Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 13

Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269

Transaction Cost Theory and International Business


Jean-François Hennart
CentER and Department of Organization and Strategy, Tilburg University, P.O. Box 90153, 5000LE Tilburg, The Netherlands

Abstract
I discuss the cross-fertilization between transaction cost theory (TCT) and international business (IB), showing how TCT provides a powerful
lens to study the institutions that organize international interdependencies, and especially multinational enterprises (MNEs). I then discuss some
of the insights that IB can provide for the further development of TCT. I argue that a full explanation of why MNEs exist must rely on information
asymmetry as well as asset specificity, and that the study of modes of foreign market entry leads to alternative viewpoints on equity joint ventures
and hybrids. I conclude by stressing the need for a simultaneous consideration of market transaction costs and internal organization costs when
examining governance choices.
© 2010 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Transaction cost theory; International business; Multinational enterprises; Global value chains; Hybrids; Equity joint ventures

It is fair to say that neoclassical economics proceeds on In this piece I discuss the cross-fertilization between transac-
the assumption that the ‘organization problem’, how individ- tion cost theory (TCT) and IB. The article has two parts. In the
uals find ways to cooperate so as to benefit from pooling their first I sketch how TCT has provided a powerful lens to look at
joint efforts and from exploiting their differences, has already the IB core topic, the institutional arrangements used to organize
been solved. Oliver Williamson’s major achievement has been interdependencies between agents located in different countries,
to transform this assumption into a research question by ask- and in particular the multinational enterprise (MNE). In the sec-
ing what mechanisms are and should be used by individuals to ond part I discuss some of the insights that IB might provide for
solve the ‘organization problem’, that is to communicate their the further development of TCT.
needs and capabilities, to reach agreement on the terms of trade, The first section of the first part presents a brief history of
and to make sure their bargains are respected ex-post. By asking how TCT gained influence among IB scholars because it could
the question and advancing testable hypotheses, Williamson’s provide a persuasive explanation for the existence and the scope
writings have spawned exciting research in a wide range of dis- of MNEs, which are central actors in IB. In the next section
ciplines, from sociology to finance. It is only fitting that this I show how TCT is able to provide a unifying paradigm that
tremendous achievement be crowned with a Nobel Memorial accounts for the many diverse forms taken by MNE activities.
Prize. The second part follows up on a few of the research oppor-
As the next pages show, the assumption of zero transaction tunities that are suggested in the first part. In the first section
costs that is implicit in neoclassical economics is particularly of the second part I argue that a persuasive account of the role
constraining in international business (IB). IB scholars study the played by MNEs in the international economy cannot only rely
governance of interdependencies between individuals located in on asset specificity but often requires recourse to information
different countries, and hence separated by geographic, institu- asymmetry and imperfect measurement arguments. The second
tional, and cultural distance. Organizing such interdependencies section looks at equity joint ventures and various contractual
is difficult given the lack of information caused by physical sep- arrangements which have played an important part in the coor-
aration, communication and cultural difficulties which make dination of international interdependencies. While these two
reaching agreement problematic, and uncertain enforcement forms have often been lumped together and labeled ‘hybrids’,
given that transactors are subject to different political jurisdic- I show that they are very different. Equity joint ventures are
tions. joint hierarchy, not hybrids of market and hierarchy. Hybrids,
on the other hand, are institutions that can be seen as simultane-
ously using the two basic organizing methods of output control
E-mail address: j.f.hennart@uvt.nl. and behavior control. In the last section I stress the importance

0022-4359/$ – see front matter © 2010 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jretai.2010.07.009
258 J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269

of simultaneous considering market transaction costs and inter- sectors, such as oil, motor vehicles, business machinery, and
nal organization costs when explaining international governance tires. This led him to argue that FDI should be understood as an
choices. attempt by homegrown monopolists to safeguard their monopoly
profits. When a reduction in international trade barriers brought
The contribution of transaction cost theory to international domestic and foreign monopolists in competition, domestic
business: the genesis monopolists attempted to take over or merge with their foreign
rivals, or to set up production in foreign countries to pre-empt
The institutional arrangements used to organize the interna- the emergence of such rivals. Through these strategies, domestic
tional interdependencies which IB scholars study can be purely monopolists expanded across borders and became MNEs. Hence
market-based, for example arm’s length exports using indepen- MNEs arose to reduce competition in final product markets in
dent distributors. They can use hierarchical processes, when industries where large barriers to entry had created and were
exchange takes place within MNEs, firms that coordinate activ- sustaining local monopolies. MNEs were institutions devised to
ities across borders through employment contracts. Or they can internalize the pecuniary externalities caused by imperfections
be hybrids of both market and hierarchy, and take the form of in the market for final products. These imperfections resulted
contracts, as happens in licensing, franchising and in the orga- from barriers to entry and government intervention, i.e. they
nization of many vertical value chains. were what Dunning and Rugman (1985) later called structural
MNEs are a relatively recent phenomenon. In the 1850s market imperfections. Internalizing pecuniary externalities due
and 1860s firms such as Singer Sewing Machines and Siemens to structural market imperfections is a zero-sum game in which
started to establish foreign factories. The trend picked up con- firms gain at the expense of consumers. Hymer thus concluded
siderable speed in the 1880s, slowed down during the Great that MNEs reduced competition, and hence that their activities
Depression, but then started again after the end of WW2, led should be severely restricted by governments. Hymer’s view of
initially by US MNEs, and then by those of Europe and Asia MNEs as exploiting abroad their monopolistic advantages was
(Jones 2005). popularized by Kindleberger (1969) and further developed by
The existence and growth of MNEs was left unexplained Caves (1971).
until the late 1970s because it fit very awkwardly with extant There is a subtle, but important difference between Hymer’s
economic theories. International trade theories assumed perfect view of MNEs internalizing pecuniary externalities due to struc-
mobility of products but perfect immobility of factors, yet the tural market imperfections in the market for final products
international expansion of firms involved the international trans- and the transaction cost view that sees firms as internalizing
fer of factors of production such as knowledge and managerial non-pecuniary externalities due to natural imperfections in the
talent. More fundamentally, the economist’s world was one of market for intermediate products (Dunning and Rugman 1985;
zero transaction costs. In such a world, MNEs are a paradox. Hennart 1982). Natural market imperfections arise because
It is generally acknowledged that doing business in a foreign agents are boundedly rational and opportunistic (Williamson
country involves additional costs over those incurred at home 1975), and this means that exchange always entails posi-
(Hymer 1976). In the absence of market transaction costs, the tive transaction costs. When the rents available from market
costs of transferring factors of production such as knowledge exchange are lower than those available from organizing the
and reputation to a foreign buyer through market processes are transaction within a firm, the MNE will expand abroad to inter-
negligible. Then why would a firm ever prefer integrating into nalize these non-pecuniary externalities (Hennart 1977, 1982).
the foreign production of goods and services incorporating its This is a positive sum game which generates rents to be shared
know-how, with all its attendant difficulties, over licensing or by producers and consumers.
franchising foreign manufacturers? Sixteen years after Hymer came the 1976 publication of
If you cannot explain what you see, see what you can explain. Buckley and Casson’s The Future of Multinational Enterprise,
When they looked at MNEs, trade economists of the time and its further development by Rugman in Inside the Multina-
saw long-term capital exports, which they called foreign direct tionals (1981). Buckley and Casson’s book, which was inspired
investment (FDI) and which in their view only differed from by Coase (1937) and by the interwar debate on the feasibil-
portfolio investments insofar as it carried control. They argued ity of using prices for central planning (Lange 1936), makes
that FDI, along with portfolio investment, flowed between coun- no reference to Williamson. Buckley and Casson argue that
tries in response to difference in real interest rates. This view MNEs are more efficient than markets because they use inter-
was not questioned until Stephen Hymer’s 1960 PhD thesis, nal prices. Using internal prices has particular advantages for
published in 1976 (Hymer 1976). Hymer looked at the foreign transferring knowledge because it makes it possible to apply
activities of US MNEs and asked why, if as alleged by FDI the- discriminatory pricing across markets, to sidestep government
orists they were undertaken in response to higher interest rates restrictions through transfer pricing, and to replace failing future
abroad than in the US, they were to a significant degree financed markets. Hence Buckley and Casson see MNEs as internaliz-
in the foreign countries where US MNEs did business. He also ing both pecuniary externalities through price discrimination
noted that US flows of FDI and portfolio investment often moved and the avoidance of taxes, and non-pecuniary externalities
in opposite direction. He asked why US FDI was undertaken by through the establishment of internal prices. These benefits have
industrial firms and not by banks and financial intermediaries, to be offset by the costs of setting up internal markets, which
and why it was concentrated in a small number of industrial are a loss of scale economies due to their smaller size and a
J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269 259

