Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 11

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/321175212

Opportunities for greater energy efficiency in


government facilities by aligning decision
structures with advances in behavio....

Article in Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews · November 2017


DOI: 10.1016/j.rser.2017.10.078

CITATIONS READS

0 23

2 authors, including:

Tripp Shealy
Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University
29 PUBLICATIONS 31 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Teaching Engineering Design for Sustainability Through Envision Case Studies: An Approach to
Overcome Cognitive Bias During Decision Making for Infrastructure View project

Climate Change Literacy View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Tripp Shealy on 23 December 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rser

Opportunities for greater energy efficiency in government facilities by T


aligning decision structures with advances in behavioral science

Laura Delgado, Tripp Shealy
Dept. of Civil and Environmental Engineering, Virginia Tech, Blacksburg, VA 24061, United States

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: In 2007, Executive Order 13423 mandated 30% energy and emission reductions for all government facilities by
Facility management 2015. Unfortunately, the government fell short of their goal by 9%. Their approach through mandates and
Government federal legislation focused predominantly on new construction and major retrofits to existing facilities. To meet
Energy reduction future energy and emission reduction goals, more emphasis on facility management is needed. The government
Cognitive bias
manages over 370 million square feet of facilities each year. The daily decision process for government facility
Choice Architecture
managers is full of competing interests, such as maintenance needs (preventative and corrective), limited op-
erating budgets, time constraints to make decisions, and bounded rationality about energy consumption and
savings. By understanding how these decisions are made and the cognitive bias that may occur, advances in
facility management decision making can reduce energy consumption. Cognitive biases to the decision making
process such as loss aversion, anchoring, and status quo bias are explored and an approach to overcome them is
offered, a tactic called choice architecture, meaning restructuring decision environments to align with beha-
vioral decision theory. Examples of choice architecture, such as, enabling procurement systems to query green
products, changing default settings in mechanical systems, and requiring the use of pay back period calculators
to account for cognitive limitations of the decision maker, are suggested and supported by behavioral science
research to help direct facility managers towards energy efficient choices. This approach, through choice ar-
chitecture, holds potential to yield relatively low-cost solutions (they do not require new mandates or laws) to
support greater energy reduction in government facility management. This merging of literature from behavioral
science to facility management is meant to open new avenues of interdisciplinary research.

1. Introduction goals.
The focus of this paper is decisions made during the operations and
The federal government is the largest user of electricity and fuel in maintenance phase of government facilities because buildings consume
the country, accounting for 1.5% of the nation's annual energy con- more energy during the operations and maintenance phase than during
sumption [1]. In 2007, Congress passed legislation to reduce its energy any other life cycle phase [4]. Also, government facility managers face
use 30% from 2003 levels by 2015 [2]. New programs for facility constant and significant challenges to energy reduction decisions. For
management like Freeze the Footprint [1] were enacted and major example, government facility managers typically transition jobs, on
retrofits to existing facilities were completed [3]. Unfortunately, the average, every three years, which could lead to myopic decisions that
federal government fell short of their goal by 9% [1]. Federal agencies discount future return on investments. These same managers are lauded
continue to pursue measures to reduce energy consumption through during yearly job evaluations for reducing operation budget ex-
new executive orders (e.g. EO 13514) and recognized financial in- penditures, possibly deterring the purchase of more expensive products
centives [1]. However, in spite of these efforts, buildings still consume that save energy over time. Additionally, during retrofits, facility
34% of all the energy used by the government [1], partially because managers are frequently not part of the design team making the deci-
many government facilities are old and not built with efficiency in sions that influence daily operations and maintenance and related en-
mind. In addition, major retrofits completed during Executive Order ergy use [5].
13423 are not as efficient as expected [3]. This paper explores the Seminal works in psychology [6,7] and new empirical studies in
decision making process and potential cognitive biases that prevents engineering [8] illustrate the benefit of adopting this perspective and
greater energy reduction to enable the government to meet its future are included in this review. The paper begins with an overview of


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: laurad89@vt.edu (L. Delgado), tshealy@vt.edu (T. Shealy).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2017.10.078
Received 29 August 2016; Received in revised form 1 June 2017; Accepted 28 October 2017
Available online 20 November 2017
1364-0321/ © 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

government energy decisions and the role of facility management. The government. Market based approaches are also needed.
purpose of this section is to illustrate the gap in research related to
behavioral and decision sciences to better inform facility managers’
decisions about energy. The next section provides the theoretical per- 2.2. Leadership in Energy and Environmental Design
spective of how decisions, of all types, are made. The premise is deci-
sion makers do not always have the appropriate time and information An example of a market based approach is the rating system
to make the best decisions, and choices should be structured to account Leadership in Energy and Environmental Design (LEED). LEED certified
for these shortcomings. The third section introduces cognitive biases buildings lease for a higher price per square foot and at a higher oc-
relevant to facility management. This includes how cognitive biases cupancy rate [14,15] suggesting a demand in the market for more
impact various fields from law to engineering and how to improve sustainable buildings. The government also mandates that all newly
decision making through an approach called choice architecture. The constructed government owned facilities meet at least LEED Gold cer-
final section offers opportunities for choice architecture within gov- tification [16,17]. However, LEED as a decision support tool may result
ernment facility management to aid in decision making for future en- in anchoring on required mandates leading to lower energy perfor-
ergy reduction. The purpose of this review is to expose new avenues of mance in buildings [18]. Likewise, just certifying a government
research related to decision making for energy reduction. The focus building with LEED does not equivocally correlate with increased en-
here is specifically about government facility management, but the ergy efficiency [19,20]. In fact, energy consumption in 9 out of 11 US
concepts and theories are applicable to many sectors. Navy LEED certified buildings did not meet the required 30% energy
reduction mandated by EO 13423. These buildings consume more
2. Government facility management and energy decisions electricity than the national averages published by the commercial
building energy consumption survey [17].
To explain how government employees make decisions about en- Even if LEED could guarantee energy reduction, the number of
ergy, decision tools and policies are split into two categories: market- government facilities already online and not retrofitted are con-
based and command control processes. The market based instruments siderably more than the number of new or recently retrofitted gov-
are programs that produce rebates for energy efficient products and ernment buildings. Therefore, small, day-to-day facility level decisions
induce pollution charges, taxes, and permits that regulate energy and hold potential to influence a large number of buildings unaccounted for
environmental harm [9]. Command control instruments are items that by LEED. Day-to-day facility maintenance decisions involve preventive
force the government to enact regulations by setting performance and maintenance, corrective maintenance, and in some cases, deferred
technology standards [9]. Command control measures are intended to maintenance [21]. The majority of these maintenance items involve
be carried out regardless of cost. Listed in this section are a mix of electrical, mechanical, and structural elements of the facility. This in-
decision support tools that represent both market based approaches and cludes procurement decisions as related to the operations and main-
command control measures for energy efficiency and facility manage- tenance of the facility [22]. Facility managers are responsible for de-
ment by the government. The objective of this section is to explain how cisions about what parts to replace, which appliances to purchase, and
the different government vehicles, market based and command control in what order. These decisions range from $200,000 HVAC systems to
processes, effect decision making in government facility management. $10 light bulbs. The next section describes the many mandates that
This section also provides an overview of the current state of research in currently affect product purchases in the federal government.
facility management decision making.

