Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 10

Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Ecological Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

Analysis

Teaching and Learning Ecosystem Assessment and Valuation T


1
David Löw Beer
University of Koblenz-Landau, Institute for Social Sciences, Department of Economics, August-Croissant-Str. 5, 76829 Landau, Germany

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: There has been very little research on teaching, learning and communicating core concepts from Ecological and
Economics education Environmental Economics. Yet, shedding light on these issues is important for more effective teaching, and to
Ecosystem Assessment and Valuation support the public debate on ideas, which aim to shape a sustainable future. This paper investigates teaching and
Phenomenography learning about one of the most researched, applied and contested concepts in Environmental and Ecological
Curriculum research
Economics: Ecosystem Assessment and Valuation (ESAV). It presents students' conceptions on ESAV gained
University
through group discussions. The transcripts were analyzed with the phenomenographic and documentary
method. The analysis focuses both on the way students describe ecological, social and economic aspects, and on
the criteria they use to make political and management decisions. The main results are that students tend to see
nature as a place for recreation and wildlife, do not see knowledge as uncertain and hardly bring up the idea of
an economic valuation. Based on students' conceptions, as well as research from Ecological and Environmental
Economics and Economics Education, I suggest a curriculum for ESAV.

1. Introduction policy. Davies and Lundholm (2012) discover different students' con-
ceptions concerning the question whether goods should be provided for
In the field of Economics Education, three different research ap- free. They range from a mere recognition that some goods are provided
proaches on teaching sustainability have evolved (Seeber and Birke, for free toward a desire to set incentives to internalize externalities.
2011): (1) Categorical analysis orients toward central elements of the Harring et al. (2017) find that after one semester of studying eco-
discipline. The only categorical research specifically dedicated toward nomics, Swedish students become slightly more likely to evaluate
sustainability is Seeber (2001), who derives contents for learning pro- economic policy instruments for the environment (taxes and subsidies)
cesses from core texts of ecological economics; (2) Paradigmatic ap- as good and efficient, and less likely to consider regulatory and in-
proaches are also closely connected to economics; however, they focus formational instruments as good and efficient. Interestingly, this result
more on deriving an economic way of thinking, and less on typical is independent of whether students improved their economic knowl-
contents of the discipline. Krol (2001) and Schug (1997) emphasize the edge. Ignell et al. (2017), as well as Löw Beer (2016a) focus on students'
need to see ecological problems as undesired by-products of economic conceptions regarding externalities, and find that most of the students
activities.2 They aim to complement ecological education with concepts want environment-friendly products to be cheaper than other products.
from social science as ecological education often heavily emphasizes Ignell et al. (2017) additionally point out that students focus more on
individual responsibility (Karpe, 1998; Krol, 2001); (3) Economic Ethic the supply than on the demand side when arguing why ecological goods
approaches focus on a discussion about “correct” values. Here, in a are more expensive. Löw Beer (2016a) finds that the vast majority of
radical version, Evans (2011) calls for the “absolute negation of the the students interviewed does not specifically connect the price ad-
capitalist world order” as a goal of sustainability education; Gibson justments to the ecological harms or benefits of products. Finally,
(2008) proposes a critical reevaluation of the belief in “technical-in- Lundholm (2007) reports that ten of the eleven students entering a
strumental solutions.” Weinbrenner (1997) finally calls for a new masters course in Sustainable Enterprising in Sweden describe the idea
paradigm in economic education oriented toward ecological limits and of pricing nature as difficult, insufficient or even dangerous.
a rejection of homo economicus. To the best of my knowledge, there is no thorough conceptual and
Empirically, only very few studies in economics education have empirical research on how to teach, and learn, about Ecosystem
covered sustainability-related topics. Davies et al. (2002) find a lack of Assessment and Valuation (ESAV). This is surprising as ESAV has been
knowledge of British students regarding economic environmental one of the most researched topics in Ecological and Environmental

E-mail address: David.LoewBeer@iass-potsdam.de.


1
Present Address: IASS Potsdam, Institute for Advanced Sustainability Studies e.V., Berliner Strasse 130, 14467 Potsdam, Germany.
2
This is very similar to the externality concept (Bator, 1958).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.12.014
Received 11 February 2017; Received in revised form 11 August 2017; Accepted 4 December 2017
Available online 08 December 2017
0921-8009/ © 2017 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

Economics in the last years (Castro e Silva and Teixeira, 2011; Hoepner political affairs must also be taught as controversial in educational in-
et al., 2012; Ma and Stern, 2006). At the same time, ESAV remains structions”.6 This is in line with a basic objective of Education for
controversial within economic disciplines. This is reflected in the Sustainable Development, which is not to force students to act sus-
foremost textbooks published in the last years. While Environmental tainably, but to enable them to shape sustainable societies if they wish
Economics textbooks mainly focus on technical aspects of different to do so (De Haan, 2006).
valuation methods (e.g., Perman et al., 2011; Tietenberg and Lewis, (B): The big comparative international educational studies, such as
2016), Ecological Economics textbooks tend to put more emphasis on the Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) and Trends
the ethical evaluation of ESAV (Costanza et al., 2015; Daly and Farley, in International Mathematics and Science Study (TIMMS), use a lit-
2010).3 The combination of being highly present, and at the same time eracy7 approach with dimensional analysis to determine contents from
contested, provides a strong rationale for dealing with ESAV in any a scientific discipline for teaching and learning (Bybee, 1997; Mullis
sustainability-related Economics courses. and Martin, 2013; OECD, 2016). At its heart lies the educational aim of
Based on the categorical and paradigmatic approaches described enabling individual and social participation through a critical analysis
above, the first aim of this paper is to structure the broad literature on and reflection of scientific concepts (Prenzel et al., 2001). The present
ESAV in Ecological and Environmental Economics from a didactical study used the methodology related to this literacy approach to find
perspective. Thereby, I suggest core contents of ESAV which need to be relevant elements of ESAV for education. This involved terms, models,
learned in order to understand the concept and important literature. ways of questioning and thinking and methods, as well as the role of
Secondly, I present results from an empirical study conducted in two science in society (ibid.). In the following, I define these elements and
German universities on students' preconceptions4 on ecosystem-use relate them to aspects of ESAV.
conflicts (Löw Beer, 2016b). Here, I show how students who have not Firstly, necessary and helpful terms should be made accessible,
been formally trained to use ESAV approach problems that could be particularly those that point to differences between routine and scien-
tackled using the ESAV approach. I demonstrate where students differ tific understanding. Basic terms of the ESAV model are natural capital
from in disciplinary knowledge, and I suggest how teaching can be as a metaphorical expression covering the whole limited stock of phy-
designed to help students gain a better understanding of the ESAV sical and biological resources (Costanza and Daly, 1992). ES as the flow
concept, and to approach it critically. of value to human societies (TEEB, 2010a), and also differentiating
The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: In the following between provisioning, supporting, (socio-)cultural and regulating ES
second part, core teaching and learning elements of ESAV are devel- (United Nations, 2005), along with noting the differences between
oped based on a literature review from Ecological and Environmental substitutable and complementary goods, the distinctions between use-
Economics and pedagogic guiding principles. Thirdly, the research and non-use values and between risk, uncertainty and radical un-
methodology of phenomenography and the research design are de- certainty or ignorance (Knight, 1921; Perman et al., 2011).
scribed and justified. Fourthly, results from an empirical study with 69 Secondly, a systematic connection between the terms needs to be
teacher trainees in economics are presented. Fifthly, contents and established. In economics, this is mainly linked to basic concepts. From
preconceptions are brought together to outline a teaching sequence. an Ecological Economics perspective the concept of joint production is
Finally, conclusions are presented and future research areas are pro- particularly important for ESAV (Baumgärtner et al., 2001), in En-
posed. vironmental Economics it is the similar concept of market failure
(Bator, 1958). They are important because ESAV is supposed to help to
2. Core Elements of ESAV for Teaching and Learning cope with the inability of markets to understand that certain ecological
benefits and costs need to be considered. Further important concepts
A core research area of subject didactics is concerned with de- are:
termining what contents from a subject are relevant, and how they
should be framed for educational purposes. Such a selection always • social welfare functions, because they make it possible to compare
involves some subjective elements. Therefore, the points raised in this values of different sources against each other
section are primarily meant as a starting point to foster further dis- • discounting, as ESAV is almost always concerned with costs and
cussion. benefits occurring at different times
To identify relevant contents, I performed a structuring content • knowledge uncertainty, which concerns both human limits to per-
analysis (Mayring, 2014). This process involved the Millennium Eco- ceiving nature, as well as the quality of ESAV
system Assessment (United Nations, 2005), the TEEB reports (TEEB, • the relationship between ES and human welfare (United Nations,
2010a, 2010b, 2010c), articles referred to in the reports, textbooks from 2005)
Ecological and Environmental Economics and the 100 most relevant, or
most cited articles in the ISI Web of Science and Google Scholar using In the third stage, typical ways of questioning and thinking, as well
the search terms “ecosystem services,” “valuation,” “ecosystem ser- as special methods of the ESAV approach are considered. This relates,
vices” and “assessment.” Content selection is further guided by (a) an on the one hand, to valuation methods. From the variety of different
acknowledged principle from civic education and (b) an established approaches, it seems important to focus teaching on at least one method
pedagogic methodology. with revealed, one with stated preferences, and also one with biophy-
(A): Controversy is seen “as a key aspect in democratic education” sical valuations to compare different methodologies. On the other hand,
(Hess, 2009) in civic education.5 In Germany, this is formalized by an typical applications of ESAV need to be covered. To focus on this part,
agreed consensus, according to which (1) overwhelming students is one can restrict the content to the applications, which differ most from
prohibited, i.e., even for “good purposes” one may not “impart desir-
able opinions,” and hinder students from “forming an independent
judgment,” and (2) “matters which are controversial in intellectual and 6
The consensus was agreed on in 1976 in the German town of Beutelsbach, and is
therefore called the “Beutelsbacher consensus.” At the following website, you can find a
translation of the text: www.lpb-bw.de/beutelsbacher-konsens.html < rev. 12/4/
3
Only Edward-Jones et al. (2004) look in detail both at philosophical and technical 2017 > .
questions. 7
In pedagogy, the term literacy was originally linked to the ability to read and write.
4
A preconception here is understood as an idea or opinion that someone has before Over the years its semantic content has been shifted toward skills which enable people to
learning about something directly. “contribute to socio-economic development, to developing the capacity for social
5
See also Schulz et al. (2010); Ten Dam and Volman (2004); Torney-Purta et al. awareness and [for] critical reflection as a basis for personal and social change”
(2001); Zohar and Nemet (2002). (UNESCO, 2005)

