Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 5

American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2016, 106(5): 52–56

http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20161069

Critiquing Robert J. Gordon’s The Rise and Fall of


American Growth

A Century of Growth and Improvement†

By Benjamin M. Friedman*

Most books about American exceptionalism No doubt the comparison that Gordon had in
begin at the beginning, that is, with the initial mind in undertaking this massive achievement
English settlement of North America in the early (764 pages) was Robert Aaron Gordon’s classic
seventeenth century. For reasons of data avail- Business Fluctuations, first published in 1952
ability, Robert J. Gordon’s monumental history (687 pages in the second edition). But in its his-
of how technology has improved American liv- torical sweep, its combination of national scope
ing standards begins in the nineteenth century, with the fine detail of the daily lives of ordinary
just after the conclusion of the Civil War. But his people, and above all its continual assumption
story follows in the long tradition of American of the specialness of the United States, Robert J.
exceptionalism nonetheless. Gordon’s book more appropriately calls to mind
As Gordon makes clear at the outset, the the pioneering treatments of the new nation’s
center of his narrative is what he portrays as an extraordinariness such as George Bancroft’s
exceptional period of time, more specifically History of the United States of America, pub-
an exceptional century. His primary claim is lished in ten volumes beginning in 1834 and
that “The economic revolution of 1870 to 1970 finally revised by the author not until well into
was unique in human history,” and he calls this Gordon’s “special century.”
period a “special century” for the way in which In light of Gordon’s emphasis on the role of
the “unique clustering” of “Great Inventions” “inventions” in enabling the improvement of
that these years brought to bear on the lives of living standards that he chronicles, this assump-
ordinary citizens “free[d] households from an tion of American specialness is apt. Today,
unremitting daily grind of painful manual labor, economists everywhere understand the central-
household drudgery, darkness, isolation, and ity of technological progress, broadly defined,
early death” (pp. 1, 2). The result, he argues, in driving economic growth. It was not always
was “a singular interval of rapid growth that will so. Adam Smith, for example, displayed little
not be repeated” (p. 3). But the exceptionalism awareness of the contribution of technological
that he claims applies not just in time, but space: advance to economic growth despite his living at
“the designation of the century between 1870 the time, and in the place, of the First Industrial
and 1970 as the special epoch applies only to Revolution. (The most immediate indication
the United States, the nation which has carved that Smith missed what was happening around
out the technological frontier for all developed him is that the example he chose in the Wealth
nations” during this period and since (p. 3). of Nations to illustrate how division of labor
enhances productivity was a “pin”, i.e., nail,
factory, rather than something to do with textile
production.) As late as the 1820s, although most
people presumably understood that they were
* Department of Economics, Harvard University, Littauer living better than their parents and grandparents
Center 127, Cambridge, MA 02138 (e-mail: bfriedman@ had a ­ half-century before, most still thought
harvard.edu).
† 
Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20161069 to visit of the experienced improvement as simply the
the article page for additional materials and author disclo- upswing of yet another “long wave.” Not until
sure statement. the 1830s did people widely recognize that these
52
VOL. 106 NO. 5 a century of growth and improvement 53

