Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 16

World Development Vol. 28, No. 5, pp.

789±804, 2000
Ó 2000 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/00/$ - see front matter PII: S0305-750X(99)00160-6

The Rise and Fall of the Washington Consensus as a


Paradigm for Developing Countries
CHARLESGORE*
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva, Switzerland
Summary. Ð The introduction of the Washington Consensus involved not simply a swing from state-led
to market-oriented policies, but also a shift in the ways in which development problems were framed
and in the types of explanation through which policies were justi®ed. Key changes were the partial
globalization of development policy analysis, and a shift from historicism to ahistorical performance
assessment. The main challenge to this approach is a latent Southern Consensus, which is apparent in
the convergence between East Asian developmentalism and Latin American neostructuralism. The
demise of the Washington Consensus is inevitable because its methodology and ideology are in
contradiction. Ó 2000 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words Ð development theory, development policies, World Bank/IMF policies


1. INTRODUCTION were generally called ``underdeveloped'' or ``less
developed'' countries, but which now generally
Developing countries is an international identify themselves, and are identi®ed by others,
practice. The essence of this practice is the as
mobilization and allocation of resources, and the ``developing countries.''
design of institutions, to transform national This paper discusses trends in the body of
economies and societies, in an orderly way, from knowledge which guides and justi®es the practice
a state and status of being less developed to one of development. It examines, in particular, the
of being more developed. The agencies engaged ideas propagated by international development
in this practice include national governments of agencies, and focuses on the shift in thinking
less-developed countries, which have adopted which occurred in the 1980s with the introduction
``development'' as a purpose to which State and widespread adoption of an approach to the
power is put, and governments of richer countries, practice of developing countries known as the
which disburse o•cial development aid to support ``Washington Consensus.'' In broad terms, this
and in¯uence this process; a variety of non- approach recommends that governments should
governmental organizations concerned to reform their policies and, in particular: (a) pursue
animate and channel popular concerns; and macroeconomic stability by controlling in¯ation
international intergovernmental organizations, and reducing ®scal de®cits; (b) open their
such as the organs of the United Nations and the economies to the rest of the world through trade
World Bank, many of which have been expressly and capital account liberalization; and (c)
set up to resolve various development problems. liberalize
Often it is the last group who have acted as the
avant-garde of development practice. It is
because of their activities, as well as the
widespread tendency of governments to copy *This paper is an extended version of comments made at
successful practice elsewhere, that it is the Berlin-Brandenburgische Akademie der Wissenschaften
Conference on ``Paradigms of Social Change'' held in Berlin
appropriate to describe developing countries as
on September 3±5, 1998. I would like to thank John Toye,
an international practice. But it is by no means Gabrielle Kohler, Richard Kozul-• Wright and two
global in scope. Indeed the practice of developing anonymous referees for critical comments on an earlier
countries is only done in a particular set of draft. The arguments and interpretations are those of the
countriesÐthose which in the 1950s and 1960s

789
790 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

author. The views expressed do not necessarily re¯ect those The structure of the revolution in thinking which
of UNCTAD. Final revision accepted: 17 October 1999. occurred with the introduction of Washington
domestic product and factor markets through Consensus policies is usually seen as a shift from
privatization and deregulation. Propagated state-led dirigisme to marketoriented policies.
through the stabilization and structural Such a switch undoubtedly occurred. But it is not
adjustment policies of the International Monetary a su•cient description of the nature of the change
Fund (IMF) and World Bank, this has been the as a paradigm shift. As Kuhn shows, when
dominant approach to development from the paradigms change, there are usually signi®cant
early 1980s to the present. The paper examines changes in the ``methods, problem-®eld, and
the introduction of the Washington Consensus as standards of solution'' which are accepted by a
a paradigm shift, and assesses the con®guration of community of practitioners (Kuhn, 1970, p. 103).
development thinking in the 1990s and pressures As a consequence, ``the proponents of competing
for a further paradigm shift, particularly in the paradigms practice their trades in di€erent
light of the East Asian ®nancial crisis and recent worlds...[they] see di€erent things when they look
attempts to construct a ``post-Washington from the same point in the same direction'' (p.
Consensus.'' 150). In examining the introduction of the
The paradigmatic nature of the Washington Washington Consensus as a paradigm shift, what
Consensus is most clearly evident in the work of matters is not simply the substantive di€erences
John Williamson (1990,1993,1997), who coined with earlier approaches, but also the nature of the
the name and also set out a speci®c formulation change in the disciplinary matrix and worldview.
of the approach at the end of the 1980s. This Here it will be argued that together with the
formulation was founded on an attempt to swing to market-oriented policies, there was a
summarize, with particular reference to policy deeper shift in the way development problems
reform in Latin America, ``the conventional were framed and in the types of explanation
wisdom of the day among the economically through which development policies were
in¯uential bits of Washington, meaning US justi®ed. This involved changes in the spatial and
government and the international ®nancial temporal frame of reference of development
institutions'' (Williamson, 1993, p. 1329). policy analysis. In brief, these changes were: the
Williamson never explicitly identi®es the partial globalization of development policy
Washington Consensus as a paradigm. But the analysis; and a shift from historicism to ahistorical
way he describes the approach conforms in many performance assessment.
respects with Thomas KuhnÕs notion of one. 1
Thus, he argued that the Washington Consensus is
a ``universal convergence,'' and that it constitutes 2. THE PARTIAL GLOBALIZATION OF
``the common core of wisdom embraced by all DEVELOPMENT POLICY ANALYSIS
serious economists'' (Williamson, 1993, p. 1334).
He codi®ed the approach as a set of 10 axiomatic Specifying development policy problems
generalizations which, given certain values, are involves both explanations of development trends
generally shared by scholars and practitioners and normative judgements about how the world
concerned with economic growth in developing should be. For each of these activities, an
countries; and he listed remaining analytical important decision which must be made is
problems on which normal economic science deciding the policy frame, i.e. what elements
needs to focus. Finally, he dismissed those who should be included when viewing a problem and
challenged the consensus view as ``cranks'' (p. what elements excluded. 2 The framing of policy
1330). As he put issues has various aspects but one which critically
it, a€ects the practice of developing countries is
whether policy problems are seen within a global
[T]he superior economic performance of countries that or national frame of reference. Explanations and
establish and maintain outward-oriented market
economies subject to macro-economic discipline is
normative judgements can each be elaborated
essentially a positive question. The proof may not be within a national or global frame of reference, and
quite as conclusive as the proof that the Earth is not ¯at, so the thinking which underpins the practice of
but it is su•ciently well established as to give sensible developing countries can be wholly national,
people better things to do with their time than to wholly global, or some combination of both
challenge its veracity (p. 1330). (Figure 1). The full globalization of development
RISE AND FALL OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS 791

policy analysis will be understood here to mean a understanding and language of national and
shift from a international policymakers after WWII.