2.1. Executive orders 2.3. Government facility management mandates

Executive orders (EO) act as command control measures for decision Information about product purchases in the federal government is
making. Enacted in 2007, EO 13423 required a 30% reduction in en- disseminated amongst different acts and statutes that can be confusing
ergy consumption in all federal government buildings by 2015 [10] and and difficult to implement. For example, there are ENERGY STAR
more recently EO 13514 pushed for strict energy measures by 2020, purchasing requirements for energy related products and services [23].
including greenhouse gas emission reductions. EO 13514 was recently There are requirements to purchase premium efficient motors for de-
replaced by EO 13693, which calls for a 2.5% annual decrease in energy vices with electric motors up to 500 horsepower. There are also re-
intensity until the end of fiscal year 2025 [11], as seen in Table 1. quirements to purchase alternative or synthetic fuels, which stipulates
The problem of command control measures like EOs is that firms that agencies compare greenhouse gas emissions when using conven-
often place more consideration on meeting the mandate and less im- tional types of fuel [2].
portance on long term benefits due to the uncertainty of determining There are also dozens of mandates governing building energy use
future gains [13]. Contract firms often believe the best way to achieve buried within U.S. energy code. There are mandates which involve
these mandates is to adopt a new technology, which can dis- building energy intensity reduction for agencies to reduce intensity in
proportionately add to the delivery cost of the project [9]. While EOs existing buildings, conduct better facility assessment benchmarking,
help reduce energy consumption, they alone are not enough (seen in improve evaluation of systems, improve training for facility managers,
Table 1) to meet the large energy reduction goals set by the reduce energy use in leased buildings, evaluate new construction
agency procedures, and monitor energy for contractor operated facil-
Table 1 ities. Additionally, there are requirements for energy efficiency, life
Executive orders that mandate energy efficiency. cycle costs, net zero, fossil fuel reduction, metering, and renewables
[2,10,23,24].
Executive Order Energy Mandate Status
These mandates are in place to help the government meet over-
EO 13423 30% energy reduction in government Short of goal by 9% arching goals of reducing greenhouse gas emissions. But when it comes
buildings by 2015 to government employees making decisions, identifying and complying
EO 13514 Meet GHG emission reduction goals Replaced with with every command control measure can become cognitively over-
1 & 2 by 2020* 13693
whelming. There is an opportunity to better align advances in beha-
EO 13693 2.5% annual decrease in energy until Current
2025 vioral sciences to reduce the cognitive burden, making decisions about
energy efficiency easier for facility managers.
GHG 1 & 2: Reduce GHG emissions by 25% relative to a 2008 FY baseline [12].

3953
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

Table 2
Gap in research connecting behavioral science to facility management decision making.

Behavioral Science Procurement Innovation Energy Efficiency Risk

Chandrashekaran and Gopalakrishnan [21] de Zwart [27] Chandrashekaran and Gopalakrishnan [21]

El-Haram and Agapiou [145] El-Haram and Agapiou [145] El-Haram and Agapiou [145] El-Haram and Agapiou [145]
Hodges [5] Hodges [5] Hodges [5]
Jackson [132] Jackson [132] Jackson [132] Jackson [132]
Khalil et al. [25]
Perrenoud et al., [146] Perrenoud et al., [146] Perrenoud et al., [146]
Pitt and Tucker [147] Pitt and Tucker [147] Pitt and Tucker [147] Pitt and Tucker [147]

2.4. Facility management literature review When decision makers are faced with alternatives that involve risk
and the probabilities of outcomes are unknown, prospect theory can
Much of the literature devoted to facility management focuses on predict decision outcomes that utility theory fails to consider [30].
sustainable needs, reducing risk, and uncertainty that contributes to Decision makers often downplay outcomes that contain risk and overly
ineffective project management (See Table 2). The solutions presented weigh outcomes that include certainty [30,39]. This is because poten-
in the literature frequently involve increased public participation, tial losses provoke greater degrees of discomfort than potential gains
training, and new policies for environmental protection [25]. However, provide satisfaction [40,41]. To overcome a potential loss, the gain
when facility managers attempt to meet energy reduction demands and must be roughly twice as great [38]. Decision makers, however, are not
mandates from the government, the uncertainty in products and ef- always risk averse. If a decision maker recently experienced a loss, the
fectiveness can lead to more risky decisions, not less [13]. Table 2 amount of risk they are willing to accept increases, in hopes to return to
provides a summary of research about facility management decision net zero or positive outcome [42].
making. This list is not exhaustive, but indicative of the research found Prospect theory explains why homeowners selling in a down market
that pertains to this study of facility management decisions about en- may insist on a higher asking price [43], why investors sell profitable
ergy. Note, both the lack of distinction in papers between government stocks too soon and retain losing stocks too long [44], and why con-
and private facility management and the lack of research connecting sumers generally hold failing assets longer than winning assets [45–47].
facility management to behavioral sciences. Prospect theory is applied to make accurate predictions about risk
Behavioral science research can help explain how cognitive biases seeking or averse behavior in politics [48], international relations [49]
influence decision making. For example, the EOs increase the risk of and public support for military intervention [50]. Framing military
decision making by stipulating a LEED score which acts as an anchoring involvement as a protective mediation to avoid geopolitical loss (i.e.
bias for facility managers. Additionally, the sorts of risks facility man- framing to avoid loss) is viewed more favorable by the general public
agers encounter in regards to sustainability are well researched but than a proactive intervention explained as benefiting foreign policy (i.e.
solutions to best correct them are often not provided [5,26–28]. Facility framing to gain) [50].
managers, for example, cannot make energy reduction decisions ap- Framing choices as losses or gains in value is often more influential
propriately if they do not consider long term costs – inadvertent loss in decision making than the resulting end point [30] because even
aversion in facility management which prevents energy savings [29]. when two presentation formats are formally equivalent, each may give
Another example, facility managers have the potential to reduce energy rise to different psychological processes [51]. Decision makers do not
consumption but are often cut out of the conversation resulting in de- immediately know the right choice, but rather perform an informal
cisions that do not maximize utility due to imperfect information reasoning process referred to as preference construction. For example,
(bounded rationality) during design and construction. medical patients given a choice between surgery or radiation preferred
The next section provides a theoretical perspective that is then ap- surgery when described as having a 90% survival rate. However when
plied to energy decision making for facility managers. The premise is the surgery was described as having a 10% mortality rate the preference
that facility managers, like other decision makers, are bounded by ra- for surgery was much lower [52].
tionality and prone to errors during decision making, which leads to The same type of preference construction is likely true for facility
less than optimal (at times irrational) outcomes. managers about energy. Framing effects that over emphasize immediate
rather than long-term savings may lead to sub-optimal decisions. The
next section expands on cognitive biases that prevent rational choice:
3. Utility to prospect theory
loss aversion, endowment effect, choice overload, discounting, status
quo, anchoring, and heuristics in decision making. These cognitive
Utility theory states decision makers select goods or services that
biases are presented because previous research across disciplines, with
meet their highest preferences. However, utility theory is not always
various demographics and scenarios, conclude similar findings. The list
consistent with observed behavior [30]. Decision makers do not always
of cognitive biases based on prior literature also relate to energy deci-
understand the outcome of each choice [31] and therefore, at times,
sions. This list is not comprehensive due to the expansive, and growing,
choose options with less than optimal outcomes [32]. For example,
body of literature about cognitive biases. The review focuses on seminal
providing too much information can overwhelm a decision maker
works that led to advances in behavioral science. The list is meant to
leading to decision paralysis, a cognitive barrier called choice overload
illustrate the vast research opportunity to improve energy related de-
[33–35]. Indeed, reducing the number of choices for a decision maker,
cisions for government facility management.
opposite of what utility theory would recommend, can increase deci-
sion makers’ satisfaction [36]. Cognitive errors like choice overload in
utility theory are numerous because cognitive and environmental bar- 4. Cognitive biases
riers restrict rational choice, known as bounded rationality. These
barriers abound, including lack of information and cognitive processing The following section summarizes how cognitive biases affect
ability [37], and conflicting short term gains with long term benefits people in all fields and professions. There are many cognitive biases,
[38]. The objective of this section is to explain the development from such as extremeness aversion [53], reciprocity [54], alternative over-
utility to prospect theory. load [55], naïve allocations [56], among many others which assist in

3954
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

Table 3
Select cognitive biases.