426
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

one another, are widely used in economic policy and can also be used in and limited number of different ways of experiencing them (Marton and
other areas of economics. This could involve cost benefit analysis (CBA) Pang, 2008). Phenomenography takes a second order perspective, fo-
as the typical decision-making process in Environmental Economics and cusing not on how phenomena really are, but on how they are experi-
multi-criteria analysis (MCA) as the typical decision-making process in enced by certain people. An important term in phenomenography is
Ecological Economics, as well as payments for ecosystem services critical aspects. An aspect or a feature is critical if it must be understood
(PES). If time permits, one could also look at natural resource damage to unlock the meaning of a concept, but has not yet been understood by
assessments and cost effectiveness analysis (CEA). the learner (Marton, 2015). Critical aspects can only be found by
The final level involves the role of Economics in society, or more studying the discipline and the learners together.
specifically: What are the potential benefits and limitations of ESAV? Phenomenographic research in economics education has so far fo-
What distinguishes ESAV from similar approaches in other fields, such cused on (a) the neoclassical concepts of price (Dahlgren and Marton,
as political sciences? Is ESAV compatible with certain societal goals? 1978; Marton and Pong, 2005; Pang et al., 2006; Pong, 1999), trade
Here, one could at first look at basic assumptions of valuation studies: (Marton and Pong, 2005; Pong, 1999), wages (Birke and Seeber, 2012)
e.g., ecological changes must have consequences for human well-being and externalities (Ignell et al., 2017; Löw Beer, 2016a) (b) an economic
to have a monetary value, human-made and natural goods must be competency such as financial literacy (Pang, 2010; Speer and Seeber,
substitutable between one another, as well as between themselves 2013) or (c) on describing normatively different conceptions of how an
(Edward-Jones et al., 2004). Secondly, contradictions between Ecolo- economic problem should be solved, such as which goods should be
gical and Environmental Economics are manifest. While there is a broad provided for free (Davies and Lundholm, 2012) or when governments
consensus in both disciplines that markets, per se, usually do not re- should intervene (Kaiser et al., 2015). The present study is similar to (a)
present values correctly, monetary valuation is almost a default strategy as it also focuses on conceptions related to a technical concept.
in Environmental Economics, while it is criticized widely in Ecological To give an example of a typical result from a phenomenographic
Economics. The critique involves framing biophysical entities that inquiry and to illustrate the hierarchical structure of students' pre-
overlap in nature in aritmomporphic (discrete) terms (Georgescu- conceptions, which will be important in the outcome spaces presented
Roegen, 1971), the incommensurability and limited substitutability of in section four, I report one of the results from Ignell et al. (2017). They
different values (Farrell, 2007; Martinez-Alier et al., 1998; Vatn and interviewed 15 Swedish students who were between 17 and 18 years of
Bromley, 1994), the impossibility of setting the scale of the economy age and who had participated in the national business and economic
based on price adjustments — because of circular reasoning as “prices educational programs. These students were asked if, and why, more
depend on the scale or distribution” (Daly and Farley, 2010) — and environmentally friendly burgers had different prices, and how they
because preference-based valuation methods are biased toward weal- should be priced. Regarding productivity, Ignell et al. found three levels
thier people (Spash, 2008; Wegner and Pascual, 2011). Major argu- of thinking of why “eco goods” are more expensive:
ments in support of a monetary valuation are that it can improve
welfare and increase conservation as people recognize that environ- (1) basic: because they are costlier to produce
mental protection, etc., are in their best interests, that there is always (2) partial: because they require more resources to produce
an implicit valuation which monetary valuation can make explicit and (3) complex: because they use more resources that have to be paid for,
more appropriate (Liu et al., 2010), and that it can structure informa- but they conserve the natural environment
tion and support decision-making processes (Arrow et al., 1996).8 Fi-
nally, within the researchers who do not fully reject ESAV, there are Because of the hierarchical structure, the third conception includes
major differences between Ecological and Environmental Economics the concept on the second level and is therefore considered more
regarding the purposes for which ESAV might be used (cf. for example complex.
Kallis et al., 2013; vs. Wunder, 2005), e.g., while many Ecological Knowledge about different conceptions can be used to design ef-
Economists are skeptical of CBA, fewer have problems using ESAV to fective lessons. These usually start with learners' preconceptions and
assess the compensation for ecological damage. aim to help them to advance toward a scientifically appropriate way of
understanding.9,10