Figure 1. Four main combinations of explanatory and normative framework in development policy analysis.
national to a global frame of reference both for There were, of course, major controversies both
explanations and normative evaluations. over the meaning of development and the means
Before the propagation of the Washington of achieving it. In the 1950s and 1960s there were
Consensus in the 1980s, mainstream explanations debates about development strategy (for
of the development process and evaluative example, balanced or unbalanced growth), the
judgements of the goals of development were nature of dualistic development processes, and
both conducted within a national frame of the role of human capital. Moreover, in the 1970s
reference. First, economic and social trends within the earlier focus on economic growth with
countries were explained, in the mainstream, on structural change was strongly challenged by
the basis of conditions within the countries those who pointed to the need to focus on social
themselves, i.e. as a result of national factors. objectives, notably income distribution, poverty,
Particular external relations might be necessary to employment and basic needs satisfaction. 3 But
start the process, or to close ``gaps'' which these disputes actually served to reinforce the
threatened its breakdown. But the key ingredients normative and explanatory frames of
of a successful development process were usually development policy analysis as being national.
identi®ed through analyses of sequences of Whatever objectives were taken to be central,
change within already industrialized countries, national objectives were the focal concern.
which were then applied in less developed Moreover the development strategy debates
countries without any reference to their di€erent essentially examined the articulation and
external situation. Second, development policies sequencing of internal (national) ingredients
were geared toward the achievement of national which could facilitate or accelerate the national
objectives. This orientation was often simply development process.
taken for granted in development policy analysis. An important countercurrent to mainstream
But it was also in¯uenced, more or less strongly, development policy analysis before the 1980s
by political and economic nationalism. According came from structuralist and dependency theories
to Johnson (1967), key features of economic elaborated in Latin America (see Kay, 1989). Like
policy in new StatesÐnamely, the desire for the dominant approach the normative concern of
greater selfsu•ciency and early industrialization, these theories was national, and indeed strongly
the preference for economic planning and public informed by nationalist concerns. But their
control, and hostility to foreign investmentÐ can analytical perspective was global in scope and this
all be traced to the mutual supporting relations underpinned their critiques of mainstream
between nationalism, aid policy, and ideas about thinking. Both structuralist and dependency
the development problem formed in the 1930s. theorists emphasized the importance of
Those ideas became part of a common centerperiphery relations as determining or
conditioning the national development process.
792 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

But some strands within dependency theory, Consensus, emerged as the main alternative to
instead of indicating how national development national developmentalism. 4
was a€ected by the articulation between internal The frame of reference for this new approach
and external factors, simply put forward an was, like the Latin American countercurrents of
antithesis to the mainstream approach, arguing the pre-1980s, partially global and partially
that external factors were the only ones that national. But rather than combining normative
mattered, and then deduced that by delinking economic nationalism with a methodological
from the world economy, an ``authentic'' internationalism, the Washington Consensus was
development process, solely founded on internal its mirror image. It combined normative economic
factors, could be made to occur. internationalism with a methodologically
In the late 1970s and early 1980s, the growth nationalist form of explanation which attributed
rate of most developing countries, with the what was happening within countries mainly to
notable exception of some countries in East Asia, national factors and policies
collapsed. The economic crises which beset most (Figure 2).
developing countries lent weight to arguments In this new approach, the key norms which
that mainstream development practice had failed. played the decisive role in de®ning development
But at the same time the East Asian success practice were the norms of a liberal international
neutralized those versions of dependency theory economic order (LIEO). In most general terms,
which argued that development would always be these norms involve a commitment to free
blocked on the periphery, and also Latin American markets, private property and individual
structuralism, which allegedly was wedded to incentives, and a circumscribed role for
inwardoriented import-substitution policies in government. But they can be speci®ed in di€erent
contrast to East AsiaÕs alleged outward- ways, according to di€erent interpretations of the
orientation. In this situation, arguments which precise content of the LIEO. For example, in the
emphasized the positive role of free markets in early 1980s, laissez-faire liberalism was strongly
development attracted greater attention. These advocated. This entailed liberalization of both
ideas had always been an element within external and domestic economic relations. But at
development policy analysis, represented, for the start of the 1990s, this extreme market
example, by early critiques of protectionism, such fundamentalism was softened with the
as G. Haberler and H. Myint, Milton emergence of the socalled market-friendly
FriedmanÕs support of free enterprise, and P.T. approach to development (see, notably, World
BauerÕs dissection of mainstream thinking Bank, 1991). This continued strongly to advocate
(Bauer, 1971). The uptake of these ideas was not liberalization of external trade and capital
strong however until the late 1970s and early movements. But, the scope of domestic economic
1980s, when a new approach to developing liberalization was limited, in particular, by
countries, which was later labeled the Washington

Figure 2. The con®guration of development policy analysis: 1950±1990.


RISE AND FALL OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS 793

recognizing more fully the legitimacy of state countryÕs exports. Empirically, the most common
intervention in cases of market failure. approach to prove the dynamic bene®ts of
These norms were propagated through two outward-orientation has been crosscountry
types of persuasive argument: ®rst, arguments regression analyses which establish the statistical
about the intrinsic ethical superiority of economic relationships between indicators of national
liberalism; and second, theoretical and empirical economic change and a series of national
analyses which demonstrate that conformity to variables, which include, in particular, indicators
the norms of a LIEO (variously de®ned) would lead of national policy. The essence of this
to better outcomes, not simply for the world methodology is areal correlation between
community as a whole, but also for individual dependent and independent variables, to identify
nation-states within it. The latter, which have the extent to which variation in the former
served as the principal form of argument between a given set of national territories
supporting the new approach, have mainly been matches variation in the latter between the same
articulated on a terrain in which promoting the territories. This can be done at a certain point in
national interest has been narrowly equated with time or for periods of time (e.g. by using growth
promoting economic growth and increasing rates over 20 years). In either case, speci®c
personal economic welfare. Important histories are ®ltered out and it is assumed that
developmentalist concerns such as constructing relationships which pertained in the past will
national unity and realizing national sovereignty continue into the future. Economic trends are
are thus excluded. On this narrowed ground, necessarily attributed to the behavior of the
attention and publicity has been given to analyses national factors.
which show that national policies which are in In the 1990s, changes in the nature of the
con¯ict with the norms of LIEO, including many external environment are increasingly being used
elements at the heart of earlier development to explain why liberalization, coupled with the
practice, such as protection of infant industries, right macroeconomic fundamentals, ``works.''
managed interest rates and selective credit, have Thus it is argued that in an increasingly globalized
been harmful to national interests, and thus world economy, in which there is the globalization
constituted domestic mismanagement and of production systems, increasing reliance on
``irrationalities.'' At the same time, the policies of trade and increased availability of external
the East Asian newly industrializing economies ®nancial ¯ows, countries which do not follow
which had actually achieved rapid and sustained Washington
growth have been described in ways which Consensus policies will be especially penalized, as
suggest that they conformed to the requisite they will be cut o€ and thus excluded from the
liberal norms. 5 For both con¯icting and intensifying (and implicitly bene®cial) global ®eld
conforming policies, their impact on the e•ciency of ¯ows. Concomitantly, those countries which do
of resource allocation has been identi®ed as the follow the right policies will be rewarded, as they
main mechanism by which domestic policies a€ect can capture foreign direct investment which
economic growth. brings technology and market access, and they
While the normative frame of reference of the can also supplement national savings with
new approach was global in scope, the international capital ¯ows, thus reaping the
explanatory arguments which sought to prove the bene®ts of the new external environment. In this
instrumental superiority of the LIEO were way, the case for liberalization is rooted in the
characterized by methodological nationalism. rhetoric of the globalization. But the analysis
That is to say, in explaining economic trends remains methodologically nationalist as it retains
within countries, they partitioned in¯uences into the distinction between external and internal
external and internal factors and attributed most (national) factors, and still attributes country
of what was happening to internal (national) trends largely to domestic policy (see, for
factors and, in particular, to domestic policy. 6 In example, IMF, 1997; World Bank, 1997).
making the case for trade liberalization and export Globalization is something which is happening to
promotion, for example, conditions of global the external economic environment of countries;
demand are generally ignored and, through the it is outside them.
``small country'' assumption, it is typically 3. THE SHIFT FROM HISTORICISM TO
assumed that foreign markets are always
available, and at prices largely independent of a
794 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