Cognitive Bias Definition Relevant Literature

Loss Aversion To avoid loss; loss provokes greater degrees of discomfort than a win provides satisfaction. [38,40,62]
Endowment Effect Placing more value on goods or services owned than non-owned. [39,47]
Choice Overload Overwhelming the decision maker with too many choices. [34,41,55]
Discounting the future Evaluation of options based on immediate gain rather than long term gains. [63–65]
Status Quo Bias When overwhelmed or lacking time, the decision maker overly weights previous decisions to inform current decision. [39,78]
Anchoring Bias Rely on previous information (the anchor) to make current decision. [18,80,82]
Heuristics Decision short-cuts when faced with difficult choices (i.e. ‘rule of thumb’). [79,82]

decision making [7]. Table 3 is not extensive but rather based on se- makers can feel dissatisfaction and regret with their choice as a result of
lected biases that appear well defined, occur in overlapping fields with too many original options [36]. Balancing the number of choices with
regularity, and are deemed relevant to facility management. For more decision makers’ preferences can improve not only decisions about food
extensive lists and descriptions of cognitive bias in energy see [53,57], purchases, but more serious decisions such as financial investments
and [58]; about infrastructure see [59], and for other general lists see [55].
[60] and [61]. The objective of this section is to explain how cognitive
bias effect all human decision making. Table 3 lists select cognitive 4.4. Discounting the future
biases and relevant associated literature.
Discounting the future explains why eating healthy foods to prevent
4.1. Loss aversion disease, saving money for retirement, and using energy efficient pro-
ducts are difficult to implement [72]. Delayed benefits are processed as
Losing something of value provokes more discomfort than a gain of losses and accelerated benefits are processed as gains [73].
something equal in value provides satisfaction [66]. Loss aversion is a Discounting the future prevents immediate action on long term
decision maker's tendency to avoid options that would result in loss challenges like climate change [74]. Action to prevent climate change is
(and associated discomfort). Loss aversion is prevalent when situations asymmetric, with high, certain upfront costs and delayed, probabilistic
could result in certain or probable loss. In these scenarios, decision benefits. Future damages of climate change have almost no effect on
makers generally prefer options with certainty not to lose [67]. current decisions [75]. To aid in such decisions about climate change,
To address the consequences of loss aversion when making policy researchers suggest to place both options in the distant future rather
decisions, researchers suggest bundling policies together that involve than only one option. For instance, $100 now or $105 in a year, most
both losses and gains to offset costs while maintaining their net benefits decision makers will choose the immediate option but if the choice is
[68]. Another real world example of loss aversion influencing motiva- between $100 in 20 years or $105 in 21 years the cost of waiting an
tion is teachers given a monetary bonus in advance and asked to give additional year does not seem as great. For climate change, this means
back the bonus if their students did not improve test scores, which led that polices that force future greenhouse gas restrictions are easier to
to a greater increase in scores compared to when teachers were pro- adopt than current restrictions [76].
mised the same bonus but not given the money upfront [69].
4.5. Status quo bias
4.2. Endowment effect
In any decision, there is typically the option to take no action, to
The endowment effect occurs when decision makers over emphasize remain at the current state or unchanged status. Consider the fact that
the value a good or service as compared to the market value [39]. incumbents usually win elections, consumers consistently buy the same
Often, endowment effect is explained by the disparity between the toothpaste brand, or a company maintains a policy using the rationale
willingness to accept (WTA) and willingness to pay (WTP) behaviors ‘that's how it's always been done’ [77]. This is known as status quo bias,
that consumers display. Buyers tend to focus on their sentiment to forgo the fact that decision makers are not likely to override current decisions
the good or service while sellers focus on the benefits of retaining the and are likely to implement past strategies [78].
item. The WTA is generally twice as great as the WTP [70]; although, it In fact, loss aversion can reinforce the status quo bias because the
can be as much as 14 times greater depending on how much attention is risk of loss due to change can be unattractive to the decision maker
drawn to the benefits of possessing the good or service [45]. The [39]. Samuelson and Zeckhauser [78] conducted an experiment by
seminal study on the endowment effect gave a group of students a presenting participants a financial situation, where participants had
coffee cup and another group a candy bar and asked both groups if they inherited a portfolio from a family member. The majority of partici-
would like to trade for a candy bar or coffee cup. In both exercises, pants preferred keeping the status quo investment option over making a
approximately 90% chose to retain their original object, suggesting the change. Similarly, status quo bias may influence government facility
value of the object they owned was greater than that of the object up for management decisions where institutional barriers reinforce previous
trade [47]. choices [79].

4.3. Choice overload 4.6. Anchoring bias

A commonly held belief is that happiness increases with the number Anchoring bias occurs when decision makers choose options based
of choices available, which is true in some scenarios (i.e. having more on previously established standards, despite its significance [80,81].
than one car option to purchase, or more than one college to attend). Anchoring bias is prevalent in estimation tasks, even if people are given
More options present more opportunities for the consumer's needs to be arbitrary anchors. In one example, a number wheel 0–100) was rigged
met, but too many options can create a cognitive burden for the deci- to select either 10 or 65. When the wheel was spun, participants were
sion maker because each option must be considered [71]. A familiar asked to estimate the number of African countries in the United Nations
example is a restaurant menu with too many dinner options. Reviewing by moving upward or downward from the number selected by the
all of the options requires more time to make a decision. Decision wheel. For groups that landed on 10, their estimate was about 40% less

3955
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

than the group given the anchor of 65 [82]. Similarly, random anchors missing features. Meanwhile, car buyers first shown the base model
can affect engineering decisions about energy in buildings. Simply an- perceive those same features as add-ons [96]. Providing an endorse-
choring decision makers to a random but high number led to an in- ment means decision makers perceive the default as the recommended
crease in perceived achievement in LEED rating system from building option because it is the most commonly chosen or fits within the social
professionals [83], demonstrating that their estimations can be greatly norm [97,98]. Organ donation rates are twice as high when the default
skewed [84]. option is to be a donor (opt-out) compared to non-donor default, likely
because the default endorses a social norm [93]. Effort references the
4.7. Heuristics cognitive energy exerted to make a decision. Sweden implemented a
default social security savings program and after 4 years 92% of people
Heuristics are shortcuts that decisions makers can take when pre- in the program were using the newly created default plan and saving
sented with complex choices. These are often described as “rules of more money than managing their funds on their own. The default op-
thumb,” decisions based on experience [85], and intuition [86,87]. tion reduced the effort required to pick a program, and likely also
Heuristics are categorized by representative and availability mental provided an endorsement [55].
models. Stereotypes are an example of representative mental model
[88] and past experiences are an example of the availability model 5.2. Framing
[89–91]. Errors in decision making occur when either model does not
align with reality. For example, assuming a business venture will fail, Framing is presenting the same information but in a positive, ne-
simply because other similar businesses have failed is a symptom of gative, or neutral tone. There are two types of framing: attribute and
availability heuristics, which can lead to quick judgments and wrong goal framing [99–101]. The difference between attribute and goal
decisions [89]. Smart structuring of decision environments can better framing is the object being highlighted. In attribute framing, the frame
anticipate when heuristics, or other cognitive biases, are likely to be is focusing on the characteristic of an option or choice. The example
used and help correct for them if needed. The next section explains one presented earlier about describing the success rate of surgery as positive
approach to account and correct for these cognitive biases. (90% survival rate) or negative (10% mortality rate) is an example of
attribute framing. Attribute framing is usually more effective when
5. Accounting for cognitive biases in decision making framed positive [102]. Goal framing relates behavior to obtaining the
goal [103]. For example, framed positive, “If you get a mammogram,
Choice architecture is a method used to account for cognitive biases you take advantage of the best method for early detection of breast
and improve decision making. The principle of choice architecture is cancer” compared to a negative frame, “If you do not get a mammo-
that decisions can be structured to focus decision-makers on the in- gram, you fail to take advantage of the best method for early detection
formation that matters most. For example, when presented with miles of breast cancer.” Surprisingly, attribute framing is most effective with
per gallon (mpg) metric, consumers wrongly assume that increases in a positive frame whereas goal framing is most effective as a negative
mpg have a linear effect in fuel use and CO2 emissions, suggesting that frame [100].
an increase from 10 to 20 mpg has the same benefit as going from 40 to
50 mpg. However, this is not true. The shift from 10 to 20 mpg reduces 5.3. Reducing choices
fuel use by 50%, whereas from 40 to 50 mpg, fuel use is reduced by only
20%. Restructuring the information as a linear metric, such as gallons Reducing the number of choices a decision maker must consider is
per mile, improves decision makers ability to pick the most efficient an effective method to mitigate choice overload. Some states offer se-
option [92]. Similar choice architecture, that more closely aligns de- niors over 100 choices of Medicare drug plans, which can be over-
cision structures with psychological processes, is improving fields from whelming. Removing options can increase the number of Medicare
medicine [93] to finance [56], to insurance [94]. patients willing to make a decision and improve the outcome [104].
The objective is to illustrate the possible advances to reduce energy There is not a clear and concise recommendation for the correct number
consumption in government facilities by connecting choice architecture of options for different decisions but the general rule is to include en-
literature to decision making for facility management in the govern- ough options that preserve the decision maker's values [60].
ment. The choice architecture approaches, listed in Table 4, are those
that appear relevant to facility management. These approaches were 5.4. Labeling
chosen because of the breadth of results from different fields with
overlapping results. By no measure, is this list exhaustive, for more Labels provide a visual or graphical method for evaluation that is
information see [60]. often beneficial when decision makers must otherwise process large
amounts of numerical information [105]. Decision-makers can consider
5.1. Defaults more options when numbers are broken into categories, such as grades,
or if they have endpoints labeled as poor or excellent. Labels also de-
Defaults influence decision making in three ways: creating a re- crease the time of information processing by allowing effective re-
ference point, providing an endorsement, and reducing effort to make a sponses to be accessed more quickly [60]. Newell and Siikmaki [106]
decision [95]. Creating a reference point frames other outcomes as a applied these techniques to increase consumer purchases of energy ef-
loss or gain and this framing impacts the decision [95]. Car buyers first ficient household appliances. By modifying the appliance labels, they
shown the “fully loaded” package perceive lesser models as having were able to nudge consumers towards energy efficient product options.