need to do on-the-spot inspections (Buckley and Casson 1976, pendence will incur information, bargaining, and enforcement
pp. 36–45). costs, i.e. transaction costs. There are two basic organizing meth-
The first application of TCT to the MNE was made by Hen- ods that can be used to perform that task, the price system and
nart in his 1977 PhD thesis at the University of Maryland, later hierarchy, and each yields different levels of rents for a given
published in book form as A Theory of Multinational Enterprise transaction because they use fundamentally different methods.
(Hennart 1982). Hennart was inspired by Williamson (1975), Consider first the need for enforcement. The price system
McManus (1972), and by property rights and agency theories does it by rewarding agents for their output at market prices. With
(e.g. Alchian and Demsetz 1972; Arrow 1974; Cheung 1969). bounded rationality and opportunism, however, measuring out-
Buckley and Casson’s, Rugman’s, and Hennart’s books, fur- put will be both necessary and costly. If measurement is costly,
ther work by these authors and by others such as Teece (1981), it may not pay to do it perfectly, and hence it will be possible for
and the incorporation of this thinking in Dunning’s eclectic some agents to overprice or undersupply output, a behavior I call
theory, all combined to persuade the IB field that MNEs could be ‘cheating’ (Hennart 1982, 1993). Switching to hierarchy reduces
explained by looking at the comparative efficiency of firms and these incentives because under hierarchy agents (employees) are
markets in conducting international transactions. TCT was also no longer rewarded on the basis of their output but on the basis
used by Anderson and Gatignon (1986) (Gatignon and Anderson of their behavior, i.e. they are rewarded for obeying the boss’
1988), Gomes-Casseres (1989), Hennart (1982, 1988a, 1991a, directives (Hennart 1982, 1993; Masten 1988).2 Hennart (1986)
2009), Hennart and Park (1993), and many others to explain the argues that it is this switch from output-based to behavior-based
modes chosen by firms to enter foreign markets, that is the choice rewards, and not the setting up of an internal market in firms
between fully or partly owned affiliates (i.e. equity joint ven- as argued by Buckley and Casson (1976) and Rugman (1981),
tures) and that between greenfield entry and acquisitions. These that explains why firms can in some cases be more efficient than
approaches, which all take a comparative institutional perspec- markets in enforcing transactions. Replacing output by behavior
tive but diverge significantly in how they explain why MNEs constraints reduces the incentives that employees have to cheat
exist, were given the generic name of ‘internalization theory’. but the uncoupling of output and reward has the unfortunate, but
By 2009 John Dunning could write that “for much of the last two unavoidable, consequence of lowering their incentives to work,
decades. . .the theory of internalization. . .has been the dominant if work is less desirable than other pursuits. In other words,
explanation of the existence and growth of the MNE qua MNE” employees will exert less effort and initiative than if they were
(Dunning 2009, p. 44).1 self-employed, i.e. they will ‘shirk’.
There are two basic ways to constrain behavior. One, which
Can transaction cost theory explain the existence and scope can be called ‘internal control’, clan (Ouchi 1979), or socializa-
of MNEs? tion (Bartlett and Ghoshal 1989), consists in choosing employees
who have the same goals as the boss, or in persuading individu-
How does one explain the existence of MNEs and the scope als with different goals to change them and internalize those of
of their activities? This is the question Hennart tackled in his the boss. The second, ‘external control’, consists in constrain-
PhD thesis (1977). He argued that TCT could provide a pow- ing the agent’s behavior, either through direct observation or
erful answer. While he acknowledged that MNEs sometimes through bureaucratic rules and procedures. Because constrain-
internalized pecuniary externalities and hence were an alterna- ing behavior through either internal or external control is costly
tive to cartels or tacit collusion, he found it more interesting to and experiences diminishing returns, it will not generally pay to
focus on how they could internalize non-pecuniary externalities. fully do it. The cost of constraining behavior will vary with
This section, based on Hennart (1977, 1982, 2000), attempts to the characteristics of transactions. External control is easier
show that TCT provides a unifying paradigm that can explain when employees are gathered on location and behavior is a
the most common types of MNEs. good guide to performance, for example in machine-paced pro-
A firm may own manufacturing capacity and a distribution cesses, but harder when this is not the case, for example when
system in its home country, but may be looking for foreign tech- employees are spread out over space, as in extensive agricul-
nology to manufacture products that will complete its product ture, or in creative industries. Internal control is easier when
line. A foreign manufacturer may have already developed such employees share a similar culture and have other social ties
products and may be willing to license his technology to the local (Ouchi 1979).
firm. For this potentially fruitful cooperation to take place, both The analysis up to now has focused on enforcement costs,
parties must be aware of each other and of the potential gains but hierarchy and the price system also differ in the way they
of cooperating, they must be able to quickly settle on a price solve the information and bargaining problems. Prices fulfill
for the technology, and they must be assured that the terms of that role in markets. When the cost of measuring output in all
the transaction will be enforced. Because of bounded rationality
and opportunism, organizing this potentially lucrative interde- 2 Note that I use the term ‘hierarchy’ to describe a method of control, not