AHISTORICAL PERFORMANCE ASSESSMENT It is according to these performance standards


that past development policies have been
The curious combination of global liberalism 7 criticized because they do not ``work'' and
and methodological nationalism which underpins narratives have been constructed about the
the way in which development is seen in the new e€ectiveness of the Washington Consensus. A
paradigm has been buttressed by a second key succession of countries which have undertaken
shift which occurred in development policy policy reform in the requisite way and achieved
analysis at the end of the 1970s. This can be good short-term growth results have also been
characterized as a shift from historicism to identi®ed as, and dubbed, ``success stories.''
ahistorical performance assessment. These stories have acted as exemplars for the new
Theorizing on development strategy from the paradigm, providing not only practical rules-of-
1950s to the 1970s was historicist in the general thumb guidance on how policy reform should be
sense that it was founded on an attempt to undertaken, but also proof of the validity of the
understand rhythms, patterns and laws of Washington Consensus.
development. 8 This understanding was based on The transition from historicism to ahistorical
historical analysis of long-term sequences of performance assessment started in the 1970s, and
economic and social change, which had occurred was initially animated by those who sought to
in the past in already-industrialized countries and re®ne the de®nition of development by adding
which were expected to re-occur, particularly if social aspects. E€orts to measure poverty based
the right policy interventions were made, in ``less on the quality of life and satisfaction of basic
developed'' countries. Such theorizing most needs were particularly important in this regard.
typically understood development as a societal Michael LiptonÕs book Why Poor People Stay
and economy-wide transition from a ``traditional'' Poor was a key text in propagating a performance-
(rural, backward, agricultural) society to a oriented approach. The uptake of the notion of
``modern'' (urban, advanced, industrial) society. urban bias, a concept which was forged within
This process was seen as a sequence of stages of debates about how to achieve redistribution with
growth, a process of modernization, or recurrent growth but which became central to the
patterns of structural transformation. 9 All neoliberal paradigm, can be attributed to its
countries were expected to go through such performance-based de®nition, and the vitriolic
patterns of development, and development debates of the late 1970s, particularly with Byres,
agencies sought to ensure or accelerate the arrival can be interpreted as an attempt to sustain a
of a better future for whole societies through historicist view (see, for example, Byres, 1979). In
interventions in these long-term processes of the 1980s, these initial moves toward
historical transformation. performance assessment were overtaken by, and
With the shift to ahistorical performance later incorporated in, the discourse and practice
assessment, the focal object of enquiry has been of structural adjustment. Adjustment involved
to describe and explain national ``performances'' improving the performance of national economies
of various types. Not surprisingly but now taken- by increasing the e•ciency of resource allocation.
for-granted, the key word in the discourse The central criterion used to measure
propagated by international development performance was current or recent GDP growth
agencies since the start of the 1980s has been rate, and macroeconomic stability, indicated by
``performance.'' Attention has been particularly ®scal and external payments balance and low
paid to economic performance, but also in¯ation. The dynamics of long-term
agricultural performance, industrial performance, transformations of economies and societies
trade performance, ®nancial performance, ®scal slipped from view and attention was placed on
performance, poverty performance, human short-term growth and re-establishing ®nancial
development performance and so on. Using these balances.
various standards, countries have been The shift to ahistorical performance assessment
partitioned into good and bad performers, and can be interpreted as a form of the
ranked according to their performance in various postmodernization of development policy
new leagues of nations. Moreover comparative analysis. It re¯ects, in particular, the questioning
performances have been explained by reference of grand narratives of historical transformation
to national factors and national policy. which was central to the appeal of the
postmodern ethos in the 1980s. 10 Before the shift,
RISE AND FALL OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS 795

development agencies acted as handmaidens of which is described in ESCAP (1990), but has been
``progress,'' ``modernization,'' ``industrialisation,'' most thoroughly reconstructed by UNCTAD in its
or the emancipation of people from oppression, annual Trade and Development Report
exploitation, disease and drudgery. After it most (particularly 1994, part 2, chapter 1; 1996, part
agencies re-oriented their work to monitor and two; 1997, part 2, chapters V and VI; and 1998,
seek to improve ``performance,'' often through part 1, chapter 3). 11
local problem-solving and local social engineering These two challenges to the Washington
designed to make economic and social institutions Consensus have shaped development thinking
``work'' better. Adjustment also entailed the and practice in di€erent ways. Indeed
abandonment of grand long-term government- development policy analysis is now characterized
directed designs for whole societies and a shift to by a double dialectic. The clash between the
decentralized decision-making, laissez-faire and Washington Consensus and the sustainable
local social engineering. But ironically, this shift human development approach acts to reinforce
away from holism could not be achieved without and conserve the key elements of the current
a holistic approach. Everything has been made paradigm, and in particular its ahistorical
subject to the rules and discipline of the market. approach and its combination of normative
The vision of the liberation of people and peoples, internationalism with methodological
which animated development practice in the nationalism, whilst the clash between the
1950s and 1960s, has thus been replaced by the Washington Consensus and ideas within the two
vision of the liberalization of economies. The goal strands of the Southern Consensus serves to
of structural transformation has been replaced undermine these elements and creates tensions
with the goal of spatial integration. and pressures for a further paradigm shift.
The key feature of the sustainable human
development approach which distinguishes it
4. THE CONFIGURATION OF DEVELOPMENT from the Washington Consensus, is that it
POLICY ANALYSIS IN THE 1990S espouses a di€erent set of values. Whereas the
Washington Consensus focuses on the promotion
The collapse of communism in Eastern Europe of GDP growth, and has been implemented
and the Soviet Union has served as con®rmation through a top-down, donorconditionality-driven
of arguments which predicted the impossibility of and outside-expert-led, approach, the sustainable
central planning and reinforced the apparent human development approach argues that the
superiority of a market-oriented development ultimate test of development practice is that it
approach. Since the late 1980s however there should improve the nature of peopleÕs lives, and
have developed two important challenges to the advocates that it should be founded on
Washington Consensus. The ®rst is the UNDP's participation and a more equal partnership
sustainable human development (SHD) approach. between developing countries and aid donors.
This approach takes up some of the themes of the This ``people-centered'' approach, which
UNICEF critique of the dominant approach, explicitly identi®es itself as an alternative
Adjustment with a Human Face, originally paradigm (see, for example, ul Haq, 1995, Part I),
published in 1987, and has been elaborated has been quite in¯uential. An important strand of
through the annual Human Development Report, development research in the early 1990s has
which ®rst appeared in 1990 (UNDP, Various sought to refute its challenge by showing that
years). The second is a latent ``Southern Washington Consensus policies in fact serve to
Consensus,'' which is founded on analyses made reduce poverty, increase employment and can, in
from the perspective of countries undertaking late themselves, deliver growth with equity, and that
industrialization and seeking to catch up with therefore social concerns are already adequately
richer countries in the global economy. This addressed by the mainstream approach. But the
Southern Consensus does not exist as a political SHD alternative has promoted the introduction of
reality. Nor has it, as yet, been articulated poverty reduction as a key goal of development
analytically. Its existence is apparent however in practice and increasing attention to possible LIEO-
the convergence between the policy conclusions compatible relaxation of Washington Consensus
of Latin American neostructuralism, initially set policies in order better to achieve poverty
out by ECLAC in 1990, and the deeper objectives (see World Bank, 1990).
understanding of East Asian development models,
796 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