Table 4
Select choice architecture that appear relevant to decision making in facility management.

Choice Architecture Example Relevant Literature

Defaults Automatic choices, such as automatic 401k enrollment for new employees. [34,55,60,61,93,150]
Framing Presentation of information, such as saying yogurt is 20% fat free versus 80% fat. [148,149,151]
Reducing Choices Narrowing options, such as giving seniors 3 Medicare options instead of hundreds. [34,60,71]
Labeling Using visual aids to make information easier to process, such as ENERGYSTAR labels on appliances. [34,60,105]

3956
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

Similar approaches are used to influence diet choices [61], car choices Likewise, anchoring bias can surface during the design process for
[41], and other forms of energy use [58]. For buildings, rating systems buildings. Professionals who help set energy performance goals for U.S.
like LEED and Energy Star provide labels or categories such as Certified buildings were shown a series of questions helping them set either a
or Platinum. These labels can drive the decision process during design 90% energy reduction goal or set one for 30% energy reduction goals.
and construction [107–109]. Participants exposed to the 90% anchor afterwards set higher energy
Defaults, framing, reducing options, and labeling are examples of performance goals than respondents exposed to the 30% anchor [18].
passive interventions to the decision making process [110]. Active in- This is important because attainable goals may actually empower, or
terventions refer to mandates and policies as described in the previous anchor, lower achievement. One method to help overcome low
section about government facility management. Both passive and active achievement are role model projects that exemplify high levels of sus-
choice interventions can help overcome bounded rationality when tainability. Engineering professionals presented with an example which
making “upstream” decisions about civil infrastructure systems and scored high sustainability ratings set 34% higher goals for their own
energy use in buildings that require active tradeoffs with multiple projects than those not presented with an example project [119].
variables and uncertain consequences. The next section summarizes Anchoring bias and status quo bias may be a result of heuristics to
recent advances connecting design engineering to behavioral science. reduce complexity of decision making during engineering design and
construction delivery. An observed heuristic is the default-design
6. Cognitive biases in civil infrastructure systems and building heuristic, a shared set of standards and practices that dictate a “good”
energy decision making building design. Default design can lead architects to repeatedly use
templates, i.e. commercial buildings that are rectangular with wind-
Previous research in cognitive biases that influence civil infra- owed, executive offices around the perimeter [79]. Related is the value-
structure systems and building energy related decision making, are added heuristic, which means that designers may short-cut decisions to
included as part of the conceptual merging of behavioral science and maximize the function and flexibility of the building (so that future
facility management. The objective of this section is to outline the owners can make use of it) over performance and profit. Another is a
specific cognitive bias that are prevalent in engineering and building shared rule of thumb to maximize investment potential by designing the
energy decision making. Only studies about decision making in these safest and most attractive investment option for owners [120]. These
fields, grounded in behavioral science also relevant to industry are heuristics reduce coordination time, help maintain order among prac-
presented. This includes papers on energy efficiency, choice archi- titioners, and are reinforced by social accountability. However, these
tecture, and cognitive bias. To begin, cognitive bias of loss aversion, heuristics can become harmful when they are not shared by the client or
status quo bias, anchoring and heuristics in decision making about project delivery team and can lead to wrong assumptions without
energy and infrastructure are discussed. proper communication and conscious consideration for how these as-
In the same way loss aversion may influence gambling decisions, sumptions influence project delivery [121]. During judgment about
loss aversion effects engineering decision making about infrastructure. risks in the design process, labeling options with additional colors and
Simply re-framing points in rating systems for sustainability as a loss in symbols lead decision makers away from riskier, more uncertain op-
achievement rather than a gain in achievement significantly improved tions, towards options with greater certainty and less risk [122]
engineers’ consideration for sustainability. Engineers endowed points in Building owners and occupants are also influenced by cognitive
the Envision Rating System [111], set a 15% higher goal for energy and biases and heuristics. Information about energy efficiency is often
water reduction than when no points were endowed [112]. Such an presented in kilowatt hours, a unit that means little to the utility cus-
increase could drastically effect possible outcomes. For example, if tomer [123]. In fact, even those knowledgeable of sophisticated energy
endowed points for rating systems was applied to all U.S. infrastructure, equations did not use said methods, instead used simple monetary
a 15% reduction in just of Envision credits related to greenhouse gas conversions considering pay back periods [123]. Companies like
emissions would result in a reduction of over 2 billion tons of CO2 Opower help customers realize their energy consumption by providing
[113]. Of course, infrastructure decisions are subject to varying con- a benchmark to their neighbors [124]. By reframing the message from
straints, goals, and resources with different stakeholder schedules, kilowatt hours to their neighbors energy use, Opower provided social
agendas, mandates, and budget cycles. A limitation of this previous pressure for change leading to over 6 billion kWh of electricity saved,
work is looking at individual decision making behavior when en- equal to $700 million in cost savings [125].
gineering decisions are frequently made in groups. A similar study, Social pressure through comparison, however, may not always be
using the Envision Rating System, investigated the effect of choice ar- the correct intervention. Wilson and Dowlatabadi [126] caution that
chitecture on engineering group decision making and found parallel great care must be taken when deciding what kind of intervention to
results to individual decision making [114]. In another approach, op- use and that the intervention must address either the psychological or
timization experiments comparing traditional approaches of max- economic driver behind the behavior to effectively reduce energy
imizing gain compared to maximizing loss reduction in infrastructure consumption. The specific behavior (i.e. choice overload, loss aversion,
asset management found that incorporating perceptions of loss leads to heuristics) must align with the appropriate intervention (i.e. policy,
better justification of the decisions made and can better account for the framing, default) to influence behavior change.
varying preferences of stakeholders [115]. Both studies, those about the A summarized list of cognitive biases and choice architecture in-
Envision Rating System and loss aversion in infrastructure asset man- terventions to engineering and building energy decision making are
agement align with previous research in behavioral science that sug- provided in Table 5. This list is by no means exhaustive of the methods
gests experts are just as likely to be influenced by choice architecture to reduce cognitive biases to improve consideration for energy effi-
interventions as novices are [116,117]. ciencies. The list focuses solely on “upstream” decisions during design,
Restructuring the decision environment can also reduce the effects where decision makers appear susceptible to the same cognitive biases
of cognitive biases during contract structuring for infrastructure de- that influence “downstream” consumers’ decision making and inter-
velopment. Status quo bias led to underestimating the project costs and ventions using choice architecture help overcome these biases. For
overestimating financial returns on investment for a capital project more see [57,126,127]. Related to households, potential options exist
between the Dutch Highway and Waterways Agency and a Dutch using heuristics, status quo bias, and satisficing to reduce energy use, as
contractor. Redirecting biases towards improved performance instead well [8] (Table 5).
of the price of managerial intervention helped remove the status quo Interventions that target facility managers may have a similar and
bias which led to more realistic expectations and more opportunities for complementary effect as interventions that focus on building occupants
financial gains [118]. and infrastructure and building designers to help reduce energy

3957
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

Table 5
Select cognitive bias and choice architecture approach to improve engineering and building decision making.