2.1. Methodology: Preconceptions and Phenomenography


2.2. Sample and Stimuli
Research in psychology, as well as in social and natural science
education, has shown that successful learning processes, which help Concerning data collection, I opted for group discussions as they
students acquire new concepts, explicitly incorporate learners' pre- have long proven to be useful for studying normative questions
conceptions. (Mangold, 1960), and as learners are confronted with complex ques-
One methodology to study learners' preconceptions is phenomeno- tions they are often only capable of developing their own ideas while
graphy (Marton, 1981, 2015; Marton and Booth, 1997; Marton and discussing them with others (Pollock, 1955). Based on group discus-
Tsui, 2004). Compared with other qualitative research approaches to sions, one can survey ideologies, opinions and attitudes, which are ty-
preconceptions, it has the advantages of avoiding speculations about pical for certain types of groups, and which therefore can be reproduced
the quality of mental representations (Marton and Pang, 2008) and its (Bohnsack, 2004; Lamnek, 2005). A common critique to group discus-
focus on the subject-specific in contrast with general preconceptions. sions is the mutual interference of participants. For two reasons, this
The object of research in phenomenography is “the qualitatively dif- was not considered problematic in the present paper: (1) Many learning
ferent ways in which people experience, understand, see or con- processes occur in groups. Therefore, it makes sense to research groups
ceptualize a particular phenomenon or an aspect of the world around to come up with suggestions, which aim to improve teaching and
them” (Marton and Pong, 2005). Phenomenography aims to create learning. (2) This research does not aim to reach any conclusions re-
outcome spaces with categories of description. These categories or garding individual conceptions, but instead focuses on the “collective
conceptions are supposed to represent different ways of experiencing a
phenomenon within a group. They are logically interrelated and in all 9
I thank Tom Green for highlighting to me, that of course, what is considered to be
phenomenographic studies conducted so far there have been a small scientifically appropriate depends on the teacher/researcher. This section aims to present
the method of phenomenography and not to discuss the quality of the economic concepts
that have been researched in phenomenography so far.
8 10
For an overview of the debate, please refer to Schröter et al. (2014) or TEEB (2010a, Studies on how to design effective lessons according to the phenomenographic ap-
Ch. 4) proach can be found in Lo et al. (2004); Marton (2015); and Marton and Pang (2013)

427
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

mind” (Marton, 1981). Also, the smallest unit of people analyzed is one know whether the participant would have made the same comment in
focus group. an individual interview (Bohnsack, 2010). Therefore, the following
In total, sixteen group discussions were led including a total of 69 analysis always refers to groups or to comments made within a group.
teacher trainees in economics in November and December 2013. Because of the qualitative nature of the research, I did not perform
Economics teacher trainees were chosen as a research group because inferential statistics. Therefore, I only pointed to apparent peculiarities
designing good learning environments for teachers is crucial as they are concerning the frequencies of statements.
important, prospective multipliers. Furthermore, all of the selected
teacher trainees in economics had, or will receive, a thorough uni- 3. Results and Discussion
versity education in economics. Therefore, the results also have im-
plications for teaching regular students of economics. In this section, results and discussions for two dimensions are pre-
The research objective was to discover the greatest possible range of sented subsequently. The first involves students' conceptions of ecolo-
conceptions within the research group of teacher trainees in Germany. gical, economic and social aspects — the second criteria for decision-
Therefore, I selected a diverse sample. With Oldenburg and Landau, I making processes.
chose two different German universities: In Oldenburg, there is an in-
tegrated course of economic education. In contrast, in Landau, students 3.1. First Results: Ecological, Economic and Social Aspects
of economic education participate in the regular economics courses for
their disciplinary training. Furthermore, students differed regarding the The participants depicted aspects related to all three dimensions of
time they studied economics education: Ten groups comprised teacher sustainability. I used the categories developed in the Millennium
trainees beginning their bachelor studies, five groups at the end of their Ecosystem Assessment (United Nations, 2005) to define the categories
bachelor studies or at the beginning of their master studies and one wherever suitable. Exemplary statements in the economic dimension
group was mixed. The group discussions lasted roughly one to 2 h. are described in more detail.
For data collection, stimuli were developed that were nontechnical Statements dealing with the exploitation of natural resources for
and vague so that students could apply the greatest possible variety of human ends were categorized as provisioning services. In the forest
conceptions, both with respect to describing different ecosystem ser- scenario, this mainly involved selling and using wood for heating or to
vices, as well as to propose decision-making processes. Therefore, it was produce paper and furniture. Some groups also pointed to the capacity
left to the students to specify the economic, ecological, social and po- of untouched forests as food sources. In the sea scenario, possible
litical circumstances of the scenarios. Furthermore, in the stimuli, any changes concerning fishing capacities were discussed. Agricultural
hint toward a decision-making procedure, such as a CBA, was avoided yields were the main concern in the city scenario. The following quote
so that different approaches could be selected. In all stimuli, students is an example where different qualities of provisioning services were
were asked to counsel a local population that was granted the authority addressed. I11: “There are different qualities of forests. There is teak or
to decide upon the future of an ecosystem with alternative uses. To something like that. Or there is a simple coniferous forest. Maybe this
increase the variety of conceptions and to understand whether con- involves big differences concerning profits and regrowth” (O B 1, forest,
ceptions depend on the topic of a scenario, a forest and maritime and a 61).11,12
urban ecosystems were selected. If a statement dealt with economic aspects of the scenario, but did
An example for a stimulus is: not show immediate relations to ES, it was classified as economic as-
pects outside the ES framework. The main concern across all scenarios
Think of a densely wooded island. In the last years, many trees have
here were jobs. Sometimes changes in profits and taxes were named. An
been cut on the island. Some of the inhabitants of the island think
exemplary quote for this category is: I46: “However, constructing wind
one should continue with that, others believe the trees should be
turbines would create maintenance jobs” (L B 2, sea, 262).
protected, and many are still undecided. Imagine if the inhabitants
Categorization in the other dimensions is straightforward and
of the island asked you: “How should we decide?” What would you
shortly illustrated in Table 1. The table also shows the categories and
advise them to do and why?
relative frequencies of the denomination in the three dimensions.
The other stimuli are presented in the appendix. There was a script Frequencies are based on counting in how many discussions a re-
with follow-up questions that were always asked. In particular, I always spective category was used at least once. Because of the qualitative
summed up the arguments presented and asked the students, “Based on nature of the study and the data collection through group discussions,
the arguments, what advice would you give to the inhabitants on how there was no differentiation whether a category had been assigned
they should reach a decision?” several times or only once during a single group discussion. In total, 10
All data were recorded and fully transcribed. Data were analyzed groups discussed the forest and the sea and 12 groups discussed the city
using a combination of phenomenography (Marton, 2015) and the scenario.
documentary method (Bohnsack, 2010). The analysis was based on an
iterative process of working through the transcripts. In the beginning, 3.2. First Discussion
six transcripts were randomly selected. Each sequence was analyzed by
a formulating (very close to the statements, focusing on the immanent The quality of students' statements in each dimension can be dif-
meaning) and a reflecting (more interpretative, connections to the ferentiated into two levels. In the economic and social dimension, more
ESAV are drawn) interpretation (Bohnsack, 2010). In the second step, complex statements directly link to the ecosystem instead of only
differences between the units of analysis, i.e. statements by partici- naming factors that refer to the scenario, but not to the ecosystem. In
pants, were scrutinized. Thirdly, the material was analyzed for simila-
rities with the goal of finding a generalization. Finally, logical re- 11
Letter I in front of the quotes stands for interviewee; all interviewees were num-
lationships between units were defined (Marton, 2015). In the
bered. At the end of the quote, L stands for Landau and O for Oldenburg as the locations of
advanced stages of the data analysis, student statements were cate- the group discussion, thereafter B stands for beginners, A for advanced students. This is
gorized in two dimensions that were particularly relevant for learning followed by the number of the group discussion in the respective category. Then the topic
about ESAV. Both are presented and discussed in the next section. Data of the group discussion is named (forest, sea or city). Finally, the page of the transcript is
given. For example, the above quote comes from interviewee 11. He or she was part of the
analysis was further supported by the qualitative data software
first beginner group in Oldenburg. The discussion quoted covers the forest scenario and
MAXQDA 11. the original quote can be found on page 63 of the (German) transcript.
It is important to note that one may not trace comments made in a 12
Please contact the author for a full package of the transcripts (in German) and ad-
group discussion to an individual participant because it is impossible to ditional data.

428
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

Table 1 Table 2
Relative frequencies of the denomination of different ecosystem and other services. Relative frequency of the denomination of boundaries.