These changes have certainly made the up, in which national enterprises build up
Washington Consensus more humane. But at the production capabilities and international
same time, the SHD approach has had the e€ect of competitiveness in a range of activities
conserving key features of the worldview of the undertaken in more advanced countries. The
dominant paradigm. Although its di€erent values structure of the economy changes as the relative
have emphasized di€erent indicators and importance of agriculture and natural resource
weighting systems, particularly to capture levels exploitation declines while that of manufacturing
of human development and poverty, these activities increases, and as production progresses
measures have reinforced a focus on short-term from less to more skill-, technology-, and capital-
performance assessment. The substitution of intensive activities. At the macrolevel, growth,
multidimensional indicators of poverty for simple structural change and productive upgrading is
income poverty, for example, has added greater driven by a rapid pace of capital accumulation,
reality to the description of deprivation and more which depends on increased domestic savings,
leverage for moral outrage, but at the cost of investment, and exports, linked together in a
crippling e€ective analysis of the dynamics of virtuous circle of cumulative causation (ECLAC,
change. Signi®cantly also, the analytical basis of 1990, pp. 48±49; ESCAP, 1990, pp. 13±14, 115,
the SHD approach, which is itself somewhat loose, 151; UNCTAD, 1996, pp. 108±112). At the
is methodologically nationalist. A central focus is microlevel, this process is founded on imitation,
the mismatch between economic growth adaptation and learning of internationally
performance and social performance and the available technologies in order to reduce costs,
ways in which domestic policy can rectify this improve quality, and introduce goods and services
mismatch to deliver more social achievements for not existing in the country, and the di€usion of
any given level of GDP per capita. Even the best practices from more advanced to less
apparent di€erence in values between the SHD advanced enterprises within the country,
approach and the Washington Consensus is less including from foreign-owned to locally-owned
clear-cut than it appears. This applies whether ®rms (ESCAP, 1990, pp. 15±17 and pp. 92±95;
human development is speci®ed rigorously, as in ECLAC, 1990, pp. 64±71).
Amartya SenÕs capability approach which An important feature of the Southern
underpins the human development index, or Consensus is that it rejects the idea that growth
through a vaguer focus on decentralization and with late industrialization can be animated using a
participation. SenÕs capability concept general blueprint. Policy measures have to be
emphasizes freedom of choice which is quite adapted to initial conditions and the external
consonant with the liberal perspective. 12 environment, and change over time as an
Moreover the project of making economic and economy matures (ECLAC, 1990, pp. 97± 102;
social institutions work better through UNCTAD, 1996, pp. 133±134; ESCAP, 1990, pp.
decentralization and the use of local knowledge, 21±23, 140±141). It is possible however, to
indigenous management practices and the identify some general policy orientations which
participation, not of the masses, but of ``local apply in all circum-
people'' and ``small communities,'' can be, and stances. 15
has easily been, fused into a kind of neoliberal First, the process of growth and structural
populism. 13 change is best achieved through the ``strategic
Whereas the SHD approach has made a moral integration'' of the national economy into the
critique of the Washington Consensus, the two international economy rather than either
strands of the Southern Consensus, Latin delinking from the rest of the world or rapid
American neostructuralism and East Asian across-the-board opening up of the economy to
developmentalism, remain focused on economic imports and external capital. This means that the
growth as the central objective. 14 They o€er timing, speed and sequencing of opening, in
however a di€erent economic analysis of how relation to di€erent types of international ¯ows,
growth occurs in late industrializing countries and should be decided on the basis of how they
on this basis propose a di€erent policy orientation support the national interest in terms of
to the dominant paradigm. promoting economic growth and structural
From the Southern perspective, national change (Singh, 1994). Multilateral norms are not
economic growth involves a process of catching- disregarded (ECLAC, 1996, p. 86; UNCTAD, 1996,
RISE AND FALL OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS 797

pp. 156±157). As far as possible, however, import 159).