Cognitive bias Choice Arch. Outcome Experimental Design

Loss aversion Framing Minimizing users’ loss in a fund allocation strategy is preferred to maximizing the performance Optimization experiments; life cycle cost
gain from a limited rehabilitation budget [115]. analysis.
Endowment Effect Defaults Endowing users with points increased engineers goals for sustainability by 15% [128]. Lab experiment with working engineers.
Anchoring bias Priming Attainable goals may anchor lower achievement. Priming to think about a higher number Lab experiment with building designers.
increased willingness for high sustainability achievement [129].
Status quo bias Framing Redirecting towards improved performance instead of the price of managerial intervention led Case study with Dutch firm.
to more realistic expectations [130].
Design heuristic Labeling Labeling a trade-off matrix with colors and symbols lead decision makers away from riskier, Lab experiment with students.
more uncertain options [122].

consumption. The next section proposes new opportunities to employ 7.2. Framing energy efficiency
choice architecture in facility management.
Framing effects can help make energy efficiency decisions more
7. Opportunity for choice architecture in facility management favorable to the decision maker. The Federal Energy Management
Program's (FEMP) Buy Energy-Efficient Products guide is designed to
The purpose of this section is to illustrate the many opportunities for support federal buyers in the purchase of energy and water efficient
choice architecture that complement command control and market products [134]. Before a facility manager makes a purchase, they can
based approaches to reduce energy in government facilities. Ultimately check the FEMP guide, which also provides an energy and cost calcu-
the objective is to make similar advances in government facility man- lator. However, the facility manager must willingly check the FEMP
agement through choice architecture as seen in retirement savings guide, which adds an elective burden to the decision making process.
[131], vehicle emissions [92], and others [61]. Given the opportunities Rather than expecting the facility manager to check the guide before
for choice architecture, the examples below are meant to provoke making a selection, defaults and framing can be used to encourage the
consideration for more research, to encourage choice architecture ap- decision maker by including a question in the procurement form asking
proaches that accelerate energy reduction in government facility if the product meets FEMP standards. Another approach is to ask facility
management decisions. managers to list the return on investment using the FEMP calculator,
forcing the cognitive effort rather than leaving the decision maker with
an elective burden. Including these elements and others mentioned in
7.1. Reducing procurement choices to energy efficient products [135] which examine cost-reflection strategies may help shift the em-
phasis from short term savings to long term savings both in energy and
The procurement process for government facility managers is financial cost.
complex due to executive orders and institutional barriers that over Taking the idea of asking for return on investment further, re-
emphasize upfront cost against long term savings [132]. What is more, structuring the procurement form by requiring first calculating energy
the number of options to consider, emergency situations to handle, use before making a product decision may reduce myopia during the
varying priorities, and lack of personnel make decision making for decision making process. As in other fields, like finance [136], re-
government facilities more challenging [12]. These types of barriers stricting choices lead to more decision making in the clients’ own long
align with behavioral science literature as choice overload (too much term best interest. Similarly, facility managers who receive new in-
information or choices to process), status quo bias and heuristics (re- formation by requiring a payback period calculation may become more
lying on previous information or choices to make decisions), risk aware of the overwhelming difference between the cheapest option and
aversion (varying priorities to account for certainty), and loss aversion the option that maximized energy savings.
(due to lack of funds). This often leads facility managers to make de-
cisions that are not the most sustainable [26]. In fact, these cognitive
barriers may deter decision makers away from investing in energy 7.3. Benchmarks and feedback loops that expand bounded rationality
saving measures due to the time and effort to generate alternative op-
tions and lack of certain in the outcomes. Choice architecture can help By introducing feedback loops and benchmarks, the decision maker
design better choice environments via reducing choices or using de- is assisted in making decisions when they do not have all of the ne-
faults holds potential to better assist facility managers. cessary time and information to make the utility maximizing decision.
A successful example of utilizing defaults to assist in energy effi- A naval base in San Diego reduced their energy consumption through
ciency is the Department of Energy Waste Isolation Pilot Plant (WIPP). an energy feedback program centered on gathering energy information
Reports showed that only 16% of WIPP purchases were “green pro- and distributing that information monthly. Energy cost and consump-
ducts,” indicating that the WIPP purchase program did not assist facility tion of the current month was compared to the same month in the prior
managers in making sustainable decisions. Managers had to select a year and displayed in relation to year-to-date data. The reports were
product first to learn if the product was environmentally or sustainably emailed to over 40 ships and departments [137]. The feedback ap-
better than other products, which hindered sustainable purchase. In proach created a benchmark that helped to better assess energy re-
response to E.O. 13514, (the goal to reduce GHG emissions by 2020 to a duction. This feedback approach works similar to homeowners taking
certain benchmark) the WIPP modified their procurement system to part in Opower's program, providing a comparison of energy use to
allow querying capabilities to better track progress, and added a field to their neighbors [123]. Although the difference is who is being targeted
indicate products with green alternatives (among other measures) for the intervention. While Opower's focus is customers’, the benchmark
[133]. The new field allowed decision makers to query just green and being suggested here is for facility managers. Shifting the focus from
energy efficient products, which reduced the number of options and the “downstream” consumers to “upstream” facility managers may have an
cognitive burden to make a decision. To go further, the WIPP pro- even greater effect in achieving energy reduction.
curement systems could add energy efficient default options for pro-
ducts ordered most frequently, further promoting decisions that lead to
energy savings.