Dimension Category Forest Sea City Category Forest Sea City

Ecologic Regulating services, e.g., “effects on micro- 30% 0% 58% Ecological boundary 20% 60% 42%
climate.” Social boundary 90% 0% 0%
Supporting services, e.g., “animals will not 60% 60% 42% Economic-technological boundary 10% 80% 17%
be able to find food anymore.” Uncertain knowledge 0% 10% 0%
Intrinsic values of nature. 30% 30% 8% Individual (property) rights 0% 10% 25%
Economic Provisioning services, e.g., “wood for 100% 20% 17% Demand 20% 40% 58%
heating.”
Economic aspects outside the ES 40% 80% 83%
framework, e.g., “jobs related to when it is argued that people should be allowed to use wood for heating
construction work.”
or cooking, if their life is endangered. An economic-technological
Social Socio-cultural services e.g., “a clear view of 90% 100% 100%
the sea.” boundary is characterized by an exclusion of either a measure, which is
Social aspects outside the ES framework, 60% 20% 83% unprofitable, or an “immature” technology. An exemplary quote is, I1:
e.g., “new migrants coming into the city.” “The wind farm should, of course only be constructed, if it is profitable”
(O A 1, sea, 12).
Uncertain knowledge can be a further boundary, which can be a
the ecologic dimension, the more complex statements do not only in-
justification for abstaining from certain actions. However, there is only
volve ecological factors, but also link them to human well-being or
one quote dealing with uncertain knowledge and that one is not even
clarify that it is a human decision to value nature for its own sake. The
fully developed, I18: “Can one really weigh this with the ecological
reason for considering them to be more complex is that they include the
damages of offshore wind turbines, which do not have long-term studies
less complex conception and add an additional aspect which is im-
yet, because offshore wind turbines have not been around for a long
portant for the ES concept.
time” (O A 3, sea, 122)?
The frequencies in which the participants speak about the variety of
Some groups argue that a decision should not be taken, if it violates
services, differ both with respect to the services themselves, as well as
individual (property) rights, e.g. I55: “It is ok, if the land is sold vo-
to the scenarios presented. When all scenarios are taken together, the
luntary and no one is damaged. But if it touches the rights of the owner,
participants discussed socio-cultural and supporting services more fre-
then, I believe, it would be going too far” (L B 5, city, 13).
quently than regulating and provisioning services. The particularly few
Finally some groups point to an effective demand as a prerequisite to
comments on regulating services might be due to the fact that, in the
avoid that new housing is created without people buying it.
current real world, they are predominantly provided free of economic
Table 2 sums up the boundaries and the relative frequencies of their
charge. Put differently, the participants see nature mainly as a recrea-
occurrence.
tional area or as the habitat of animals and plants. Only some groups
point to the complex and, at the same time, fundamental dependency of
(b) Subjective factors
human livelihood on ES.
Comparing the scenarios, groups debating the forest scenario use a
Some students support decisions, that are not based on objective
greater variety of ecosystem services. Participants seem to have less
factors, but on individual emotions, experiences or attitudes. I label
difficulty recognizing wood as an exploitable resource than detecting
them subjective factors. An exemplary quote is: I55: “It depends,
comparable resources in a maritime or urban ecosystem.
whether the people are future-oriented or whether they think: devil-
may-care” (L B 4, sea, 291).
3.3. Second Results: Decision-making Criteria
(c) Decisions based only either on an economic, ecological or social
The participants name various criteria they consider relevant for a criterion
decision. They can be summarized under four parent categories:
During most of the group discussions, some students propose solu-
(a) statements defining a boundary tions based on a criterion that only involves one dimension of sus-
(b) statements solely focused on subjective factors tainability. Statements are categorized as cost-effectiveness if decisions
(c) considerations which only refer to one sustainability dimension are based on comparing economic costs and benefits, e.g. income
(d) considerations which include two or three sustainability dimensions generated by selling wood compared with the costs of cutting and
transportation. Comments labeled as environmental compatibility want
In the following, I describe categories in the four areas; to base decisions solely on one or more ecological factors. Finally,
statements categorized as purpose or motif aim for decisions based on
(a) Boundaries the reasons or justifications for taking an action, e.g. the intended use of
timber or – as in the following quote – of an area.
Based on the data, I define boundaries as follows: If a boundary is I47: “It depends, what is built. For example if city a13 constructs
crossed, students argue that a certain action has to be either taken or student homes, then this is reasonable.
refrained from. The students use six different types of boundary con- I48: But so that grocery store a builds something new …
ditions. I47: … That would be unnecessary.”
Ecological boundaries imply that one should refrain from an action, (L B 2, city, 257)
if the environment or animals are endangered to a specified degree. An
exemplary quote is, I48: “If an endangered dolphin or whale species In only four of the 32 group discussions money is considered as a
lives there, we should do without the money [from wind power, DLB]” measure to facilitate the decision-making process. It is always linked to
(L B 2, sea, 263).
Similarly, participants describe social boundaries as basic human 13
For purposes of data protection, personal data such as names of people, companies
needs that need to be fulfilled, almost regardless of the consequences to and places have been anonymised in the transcripts. Anonymised data has been put in
other areas. Social boundaries are mainly used in the forest example italics.