liberalization should be gradualÐto enable Elements of a productive development policy
national enterprises to build up production include: technology policy, ®nancial policy, human
capabilities and thus face external resource development, physical infrastructure
competitionÐand selective. Tari€s should also be development, and industrial organization and
complemented by special measures to promote competition policy (UNCTAD, 1994, pp. 57±69,
exports (ECLAC, 1990, pp. 103±107; ECLAC, 1995, ECLAC, 1990, pp. 107±148, ECLAC, 1995, pp.
chapter VI; and for East Asian policies, UNCTAD, 161±190; ESCAP, 1990, chapter V, pp. 149±150).
1994, pp. 58±59). Capital account liberalization These elements can form part of, but they should
should also be gradual and should be managed, in not be simply equated with, a selective industrial
coordination with domestic ®nancial policy. They are directed at improving productivity
development, to ensure that capital ¯ows are, as and competitiveness in agriculture and natural-
much as possible, additional to, rather than a resource based activities as well as manufacturing
substitute for, domestic resources, that they (ESCAP, 1990, pp. 22, 70±75; ECLAC, 1990, pp.
support increased investment rather than 126±137). They entail a mix of sectorallyneutral as
consumption, and that they do not undermine well as selective policies. Moreover their main
macroeconomic stability (ECLAC, 1995, pp. goal is to accelerate the rate of capital
285±291; UNCTAD, 1998, pp. 75±76, 101± 106). accumulation and learning throughout the
Inward FDI should support the build-up of economy.
domestic production capabilities and exports, and Third, the successful implementation of these
this is not automatic but requires speci®c development policies requires
domestic policies (ESCAP, 1990, p. 132; ECLAC, governmentbusiness cooperation within the
1990, p. 45; UNCTAD, 1996, pp. framework of a pragmatic developmental State.
131±133). The policies are implemented, as far as possible,
Secondly, growth and structural change is best through private initiative rather than public
promoted through a combination of a ownership, and through the market mechanism
macroeconomic policy and what Latin American rather than administrative controls. But
neostructuralists describe as a ``productive government plays a key role both in animating the
development policy.'' The macroeconomic policy ``animal spirits'' of the private sector and
is growth-oriented. It seeks to reduce in¯ation and harnessing the aggressive pursuit of pro®ts, which
®scal de®cits, but also aims to ensure full are the motor of the system, to the realization of
utilization of production capacity and encourage the national interest. This requires the
the pace of capital formation (ECLAC, 1996, enhancement of state capacities rather than state
chapter V; ESCAP, 1990, pp. 17±19). The minimalism. Policy should be formulated by a
productive development policy involves a range of capable and pragmatic economic bureaucracy
measures, coordinated with the trade policy, which, through various formal and informal ties
which are designed to improve the supply with business, develops a common vision of
capabilities of the economy as a whole and also development objectives and targets, and a
speci®c sectors within it, and to help private common understanding of how these can best be
enterprise identify and acquire competitive achieved (ECLAC, 1990, pp. 94±96; Evans, 1998).
advantages. These measures are founded on a But government must ensure that any support or
dynamic interpretation of the principle of protection for the private sector is conditional on
comparative advantage. In this forward-looking investment, export or productivity targets, and
approach, the opportunities of current relative also temporary. Policies should also focus on
cost advantages are exploited to the full, but overcoming speci®c problems which impede the
e€orts are made at the same time to promote achievement of national development objectives,
investment and learning in economic activities notably, missing markets and the lack of an
where comparative advantage can realistically be entrepreneurial base, imperfections in technology
expected to lie in the immediate future as the and capital markets, risks of exporting, and
economy develops and as other late dynamic complementarities between sectors
industrializing countries catch up (ESCAP, 1990, which render competitiveness systemic rather
pp. 148±149; OECF, 1991; UNCTAD, 1996, pp. than just dependent on ®rm-level capabilities
112±123; ECLAC, 1995, pp. 132±135, (UNCTAD, 1994, pp. 50, 69; ECLAC, 1995, pp.
798 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

152±157; ECLAC, 1996, Box VI.1; JDB/ JERI, 1993, of the world economy. A global analytical
pp. 53±56). perspective is adopted and this has a realist rather
Fourth, distributional dimensions of the growth than idealist view of the way in which market
process are managed in order to ensure the economies work. This recognizes vulnerabilities
legitimacy of the overall growth process. associated with integration into the international
This is primarily achieved through a production- economy and also external constraints due to
oriented approach rather than redistributive restrictions in access to advanced country
transfers. That is to say, the main bases for a more markets, falling terms of trade for primary
equitable and inclusive growth process are wide commodities and simple manufactures,
asset ownership and the expansion of productive cartelization in global markets, di•culties in
employment. Important policies in this regard are: gaining access to technology, and instabilities of
agrarian reform and rural development policies; the international ®nancial system. Finally, the
high rates of re-investment of pro®ts and the approach is normatively rooted in a distinctive
establishment of pro®trelated payment systems; form of economic nationalism. This is not
support for small and medium enterprises, ideologically committed to self-su•ciency or
particularly through ®nancial policies; and broad- public ownership, nor hostile to foreign ownership
based human resource development (Campos & in and of itself. It does not seek the appearance of
Root, 1996; ECLAC, 1992, pp. 15±27; UNCTAD, catching up, through either imitating
1997, pp. consumption standards, or setting up showcase
183±189). industries. It respects multilateral rules and
Finally, regional integration and cooperation arrangements, engaging in their design,
policies are identi®ed as an important element of negotiation and interpretation. But its aim is to
strategic integration (ECLAC, 1990, chapter VI; build international competitiveness as part of a
ECLAC, 1994, pp. 9±19; ESCAP, 1990, pp. 24±25; long-term national economic project founded on
UNCTAD, 1996, Part II, chapter 1, especially pp. the development of national capabilities.
75±79, 92±94). Such policies should support the Of the two strands of the Southern Consensus,
goal of increased international competitiveness, the challenge from the East Asian development
for example, by promoting regional production models has proved to be most powerful because
chains, and also nurture the development of these models have, in terms of their performance
regional markets in order to reduce demand-side and according to the criterion of economic
constraints on growth. growth, ``worked'' spectacularly well. Since the
These substantive features of the Southern early 1990s, the major fault line in development
Consensus arise because Latin American policy analysis has thus been the discrepancy
neostructuralism and East Asian between the policies which have been pursued in
developmentalism are rooted in a totally di€erent rapidly growing and industrializing East Asian
worldview to the Washington Consensus (Figure economies and the policies advocated by the
3). This does not reject performance standards as Washington Consensus. 16 Kuhn argues that the
a guide to policy, but actions are founded on questioning of a paradigm begins when anomalies
historical analysis, particularly of long-term arise between paradigmatic expectations and
processes of late industrialization in the periphery actual events, and shows that numerous ad hoc

Figure 3. The con®guration of development policy analysis: 1990s and beyond.