3958
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

7.4. Default HVAC temperatures Thaler and Knetsch wrote that “…models that ignore loss aversion
predict more symmetry and reversibility than are observed in the
Defaults need to make sense in the physical and workplace contexts world, ignoring potentially large differences in the magnitude of re-
in which they are used; a single default setting may be inappropriate for sponses to gains and to losses” [39]. Facility mangers control lighting,
an entire building or organization. For example, the same temperature ventilation, air temperature and equipment maintenance. Not ac-
setting may result in different levels of comfort on north versus south counting for the decision variables of facility managers may contribute
facing sides of buildings or in workspaces where occupants are seden- to the variance in modeled energy consumption and actual energy
tary versus active. Facility managers could widen the temperature consumed in buildings [5]. This is an area of research needed to bridge
range and give occupants control. Occupant control and varying default facility decisions with energy modeling.
energy settings across building zones leads to overall lower energy Energy policy and products receive the most attention, despite the
demand, higher staff satisfaction, and ease of operation [138]. The U.S. fact that most life cycle costs for a building occur during the operations
Postal Service enacted a similar default change by making the off po- and maintenance phase. Despite such influence over building perfor-
sition the default setting for their mechanical heating and cooling sys- mance, facility managers often do not optimize potential energy savings
tems in unused indoor spaces, saving nearly $41 million [139]. because they are not informed of management goals and often make
Building automation systems provide another opportunity to update decisions without consideration of long term life cycle costs. Ultimately,
default settings [140,141]. Building automation systems are an inter- aligning decision environments with behavioral science and using
face to control HVAC temperature set points and occupancy schedules choice architecture while placing greater emphasis on energy efficiency
[142]. In case studies about a mosque [140] and a school [143], can contribute to meeting future energy reduction goals.
changing the preset defaults to better align with building use reduced
energy consumption on average by 30%. While much research on be- References
havior change for energy savings is focused around the occupant [144],
changing defaults within building automation system is intended for [1] EIA. Comprehensive annual energy data and sustainability performance. U.S.
the facility manager. Again, the difference is who the default is in- Department of Energy; 2014.
[2] Rahall N, Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007 (2007 - H.R. 6); 2007.
tended to help. Better informing facility manager decisions requires [3] Menassa CC. Evaluating sustainable retrofits in existing buildings under un-
reaching far less people compared to the occupants in the building. certainty. Energy Build 2011;43(12):3576–83.
[4] Wu HJ, Yuan ZW, Zhang L. Life cycle energy consumption and CO2 emission of an
office building in China. Int J Life Cycle Assess 2012;17.
8. Conclusion [5] Hodges Christopher. A facility manager's approach to sustainability. J Facil Manag
2005;3(4):312–24.
The government currently uses policy and mandates to improve [6] Howard TJ, Culley SJ, Dekoninck E. Describing the creative design process by the
integration of engineering design and cognitive psychology literature. Des Stud
energy efficiency in facilities, with relatively little implementation of 2008;29(2):160–80.
behavioral science research [61,110]. Opportunities exist for govern- [7] Kunreuther H, Weber EU. Aiding decision making to reduce the impacts of climate
ment agencies to adopt choice architecture as a method to encourage change. J Consum Policy 2014;37(3):397–411.
[8] Frederiks ER, Stenner K, Hobman EV. Household energy use: applying behavioural
and meet energy reduction goals. Increased awareness of cognitive
economics to understand consumer decision-making and behaviour. Renew
biases, plus the implementation of choice architecture, is leading to Sustain Energy Rev 2015;41:1385–94.
advances in engineering for sustainability [112], and energy reduction [9] Jaffe AB, Newell RG, Stavins RN. Environmental policy and technological change.
in residential buildings [58]. Similar research is needed to merge be- Environ Resour Econ 2002;22(1):41–70.
[10] Executive Order (EO) 13423; 2007.
havioral science to facility management to help reduce energy con- [11] Executive Order (EO) 13693 – Planning for Federal Sustainability in the Next
sumption in buildings. Decade; 2015.
The decision making process for government facility managers is [12] Alford S, FY 2014 USCG Operational Sustainability Performance Plan, USCG,
Office of Energy Management, 2015.
complex and often encourages immediate savings over long term sav- [13] Hassett KA, Metcalf GE. Energy tax credits and residential conservation invest-
ings. Provided for discussion are potential cognitive biases such as ment: evidence from panel data. J Public Econ 1995;57(2):201–17.
status quo bias, anchoring, and loss aversion that prevent facility [14] Blumberg D. LEED in the U.S. commercial office market: market effects and the
emergence of LEED for existing buildings. J Sustain Real Estate 2012;4(1):23–47.
managers from making choices that result in energy reduction. Use of [15] Dermisi S. Effect of LEED ratings and levels on office property assessed and market
framing effects, role models, defaults, and labels can help reduce cog- values. J Sustain Real Estate 2009;1(1):23–47.
nitive barriers. For example, endowing design engineers with sustain- [16] LEED Building Information. [Online]. Available: 〈http://www.gsa.gov/portal/
category/25999〉. [Accessed 08-Jul-2016].
ability points on a rating system like Envision frames the decisions [17] Menassa C, Mangasarian S, El Asmar M, Kirar C. Energy consumption evaluation of
about energy and water reduction as a loss in points instead of a gain in US Navy LEED-certified buildings. J Perform Constr Facil 2011;26(1):46–53.
points towards certification. Role model projects can illustrate feasi- [18] Klotz L, Mack D, Klapthor B, Tunstall C, Harrison J. Unintended anchors: building
rating systems and energy performance goals for US buildings. Energy Policy
bility of high achievement, which can encourage engineers to consider
2010;38(7):3557–66.
similar methods toward energy and water reduction. Rewording con- [19] Scofield JH. Do LEED-certified buildings save energy? Not really…. Energy Build
tract structures can help remove status quo bias leading to more ac- 2009;41(12):1386–90.
curate estimation of project costs. [20] Scofield JH. Efficacy of LEED-certification in reducing energy consumption and
greenhouse gas emission for large New York City office buildings. Energy Build
Examples of similar choice architecture that could be expanded in 2013;67:517–24.
the government applications were provided. For example, reducing [21] Chandrashekaran A, Gopalakrishnan B. Maintenance risk reduction for effective
procurement choices by allowing facility mangers to query green or facilities management. J Facil Manag 2008;6(1):52–68.
[22] United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), Buildings can play key role in
efficient products in one Department of Energy facility helped reduce combating climate change, UNEP News Centre; 2007.
the cognitive burden of decision making and led to more energy effi- [23] Energy Policy Act of 2005, vol. 594; 2005.
cient purchases. Another, is requiring facility managers to check certain [24] Energy Policy Act of 1992; 1992.
[25] Khalil N, Husin HN, Mahat N, Nasir N. Sustainable environment: issues and so-
product guides or use pay back period calculators prior to selecting a lutions from the perspective of facility managers. Procedia Eng 2011;20:458–65.
product. This approach accounts for loss aversion, the endowment ef- [26] Jackson J. Promoting energy efficiency investments with risk management deci-
fect, and cognitive limitations of the decision maker, forcing the use of a sion tools. Energy Policy 2010;38(8):3865–73.
[27] de Zwart A. Is innovation possible, or even imperative, for facility management?
decision tool before making a purchase. Facilities 1995;13(13):6–16.
While this review aims to increase consideration for energy reduc- [28] Khalil N, Husin HN, Mahat N, Nasir N. Sustainable environment: issues and so-
tion during decision making for facility management, there are also lutions from the perspective of facility managers. Procedia Eng 2011;20:458–65.
[29] Hodges CP. A facility manager's approach to sustainability. J Facil Manag
opportunities within choice architecture to improve energy prediction
2005;3(4):312–24.
models for buildings. In a 1991 study of loss aversion, Kahneman,