429
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

the idea of a financial compensation as illustrated in the following valuation in Ecological Economics (cf. Section 2). Specifically, crossing
quote. I36: “That one, for example, pays a compensation to the tourism a boundary usually involves a non-marginal change while prices are
industry, which will be paid by wind power stations” (L F 2, sea, 54). usually considered to be set according to marginal changes. Therefore,
some ecological economists generally reject monetary valuation (e.g.,
(d) Decisions based on a mixture of economic, social and ecological Georgescu-Roegen, 1971), and others consider it inappropriate in the
aspects cases, when a boundary is crossed. However, particularly the second
argument is not brought up by the students. For them, naming
Both the following categories describe balancing between at least boundaries often had a function fairly different from the one in eco-
two of the three dimensions of sustainability. nomics, namely emphasizing uncontroversial answers. For example: It
The criterion location-independent choice between economy and was very difficult to contradict somebody saying that new construction
ecology is defined as decisions based on general economic and ecolo- areas should not be developed if no one wants to buy the new houses.
gical factors, i.e., unrelated to a specific context. The participants de- For the participants, the argument about the functions of boundaries is
scribe economic and ecologic factors as contradictory to each other. supported by the fact that many groups emphasize the necessity of the
Most of the time, the students only point out the contradictions without existence of boundaries, but avoid explaining how decision-making
explaining which side should be preferred or how both aspects should might look like, if no boundary is crossed. An important reason for the
be weighed against each other. An exemplary quote is, I54: “My opi- focus on boundaries might not be explained by the content of their
nion, contra: the environmental impact. Animals which fly into such a statements, but by the desire of the participants to be respected by other
wind turbine. You can watch videos on YouTube about this. (…) Pro: group members. Therefore, they prefer statements everybody can agree
Our thirst for energy constantly grows and wind turbines are clean vs. controversial ones.
energy” (L B 4, sea, 290f.). Uncertainty of knowledge is crucial in Ecological Economics, and
In statements categorized as dependent on the ecological as well as linked to the precautionary principle (Epstein, 1980; Gollier et al.,
economic and/or social context, students argue that local conditions 2000) and the safe minimum standard (Bishop, 1978). In contrast, the
such as the job market situation or the level of environmental de- students interviewed seem to largely ignore this challenge and its
gradation should determine a decision, e.g., I5: “So, if we had a city consequences for the assessment of ecosystems, as well as policy re-
where a lot of young people are unemployed, then I would advise the commendations.
inhabitants to use the areas in a smart way, i.e., to let companies de- I compared how closely conceptions resemble the technical concept
velop in order to lower unemployment. (….) If we had an area where by looking at the way, nature was treated, i.e. conceptions are con-
many people already have a job, I might not favor that because every sidered more complex, if (1) natural aspects are described as services
city needs its recreational areas” (O A 2, city, 4). and if (2) several services are included. Statements found in the parent
Table 3 depicts relative frequencies of the use of the different cri- categories of decisions based on an individual (b) or an economic,
teria across the groups. ecological or social criterion (c) at most include one ES. The criteria
decisions based on a mixture of social, ecological or social criteria (d)
are more complex as they can include several ES.
3.4. Second Discussion Even though all the scenarios refer to the same phenomenon,
namely ecosystems with alternative uses, the frequency of the use of the
Boundaries — as defined in 4.3 (a) — are discussed in all scenarios, criteria differs depending on the scenario used. Whereas the groups
however there are important differences regarding the frequencies in argue that the yields from forests, as well as a construction area in a
the different categories. Social boundaries can only be found in the city, can be used in multiple ways, the criterion of purpose or motif is
forest scenario. This is linked to the tendency of the students to locate not used in the discussions concerning the maritime ecosystem. In
the scenario in a poor surrounding while they typically discuss rich contrast, the criteria of cost-effectiveness and environmental compat-
societies when dealing with the sea and urban scenarios. The more ibility are used more in the maritime scenario. All in all, relatively few
frequent references to an economic-technological boundary are prob- students discussing the forest scenario advise decisions based solely on
ably due to the fact that in the scenario itself, a technology, namely economic criteria and many describe a trade-off between higher eco-
offshore wind turbines, has been presented while no technology has nomic yields and environmental degradation, which lowers quality of
been mentioned in the other scenarios. life.
Students name demand as a boundary condition more often in the While all groups consider various dimensions of sustainability in
urban scenario as they fear bad planning. their analysis, the idea to compare different forms of use through a
The identification of boundaries is also a typical procedure in (monetary) valuation does not occur to the students. This is surprising,
Environmental and particularly in Ecological Economics. In the dis- given the great importance of a monetary valuation in Environmental
ciplines, it is argued that an optimization should be avoided firstly for Economics. However, based on the data, I cannot interpret whether the
ethical reasons, if a boundary might be crossed, e.g. if natural capital students would reject a monetarization of nature. Rather, the idea of
(Farley, 2010) is reduced below a certain threshold. Furthermore, the valuation seems not to occur to them.
existence of boundaries is part of the general critique against monetary Finally, I found only minor differences between student groups at
the beginning and the end of their university studies. There is almost no
Table 3 difference in the frequencies of the use of the multidimensional criteria.
Relative frequency of decision making criteria dependent on scenarios.
However, in the groups with more advanced students, arguments re-
Category Forest Sea City ferring to only one dimension of sustainability are more common. There
is some progression in the sense that more advanced groups tend to
Subjective factors 90% 70% 50% delineate criteria more clearly, i.e., they will state consequences for the
Cost-effectiveness 30% 90% 75%
Environmental compatibility 30% 50% 17%
provision of ES in different circumstances and directly connect them to
Purpose or motif 70% 0% 83% a criteria, while beginners more often just describe aspects of the
Financial compensation 10% 30% 25% phenomenon without clarifying what they imply for decision making.
Location-independent choice between economy and 40% 60% 58% Comparing an Environmental and an Ecological Economics ap-
ecology
proach, one can infer that students' preconceptions rather mirror initial
Dependent on the ecological as well as economic and/or 90% 50% 83%
social context stages of a MCA typical for Ecological Economics: They point to various
aspects relevant for a decision and often describe the positive and

430
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

negative consequences of different management options. However, they Thereupon students are asked to come up with suggestions on how
do not address the necessity to weigh the various aspects. single ES can be assessed and valued to motivate them for a detailed
Finally, it is worthwhile to note that all group discussions have been examination of ESAV. A good strategy here might be to compare similar
conducted in German universities. Other conceptions, or another dis- ecosystems where one ES differs, e.g., two forests with different carbon
tribution of the conceptions, might be found if people with different uptake capacities, trees with different market-values or with wealthier
attitudes toward markets or environmental awareness were inter- or poorer inhabitants and neighbors. Afterwards, small groups of stu-
viewed. dents are asked to prepare presentations on:

(1) selected valuation methods, including an assessment of their ad-


4. Suggestions for a Curriculum
vantages and disadvantages, and the values that can be captured by
it, and examples of their use
The following short curriculum is based on the core contents de-
(2) uncertain knowledge and discounting, including different risk
veloped, and preconceptions described in the previous sections. It is
terms, the precautionary principle and safe minimum standard, as
designed for university education with teacher trainees in Economics. If
well consequences of varying social discount rates for long-term
applied to undergraduate, and particularly graduate education in
investments
Economics in general, it might be worthwhile to consider spending
(3) selected ESAV applications, including a comparative assessment
more time on actually assessing and valuing ecosystem systems. As with
based on typical policy goals from Environmental vs. Ecological
any curriculum, depending especially on the specific learner group,
Economics
other methods are conceivable. Furthermore, the research has shown
some major misconceptions of students regarding basic ecology (e.g., an
After the presentations, the whole class draws conclusions on how
almost complete lack of the idea of irreversibility). It might therefore be
the gained knowledge can be used to assess and manage ES in an urban
worthwhile to first teach basic biological concepts. However, this is not
ecosystem.
the focus of this paper.
Then students apply and deepen their knowledge using the case
Phenomenographers argue that teaching a complex concept should
method (Carlson and Velenchik, 2006). The basic structure of the cases
start by looking at it as a whole, and then looking at its parts (Marton,
can be similar to the scenarios developed for the group discussions
2015). As students name a greater number, and more diverse ES in the
described above. However, students should be provided with more data
forest scenario, it makes sense to start with a forest. First, the lecturer
concerning the ecological, social and economic conditions, and these
briefly characterizes the ecosystem and its possible conflicts between
should be varied, e.g., by including a more or less valued/appreciated
land uses (e.g., size, location, main ecologic traits, property rights). The
species. If the course objective is an introduction, or if it is part of
learners are then asked to brainstorm about the functions of forests for
teacher training, then students are asked to structure the information,
humans.
to suggest how relevant data can be collected and which policy mea-
Only few participants suggested comparing ES based on a monetary
sures (e.g., PES schemes) could be appropriate. If the objective is
valuation, but it is widely used in Environmental and Ecological
teaching students to actually execute valuation studies, real data can be
Economics research, as well as Economic policy, a practical trial and
provided for students to conduct analysis on their own.15
reflection of the use of monetarized data are at the heart of the sug-
Finally, the class conducts the role-play again, but this time, groups
gested learning sequence. Therefore, I propose an issue-based repeated
are provided with data from valuation studies. As is common in re-
role-play (Errington, 1997) where specific content knowledge is trans-
search, values should be presented with a range to demonstrate un-
mitted between the iterations.
certainties and to provide groups with a negotiation space. To avoid
In the role-play, a group of students is asked to represent the role of
overwhelming students (see Section 2), groups are free to use or reject
a local committee oriented toward the common good, which decides
the results of the valuation studies, as there is also fundamental oppo-
about the future use of a forest. It hosts a public hearing where different
sition to monetizing nature in today's civil society groups. After the
groups (e.g., timber industry, water suppliers, tourist agency, in-
committee has declared its decision, the course of the discussions and
habitants) present their views. Additionally, one person with some
results in both rounds of the role-play are compared to uncover po-
background in ecology (this can also be the lecturer) should correct
tentials and limitations of monetary valuation. Here, one should also
basic ecological misconceptions, such as the widely held opinion in the
reflect how discussions and attitudes change when money and mone-
group discussions that there is no differences in the carbon uptake
tary values are included (Caruso et al., 2013; Frey and Oberholzer-Gee,
between new and older forests. After the committee has made and
1997; Vohs et al., 2008) In the process, one might check the results of
communicated its decision, a reflection of the discussion focuses on the
the panel against those that would have been reached based on a CBA
challenges the different groups, particularly the committee, faced in
and discuss which methodology is able to better represent peoples'
considering various interests. This is meant to mirror students' pre-
choices.
conceptions: They often name many relevant aspects for a decision, but
Finally, there should be a general debate about the pros and cons of
lack a strategy to adequately take all of them into account in the de-
ESAV, which is not based on the usability of data, but on the general
cision-making process. Pedagogically, this should create a “state of
question of whether ESAV is an appropriate procedure to decide about
suspense” (Marton and Booth, 1997) that motivates learners to expand
the use of ecosystems (cf. Section 2).
their mental model because they realize that their conceptions do not
Table 4 summarizes the suggested learning objectives and teaching
suffice to solve the problem.
methods.
At this point, the teaching of the technical concept begins. First,
basic terms relevant for ESAV (see Section 2) should be introduced
using standard instruction methods such as text-based discussions and
teacher presentations. In the same manner, the concepts of joint pro-
duction or market failure, as well as the significance of prices as signals
(footnote continued)
of relative scarcities, should be revised as these are basic justifications from Deelmster & Brauer can be found here: http://w3.marietta.edu/~delemeeg/
for ESAV.14 games < rev. 12/4/2017 > .
15
An excellent resource here is Kareiva et al. (2011), which provides a great number of
examples and is linked to the Natural capital project (cf. http://www.
14
If students have not been exposed to these concepts, it might be good to start with an naturalcapitalproject.org < rev. 12/4/2017 >) providing a free and open source soft-
economic game. An extensive database of economic classroom experiments and games ware solutions that can be learned fairly quickly.