RISE AND FALL OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS 799

modi®cations typically are made to maintain an responsible for the crisis. On the other side, it is
old paradigm before the accumulation of argued that the crisis is mainly due to speculative
anomalies requires, and the availability of a ®nancial ¯ows and contagion. But domestic policy,
superior alternative paradigm enables, a particularly fast ®nancial liberalization, is also said
paradigm shift. With increasing awareness of the to have played a role. The abandonment of
discrepancy between Washington Consensus government coordination of capacity expansion
recommendations and East Asian development has led to overinvestment, and the lack of
practices, such a process has occurred with the government supervision of the scale of the foreign
Washington Consensus. The discrepancy has been debts of domestic companies has precipitated
a key factor which has impelled the shift in the overexposure to external debt. Finally, the IMF
Washington Consensus from laissez-faire bailout packages are said to have exacerbated the
liberalization to the market-friendly approach. But problem. At best they are seen as a misdiagnosis;
more fundamental change has, at the same time, at worst, an attempt to use the crisis further to
been slowed by semantic ambiguities, particularly impose in a deeper way LIEO norms on domestic
centred on the key words ``outward-oriented'' economic activity.
and ``openness'' (see Gore, 1996a), and also Although these debates are still playing
further work to re-describe the East Asian themselves out, it is becoming increasingly
experience as being compatible with the norms of unconvincing to attribute the crisis solely to
the market-friendly LIEO. The World BankÕs East domestic mismanagement (see, for example,
Asian Miracle studyÐ which was prompted by Chang, Palmer & Whittaker, 1998), or analytically
disagreements between the Japanese to separate external and internal factors.
government and the World Bank on speci®c Moreover the Washington Consensus has cracked
development policy mechanisms and which Wade in the practical sense that real di€erences of
(1996) has explicitly dubbed an exercise in the opinion have emerged in Washington, between
``art of paradigm maintenance''Ðis a particularly the IMF and the World Bank, on the causes of the
signi®cant example of the latter (World Bank, crisis and how best to handle it. One important
1993). opinion-leader, Paul Krugman (1995), has already
These re-descriptions have, like earlier written the obituary of the Washington
characterizations, now been shown to have Consensus. After the Mexican crisis of 1994, he
inconsistencies and ambiguities (Amsden, 1994; argued that the major mechanism through which
Rodrik, 1994). But the debate has taken yet its policies have worked is a speculative bubble in
another turn with the ®nancial crisis in East Asia, emerging markets in which policy reforms
and the apparent fall of the newly industrializing attracted private capital ¯ows, and the attraction
economies which hitherto had been claimed on all of the ¯ows stimulated policy reforms, and that
sides as ``legitimating this bubble had now burst. In e€ect, he exposed
angels.'' market-friendly policies as actually being markets-
friendly ± ®nancial markets, that is. Similarly,
Joseph Stiglitz (1998a,b) has argued that there is a
5. THE COMING PARADIGM SHIFT need for a ``post-Washington Consensus,'' a new
paradigm. This should seek to achieve broader
The ®nancial crisis in East Asia is signi®cant for objectivesÐembracing a focus on the living
the future directions in development thinking and standards of people and the promotion of
practice. Economic growth has fallen dramatically equitable, sustainable and democratic
in developing countries and, just as there was development. It should use a wider range of
during the crisis of the early 1980s, there is now instruments to build markets as well as to correct
increasing reason to call into question the market failure, and to foster competition as well
e€ectiveness of dominant policies. Commentators as liberalization and privatization. It should also
of every persuasion have been quick to argue that adopt limited forms of regulation, if necessary
events con®rm their analysis. Some of those who controlling short-term international capital ¯ows.
support the Washington Consensus have reversed Finally change should not be imposed from
their earlier description of East Asian policies as outside but requires ownership, participation,
market-friendly, and identi®ed domestic partnership and consensusbuilding.
mismanagement, in the guise of crony capitalism It may be too early yet to announce the fall of
and excessive government intervention, as the Washington Consensus. Stiglitz's proposed
800 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

new paradigm contains some important shifts on convergence with Latin America neostructuralism,
values, continuing the incorporation of the goals and extended to Africa and the least developed
and implementation style advocated by SHD, and, countries. But while this approach can o€er a
perhaps more signi®cantly, it argues for a return more e€ective way of developing countries than
to the notion of a development strategy, based on the Washington Consensus, it does not, as it
a long-term perspective, respecting historical stands, provide an ideal alternative paradigm. This
speci®cities and with a more holistic approach is not because the current ®nancial crisis has
centred on the transformation of societies. somehow nulli®ed the development
Development should no longer be a monopoly of transformation which has occurred in East
economists. But the proposed post-Washington AsiaÐthough the crisis demands closer
Consensus consensus can also be interpreted as consideration of the issue of ``development
simply a change to preserve the old order by strategy in the age of global money.'' 17 Rather it is
making it more e€ective as well as more humane. because it remains a moot point whether it is
In elaborating the new paradigm, Stiglitz (1998b, possible to achieve similar results to those
p. 34) explicitly states that a key task is to lessen achieved by East Asian countries in their high-
the momentum of an expected swing of the growth period, given the widespread,
pendulum of opinion against openness. The simultaneous adoption of past East Asia-type
proposal retains a strong commitment to the policies. Moreover, though exaggerated, some
fundamental principles of a LIEO founded on open new global rules, particularly concerning
trade regimes, competitive markets and open technological borrowing and adaptation, may
societies. But, by de-linking trade and ®nancial inhibit the replication of some of these policies.
liberalization and then analytically separating In the future, the full globalization of
short-term from long-term international capital development policy analysis seems inevitable
¯ows, it reduces the risk that in the aftermath of (Figure 3). This will entail the explanation of
the ®nancial crisis the liberalization of external national development trends in a global context,
economic transactions will be called into question and also the elaboration of alternative normative
as a whole. Through this analytical splitting, what principles for the international regimes which
previously was propagated as a total package can constrain and enable national policy choices. Signs
now be taken to be a more ¯exible menu of that such a spatial frame shift is now occurring are
options, and any possible backlash against evident in diverse and unconnected analytical
liberalization can be more easily contained. arenas. These include: attempts to link
Whether or not StiglitzÕs courageous international trade theory to labor market
intervention is a rupture with the past or the performance (Wood, 1994); the development of
preservation of the old regime, more profound the new economic geography (Ottavino & Puga,
change is inevitable. This is because the forced 1998) and sociological analysis of global
marriage of global liberalism and methodological production chains (Gere•, 1995); work on global
nationalism, the latter providing the empirical environmental commons; and the emergence of
justi®cation for the internalization in domestic social exclusion as a concept of deprivation (Gore,
policy of the prescribed international norms of the 1996b). The spatial frame shift is likely to be linked
former, is inherently unsustainable. The only to the re-introduction of a historical perspective,
circumstances under which methodological which is already becoming evident, for example,
nationalism is a completely coherent approach to in analyses of the history of globalization of
explanation is if national economies are economic activity (Bairoch, 1993; Bairoch & Kozul-
completely isolated and closed from outside Wright, 1998; Brenner, 1998). But with the
in¯uences. The more that the norms of a LIEO are rejection of grand narratives, bringing history back
adhered to, the more that national economies in should not presage a return to the old
become open to outside in¯uences, the less teleological historicism, but rather identify
tenable methodological nationalism becomes as a alternative situations and possible development
form of explanation. The dominant paradigm is paths, and thereby inform a pragmatic
thus unstable. Its ideology and methodology are commitment to progressive change in favor of
in contradiction. present as well as future generations. The values
The coming paradigm shift will be driven by the which will glue together the new way of seeing the
main ``workable'' alternative, East Asian models, world are, like the methods of global analysis, as
politically strengthened through their yet unclear. The most likely prospect is that we

NOTES
RISE AND FALL OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS 801

shall be blown into the future facing backward, objectives, and to marry universal values with a
embracing a form of embedded communitarian respect for diversity. But this is still waiting to be
liberalism, which seeks to reconcile the born.
achievement of national, regional and global
1. That is, a constellation of beliefs, values, 10. Lyotard (1984) sees the main criterion which is
techniques and group commitments shared by members of used to legitimate knowledge after the questioning of the
a given community, founded in particular on a set of shared grand narratives as ``performativity,'' which is understood
axioms,modelsandexemplars(seeKuhn,1970).Theterm as assessment of the performance of systems in terms of
``paradigm'' is used in this sense throughout this paper. the best input/output relations (p. 46).