the managers who implement it in firms. As I argue below ‘firm’ is not the
same thing as ‘hierarchy’, and neither is ‘market’ equivalent to ‘price’. Prices
1 As Dunning note on the same page, there has been lately an attempt by the (output control) and hierarchy (behavior control) are organizing methods, while
resource-based view to provide an alternative explanation for the existence and markets and firms are institutions. Both institutions make use of both methods
development of MNEs. simultaneously, but markets use predominantly prices, and firms hierarchy.
260 J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269

of its relevant dimensions is high, prices will give inaccurate 1982).4 Innovating firms will expand into foreign manufacturing
signals, and it will pay to use a centralized system of managerial through the establishment of greenfield plants or the acquisition
directives rather than a decentralized system under which agents of local firms. The same logic explains why many types of tacit
react autonomously to price signals. Employees will be asked knowledge are difficult to obtain through in-licensing (Davies
to collect a small part of the needed information which will be 1977, 1993). If the needed tacit knowledge is embedded in for-
aggregated and synthesized by the boss and sent back to employ- eign firms, the knowledge-seeking firm will have to access it
ees for execution. Because employees do not directly benefit through the full or partial takeover of these foreign firms or
from the information they pass on, they will have fewer incen- through the establishment of greenfield joint ventures with them
tives than market participants to collect and transfer accurate (Hennart 1988a, 2009; Mowery, Oxley, and Silverman 1996).
information (Hennart 1993; Williamson 1975). The price sys- While most IB scholars have focused on firms going abroad
tem solves the bargaining problem by making prices exogenous, to exploit their knowledge, historians have noticed that this is
while hierarchy does it through fiat. not the only motivation for foreign expansion. Fieldhouse (1986,
An MNE will be the chosen method to internalize non- p. 25), for example, notes that MNEs ventured abroad for many
pecuniary externalities when organizing the interdependence of different reasons and that “motives for FDI [MNEs] were there-
agents located in different countries through hierarchy will result fore infinitely more complex than any unitary theory of the MNE
in higher rents than using prices and when the benefits of orga- could possibly comprehend, and had no necessary connection
nizing interdependencies net of their costs are positive.3 When to the internalization concept”. As the following pages show,
is this likely to be the case? Hennart argues that TCT can predict however, TCT can account for the wide variety of forms taken
which types of international interdependencies are likely to be by MNE expansion.
internalized by MNEs and that this explains the types of MNEs Reputation earned in one country is often valuable in another.
observed in practice. Just like know-how can be embedded in a patent, reputation can
be embedded into a trademark which can be rented if its unautho-
Knowledge and reputation rized use (counterfeiting) can be controlled and if free-riding by
trademark renters can be curbed. A trademark is a public good to
Internalization scholars have advanced that firms set up man- all those using it, and users can free-ride on the collective reputa-
ufacturing facilities abroad because this is the most efficient way tion of those using the trademark by selling trademarked output
to exploit their knowledge (Buckley and Casson 1976; Cantwell at less than advertised quality. If quality differences are costly to
1989; Magee 1977; Rugman 1981; Teece 1981). Following detect, and a significant fraction of the customers are non-repeat,
Arrow (1962), Hennart (1977, 1982) argues that imperfect prop- trademark users will have incentives to engage in this form of
erty rights in knowledge can be traced down to a fundamental cheating because only a small part of the reputation loss due to
problem of information asymmetry, insofar as sellers have better cheating will be borne by them. If sophisticated measurement
information than buyers on the content of the technology they methods were available that could instantly measure the impact
have developed, but cannot divulge it pre-purchase, since by the output of cheaters has on the reputation capital of all those
doing this they would be transferring their know-how to buyers sharing the trademark and immediately debit their bank account,
free of charge. Patent systems are supposed to solve this problem, then a simple trademark rental would be possible. Given that this
because they theoretically make it possible for inventors to make is beyond present measurement capabilities, the next best thing is
their knowledge public while keeping full property rights to it. a franchising contract by which franchisors specify some behav-
In practice patents suffer from significant limitations (Hennart ioral rules to be followed by trademark renters (franchisees) so
1982; Levin et al. 1987). Tacit knowledge cannot be written into as to limit their ability to reduce quality. If this is difficult to do,
patents, and hence cannot be patented. Patent enforcement is and if the reputation rents at risk are large, trademark owners
costly, and in many countries patent laws are weakly enforced. will have to integrate into the production of the products using
Knowledge interdependencies will be organized by licensing their trademark. Employees, paid a salary less related to outlet
contracts when knowledge can be described in patents, when profits, have fewer incentives to cheat, but higher incentives to
patents are easy to defend in court, and when they are strongly shirk. Everything else constant, MNEs will be chosen over fran-
enforced by public authorities (Arora and Fosfuri 2000; Caves, chising to organize international interdependencies involving
Crookell, and Killing 1982; Contractor 1984; Davidson and reputation when (a) counterfeiting can be curbed and the poten-
McFetridge 1984; Davies 1977). In the opposite case, typically tial rents from reputation are high; (b) it is relatively difficult
that of management or marketing know-how, high informa- to devise and enforce behavioral constraints that when followed
tion and enforcement costs will preclude contractual transfer. will assure a given level of output quality; and (c) it is rela-
Transfer within a firm may then be more efficient because the tively easy to control shirking by employees. Hence reputation
incentives facing sender and receiver of know-how are now to is generally exploited in-house in banking, advertising, man-
collaborate in the transfer, not to cheat each other (Hennart agement consulting, and high-level legal advice, sectors where

3 This is an important, but neglected, condition. At a given level of technology, 4 This advantage will be lost if the internal transferor and transferee of know-
some interdependencies are just too expensive to organize, whether by firms or how are put in separate profit centers and granted bonuses based on their units’
by markets (Hennart 1982). profits, as this may recreate the level of cheating found in markets.
J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269 261