431
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

Table 4
Learning objectives and teaching methods.

Area Learning objectives – Students are able to … Teaching methods

Ecosystems and their services … explain basic ecological terms relevant for ESAV Teacher presentations
… identify differences between provisioning, regulating, socio-cultural and supporting ES Structured reading
… relate ES to human welfare
Basic economic models … analyze types and reasons of market failure Socratic method
… explain und evaluate economic welfare criteria Student presentations
… explain and make use of the concepts of risk, uncertainty, and discounting
Valuation methods and their … compare economic valuation methods based on revealed and stated preferences and on Role-play to decide upon the management
application biophysical factors strategy of an ecosystem
… develop a policy recommendation for an ecosystem with conflicting interests taking into Student presentations about applications of
account the ES applicable and possibilities (e.g. data requirements, uncertainties, etc.) to value ESAV
them Case method to apply knowledge gained
… distinguish and characterize typical applications of ESAV (e.g. CBA, MCA, PES)
Evaluating ESAV … judge possibilities of potentials and limits and applications of ESAV based on the criteria of Role-play to decide upon the management
ecological scale, just distribution, and efficiency as well as criteria developed by students' strategy of an ecosystem
themselves Debate

Action verbs are based on the revised Bloom's taxonomy by Anderson and Krathwohl (2001).

5. Conclusions usual steps in a valuation study. Besides introducing students to ESAV,


it allows them to understand differences between Environmental and
From an educational perspective, ESAV is an outstanding topic. By Ecological Economics and discussions within both schools of thought,
looking deeply into the concept itself, one can understand the multiple as well as reflecting on the appropriateness, applicability and limita-
dimensions in which humans depend on an ecosystem and also a core tions of the ESAV approach. It is therefore meant not as a suggestion
strategy of how Economics approaches sustainability problems. solely for Economics students, but as a contribution to citizens' educa-
Studying the debates around ESAV can enable students to detect dif- tion in general.
ferences between Ecological and Environmental Economics, and to As none of the groups raised the idea of using a monetary valuation
participate in an important political and scientific debate. On this basis, to compare different management options for an ecosystem, the scope
the paper develops ambitious teaching contents that are based on the of recommendations for teaching are limited. In future research, it will
idea that it is preferable to teach some concepts in depth and from therefore be interesting to focus on students' understanding of different
different angles, over the idea to superficially touch on many topics. valuation methods or to critically discuss ESAV in general.
Empirically, I have analyzed how teacher trainees in economics, Furthermore, the suggested curriculum should be evaluated.
who have not been exposed to ESAV in their studies, handle problems
that might be dealt with using the ESAV concept. The main results were Acknowledgements
that most of them see nature as a place for recreation and wildlife, but
only few recognize regulatory and provisioning services. Furthermore, I am very grateful to Günther Seeber, Franziska Birke and Sören
they bring up a great variety of different boundaries and decision- Asmussen for their support. I thank an anonymous reviewer, whose
making criteria. However, they lack ideas of how to decide in situations critical remarks have helped to improve the article substantially.
where no boundary is crossed and to weigh the different management Furthermore, I thank Sandra Bauske, Thomas Dörfler, Moritz Drupp,
options or criteria against each other. Furthermore, they do not see Malin Elsen, Alejandro Esguerra, Joshua Farley, Heiko Gerlach, Tom
knowledge as uncertain and hardly bring up the idea of an economic Green, Stefan Meissner, Susanne Offen, Ming-Fai Pang, Taylor Ricketts,
valuation. These last two results show a great contradiction between Astrid Sauermann, Mandy Schulze, Anne Winkler and the participants
disciplinary and students' approaches. They hint at the need to both of the 2015 Degöb conference for helpful comments.
carefully consider basic scientific results from ecology, as well as to be
aware that ESAV might not be an intuitive approach, even for eco- Funding
nomics students.
Based on students' preconceptions and core contents from the dis- This work was supported by the German Federal Ministry of
cipline, I suggested a short ESAV curriculum, which goes beyond the Education through a PhD scholarship of the Hans-Böckler foundation.

Appendix A. Scenarios on Ecosystem Service Valuation and Assessment

Topic Stimuli (German) Stimuli (English Translation)

Forest Stellt Euch eine recht waldreiche Insel vor. In den letzten Jahren Think of a densely wooded island. In the last years, many trees
sind auf der Insel viele Bäume gefällt worden. Einige Bewohner der have been cut on the island. Some of the inhabitants of the island
Insel finden man sollte so weiter machen, andere finden die Bäume think one should continue with that, others believe the trees
sollten geschützt werden und viele sind noch unentschlossen. Stellt should be protected and many are still undecided. Imagine the
Euch nun vor, die Inselbewohner würden Euch fragen: “Wie sollen inhabitants of the island asked you: “How should we decide?”
wir uns entscheiden?” Was würdet Ihr ihnen raten und warum? What would you advise them to do and why?
Sea Wie Ihr vielleicht wisst, gibt es gerade an vielen Orten eine As you might know, in many places, there is a discussion, whether
Diskussion darüber, ob Windkraftanlagen vor den Küsten gebaut wind turbines should be built off the coast. Imagine, a town by the
werden sollten. Stellt Euch nun vor, ein Ort an der Nordsee darf North Sea may decide itself, whether a wind farm is constructed off
selbst entscheiden, ob so ein Windpark vor “seiner” Küste “its” coast. Some of the inhabitants of the town think this is a good
eingerichtet wird. Einige Bewohner des Ortes finden das gut, andere idea, others are against it and many are still undecided. If the
sind dagegen und viele sind noch unentschlossen. Wenn Euch nun

432
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

die Bewohner fragen würden: “Wie sollen wir uns entscheiden?” inhabitants asked you: “How should we decide?” What would you
Was würdet Ihr ihnen raten und warum? advise them to do and why?
City Eine Stadt überlegt, neue Bauflächen auszuweisen. Einige finden das A town considers approving new construction areas. Some think,
gut, andere sind dagegen, und viele sind noch unentschlossen. Wenn this is a good idea, others are against it, and many are still
nun von den Gesetzen her beides möglich wäre und Euch die undecided. If the laws allowed following both options and the
Bewohner der Stadt fragen würden: “Wie sollen wir uns inhabitants of the city asked you: “How should we decide?” What
entscheiden?” Was würdet Ihr ihnen raten und warum? would you advise them to do and why?