2. For an extended discussion of the importance of 11. Various academic books and articles are
frames in policy analysis, see Schon and Rein (1994).• The associated with these policy reports. Key elements of Latin
notion of the frame is also pivotal in Amartya SenÕs work American neostructuralism, which developed as a response
on development evaluation, though he uses the term to the weaknesses of both neoliberalism and
``informational basis'' of evaluative judgements rather than importsubstitution industrialization, are set out in Bitar
``frame.'' (1988), Ffrench-Davies (1988), Sunkel and Zuleta (1990),
Fajnzylber (1990) and Sunkel (1993), and are surveyed in
3. For deeper discussion of these debates, and the Kay (1998). A Japanese view of the contrast between East
role of international development agencies in them, see Asian developmentalism and the Washington Consensus is
Arndt (1987), chapters 3 and 4. set out in OECF (1990), whilst Okudo (1993) and JDB/JERI
(1993) discuss the Japanese approach, focusing on two
important policy mechanisms which diverge from the
4. This was a complex historical process. As Kuhn tenets of the dominant approachÐtwo-step loans and
(1970) explains, the timing of paradigm shifts is in¯uenced policy-based lending. UNCTADÕs reconstruction of East
not simply by scienti®c and policy debate, but also broader Asian developmentalism, which was elaborated
political and ideological con®gurations. These broader independently of Latin American neostructuralism, draws
changes, which include the election of conservative on analyses of the Japanese development experience,
political leaders in the United Kingdom, United States and particularly Akamatsu (1961, 1962) and Shinohara (1982),
Germany in the late 1970s and early 1980s, will not be dealt and key elements are set out in Akyuz and Gore (1996) and
with here. For a subtle account, which locates changes in Aky• uz•
development thinking and practice within a broader (1998).
counter-revolution against Keynesian economic policies,
see Toye (1993).
12. For an outline of this approach see, inter alia,
Sen (1993), and an analysis of the limits of its moral
5. For these two lines of argument, see various
individualism is made in Gore (1997).
World Development Reports, particularly World Bank
(1983, 1986, 1987). The last, as well as criticizing deviant
policies, is an exemplar of the mobilization of East Asian 13. For examples of a loose approach to poverty
experience to support key principles of a LIEO. analysis based on the concept of sustainable human
development, see UNDP (1995a,b); but Banuri et al. (1994)
attempt to give a more rigorous speci®cation of the concept
6. For an extended discussion of methodological
through the notion of social capital. An interesting recent
nationalism, see Gore (1996a).
development has been to link sustainable human
development to the promotion of human rights discourse,
7. The term ``global liberalism'' is used here as which some see as an alternative global ethics to
shorthand for various types of LIEO, which may or may not neoliberalism. The increasing incorporation of the voice of
allow a circumscribed role for national government nongovernment organizations (NGOs) into or alongside UN
intervention in market processes. social deliberations is also a€ecting the SHD approach. A
good discussion of some of the notions which animate
8. The term ``historicism'' is used here in the most these discussions is Nederveen Pierterse (1998).
general sense given by Popper (1960, p. 3). It does not imply
that planning which aims at arresting, accelerating or 14. It is di•cult to identify an African strand to the
controlling development processes is impossible, though Southern Consensus, but Mkandawire and Soludo (1999)
some historicists would adopt this stronger position seek to develop an African alternative to the Washington
(Popper, 1960, pp. 44±45). Consensus, and UNCTAD (1998, part 2) has drawn
implications of the East Asian development experience for
9. Exemplars are Rostow (1960) and Chenery and Africa.
Syrquin (1975). 15. There are some divergences between the East
Asian and Latin American approaches. The latter gives more
prominence to environment and democracy, is less
802 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

committed to aggressive sectoral targeting (ECLAC, 1996, 16. For an interesting alternative interpretation of
pp. 70±71; Ocampo, 1999), and has a more re®ned policy this fault line, see Yanagihara (1997) who contrasts an
analysis of the process of ®nancial integration than East ingredients approach and a framework approach and seeks
Asian developmentalism (ECLAC, 1995, Part 3). But their ways of synthesizing them.
similarities, and common disagreements with the
Washington Consensus, are more striking. 17. To paraphrase Yanagihara and Sambommatsu
(1996).
Akamatsu, K. (1961). A theory of unbalanced growth in the ECLAC (1990). Changing production patterns with social
world economy. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 86, equity: the prime task of Latin America and Caribbean
REFERENCES
196±215. development in the 1990s. ECLAC, Santiago,
Akamatsu, K. (1962). A historical pattern of economic Chile.
growth in developing countries. The Developing ECLAC (1992). Social equity and changing production
Economies, 1 (1), 3±25. patterns: an integrated approach. ECLAC, Santiago,
Akyuz, Y. (1998) New Perspectives on East Asia.• Journal of Chile.
Development Studies (special issue) 34 (6). ECLAC (1994). Open regionalism in Latin America and the
Akyuz, Y., & Gore, C. G. (1996). The investment-pro®ts• Caribbean: economic integration as a contribution to
nexus in East Asian industrialization. World changing production patterns with social equity. ECLAC,
Development, 24 (3), 461±470. Santiago, Chile.
Amsden, A. (1994). Why isn't the whole world ECLAC (1995). Policies to improve linkages with the global
experimenting with the East Asian model to develop?: economy. ECLAC, Santiago, Chile.
review of the East Asian miracle. World Development, ECLAC (1996). Strengthening development: the interplay of
22 (4), 627±634. macro- and microeconomics. ECLAC, Santiago,
Arndt, H. W. (1987). Economic development: the history of Chile.
an idea. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ESCAP (1990). Restructuring the developing economies of
Bairoch, P. (1993). Economic and world history. Brighton: Asia and the Paci®c in the 1990s. United Nations, New
Wheatsheaf. York.
Bairoch, P., & Kozul-Wright, R. (1998). Globalization myths: Evans, P. (1998). Transferable lessons? Re-examining the
some historical re¯ections on integration, institutional prerequisites of East Asian economic
industrialization and growth in the world economy. In policies. Journal of Development Studies, 34 (6), 66±86.
R. Kozul-Wright & R. Rowthorn, Transnational Fajnzylber, F. (1990) Industrialization in Latin America: from
corporations and the global economy (pp. 37±68). the ``black box'' to the ``empty box.'' Cuardenos de la
London: Macmillan; New York: St. Martins Press. CEPAL, 60, CEPAL, Santiago, Chile.
Banuri, T. et al. (1994). De®ning and operationalizing Ffrench-Davies, R. (1988). An outline of a neo-structuralist
sustainable human development: a guide for approach. CEPAL Review, 34, 37±44.
practitioners. Bureau for Programme Policy and Gere•, G. (1995). Contending paradigms for crossregional
Evaluation. New York: UNDP. comparison: development strategies and commodity
Bauer, P. T. (1971). Dissent on development: studies and chains in East Asia and Latin America. In P. H. Smith,
debates in development economics. London: Latin America in comparative perspective: new
Weidenfeld and Nicolson. approaches to methods and analysis (pp. 33±58).
Bitar, S. (1988). Neo-conservatism versus neo-structuralism Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
in Latin America. CEPAL Review, 34, 45±62. Brenner, R. Gore, C. G. (1996a). Methodological nationalism and the
(1998). The economics of global turbulence: a special report misunderstanding of East Asian industrialization.
on the world economy, 1950±98, New Left Review, 229, European Journal of Development Research, 8 (1),
(May/June). 77±122.
Byres, T. J. (1979). Of neopopulist pipedreams: Daedalus in Gore, C. G. (1996b). Social exclusion, globalization, and the
the Third World and the myth of urban bias. Journal of trade-o€ between e•ciency and equity. In G. Kohler• et
Peasant Studies, 6 (2), 210±244. al., Questioning development: essays in the theory,
Campos, J. E., & Root, H. L. (1996). The key to the Asian policies and practice of development interventions (pp.
miracle: making shared growth credible. Washington, 103±116). Metropolis Verlag, Marburg.
DC: The Brookings Institution. Gore, C. G. (1997). Irreducibly social goods and the
Chang, H. -J., Palmer, G., & Whittaker, D. Hugh. (1998). The informational basis of Amartya Sen's capability
Asian crisis. Cambridge Journal of Economics (special approach. Journal of International Development, 9 (2),
issue), 22. 235±250.
Chenery, H. B., & Syrquin, M. (1975). Patterns of Haq, M. ul. (1995). Re¯ections on human development.
development, 1950±70. London: Oxford University Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Press. IMF (1997) World economic outlook. Globalization:
opportunities and challenges. IMF, Washington DC.
RISE AND FALL OF THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS 803