behavioral rules that ensure output quality are difficult to spec- ponents, for example why car assemblers vertically integrate
ify and distribution is selective, while it is generally exploited into engine production but purchase other parts (Monteverde
through franchising in fast food, hotels, employment agencies, and Teece 1982).
car rental, and gasoline distribution, sectors where distribution The same considerations apply to the governance of interde-
is intensive and such behavior rules are easier to contractually pendencies between manufacturers, distributors, and retailers.
specify (Fladmoe-Lindquist and Jacque 2005; Hennart 1982, The effective distribution of products and services in for-
2000).5 eign market usually requires physical investments (warehouses,
inventories, repair facilities, transportation equipment) as well as
Global value chains intellectual ones (training salespeople to demonstrate and repair
the product). These tasks are usually performed by indepen-
Value chains, the successive tasks necessary for bringing a dent agents and/or distributors and interdependences between
product or service to market, become international when the manufacturing and distribution organized through market sale,
stages are located in different countries. Value chains can be for example by having manufacturers sell products to distrib-
organized on spot markets, within MNEs, or by various types utors which resell them to final consumers. In some specific
of contracts (Gereffi, Humphrey, and Sturgeon 2005). Of the cases, however, coordination through market sale or distribu-
three, contracts seem to be the most common (Campbell and tion contracts will be relatively less efficient than coordination
Parisotto 1995). Three conditions seem to lead to value chains through hierarchy and manufacturers will vertically integrate
being organized within an MNE: (1) their efficient functioning into wholesaling and/or retailing (or wholesalers and/or retail-
requires that some or all of the parties make transaction-specific ers will integrate into manufacturing). Such integration will
investments; (2) participants in the value chain can free ride on occur for the three reasons mentioned above. First, distrib-
each other because the separate impact of their output on the rep- utors may be reluctant to invest in physical or intellectual
utation of the product is difficult to assess; (3) timely exchange assets with low resale value outside the specific trading rela-
of tacit information between value chain participants is crucial tionship because such investments expose them to being held
but difficult to negotiate. For expository convenience, I start up (Williamson 1985). As in the case of raw materials, dis-
with the coordination of the upstream stages of value chains, tribution contracts can protect distributors, but only when the
that between raw materials, parts, manufacturing, and assem- environment is predictable. When this is not the case, integrating
bly stages, and then discuss the coordination of downstream manufacturing and distribution within an MNE is often the best
stages, that between manufacturing/assembly and wholesaling solution (Anderson and Coughlan 1987; Klein, Frazier, and Roth
and retailing. 1990). Singer Sewing Machine, for example, integrated into
The hierarchical coordination of flows of natural resources both domestic and foreign retailing in the 1850s because inde-
through MNEs has been a persistent feature of the international pendent agents were unwilling to make the transaction-specific
economy since the nineteenth century which saw the emergence investments that would maximize sales: they were unwilling to
of vertically integrated MNEs in oil, aluminum, bananas, and learn how to demonstrate the machines, to carry stocks, and
rubber. The efficient processing of some minerals requires facil- to finance the sale of what was then a new and costly prod-
ities which are optimized for a particular ore source (Hennart uct (Hennart 1982; Wilkins 1970). Second, the difficulty of
1988b; Stuckey 1983). Once built, the facilities are thus depen- separating the impact that manufacturers, distributors, and retail-
dent on a single ore seller. Spot ore purchases would then expose ers have on product quality accounts for vertical integration
processors to sellers jacking up the price ex-post if dependence in value chains for perishable goods (Williamson 1985). The
is not bilateral (they would risk being held up). If this is the case, quality of bananas, for example, depends on careful handling
processors will ask ore sellers to promise not to make unilateral at each stage, but it is difficult to know who is responsible
changes in the terms of trade. This, however, requires being able for bruised bananas by the time they are with the customer.
to anticipate all potential contingencies, a difficult task when Banana distribution also requires important transaction-specific
facilities are long-lived, and there is considerable non-indexable investments. These two reasons explain why banana distribu-
uncertainty. Then contracts provide only limited protection and tors integrated into banana transport and plantations in the last
vertical integration may be more efficient (Stuckey 1983; Franz, years of the 19th century (Read 1986; Litvak and Maule 1977;
Sternberg, and Strongman 1986). The preceding considerations Wilkins 1970). Third, successful sales are sometimes crucially
explain why MNEs internalize the international trade of cer- dependent on timely marketing feedback from retailers, but it
tain natural resources such as oil, bauxite, and certain types may be difficult for manufacturers to craft contracts that ade-
of tin ores (Hennart 1988b; Stuckey 1983; Teece 1976) and quately reward them for providing this tacit information. In
why assemblers integrate into the manufacture of some com- that case vertical integration may be efficient. The clothing
retailer Zara, for example, has vertically integrated into gar-
ment manufacture to respond more quickly to fashion trends
5 For some empirical evidence in a domestic context see for example Caves
(Tokatli 2008). Vertical integration between manufacturers, dis-
and Murphy (1976), Brickley and Dark (1987), Kidwell, Nygaard, and Silkoset tributors and retailers seems, however, to be more the exception
(2007) and Lafontaine and Shaw (2005). Franchisors can also be expected to
free-ride. They may collect money up-front by selling the right to franchise large
than the rule. In most cases the coordination between manufac-
territories, and then leave the business. To reassure franchisees that they will not turers and wholesalers/retailers takes the form of contracts by
act that way, most franchisors own some outlets. which the value chain participants agree to follow behavioral
262 J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269

