategy
Research Working Paper 19549. and the Long Tail: Evidence from the Recorded
Weyl, E. Glen. 2010. “A Price Theory of Multi-sided Music Industry.” Management Science 64 (1):
Platforms.” American Economic Review 100 (4): 24–42.
1642–72. Zhang, Xiaoquan (Michael), and Feng Zhu. 2011.
White, Alexander. 2013. “Search Engines: Left Side “Group Size and Incentives to Contribute: A Natural
Quality versus Right Side Profits.” International Experiment at Chinese Wikipedia.” American Eco-
Journal of Industrial Organization 31 (6): 690–701. nomic Review 101 (4): 1601–15.

Вам также может понравиться