References Gollier, C., Jullien, B., Treich, N., 2000. Scientific progress and irreversibility: an eco-
nomic interpretation of the ‘precautionary principle. J. Public Econ. 75, 229–253.
Harring, N., Davies, P., Lundholm, C., 2017. Learning economics and attitudes to market
Anderson, L.W., Krathwohl, D.R., 2001. A Taxonomy for Learning, Teaching, and solutions to environmental problems. Educ. Sci. 7, 1–15.
Assessing: A Revision of Bloom's Taxonomy of Educational Objectives. Longman, Hess, D.E., 2009. Controversy in the Classroom: The Democratic Power of Discussion.
New York. Routledge, New York.
Arrow, K.J., Cropper, M.L., Eads, G.C., Hahn, R.W., Lave, L.B., Noll, R.G., Portney, P.R., Hoepner, A.G., Kant, B., Scholtens, B., Yu, P.-S., 2012. Environmental and ecological
Russell, M., Schmalensee, R., Smith, V.K., Stavins, R.N., 1996. Is There a Role for economics in the 21st century: an age adjusted citation analysis of the influential
Benefit-Cost Analysis in Environmental, Health, and Safety Regulation? Science- articles, journals, authors and institutions. Ecol. Econ. 77, 193–206.
AAAS-Weekly Paper Edition 272. pp. 221–222. Ignell, C., Davies, P., Lundholm, C., 2017. Understanding ‘price’ and the environment:
Bator, F.M., 1958. The anatomy of market failure. Q. J. Econ. 72, 351–379. exploring upper secondary students' conceptual development. J. Soc. Sci. Educ. 16,
Baumgärtner, S., Dyckhoff, H., Faber, M., Proops, J., Schiller, J., 2001. The concept of 68–80.
joint production and ecological economics. Ecol. Econ. 36, 365–372. Kaiser, T., Birke, F., Lutter, A., 2015. Schülerkonzepte zu ordnungspolitischen Fragen.
Birke, F., Seeber, G., 2012. Lohnunterschiede im Schülerverständnis: eine Eine phänomenographische Untersuchung [Students' conceptions on regulatory
phänomenographische Untersuchung [Student understandings of wage differences: a policy. A phenomenographic inquiry]. Zeitschrift für Didaktik der
phenomenographic inquiry]. In: Retzmann, T. (Ed.), Entrepreneurship und Gesellschaftswissenschaften, Schwerpunktheft ‘Ordnung’ 6, 92–110.
Arbeitnehmerorientierung. Leitbilder und Konzepte für die ökonomische Bildung in Kallis, G., Gómez-Baggethun, E., Zografos, C., 2013. To value or not to value? That is not
der Schule [Entrepreneurship and Employee Orientation. General Orientation and the question. Ecol. Econ. 94, 97–105.
Concepts for Economic Education in School]. Wochenschau Verlag, Schwalbach/Ts, Kareiva, P., Tallis, H., Ricketts, T.H., Daily, G.C., Polasky, S., 2011. Natural Capital:
pp. 223–237. Theory and Practice of Mapping Ecosystem Services. Oxford University Press, Oxford,
Bishop, R.C., 1978. Endangered species and uncertainty: the economics of a safe New York.
minimum standard. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 60, 10–18. Karpe, J., 1998. Zur Integration ökonomischen Wissens in eine europäische
Bohnsack, R., 2004. Group discussion and focus groups. In: Flick, U., von Kardoff, E., Umweltbildung [On the integration of economic knowledge in a European environ-
Steinke, I. (Eds.), A Companion to Qualitative Research. Sage, London, pp. 210–221. mental education]. In: Kruber, K.P. (Ed.), Europa – Herausforderung für die
Bohnsack, R., 2010. Documentary Method and Group Discussions. In: Bohnsack, R., Pfaff, ökonomische Bildung [Europe – Challenges for Economic Education]. Thomas
N., Weller, W. (Eds.), Qualitative Analysis and Documentary Method in International Holbein, Bergisch-Gladbach, pp. 107–136.
Educational Research. Babara Budrich, Opladen, pp. 99–124. Knight, F.H., 1921. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Univ. of Chicago Press, Chicago [u. a.].
Bybee, R.W., 1997. Achieving Scientific Literacy: From Purposes to Practices. Heinemann Krol, G.-J., 2001. Environmental problems, morals and incentives in modern societies. In:
Education Books, Portsmouth, NH. Tolba, M.K. (Ed.), Our Fragile World: Challenges and Opportunities for Sustainable
Carlson, J.A., Velenchik, A.D., 2006. Using the Case Method in the Economics Classroom. Development. Encyclopedia of Life Support Systems, Oxford, pp. 973–982.
In: Becker, W., Becker, S., Watts, M. (Eds.), Teaching Economics: More Alternatives to Lamnek, S., 2005. Gruppendiskussion: Theorie und Praxis [Group Discussions: Theory
Chalk and Talk. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp. 59–74. and Practice], 2nd ed. Beltz, Weinheim [u. a.].
Caruso, E.M., Vohs, K.D., Baxter, B., Waytz, A., 2013. Mere exposure to money increases Liu, S., Costanza, R., Farber, S., Troy, A., 2010. Valuing ecosystem services. Ann. N. Y.
endorsement of free-market systems and social inequality. J. Exp. Psychol. Gen. 142, Acad. Sci. 1185, 54–78.
301. Lo, M.L., Marton, F., Pang, M.-F., Pong, W.Y., 2004. Toward a Pedagogy of Learning. In:
Castro e Silva, M., Teixeira, A.A.C., 2011. A bibliometric account of the evolution of EE in Marton, F., Tsui, A.B.M. (Eds.), Classroom Discourse and the Space of Learning, New
the last two decades: is ecological economics (becoming) a post-normal science? Ecol. Jersey, pp. 189–225.
Econ. 70, 849–862. Löw Beer, D., 2016a. (How) should prices be adjusted to reflect the environmental harm
Costanza, R., Daly, H., 1992. Natural capital and sustainable development. Conserv. Biol. of products? – teacher trainees' understanding of an eco-economic phenomenon.
6, 37–46. Zeitschrift für ökonomische Bildung 5, 50–71.
Costanza, R., Cumberland, J.H., Daly, H., Goodland, R., Norgaard, R.B., Kubiszewski, I., Löw Beer, D., 2016b. Ökonomische Bildung für eine nachhaltige Entwicklung. Eine
Franco, C., 2015. An Introduction to Ecological Economics. CRC Press, Boca Raton, phänomenographische Untersuchung in der Lehrerinnenbildung [economic educa-
London, New York. tion for a sustainable development. A Phenomenographic Inquiry in Teacher
Dahlgren, L.O., Marton, F., 1978. Students' conceptions of subject matter: an aspect of Training]. Barbara Budrich, Leverkusen.
learning and teaching in higher education. Stud. High. Educ. 3, 25–35. Lundholm, C., 2007. ‘Pricing nature at what price?’ A study of undergraduate students'
Daly, H., Farley, J., 2010. Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications, 2nd ed. conceptions of economics. South. Afr. J. Environ. Educ. 24, 126–140.
Island Press, Washington. Ma, C., Stern, D.I., 2006. Environmental and ecological economics: a citation analysis.
Davies, P., Lundholm, C., 2012. Students' understanding of socio-economic phenomena: Ecol. Econ. 58, 491–506.
conceptions about the free provision of goods and services. J. Econ. Psychol. 33, Mangold, W., 1960. Gegenstand und Methode des Gruppendiskussionsverfahrens [Subject
79–89. and Method of the Group Discussion Procedure]. Europäische Verlagsanstalt,
Davies, P., Howie, H., Mangan, J., Telhaj, S., 2002. Economic aspects of citizenship Frankfurt am Main.
education: an investigation of students' understanding. Curric. J. 13, 201–223. Martinez-Alier, J., Munda, G., O'Neill, J., 1998. Weak comparability of values as a
De Haan, G., 2006. The BLK ‘21’programme in Germany: a ‘Gestaltungskompetenz’-based foundation for ecological economics. Ecol. Econ. 26, 277–286.
model for education for sustainable development. Environ. Educ. Res. 12, 19–32. Marton, F., 1981. Phenomenography - describing conceptions of the world around us.
Edward-Jones, G., Davies, B., Hussain, S., 2004. Ecological Economics. An Introduction. Instr. Sci. 10, 177–200.
Blackwell Science Ltd., Malden [u. a.]. Marton, F., 2015. Necessary Conditions of Learning. Routledge, New York, London.
Epstein, L.G., 1980. Decision making and the temporal resolution of uncertainty. Int. Marton, F., Booth, S., 1997. Learning and Awareness. L. Erlbaum Associates,
Econ. Rev. 21, 269–283. Mahwah, N.J.
Errington, E., 1997. Role-play. Higher Education Research and Development Society of Marton, F., Pang, M.F., 2008. The idea of phenomenography and the pedagogy of con-
Australasia Inc, Canberra. ceptual change. In: Vosniadou, S. (Ed.), International Handbook of Research on
Evans, T.L., 2011. Living and Learning Sustainability: Pedagogy and Praxis in Conceptual Change. Routledge, New York, pp. 533–559.
Sustainability Education. Prescott College. Marton, F., Pang, M.F., 2013. Meanings are acquired from experiencing differences
Farley, J., 2010. The role of prices in conserving critical natural capital. Conserv. Biol. 22, against a background of sameness, rather than from experiencing sameness against a
1399–1408. background of difference: putting a conjecture to the test by embedding it in a
Farrell, K.N., 2007. Living with living systems: the co-evolution of values and valuation. pedagogical tool. Front. Learn. Res. 1, 24–41.
Int J Sust Dev World 14, 14–26. Marton, F., Pong, W.Y., 2005. On the unit of description in phenomenography. High.
Frey, B.S., Oberholzer-Gee, F., 1997. The cost of price incentives: an empirical analysis of Educ. Res. Dev. 24, 335–348.
motivation crowding-out. Am. Econ. Rev. 87, 746–755. Marton, F., Tsui, A.B.M., 2004. Classroom Discourse and the Space of Learning. Lawrence
Georgescu-Roegen, N., 1971. The Law of Entropy and the Economic Process. Harvard Erlbaum, New Jersey, pp. 256.
University Press, Cambridge. Mayring, P., 2014. Qualitative Content Analysis: Theoretical Foundation, Basic
Gibson, H., 2008. Ideology, instrumentality and economics education: on the secretion of Procedures and Software Solution, Klagenfurt.
values within philanthropy, financial capability and enterprise education in English Mullis, I.V.S., Martin, M.O., 2013. Timms 2015 assessment frameworks. In: International
schools. Int. Rev. Econ. Educ. 7, 57–78. Association for the Evaluation of Educational Achievement, I. TIMSS & PIRLS