rules imposed by a channel leader (who can be a manufacturer Conclusion


or a representative of a group of manufacturers, a wholesaler,
or a retailer) (Brown 1984; Menard 1996). To insure consistent IB scholars study the institutions used to organize interna-
quality, British supermarkets, for instance, have signed contracts tional economic interdependencies. Hence it is not surprising
with their African suppliers of fresh produce that specify how the that they have found TCT particularly useful. As the preced-
latter should grow their crops, process, and transport them. These ing pages show, TCT offers a persuasive explanation of why
contractual stipulations are enforced through on the spot inspec- and when MNEs are the most efficient institution to organize
tions, in some cases without prior notice (Dolan and Humphrey international interdependencies. The arguments used have relied
2000). on asset specificity, but also on information and measurement
costs. The analysis of the governance of international transac-
Finance tions also reveals the relative importance of two institutional
arrangements, equity joint ventures and contracts (Dolan and
Williamson’s (1988) view of debt and equity as alternative Humphrey 2000; Gereffi, Humphrey, and Sturgeon 2005), which
governance structures provides a powerful lens with which to have been labeled ‘hybrids’ in the TCT literature (Boerner
understand poorly understood MNE types. Lending is risky and Macher 2003; Kreps 1990; Menard 1996; Oxley 1997;
because the two parts of the transaction, providing funds and Williamson 1996). This relative importance of hybrids in the
being repaid, are not simultaneous, and because money is fun- international context may be due to the high cost of extend-
gible. The main safeguards available to lenders include lending ing hierarchical control over borders (Hennart 1991b). The next
(1) to borrowers they know; (2) to projects with which they are sections address these issues.
familiar and (3) when there is good collateral. Because geo-
graphic distance creates barriers to the flow of information, we
can predict that international lending will be restricted to a spe- Possible contribution of international business to
cific category of projects. Indeed the evidence shows that banks transaction cost theory
have limited their international lending to short-term loans on
receivables, while long-term lending has been typically to gov- Applying a theory to a new context is usually helpful in fur-
ernments, or to borrowers with good collateral such as land. thering its development, and IB is no exception. In the rest of
Whenever banks have deviated from this, as they did in the this article, I focus on a few of the many areas where I see IB
1970s, the results have been disastrous. One alternative to the making useful contributions to TCT. I will argue that applying
contractual exchange of financial funds across countries through TCT to IB suggests a broader conceptualization of transaction
international bank lending or international bonds is to organize costs, provides a better understanding of equity joint ventures
the interdependence between lenders and borrowers through and hybrids, and calls for more attention to the costs of using
hierarchical methods. This means that individuals with projects hierarchy to organize international interdependencies.
will self-finance and ask others to become co-owners in syndi-
cates, or that they will sell shares to the public at large on stock Beyond asset specificity
exchanges. This solution gives lenders better and more flexi-
ble control on the use of their funds and alleviates the tendency The analysis of the various types of international transactions
that borrowers have to take excessive risk (Jensen and Meckling that have been organized by MNEs shows that the concept of
1976; Williamson 1988). Internationally, the hierarchical trans- asset specificity, while useful to explain the hierarchical organi-
fer of capital has taken two main forms, an intermediated one zation of vertical value chains, may be insufficient to provide a
where MNEs based in capital-abundant countries borrow on full understanding of the internalization of capital flows, and of
their good name and use the funds to finance activities in that of knowledge and goodwill.
capital-poor ones, and an non-intermediated form, the ‘free- Williamson (1988) argues that the viability of lending hinges
standing company’ (Hennart 1994a, 1994b, 1998; Wilkins and on the extent to which collateral is asset specific. While it is
Schroeter 1998). Free-standing firms were the dominant type true that this an important factor, an explanation of the choice
of MNEs before 1914 and are still being formed today. They between debt and equity that would entirely rely on this concept
were single business operations, operating a single mine or a would play down the role of information asymmetry between
single plantation in a foreign country. They were domiciled in lenders and borrowers and that played by reputation in enforc-
the main equity markets, but had only a skeletal head office ing loan transaction. Lenders may lend if they have confidence
there. Their actual operations were in capital-poor countries, in the integrity and capabilities of borrowers, and a good under-
and in activities not widely understood and offering poor col- standing of their projects, even in the absence of good collateral.
lateral, then in mining and plantations, today in mining but Similarly, reputation effects may play an important role where
also in R&D-intensive activities such as biotechnology (Hennart recourse to court enforcement is not feasible and it may be
1994a, 1994b, 1998). TCT explains why these free-standing difficult to repossess collateral. This suggests that information
firms, often viewed by business historians and economists as asymmetry between lenders and borrowers may be as important
purely speculative or a by-product of colonial expansion (Casson as asset specificity in fostering hierarchical links between saving
1994), were in fact viable and long-lived business institutions and investment, a point made by Williamson (1975, pp. 141–49)
(Hennart 1994b). when explaining the efficiency of internal capital markets.
J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269 263

Similarly, explaining the choice between licensing and verti- The study of modes of foreign market entry suggests, how-
cal integration in terms of asset specificity does not seem to tell ever, that EJVs should not be seen as hybrids of market and
the whole story. While there is evidence that licensees and pur- hierarchy, but instead as joint hierarchy. Successful operation in
chasers of plant and equipment are often dependent on licensors a foreign market requires the bundling of non-location-bound
for help with troubleshooting the implementation of the licensed factors such as technological, marketing assets, and/or financial
technology, and hence are sometimes in a position to be held resources, and location-bound factors such as land, labor, dis-
up by licensors (Hennart 1989), arguing that asset specificity tribution networks, permits and licenses, and so forth. In Fig. 1
drives the choice between licensing and integration implies that I assume for simplicity that all these location-bound factors are
licensing contracts involve technology that is less transactor- held by a single local firm so that there are only two input suppli-
specific than that used in internal transfers. Yet one would ers, an MNE contributing knowledge and a local firm supplying
expect all licensees to make transaction-specific investments all the other factors of production needed for local production.
since licensing agreements usually involve patented innovations, What is the most efficient way to bundle them when their sale
and patented products and processes are unique, since novelty is subject to positive transaction costs, and specifically, who,
is a requirement for patenting. Arguments based on informa- of the MNE or the local firm, should hold title to the profits
tion asymmetry seem more persuasive. IB scholars have shown that will be generated by their joint effort? It can be argued
that newer and more tacit technologies, and those available from that the party who should receive title to the profits, i.e. who
only few sources, are transferred internally, whereas older and should be paid with what remains after the other factor owner
better known technologies tend to be licensed (Davidson and has received his ex ante contractually agreed payment, should be
McFetridge 1984; Davies 1977, 1993; Kogut and Zander 1993). the one whose contribution is the hardest to measure (Eswaran
The same argument seems also to apply to the international trans- and Kotwal 1985). The reason is that the residual claimant can
fer of reputation. There the choice between operating outlets be expected to self-monitor to maximize the output of the bun-
with employees vs. franchising them does not seem to be driven dle. In Fig. 1, I assume that the knowledge supplied by the MNE
by asset specificity, but, as we have seen, is better understood can be either explicit and patented knowledge whose transfer
as a tradeoff between the cost of curbing free-riding by fran- incurs low transaction costs (it is ‘easy to transact’ – column
chisees and that of monitoring employees (Brickley and Dark 1), or tacit and poorly protected, in which case its transfer will
1987; Fladmoe-Lindquist and Jacque 2005; Kidwell, Nygaard, incur high transaction costs (‘difficult to transact’ – column 2).
and Ragnhild 2007). Likewise, the package of factors of production owned by the
local firm can either be transferable at low transaction costs –
Equity joint ventures easy to transact (row 1) or at high transaction costs – difficult
to transact (row 2). This simple model predicts that when MNE
The general view in TCT is that equity joint ventures (EJVs) knowledge is easy to transfer but local factors are hard to transfer,
are hybrids, one of the three discrete governance structures the solution that will maximize total rents will consist in having
alongside market and hierarchy (Boerner and Macher 2003, p. the local firm hold the residual, and purchase MNE knowledge
5; Kreps 1990; Williamson 1991, p. 292). Oxley writes that the on the market (through licensing contracts, the purchase of cap-
EJV is “the classic form of hybrid organization” because it sits ital goods incorporating that knowledge, or the acquisition of
between markets and hierarchy in terms of incentive intensity, firms in which the knowledge is embedded). Likewise, when
administrative controls, and contract support. She argues that MNE knowledge is hard to transfer and local factors are easy to
“the intensity of incentives in a joint venture is not reduced to the acquire, the optimal solution will be to have the MNE purchase
same extent as in a fully integrated structure (since parties to the or rent the local factors held by the local firm (or purchase the
transaction retain a degree of autonomy)”. Administrative con- local firm) and keep the residual – the MNE will establish a
trols are also in-between markets and hierarchy because “. . .in greenfield wholly owned affiliate or fully acquire the local firm.
contrast to directives from senior management or the board of Whenever the market exchange of both the knowledge held by
directors in a fully integrated firm, the directives from joint the MNE and the local factors held by the local firm would incur
venture companies are subject to negotiation and compromise”. high transaction costs, the optimal solution is to give both parties
Lastly, because of the need for continued cooperation, the gov- a claim to the profits of the bundle. This results in a ‘residual
ernance of joint ventures is not characterized by classical control sharing agreements’ (Hennart 1988a, 2009) in which both input
law but “by the highly adjustable framework of ‘neoclassical’ suppliers share the profits and have joint decision rights over
or ‘relational contracting”’ (Oxley 1997, pp. 390–1). Consistent the venture. Greenfield EJVs, partial acquisitions, partnerships
with this view of EJVs as half-way between pure market and and sharecropping contracts are examples of residual sharing
pure hierarchy, Williamson (1991, p. 292) has argued that while agreements. Such arrangements will be efficient when giving
hierarchy is used when asset specificity is very high, and markets both parties medium incentives to both cheat and shirk is prefer-
when it is very low, EJVs and hybrids are used when it is at inter- able to giving strong incentives to one of the parties to cheat,
mediate levels. Consequently, some authors (e.g. Erramili and and the other to shirk, as would be the case if title to the prof-
Rao 1993) have modeled the choice between EJVs and wholly its was fully allocated to one of the parties. Hence EJVs are
owned affiliates as determined by the level of asset specificity, not chosen when transaction cost are at intermediate levels (for
with wholly owned operations chosen when asset specificity is example because asset specificity is at an intermediate level)
high and EJVs when it is lower. but when they are simultaneously high for two or more par-
264 J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269