JDB/JERI (Japan Development Bank and Japan Economic Sen, A. (1993). Capability and well-being. In M. Nussbaum
Research Institute) (1993). Policy-based ®nance: the & A. Sen, The quality of life (pp. 30± 54). Oxford:
experience of postwar Japan. Final Report to the World Clarendon Press.
Bank, Washington, DC. Shinohara, M. (1982). Industrial growth, trade and dynamic
Johnson, H. J. (1967). The ideology of economic policy in the patterns in the Japanese economy. Tokyo: Tokyo
new States. In H. G. Johnson, Economic nationalism in University Press.
old and new states (pp. 124±141). Chicago: University Singh, A. (1994). Openness and the market-friendly
of Chicago Press. approach to development: learning the right lessons
Kay, C. (1989). Latin American theories of development and from development experience. World Development, 22
underdevelopment. London: Routledge. (12), 1811±1823.
Kay, C. (1998). Relevance of structuralist and dependency Stiglitz, J. (1998a). More instruments and broader goals:
theories in the neoliberal period: a Latin American Moving toward the post-Washington consensus. The
perspective. Working Paper Series No. 281, Institute of WIDER Annual Lecture, Helsinki, Finland, January
Social Studies, The Hague. 7.
Kuhn, T. (1970). The structure of scienti®c revolutions (2nd Stiglitz, J. (1998b). Towards a new paradigm for
ed.) enlarged. In International encyclopaedia of uni®ed development: Strategies, policies, and processes.
science (Vol. 2, No. 2). Chicago: University of Chicago Prebisch Lecture given at UNCTAD, Geneva, October 19.
Press. Sunkel, O., & Zuleta, G. (1990). Neo-structuralism versus
Krugman, P. (1995). Dutch tulips and emerging markets. neo-liberalism in the 1990s. CEPAL Review, 42, 36±51.
Foreign A€airs, 74 (4), 28±44. Sunkel, O. (1993). Development from within: toward a
Lyotard, J. -F. (1984). The post-modern condition: a report neostructuralist approach for Latin America. Boulder,
on knowledge. Manchester: Manchester CO: Lynne Reinner Publishers.
University Press. Toye, J. (1993). Dilemmas of development: re¯ections on
Mkandawire, T., & Soludo, C. (1999). Our continent, our the counter-revolution in development theory and
future: African perspectives on structural adjustment. practice (2nd ed.). Oxford: Blackwell.
Trenton, NJ, and Asmara, Eritrea: Africa World UNCTAD (1994). Trade and development report. Geneva:
Press. United Nations.
Nederveen Pierterse, J. (1998). My paradigm or yours? UNCTAD (1996). Trade and development report. Geneva:
Alternative development, post-development, re¯exive United Nations.
development. Development and Change, 29, 343± 373. UNCTAD (1997). Trade and development report. Geneva:
Ocampo, J. A. (1999). Beyond the Washington Consensus: United Nations.
an ECLAC perspective. Paper prepared for the UNCTAD (1998). Trade and development report. Geneva:
conference on Beyond the Washington Consensus: Net United Nations.
Assessment and Prospects for New Approach, UNDP (various years). Human development report. New
organized by the Department of Comparative Research York: Oxford University Press.
on Development of the Ecole des Hautes Etudes en UNDP (1995a). Poverty eradication: a policy framework for
Sciences Sociales, Paris, and MOST of UNESCO, June country strategies. New York: UNDP.
1999, Paris. UNDP (1995b). From poverty to equity: an empowering and
OECF (1990). Issues related to the World BankÕs approach enabling strategy. New York: UNDP.
to structural adjustment ± proposal from a major Wade, R. (1996). The World Bank and the art of paradigm
partner. OECF Discussion Paper No. 1. maintenance: the East Asian Miracle in political
Okudo, H. (1993). Japanese two-step loans: the Japanese perspective. New Left Review, 217, 3±36.
approach to development ®nance. Hitotsubashi Journal Wood, A. (1994). North±South trade, employment and
of Economics, 34, 67±85. inequality: changing fortunes in a skill-driven world.
Ottavino, G. I. P., & Puga, D. (1998). Agglomeration in the Oxford: Clarendon Press.
global economy: a survey of the `New Economic Williamson, J. (1990).What Washington means by policy
Geography'. The World Economy, 21 (6), 707±732. reform. In J. Williamson, Latin American adjustment: how
Popper, K. R. (1960). The poverty of historicism (2nd ed.). much has happened (pp. 5±20). Washington DC: Institute of
London: Routledge, Kegan and Paul. International Economics. Williamson, J. (1993). Democracy
Rodrik, D. (1994). King Kong meets Godzilla: the World Bank and the `Washington Consensus'. World Development, 21
and the East Asian miracle. CEPR Discussion Paper, No. (8), 1329±1336.
944, CEPR Oxford. Williamson, J. (1997). The Washington Consensus revisited.
Rostow, W. (1960). The stages of economic growth: a non- In L. Emmerij, Economic and social development into
communist manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge the XXI century (pp. 48±61). Washington DC: Inter-
University Press. American Development Bank (distributed by John
Schon, D., & Rein, M. (1994).• Frame re¯ection: towards the Hopkins University Press, Baltimore).
resolution of intractable policy controversies. New York: World Bank (various years). World development report.
Basic Books. New York: Oxford University Press.
804 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

World Bank (1993). The East Asian miracle. New York:


Oxford University Press.
World Bank (1997). Global economic prospects and the
developing countries. Washington DC: World Bank.
Yanagihara, T. (1997). Economic system approach and its
applicability. In T. Yanagihara & S. Sambommatsu, East
Asian development experience: economic system
approach and its applicability (pp. 1±35). Tokyo:
Institute for Developing Economies.
Yanagihara, T., & Sambommatsu, S. (1996). Exchange rate
¯uctuations and Asian responses: growth strategy in the
age of global money. IDE Spot Survey. Tokyo: Institute
for Developing Economies.

Вам также может понравиться