gains were here to stay, and moreover, that more vivid ­imaginations were more plentiful. In his
were to come. Thanksgiving Day sermon that year, Henry
And it was no coincidence that this awareness Ward Beecher, perhaps the nation’s best known
of the prospect of economic advance continuing preacher of the era, told his congregation, “The
on indefinitely, together with a recognition of the future fortunes of America will be fabulous. … I
central role of ongoing technical progress under- look forward into that ‘golden’ future, literally,
lying it, first emerged in America. The first clear which is opening before us. And marvel whether
expression of this idea (of which I am aware) the most poetic dreams of growing wealth may
in the economics literature came from Francis not fall short of the reality” (Beecher 1870, p.
Wayland. In The Elements of Political Economy, 211).
which became the ­best-selling economics text in The central argument of Gordon’s book is that
America before the Civil War, Wayland (1837, Wayland and Beecher, looking forward on the
p. 53) acknowledged the enormous progress of eve of the “special century,” got it right; but that
recent decades and went on to conclude, “If it be the same optimism applied to the future as seen
asked, how far may this increased productive- from today would be mistaken. The era of new
ness of human industry be carried, we answer, inventions and discoveries not conceivable in
it is impossible to tell, unless we can ascertain advance, even to the most vivid imagination, and
how great are the blessings which God has in of a consequent increase in wealth exceeding the
reserve for man.” Making explicit the link to most poetic dreams, is over.
technical progress, he continued, “Who can esti-
mate the benefits conferred on man by the mag- I.  Not Just More, but Different
net, or by steam, or by the printing press? And
what reason have we to assume that the gifts of Economics is a quantitative discipline.
God are exhausted, or that there are not yet other Modern analytic investigation of economic
and more excellent natural agents to be discov- growth traditionally frames the matter within
ered, or other modes of using those which we one or another mathematical model in which
are already acquainted with, that shall produce “growth” simply means more: more output,
even more surprising results than any which we more consumption, presumably more of every-
have yet witnessed?” thing (except labor per worker). The fact that
Although Gordon’s narrative starts a third of actual economic advance normally means pro-
a century later, his emphasis echoes Wayland in ducing and consuming different things requires
attributing “increased productiveness” to dis- cumbersome technical apparatus, of one form or
coveries and inventions: in Wayland’s case mag- another, and is therefore a matter most often left
netism (and therefore electricity), steam (and implicit.
therefore engines for production as well as the A primary strength of Gordon’s achieve-
­then-still-new railroad), and the printing press. ment is that qualitative change is central to his
Gordon’s list of “Great Inventions” put to use narrative. Indeed, the implicit tension between
between 1870 and 1970 likewise includes elec- economists’ usual rendering and what he has in
trification, steam power, and railroads, along mind first shows up on the book’s cover. The title
with the internal combustion engine, powered refers to American growth; the subtitle points to
air flight, a host of drugs and medical proce- the US standard of living. Early on (Table 2–2,
dures, and such household basics as running pp. 38–39), he emphasizes that almost 60 per-
water, central heating, and indoor sanitation. cent of American consumption today consists of
But Gordon’s assessment of future prospects goods and services “invented or largely devel-
differs sharply. “Before the discovery of these oped after 1869.”
agents,” Wayland wrote, “the most vivid imag- Part of what enables Gordon to integrate this
ination could never have conceived of the ben- qualitative change in citizens’ living standards
efits which they have already conferred upon with the more familiar quantitative examination
society. There is no reason to suppose that we of the economy’s growth record is the exper-
are now more capable of fathoming the good- tise, evident in many of his prior works as well,
ness of God, than our ancestors were, three that he brings to bear in deploying the often
or four hundred years ago” (pp. 53–54). By awkward technical machinery required for this
1870, when Gordon’s “special century” began, analysis, such as price indexes adjusted for both
54 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2016