Fig. 1. Optimal assignment of residual rights in foreign market entry. Source: Hennart (2009).

ties who are contributing complementary inputs. In that sense hierarchy, as an organizing method, does not reward agents on
joint ventures are not hybrids, they are hierarchy, albeit joint the basis of their output, but on the basis of their behavior.
hierarchy. Breaking the connection between output and rewards reduces
the incentives that agents have to cheat but also those they have
to maximize output, and hence the behavior of employees will
Hybrids
have to be monitored by their superiors. If imposing behav-
ior constraints also experiences diminishing returns, it will not
If EJVs are not hybrids, then what are hybrids? Carter and
pay to monitor or socialize employees to the point where shirk-
Hodgson note that “compared with vertical integration, there is
ing is reduced to zero, so the total enforcement costs of using
less of a consensus over the nature and causes of hybrid rela-
hierarchy (total shirking costs) will be those of curbing shirk-
tionships. Many empirical researchers regard the understanding
ing through monitoring and/or socialization, and the residual
of hybrid relationships as a major challenge and propose that
amount of shirking that will not be worth curbing.
Williamson’s transaction cost economics framework is inade-
Fig. 2, adapted from Hennart (1993), shows how the optimal
quate for this task. Many different phenomena are described
institution chosen will depend on the level of total enforcement
as hybrids, and what exactly constitutes a hybrid relationship
costs. Institutions are arrayed on the x-axis, and are defined by
is open to dispute” (Carter and Hodgson 2006, p. 468). Yet,
their mix of output and behavior constraints. The y-axis mea-
because hybrids play such an important role in organizing inter-
sures the level of enforcement costs, totalcheating costs, total
national interdependencies, understanding their nature is both
theoretically and empirically important.
A starting point for understanding hybrids might be to ask
why replacing a market transaction by a hierarchical one (i.e.
having a task taken from a contractor and given to an employee)
may increase the rents of organizing the interdependence. To
simplify, I will concentrate on enforcement costs and ignore
information and bargaining costs. As argued above, the price sys-
tem rewards agents for their output. Given opportunism, some
market participants may be incited to both undersupply the pos-
itive dimensions of output and to oversupply the negative ones,
i.e. to cheat. Market participants will thus have to invest in mea-
suring output. If measurement experiences diminishing returns,
perfect measurement will not be worthwhile. Total cheating
costs, which are the enforcement costs of using the price system,
will be the sum of measurement costs and the unavoidable level
or residual cheating due to imperfect measurement. The costlier
it is to measure all the relevant positive and negative dimensions
of output, the higher total cheating costs.
When cheating costs are high, switching the transaction to
hierarchy may increase rents. This is because, as argued above, Fig. 2. Organizing methods and institutions.
J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269 265

shirking costs, and their sum, total enforcement costs. The level 1987; Robertson and Anderson 1993; Wilkins 1970).6 In other
of total cheating costs for a given transaction is given by line CC . words, they are likely to cheat. A move to the right of M means
Consistent with the argument made above, CC falls as output a decrease in output incentives and an increase in behavior con-
incentives are loosened because this loosening reduces incen- straints, and hence a decrease in cheating but an increase in
tives to cheat. SS , the total level of shirking costs, rises as an shirking costs. Manufacturers may want to keep the benefits of
agent’s rewards is increasingly based on her behavior, since the output incentives and avoid turning reps into employees because
payoff to spend paid time to indulge in other pursuits increases it is costly to monitor the behavior of salaried salespeople, espe-
with the proportion of her income paid on a time-basis. The level cially if they do outside sales. On the other hand, they may want
of the CC and SS curves for a given transaction reflect how to control the more costly of the negative side effects caused
effective output measurement and monitoring of behavior are by output incentives. A solution is to have reps agree to fol-
at enforcing transactions. Fig. 2, for example, shows a transac- low some behavioral rules imposed by manufacturers. Pre-war
tion for which using only output measurement incurs lower total British manufacturers required their foreign reps to hold min-
enforcement costs than using only behavior constraints, but the imum levels of stocks, specified a minimum level of showing
opposite could be the case for other transactions. One assump- they had to do, and reserved the right to refuse orders, to moni-
tion of the graph is that behavior and output measurement are tor stocks and to inspect sales records (Nicholas 1983). Further
substitutes. In other words, it is not efficient to both increase out- increases in behavior constraints imposed on reps are likely,
put and behavior constraints at the same time. This assumption however, to reduce their incentive to generate sales, as they
is discussed below. The non-linearity of the CC and SS curves will balk at having their behavior constrained by manufactur-
reflects the assumption that each organizing method experiences ers while they alone bear the negative earnings consequences of
diminishing returns as it is applied more intensively. Point M such constraints. At some point they will resist the imposition of
corresponds to the economist’s view of pure markets, that is full additional behavior constraints and will demand a base salary in
output incentives and zero behavior constraints. At point M total addition to their commission, i.e. they ask to become employees.
shirking costs (given by line SS ) are zero, while total cheating This salary plus commission package, represented by point B,
costs (given by line CC ) are at their maximum. Point H cor- will therefore be optimal if both measuring output and constrain-
responds to a purely hierarchical firm, where agents are fully ing behavior experience diminishing returns. If price incentives
rewarded on the basis of their behavior, and hence where cheat- result in very high cheating costs, and if shirking is relatively
ing costs are zero while shirking costs are at their maximum. easy to control, then the manufacturing firm will use employees
Point T corresponds to a mix of output and behavior constraints paid a straight salary (point H). For example, a firm which wants
that is biased towards output incentives. As I argue below, con- its salespeople to use low-pressure, expertise-based sales tactics
tracts are examples of this type of institutions insofar as they may find that obtaining this by contract is next to impossible
include hierarchical elements in what are still basically market due to the difficulty of defining and measuring behavioral rules
relationships (Stinchcombe 1985). Point B corresponds to a mix on which both parties can agree, and that fully constraining and
of output and behavior constraints biased towards behavior con- rewarding behavior through an employment contract is more
straints, for example an employment contract with significant efficient.7
output-related rewards (piece work, bonuses, and commissions). While it is important to keep it mind that it only focuses
The institution chosen for a given transaction will be the one that on enforcement, and neglects differences in how the price sys-
uses the mix of output and behavior constraints that yields the tem and hierarchy solve the information problem, the model
lowest level of total enforcement costs, which are the sum of presented above has a number of implications that are sup-
total cheating and total shirking costs. Fig. 2 corresponds to ported by the empirical evidence. First, it predicts that the share
the situation where the most efficient institution is a contract of salary (behavior-related pay) in a salesperson’s total com-
because the increase in total shirking costs that would accom- pensation package should be higher the more important the
pany the imposition of additional behavior constraints would hard-to-measure dimensions of output, such as demonstration
be higher than the reduction in cheating costs such a move and service, and the easier it is to monitor behavior. John and
would accomplish. Weitz (1989) found that the share of salary in total compensation
Personal selling, for example, can be obtained from indepen- was higher when what was expected of salespeople went beyond
dent agents called manufacturer representatives (reps) or from making sales, specifically when salespeople spent more time on
salaried employees. Reps are independent contractors paid com- non-selling activities, when customers had higher information
missions on the sales they make. They have strong incentives to needs, and when output measures (sales and costs) were deemed
maximize sales, and usually achieve higher sales than employ-
ees, but at the expense of those aspects of their output which are
not measured. Hence even though they may be asked to provide 6 Unless they are selling to return customers and are in the business for the