433
D. Löw Beer Ecological Economics 146 (2018) 425–434

International Study Center, Lynch School of Education, Boston College. diverse trail. Environ. Values 17, 259–284.
OECD, 2016. PISA 2015 assessment and analytical framework. In: Science, Reading, Speer, S., Seeber, G., 2013. Financial understanding: a Phenomenographic access to
Mathematic and Financial Literacy. OECD Publishing, Paris. students' concepts of credits. J. Soc. Sci. Educ. 12, 41–51.
Pang, M.-F., 2010. Boosting financial literacy: benefits from learning study. Instr. Sci. 38, TEEB, 2010a. In: Sukhdev, P. (Ed.), The Economics of Ecosystem & Biodiversity.
659–677. Earthscan, London, New York.
Pang, M.-F., Linder, C., Fraser, D., 2006. Beyond lesson studies and design experi- TEEB, 2010b. The Economics of Ecosystem & Biodiversity. TEEB for Business. Earthscan,
ments–using theoretical tools in practice and finding out how they work. Int. Rev. London, New York.
Econ. Educ. 5, 28–45. TEEB, 2010c. In: Berghöfer, A. (Ed.), The Economics of Ecosystem & Biodiversity. TEEB
Perman, R., Ma, Y., Common, M.S., Maddison, D., McGilvray, J., 2011. Natural Resource Manual for Cities: Ecosystem Services in Urban Management. Earthscan, London,
and Environmental Economics, 4th ed. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow, New New York.
York. Ten Dam, G., Volman, M., 2004. Critical thinking as a citizenship competence: teaching
Pollock, F., 1955. Gruppenexperiment [Group Experiment]. Europäische Verlags-Anstalt, strategies. Learn. Instr. 14, 359–379.
Frankfurt. Tietenberg, T.H., Lewis, L., 2016. Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, 10th
Pong, W.-Y., 1999. In: The Dynamics of Awareness. 8th European Conference for Learning ed. Routledge, London; New York.
and Instruction. EARLI, pp. 1–12. Torney-Purta, J., Lehmann, R., Oswald, H., Schulz, W., 2001. Citizenship and Education
Prenzel, M., Rost, J., Senkbeil, M., Häußler, P., Klopp, A., 2001. Naturwissenschaftliche in twenty-eight Countries: Civic Knowledge and Engagement at Age Fourteen. IEA,
Grundbildung: Testkonzeption und Ergebnisse [Basic Science Education. Test Amsterdam.
Conception an Results]. In: PISA-Konsortium, D., Baumert, J., Klieme, E., Neubrand, UNESCO, 2005. Literacy for Life. Education for All. Global Monitoring Report 2006.
M., Prenzel, M., Schiefele, U., Schneider, W., Stanat, P., Tillmann, K.-J., Weiß, M. United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization, Paris.
(Eds.), PISA 2000: Basiskompetenzen von Schülerinnen und Schülern im inter- United Nations, U., 2005. Milennium Ecosystem Assesment: Global Assessment Report.
nationalen Vergleich [PISA 2000: Basic Competencies of Students in Intenational Island Press, Washington, DC.
Comparison]. VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, Wiesbaden, pp. 191–248. Vatn, A., Bromley, D.W., 1994. Choices without prices without apologies. J. Environ.
Schröter, M., Zanden, E.H., Oudenhoven, A.P., Remme, R.P., Serna-Chavez, H.M., Groot, Econ. Manag. 26, 129–148.
R.S., Opdam, P., 2014. Ecosystem services as a contested concept: a synthesis of Vohs, K.D., Mead, N.L., Goode, M.R., 2008. Merely activating the concept of money
critique and counter-arguments. Conserv. Lett. 7, 514–523. changes personal and interpersonal behavior. Curr. Dir. Psychol. Sci. 17, 208–212.
Schug, M.C., 1997. Teaching the economics of the environment. Citiz. Soc. Econ. Educ. 2, Wegner, G., Pascual, U., 2011. Cost-benefit analysis in the context of ecosystem services
47–55. for human well-being: a multidisciplinary critique. Glob. Environ. Chang. 21,
Schulz, W., Ainley, J., Fraillon, J., Kerr, D., Losito, B., 2010. ICCS 2009 International 492–504.
Report: Civic Knowledge, Attitudes, and Engagement among Lower-Secondary School Weinbrenner, P., 1997. Plädoyer für eine “zukunftsfähige” ökonomische Bildung
Students in 38 Countries. IEA, Amsterdam. [Pleading for a ‘sustainable’ economic education]. In: Kruber, K.-P., Breier, K.-H.
Seeber, G., 2001. Ökologische Ökonomie: Eine kategorialanalytische Einführung (Eds.), Konzeptionelle Ansätze ökonomischer Bildung [Conceptional Approaches for
[Ecological Economics: An Introductory Categorial Analysis]. Dt. Univ.-Verl, Economic Education]. Thomas Hobein, Bergisch Gladbach, pp. 225–262.
Wiesbaden. Wunder, S., 2005. Payments for Environmental Services: Some Nuts and Bolts. CIFOR
Seeber, G., Birke, F., 2011. Using a fox to guard the geese? A German debate on the Jakarta, Indonesia.
purposes of economic education in relation to sustainability and the role of values. Zohar, A., Nemet, F., 2002. Fostering students' knowledge and argumentation skills
Citiz. Soc. Econ. Educ. 10, 170–181. through dilemmas in human genetics. J. Res. Sci. Teach. 39, 35–62.
Spash, C.L., 2008. How much is that ecosystem in the window? The one with the bio-

434

Вам также может понравиться