3959
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

[30] Kahneman D, Tversky A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. J Exp Psychol Gen 2009;138(3):329–40.
Econom Pre-1986 1979;47(2):263–91. [74] Messner D, Weinlich S. Global cooperation and the human factor in international
[31] Simon HA, Models of man; social and rational; 1957. relations. Routledge; 2015.
[32] Friedman L. Bounded rationality versus standard utility-maximization: a test of [75] Karp L. Global warming and hyperbolic discounting. J Public Econ
energy price responsiveness. Judgm Decis Public Policy 2002:138–73. 2005;89(2–3):261–82.
[33] Iyengar SS, Lepper MR. When choice is demotivating: can one desire too much of a [76] Karp L, Tsur Y. Time perspective and climate change policy. J Environ Econ Manag
good thing? J Pers Soc Psychol 2000;79(6):995. 2011;62(1):1–14.
[34] Johnson E, et al. Beyond nudges: tools of a choice architecture. Mark Lett [77] Eidelman S, Crandall CS. Bias in favor of the status quo. Soc Personal Psychol
2012;23(2):487–504. Compass 2012;6(3):270–81.
[35] Madrian BC, Shea DF. The power of suggestion: inertia in 401 (k) participation and [78] Samuelson W, Zeckhauser R. Status quo bias in decision making. J Risk Uncertain
savings behavior. National bureau of economic research; 2000. 1988;1(1):7–59.
[36] Iyengar SS, Lepper MR. When choice is demotivating: can one desire too much of a [79] Beamish TD, Biggart NW. The role of social heuristics in project-centred produc-
good thing? J Pers Soc Psychol 2000;79(6):995–1006. tion networks: insights from the commercial construction industry. Eng Proj Organ
[37] Simon HA. A behavioral model of rational choice. Q J Econ 1955;69(1):99–118. J 2012;2(1–2):57–70.
[38] Benartzi S, Thaler RH. Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle [80] Jacowitz KE, Kahneman D. Measures of anchoring in estimation tasks. Pers Soc
[Working Paper 4369]. National Bureau of Economic Research; 1993. Psychol Bull 1995;21(11):1161.
[39] Kahneman D, Knetsch JL, Thaler RH. Anomalies: the endowment effect, loss [81] Strack F, Martin L, Schwarz N. Priming and communication: social determinants of
aversion, and status quo bias. J Econ Perspect 1991:193–206. information use in judgments of life satisfaction. Eur J Soc Psychol
[40] Kahneman D, Tversky A. Choices, values, and frames. Am Psychol 1988;18(5):429–42.
1984;39(4):341–50. [82] Tversky A, Kahneman D. Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. sci-
[41] Schwartz B. Self-determination: the tyranny of freedom. Am Psychol ence 1974;185(4157):1124–31.
2000;55(1):79. [83] Klotz L, Mack D, Klapthor B, Tunstall C, Harrison J. Unintended anchors: building
[42] Tversky A, Kahneman D. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. rating systems and energy performance goals for U.S. buildings. Energy Policy
Science 1981;211(4481):453–8. 2010;38(7):3557–66.
[43] Genesove D, Mayer C. Loss aversion and seller behavior: evidence from the [84] Jacowitz KE, Kahneman D. Measures of anchoring in estimation tasks. Pers Soc
housing market. Q J Econ 2001;116(4):1233–60. Psychol Bull 1995;21:1161–6.
[44] Odean T. Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? J Financ [85] Gigerenzer G. Gut feelings: the intelligence of the unconscious. Penguin; 2007.
1998;53(5):1775–98. [86] Dijksterhuis A. Think different: the merits of unconscious thought in preference
[45] Carmon Z, Ariely D. Focusing on the forgone: how value can appear so different to development and decision making. J Pers Soc Psychol 2004;87(5):586–98.
buyers and sellers. J Consum Res 2000;27(3):360–70. [87] Newell BR, Shanks DR. Unconscious influences on decision making: a critical re-
[46] Cummings RG, Brookshire DS, Bishop RC, Arrow KJ. Valuing environmental view. Behav Brain Sci 2014;37(1):1–19.
goods: an assessment of the contingent valuation method. Rowman & Littlefield [88] Gilovich T, Savitsky K. Like goes with like: the role of representativeness in er-
Pub Incorporated; 1986. roneous and pseudo-scientific beliefs. In: Gilovich T, Griffin D, Kahneman D,
[47] Knetsch JL. The endowment effect and evidence of nonreversible indifference editors. Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. New York,
curves. Am Econ Rev 1989;79(5):1277–84. NY, US: Cambridge University Press; 2002. p. 617–24.
[48] Patty JW. Loss aversion, presidential responsibility, and midterm congressional [89] Gilovich T, Griffin D, Kahneman D. Heuristics and biases: the psychology of in-
elections. Elect Stud 2006;25(2):227–47. tuitive judgment. Cambridge University Press; 2002.
[49] Berejikian JD. Model building with prospect theory: a cognitive approach to in- [90] Schwarz N, Bless H, Strack F, Klumpp G, Rittenauer-Schatka H, Simons A. Ease of
ternational relations. Polit Psychol 2002;23(4):759–86. retrieval as information: another look at the availability heuristic. J Pers Soc
[50] Nincic M. Loss aversion and the domestic context of military intervention. Polit Psychol 1991;61(2):195–202.
Res Q 1997;50(1):97–120. [91] Yilmaz S, Daly SR, Seifert CM, Gonzalez R. How do designers generate new ideas?
[51] Thaler RH, Sunstein CR, Balz JP. Choice architecture [SSRN Scholarly Paper ID Design heuristics across two disciplines Des. Sci 2015;1.
1583509]. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network; 2010. [92] Larrick RP, Soll JB. The MPG illusion. Science 2008;320(5883).
[52] McNeil BJ, Pauker SG, Sox Jr HC, Tversky A. On the elicitation of preferences for [93] Johnson EJ, Goldstein D. Do defaults save lives? Science 2003;302(5649):1338–9.
alternative therapies. N Engl J Med 1982;306(21):1259–62. [94] Johnson EJ. Framing, probability distortions, and Insurance decisions. J Risk
[53] Houde S, Todd A. List of behavioral economics principles that can inform energy Uncertain 1993;7(1):35–51.
policy. Work Prog Preco Energy Effic Cent Stanf Univ 2010;2:17. [95] Dinner IM, Johnson EJ, Goldstein DG, Liu K. Partitioning default effects: why
[54] Gneezy U, Niederle M, Rustichini A, et al. Performance in competitive environ- people choose not to choose [SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 1352488]. Rochester, NY:
ments: Gender differences. Q J Econ -Camb Mass 2003;118(3):1049–74. Social Science Research Network; 2010.
[55] Cronqvist H, Thaler RH. Design choices in privatized social-security systems: [96] Park CW, Jun SY, MacInnis DJ. Choosing what I want versus rejecting what I do
learning from the Swedish experience. Am Econ Rev 2004:424–8. not want: an application of decision framing to product option choice decisions. J
[56] Fox CR, Langer T. Biases in allocation under risk and uncertainty: partition de- Mark Res 2000;37(2):187–202.
pendence, unit dependence, and procedure dependence. Unit Depend Proced [97] Brown CL, Krishna A. The skeptical shopper: a metacognitive account for the ef-
Depend 2005;10 2005. fects of default options on choice. J Consum Res 2004;31(3):529–39.
[57] Gillingham K, Newell RG, Palmer K. Energy efficiency economics and policy. [98] McKenzie CRM, Liersch MJ, Finkelstein SR. Recommendations implicit in policy
National Bureau of Economic Research; 2009. defaults. Psychol Sci 2006;17(5):414–20.
[58] Wilson C, Dowlatabadi H. Models of decision making and residential energy use. [99] Heath C, Larrick RP, Wu G. Goals as reference points. Cogn Psychol
Annu Rev Environ Resour 2007;32:169–203. 1999;38(1):79–109.
[59] Shealy T, Klotz LE. Encouraging elegant solutions by applying choice architecture [100] Krishnamurthy P, Carter P, Blair E. Attribute framing and goal framing effects in
to infrastructure project delivery. Constr Glob Netw 2014. health decisions. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 2001;85(2):382–99.
[60] Johnson E, et al. Beyond nudges: tools of a choice architecture. Mark Lett [101] Levin IP, Schneider SL, Gaeth GJ. All frames are not created equal: a typology and
2012;23(2):487–504. critical analysis of framing effects. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process
[61] Sunstein CR, Simpler: the future of government; 2013. 1998;76(2):149–88.
[62] McGraw AP, Larsen JT, Kahneman D, Schkade D. Comparing gains and losses. [102] Levin IP, Gaeth GJ. How consumers are affected by the framing of attribute in-
Psychol Sci 2010;21(10):1438–45. formation before and after consuming the product. J Consum Res 1988:374–8.
[63] Shamosh NA, Gray JR. Delay discounting and intelligence: a meta-analysis. [103] Heath C, Larrick RP, Wu G. Goals as reference points. Cogn Psychol
Intelligence 2008;36(4):289–305. 1999;38(1):79–109.
[64] Shiv B, Loewenstein G, Bechara A, Damasio H, Damasio AR. Investment behavior [104] Kling JR, Mullainathan S, Shafir E, Vermeulen L, Wrobel MV. Misperception in
and the negative side of emotion. Psychol Sci 2005;16:435–9. choosing medicare drug plans. Unpubl Manuscr 2008.
[65] Weber EU. Experience-based and description-based perceptions of long-term risk: [105] Peters E, Dieckmann NF, Västfjäll D, Slovic CK, P, Hibbard JH. Bringing meaning
why global warming does not Scare us (yet). Clim Change 2006;77(1–2):103–20. to numbers: the impact of evaluative categories on decisions. J Exp Psychol Appl
[66] Tversky A, Kahneman D. Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference-dependent 2009;15(3):213–27.
model. Q J Econ 1991:1039–61. [106] Newell RG, Siikamäki JV. Nudging energy efficiency behavior: the role of in-
[67] Kahneman D, Tversky A. Choices, values, and frames. Am Psychol 1984;39(4):341. formation labels [Working Paper 19224]. National Bureau of Economic Research;
[68] Milkman KL, Mazza MC, Shu LL, Tsay C-J, Bazerman MH. Policy bundling to 2013.
overcome loss aversion: a method for improving legislative outcomes. Organ [107] Corbett CJ, Muthulingam S. Adoption of voluntary environmental standards: the
Behav Hum Decis Process 2012;117(1):158–67. role of signaling and intrinsic benefits in the diffusion of the leed green building
[69] Roland J, Fryer G, Levitt SD, List J, Sadoff S. Enhancing the efficacy of teacher standards [SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 1009294]. Rochester, NY: Social Science
incentives through loss aversion: a field experiment [Working Paper 18237]. Research Network; 2007.
National Bureau of Economic Research; 2012. [108] Leland SM, Read DC, Wittry M. Analyzing the perceived benefits of LEED-certified
[70] Kahneman D, Knetsch JL, Thaler RH. Experimental tests of the endowment effect and energy star–certified buildings in the realm of local economic development
and the coase theorem. J Polit Econ 1990;98(6):1325–48. [891242415587526]. Econ Dev Q2015. [891242415587526].
[71] Schwartz B. The paradox of choice: why more is less; 2004. [109] Matisoff D, Noonan DS, Flowers M. Competition and Green Signaling: the Case of
[72] Weber L. Some reflections on barriers to the efficient use of energy. Energy Policy LEED. Acad Manag Proc 2015;2015(1):15717.
1997;25(10):833–5. [110] Thaler RH, Sunstein C. Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and
[73] Hardisty DJ, Weber EU. Discounting future green: money versus the environment. happiness. Yale University Press; 2008.