demonstration, instruction, after-sales service, and to truthfully long term.


7 The defining characteristic of the employment contract is that employees are
represent product characteristics and the extent to which they
fit the needs of their customers, the model would predict that rewarded on the basis of appropriate behavior, and this also applies to salaried
salespersons. The most common criteria used by sales managers to evaluate their
reps rewarded on sales are more likely to provide less of these subordinates were (in descending order): attitude, product knowledge, selling
ancillary services and to be less than fully honest in their repre- skills, appearance and manners, and tied for the last place, communication skills
sentations to customers (Anderson 1988; Anderson and Oliver and sales volume (Jackson, Keith, and Schlacter 1983).
266 J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269

by supervisors to be poor measures of performance. These find- distribution contracts, stipulate detailed behavioral rules growers
ings were supported by Krafft, Albers, and Lal (2004), who also must follow (Dolan and Humphrey 2000).
found that reps were used when travel requirement were high (i.e. We have seen that firms can impose behavioral constraints
when their behavior was harder to monitor). Anderson (1985) through both external means (setting up behavioral rules and
investigated a closely related variable, the choice between using observing their compliance) or through internal means (having
reps vs. company employees, and found that employees were employees who share the same goals or socializing them so that
used when output was a bad measure of performance, a finding they do). Likewise, setting up behavioral rules to complement
confirmed by Krafft, Albers, and Lal (2004). Another implica- output monitoring in hybrid institutions need not necessarily
tion is that because measuring output and monitoring behavior take the form of legal contracts. Behavioral compliance can
experiences diminishing returns, most salespeople should be also be obtained through socialization, so that all parties to the
rewarded by hybrid compensation packages, that is packages transaction will voluntarily agree to norms of behavior that will
that combine salary and commission. Such packages are in fact maximize the global rents of the value chain. This results in what
common. In the US, for example, 70 percent of the manufactur- has been called relational governance (Dyer 1996; Heide 1994)
ing firms surveyed reported rewarding salespeople with salary and relational value chains (Gereffi, Humphrey, and Sturgeon
and commission, 14 percent with straight salary, and 19 percent 2005), a mode of governance that is facilitated by membership
with straight commission (Sales and Marketing Management in the same social group or by investments in socialization.
1989). To sum up, contracts and relational governance should be
I have used the example of personal selling, but the model clearly distinguished from arm’s length transactions. In contrast
is very general. As I have argued earlier, the high cost of mea- to EJVs, contracts and relational governance are true hybrids,
suring and pricing the impact of free-riding on the goodwill in the sense that they make use of both output incentives and
capital of a franchise chain prevents the arm’s length rental behavior constraints. It is also important to distinguish between
of trademarks (point M). Given this, the next best thing is organizing methods and institutions. This is preferable to cat-
a franchising contract (point T). These provide strong output egorizing spot markets, hybrids, and firms into discrete types,
incentives which limit shirking, since franchisees get to keep since these three institutions exhibit considerable heterogeneity,
most of what they make, while cheating costs (free-riding on even within a legal category. For instance, while they both are
quality) are kept in check through the imposition on franchisees called firms, small biotechnology research firms differ radically
of behavioral rules devised to guarantee specific quality lev- from large pharmaceutical companies.
els (e.g. the QSC clauses in fast food). The attractiveness of
franchising is that it reduces shirking, so the higher the cost Benefits and costs of hierarchy
of monitoring employees, the more likely franchising (Brickley
and Dark 1987; Fladmoe-Lindquist and Jacque 2005; Lafontaine Lastly, the preceding examples of personal selling, fran-
1992). When it is difficult to maintain standard quality by impos- chising, and global value chains make it clear that one cannot
ing behavior constraints and franchising would result in too understand governance choice by only looking at market trans-
much cheating (free-riding), and when distribution is selective action costs. For example, from the point of view of enforcement
so the number of outlets is smaller and hence monitoring prob- costs, one cannot fully predict whether a particular outlet will be
lems less serious (shirking costs are lower), the optimal solution franchised or company-owned based only on the likelihood of
is be for the trademark owner to operate the outlets with employ- free-riding (cheating). One must also simultaneously consider
ees (point H). If this solution results in too much shirking, outlet the costs of monitoring employees (shirking). Keeping oppor-
managers may be paid bonuses based on the profitability of the tunities for free-riding constant, Brickley and Dark’s (1987)
outlet (point B). empirical study of US franchising shows that distance from
The preceding analysis also explains why most international HQ increases the probability an outlet will be franchised while
value added chains are neither vertically integrated within MNEs Fladmoe-Lindquist and Jacque (2005) find that an outlet is more
nor handled in arm’s length markets. Take the case of agricultural likely to be franchised the greater the geographic and cultural
produce. As food safety has become more important, the costs of distance between the country where it is located and the United
measuring the relevant characteristics of agricultural output have States. These are not isolated findings: in the empirical litera-
increased, thus reducing the efficiency of arm’s length trans- ture on franchising, the variables proxying for monitoring costs
actions. At the same time operating at all stages of the value receive consistently stronger empirical support than those prox-
chain would force a firm to do business in unfamiliar industries ying for free-riding opportunities (Lafontaine and Slade 2002).
and countries, thus increasing monitoring costs. The problems To understand governance, it is not sufficient to focus on mar-
faced by buyers in buyer-driven value chains are similar to those ket failure, it is also necessary to develop a theory of the relative
faced by manufacturers and franchisors, with the difference that benefits and costs of firm organization. From an enforcement
buyers need to assure that a large number of upstream produc- point of view, the cost and benefits of hierarchy are those that
ers supply output of consistent quality while manufacturers and derive from directly controlling behavior (as opposed to mea-
franchisors have the same problem with a large number of down- suring output) and hierarchy is an efficient organizing method
stream retailers and producers. It is therefore not surprising that when a consistent output can be obtained by specifying behavior,
the institutions chosen have been similar, with buyers entering and when monitoring such behavior is relatively easy. The latter
contracts with growers which, like in the case of franchising or can be proxied by geographic distance, and while this proxy is
J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269 267