product quality change and the introduction of advance until 1970, and then a slower pace since
new products. But even more important for the (which Gordon predicts will prove permanent).
book’s overall impact—and especially in light There is no reason, however, for granularity
of the emphasis on “Great Inventions” and their along this dimension to stop at distinguishing
fruits—is Gordon’s reliance on historical narra- the 1870–1970 interval from what came before
tive that frees him from the constraints of the and after. Gordon of course acknowledges the
more familiar analytical models. point, most evidently in assessing the special
Gordon exploits this freedom to organize his character of the Great Depression of the 1930s
narrative not in the usual chronological format as well as of World War II and its immediate
but by aspects of economic activity—still mean- aftermath (see, especially, ch. 16). But while
ing, however, what people produced and either these two events may have been the most strik-
consumed or used as intermediate production ing in the differences they presented—and, as
inputs: chapters on food and clothing; on the Gordon argues, following Field (2011), those
physical environment of homes; on transporta- differences are interesting and important eco-
tion; on communication; on health and mortal- nomically—the remainder of the “special cen-
ity; on working conditions; and on entertainment tury” was not homogeneous either.
and other ways of deploying leisure. One imme- What presumably matters for this purpose is
diately apparent advantage of this approach the span of time over which ordinary citizens
is the opportunity it opens for the richness of assess their economic ­well-being to determine
detail that characterizes the entire book: build- if they are “getting ahead.” And even that may
ing elevators, Mason jars, canned meat, sewing differ depending on the purpose for which they
machines, refrigerators, ­ X-rays, color televi- are assessing it. Do people compare how they
sions, cell phones, and thousands of other exam- are living now to how they lived last year? To
ples that make Gordon’s a story about everyday how they remember living ten years ago? To
life. But more fundamentally, addressing the how they think people lived 50 years earlier?
evolution of economic life over a century and For purposes of gauging the impact of economic
a half in this way also makes clearer why what growth or stagnation on the attitudes that shape
happened mattered to those who lived through the social and political evolution of democratic
it. Although one would never guess from the societies, the evidence suggests that what mat-
usual literature of economic growth, most peo- ters most is intergenerational comparisons: peo-
ple actually do not form their attitude toward ple compare how they live to how their parents
the economy in which they live by studying lived, their opportunities to those their parents
the national income statistics. What matters had, how they are raising their children to what
to them is how they live, and (as Adam Smith they remember from their own childhood, and,
insightfully emphasized) whether they are get- in time, their children’s opportunities to their
ting ahead. own. Gordon’s “special century” in America (on
average, he reports, a doubling in living stan-
II.  A Special Century but not Homogeneous dards every 32 years) naturally lends itself to
this kind of outlook. But the standard of living
What this d­ imension-by-dimension narrative did not advance uniformly, and the development
organization does not do, however, is readily and character of American democracy did not
enable Gordon to distinguish how the pace of the remain unchanged, over this period. None of this
improvement he chronicles, or citizens’ aware- is Gordon’s story, nor, in light of his narrative’s
ness of it and reactions to it, varied over time. grounding in technology and the specific goods
Gordon’s central claim is the specialness of the and services produced, is it meant to be.
century from 1870 to 1970. He is at pains to con-
trast this view to the nowadays familiar account III.  Looking Forward: Heterogeneity in a
distinguishing essentially all of human history to Different Dimension
about 1800, during which there was little or no
improvement in living standards, from the era Gordon’s narrative also explicitly recog-
of growth and improvement since then. The por- nizes that, even at any given point in time, the
trayal in his book is more granular: some advance American population did not (and does not) live
before 1870, then spectacular and unprecedented at a uniform standard. Life in the city d­ iffers
VOL. 106 NO. 5 a century of growth and improvement 55

from that on the farm. Geographic regions, espe- democracy are worrisome. Historically—not
cially the South in his period, differ from one always and everywhere, but most of the time and
another. Most important, the rich are different in most places—rising living standards, broadly
from the poor. And, since the end of the “spe- shared in the population, have led to expansion of
cial century,” they are becoming increasingly opportunity and generosity, increased tolerance,
different. This widening inequality is a key and stronger democracies. Stagnating incomes
part of the basis for the pessimistic outlook he have mostly resulted in the opposite (Friedman
offers for the future growth of American living 2005). A high standard of living per se is no
standards. guarantee against the perverse social, political,
To recall, Gordon’s central claim is that what- and moral consequences of s­tagnation. And as
ever new advances occur will be insufficient to Alexander Gerschenkron (1943, p. 5) observed,
replicate the impact of the “Great Inventions” “even a long democratic history does not nec-
that propelled the special century’s unprece- essarily immunize a country from becoming a
dented growth. But he points as well to “head- ‘democracy without democrats’.”
winds” that—not permanently, but for long But what if Gordon is wrong in this regard?
enough to matter against the sweep of the his- Some economists, most prominently Erik
torical narrative he offers—will further retard Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee (2014),
the growth of living standards for the average point to the electronic revolution as the source
citizen. Foremost among these, in his telling, is of unprecedented gains in productivity in the
widening economic inequality. ­twenty-first century. Gordon labels such views
Widening inequality has already mattered “­
techno-optimism,” acknowledging the tran-
in just this way, as the incomes of the major- sition from mainframe computers to isolated
ity of Americans have failed to keep pace with personal computers to the Internet to smart
the growth of aggregate output per capita. The phones and tablets, but dismissing its impor-
difference is not merely a matter of the recent tance on the ground that “its effect was felt in
financial crisis. From 2000 to the p­ recrisis peak a limited sphere of human activity” (p. 578).
in 2007, total output per capita rose on average No doubt some people said similar things when
by 1.5 percent per annum in real terms; the real railroads, and then motor cars, and then pow-
median family income rose at just 0.1 percent per ered flight, first appeared—each was at first a
annum. Combining the crisis and the subsequent novelty, and used for transportation only by
recovery, real output per capita in 2014 was 1.4 the daring and the rich—and probably with the
percent above that in 2007; real median family introduction of many of Gordon’s other “Great
income in 2014 was 4.9 percent below the 2007 Inventions” too. Only time will tell whether
level. (Some part of these differences, but only we are, as Francis Wayland put it, “more capa-
a small part, is due to declining average family ble of fathoming the goodness of God than our
size.) As is by now well-known, this widening of ancestors were.”
inequality is mostly a matter of those at the very Even if the “­techno-optimists” turn out to be
top of the income distribution separating from the right, however, concern for America’s foresee-
rest. In short, most of the fruits of incremental able future still seems warranted, albeit on dif-
production now accrue to only a small part of the ferent grounds. If the driverless cars and other
population. ­human-free ways of carrying out economic tasks
Gordon sees this widening inequality, that Brynjolfsson and McAfee (2014) envi-
together with other “headwinds” of presumably sion do replace as much labor as they expect,
more finite duration, as compounding the poor then demand for labor, in many of the jobs that
growth prospects that he envisions on techno- Gordon hails as having revolutionized—for the
logical grounds. Because currently evolving better—the character of work over the “special
inventions will fail to match those that made the century” will fall sharply. In time, new applica-
“special century” special, growth of aggregate tions for this released labor, perhaps producing
output per capita will continue to fall short of the new goods and services also not yet envisioned,
­pre-1970 rate. And with widening inequality, the will presumably emerge. The transition could
increase in most Americans’ incomes and living be a long one, however, easily long enough to
standards will fall shorter still. If he proves right, count even in a highly t­ ime-aggregated narrative
prospects for American society and American like Gordon’s. To be sure, if the reason for such
56 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2016