3960
L. Delgado, T. Shealy Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 82 (2018) 3952–3961

[111] Envision™ Sustainable Infrastructure Rating System, Institute for Sustainable [132] Jackson J. Energy budgets at risk (EBaR): a risk management approach to energy
Infrastructure, 2012. [Online]. Available: 〈http://www.sustainableinfrastructure. purchase and efficiency choices. John Wiley & Sons; 2008.
org/rating/index.cfm〉. [Accessed 05 May 2013]. [133] Dion J, Enabling Sustainable acquisition by improving procurement systems,
[112] Shealy T, Klotz L, Weber EU, Johnson EJ, Bell RG. Using framing effects to inform Department of Energy, EE-0756; 2012.
more sustainable infrastructure design decisions. J Constr Eng Manag [134] Bunch S, Buy energy-efficient products, Department of Energy, DOE/GO-102016-
2016;0(0):4016037. 104880; 2016.
[113] Shealy T, Klotz L. Well-endowed rating systems: how modified defaults can lead to [135] Hobman EV, Frederiks ER, Stenner K, Meikle S. Uptake and usage of cost-reflective
more sustainable performance. J Constr Eng Manag 2015;141(10):4015031. electricity pricing: insights from psychology and behavioural economics. Renew
[114] Shealy T, Klotz L, Weber E, Johnson, E, Bell R, Harris N, Alleviating biases in Sustain Energy Rev 2016;57:455–67.
infrastructure decisions for sustainability: a summary of five experiments and a [136] Thaler RH, Benartzi S. Save More Tomorrow™: using Behavioral Economics to
call to action for the engineering project management research community, pre- Increase Employee Saving. J Polit Econ 2004;112(S1):S164–87.
sented at the Engineering Project Organization Conference, Cle Elum, WA; 2016. [137] Dion J, Duke J, Data, feedback, & awareness lead to big energy savings,
[115] Saad DA, Hegazy T. Behavioral economic concepts for funding infrastructure re- Department of Energy, EE-0761, 2012.
habilitation. J Manag Eng 2015;31(5):4014089. [138] Kemp-Hesterman A, Glick S, Cross JE. Reducing electrical energy consumption
[116] Englich B, Mussweiler T, Strack F. Playing dice with criminal sentences: the in- through behaviour changes. J Facil Manag 2014;12(1):4–17.
fluence of irrelevant anchors on experts' judicial decision making. Pers Soc Psychol [139] Dion J, Shiof D, USPS - Lean Green Teams, Department of Energy, EE-0760; Aug.
Bull 2006;32(2):188–200. 2012.
[117] Northcraft GB, Neale MA. Experts, amateurs, and real estate: an anchoring-and- [140] Budaiwi I, Abdou A. HVAC system operational strategies for reduced energy
adjustment perspective on property pricing decisions. Organ Behav Hum Decis consumption in buildings with intermittent occupancy: the case of mosques.
Process 1987;39(1):84–97. Energy Convers Manag 2013;73:37–50.
[118] M. van Buiten and A. Hartmann, Public-private partnerships: Cognitive biases in [141] Aste N, Manfren M, Marenzi G. Building automation and control systems and
the field, in Engineering Project Organization Conference; 2013. performance optimization: a framework for analysis. Renew Sustain Energy Rev
[119] Harris N, Shealy T, Klotz L. How exposure to “role model” projects can lead to 2017;75:313–30.
decisions for more sustainable infrastructure. Sustainability 2016;8(2):130. [142] CEM BLCPDCEM, WCTPDP, PE WJKPD. Guide to energy management. 8 edition
[120] Beamish TD, Biggart N. Social heuristics: decision making and innovation in a Lilburn, GA: Fairmont Press; 2016.
networked production market [SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 1533429]. Rochester, NY: [143] AlFaris F, Juaidi A, Manzano-Agugliaro F. Improvement of efficiency through an
Social Science Research Network; 2010. energy management program as a sustainable practice in schools. J Clean Prod
[121] Gigerenzer G, Selten R. Bounded rationality: the adaptive toolbox. Mit Press; 2002. 2016;135:794–805.
[122] Buiten, M, Hartmann A, Meer J, Nudging for smart construction: tackling un- [144] Heydarian A, Pantazis E, Carneiro JP, Gerber D, Becerik-Gerber B. Lights,
certainty by changing design engineers' choice architecture, presented at the building, action: impact of default lighting settings on occupant behaviour. J
Engineering Project Organization Conference, Cle Elum, Washington, USA; 2016. Environ Psychol 2016;48:212–23.
[123] Kempton W, Montgomery L. Folk quantification of energy. Energy [145] El‐Haram Mohamed A, Agapiou Andrew. The role of the facility manager in new
1982;7(10):817–27. procurement routes. J Qual Maint Eng 2002;8(2):124–34 https://doi.org/10.110
[124] Allcott H, Mullainathan S. Behavior and energy policy. Science 8/13552510210429983.
2010;327(5970):1204–5. [146] Perrenoud Anthony J, Lines Brian C, Sullivan Kenneth T. Measuring risk man-
[125] Laskey A, Kavazovic O. OPOWER: energy efficiency through behavioral science agement performance within a capital program. J Facil Manag 2014;12(2):158–71
and technology. XRDS 2010;17(4). https://doi.org/10.1108/JFM-03-2013-0018.
[126] Wilson C, Dowlatabadi H. Models of decision making and residential energy use. [147] Pitt Michael, Tucker Matthew. Performance measurement in facilities manage-
Annu Rev Environ Resour 2007;32:169–203. ment: driving innovation? Prop Manag 2008;26(4):241–54 https://doi.org/10.
[127] Chai K-H, Yeo C. Overcoming energy efficiency barriers through systems ap- 1108/02637470810894885.
proach—a conceptual framework. Energy Policy 2012;46:460–72. [148] Gillingham K, Newell RG, Palmer K. Energy Efficiency Economics and Policy,
[128] Shealy T, Klotz L. Well-endowed rating systems: how modified defaults can lead to Discussion Paper 09-13. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future; 2009.
more sustainable performance. J Constr Eng Manag 2015;141(10):4015031. [149] Tversky A, Kahneman D. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice.
[129] Klotz L, Mack D, Klapthor B, Tunstall C, Harrison J. Unintended anchors: building Science 1981;211:453–8.
rating systems and energy performance goals for US buildings. Energy Policy [150] Weber EU, Johnson EJ. Mindful judgment and decision making. Annu Rev Psychol
2010;38(7):3557–66. 2009;60:53–86.
[130] van Buiten M, Hartmann A, Public-private partnerships: Cognitive biases in the [151] Hardisty David, Johnson Eric, Weber Elke. Framing Interacts With Political
field. In: Engineering Project Organization Conference; 2013. Affiliation to Predict Environmentally-Relevant Purchase Preferences. Samu
[131] Goldstein DG, Johnson EJ, Sharpe WF. Choosing outcomes versus choosing pro- Sridhar, Vaidyanathan Rajiv, Duluth Dipankar Chakravarti, editors. AP - Asia-
ducts: consumer‐focused retirement investment advice. J Consum Res Pacific Advances in Consumer Research, 8. MN: Association for Consumer
2008;35(3):440–56. Research; 2009. p. 379–80.

3961

View publication stats

Вам также может понравиться