sharply depressed demand for labor is increased REFERENCES


productivity, in principle the society could
simply make do with a much shorter work-
­ Bancroft, George. 1882. History of the United
week, as Keynes (1930) famously predicted in States: From the Discovery of the Continent.
his “Grandchildren” essay nearly a century ago. New York: Appleton
But no one now foresees a change in American Beecher, Henry Ward. 1870. “The Tendencies of
society’s ways of distributing income that American Progress.” In The Original Plym-
would allow those working Keynes’s ­15-hour outh Pulpit. Vol. V, 203–219. Chicago: Pilgrim
weeks to enjoy improvement in their living Press.
standard anything like what Gordon’s “spe- Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Andrew McAfee. 2014.
cial century” brought to the great mass of the The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and
population. Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies.
New York: Norton.
IV.  Conclusion: Improvement and Increase Field, Alexander J. 2011. A Great Leap Forward:
1930s Depression and US Economic Growth.
The language of Adam Smith’s day aspired New Haven, CT: Yale.
to “advance” and “improvement.” The lan- Friedman, Benjamin M. 2005. The Moral Con-
guage of economics in the late twentieth and sequences of Economic Growth. New York:
early ­twenty-first centuries addresses “growth” Knopf.
and “expansion.” Economics has made signif- Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1943. Bread and
icant achievements in understanding the latter. Democracy in Germany. Berkeley: University
Despite numerous empirical studies of such of California.
observable phenomena as patents and R&D Gordon, Robert Aaron. 1952. Business Fluctua-
spending, the former largely remains a mystery. tions. New York: Harper and Brothers.
Robert Gordon’s magnificent historical study Gordon, Robert J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of
combines the quantitative analysis of growth American Growth. Princeton: Princeton Uni-
and expansion with the qualitative dimension versity Press.
of advance and improvement. A major contri- Keynes, John Maynard. 1930. “Economic Pos-
bution of Gordon’s rich and ­fine-grained exam- sibilities for Our Grandchildren.” Nation and
ination of precisely what improvement in living Athenaeum, October 11 and 18.
standards has meant, and why it has mattered Smith, Adam. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature
to ordinary citizens, may be to focus future and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Oxford:
economic research on understanding better the Oxford University Press [1976].
invention and discovery that make such progress Wayland, Francis. 1837. Elements of Political
happen. Economy. New York: Leavitt.

Вам также может понравиться