very crude, it has shown surprisingly good explanatory power. Anderson, E. and Richard Oliver (1987), “Perspectives on Behavior-Based Ver-
Naturally enforcement is not the only transaction cost. From an sus Outcome-Based Salesforce Control Systems,” Journal of Marketing, 51
information viewpoint, hierarchical coordination would seem (October), 76–88.
Arora, Ashish and Andrea Fosfuri (2000), “Wholly-Owned Subsidiary vs.
to have an advantage when the boss has better information than Technology Licensing,” Journal of International Business Studies, 31,
the workers, with the price system being more efficient in the 555–72.
opposite case (Hayek 1945; Hennart 1991b). Arrow, Kenneth (1962), “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for
The need for a realistic theory of the benefit and cost of Invention,” in The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Kenneth Arrow
hierarchy is particularly great in IB. If, as I have argued, ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 609–25.
(1974), The Limits of Organization, New York: Norton.
internalizing transactions means replacing a decentralized infor- Bartlett, Christopher and Sumantra Ghoshal (1989), Managing Across Borders:
mation structure with a centralized one, and measurement The Transnational Solution, Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
of output with control of behavior, then one can understand Boerner, Christopher and Jeffery Macher (2003), “Transaction Cost Economics:
why shirking and information loss will impose serious limits An Assessment of Empirical Work in the Social Sciences.” working paper,
on MNEs.8 The greater physical distance between headquar- Georgetown University.
Brickley, James and Frederick Dark (1987), “The Choice of Organizational form:
ters and employees in MNEs than in domestic firms makes the Case of Franchising,” Journal of Financial Economics, 18, 401–20.
direct external control of behavior more difficult, interna- Brown, Wilson (1984), “Firm-Like Behavior on Markets: The Administered
tional accounting differences and differences in the environment Channel,” International Journal of Business Organization, 2, 236–7.
impair the efficiency of bureaucratic control, while the use Buckley, Peter and Mark Casson (1976), The Future of the Multinational Enter-
of socialization is made problematic by the MNE having prise, London: Macmillan.
Campbell, Duncan and Parisotto, Aurelio (1995), The Global Value Chain Con-
a mix of employees with different national cultures. Differ- cept in Relation to the Institute’s Program of Work, Paper Presented at the
ences between domestic and foreign environments means that Workshop on the International Organization of Production, Geneva.
employees located in foreign countries will have a substantial Cantwell, John (1989), Technological Innovations and Multinational Corpora-
information advantage over HQ, making centralized direction tions, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
less efficient and providing subsidiary managers with substantial Carter, Richard and Geoffrey Hodgson (2006), “The Impact of Empirical Tests
of Transaction Cost Economics on the Debate on the Nature of the Firm,”
opportunities for suboptimization. As a result, one would expect Strategic Management Journal, 27, 461–76.
that the costs of organizing transactions within firms would Casson, Mark (1994), “Institutional Diversity in Overseas Enterprise: Explain-
have a determining impact on the governance of international ing the Free-Standing Company,” Business History, 36 (4), 95–108.
transactions. Caves, Richard (1971), “International Corporations: The Industrial Economics
of Foreign Investment,” Economica, 38 (139), 1–27.
Caves, Richard and William Murphy (1976), “Franchising: Firms, Markets, and
Conclusion Intangible Assets,” Southern Economic Journal, 42, 572–86.
Caves, Richard, Harry Crookell and Peter Killing (1982), “The Imperfect Market
TCT has provided a remarkably useful lens to understand IB for Technology Licenses,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 45,
phenomena. Applying TCT to the research questions asked by 249–67.
Cheung, Steven (1969), “Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of
IB researchers raises some challenging questions that call for Contractual Arrangements,” Journal of Law and Economics, 12, 23–42.
further theoretical developments. This is the mark of a powerful Coase, Ronald (1937), “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4, 386–405.
theory. Contractor, Farok (1984), “Choosing Between Foreign Direct Investment and
Licensing: Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Tests,” Journal of
International Business Studies, 15, 167–88.
Acknowledgement Davidson, William and Donald McFetridge (1984), “International Technology
Transactions and the Theory of the Firm,” Journal of Industrial Economics,
I thank Arne Nygaard for his support and encouragement. 32 (3), 253–64.
Davies, Howard (1977), “Technology Transfer Through Commercial Transac-
tions,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 26, 161–75.
References
(1993), “The Information Content of Technology
Transfers: A Transaction Cost Analysis of the Machine Tool Industry,”
Alchian, Armen and Harold Demsetz (1972), “Production, Information Costs, Technovation, 13 (2), 93–100.
and Economic Organization,” American Economic Review, 62 (1), 777–95. Dolan, Catherine and John Humphrey (2000), “Governance and Trade in Fresh
Anderson, Erin (1985), “The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee: A Vegetables: The Impact of UK Supermarkets on the African Horticulture
Transaction Cost Analysis,” Marketing Science, 4, 234–5. Industry,” Journal of Development Studies, 37 (2), 147–76.
(1988), “Transaction Cost Determinants of Opportunism Dunning, John (1977), “Trade, Location of Economic Activity, and the Multina-
in Integrated and Independent Sales Forces,” Journal of Law, Economics, and tional Enterprise: A Search for an Eclectic Approach,” in The International
Organization, 9, 247–64. Allocation of Economic Activity, Bertil, Ohlin P. O. Hesselborn and P. M.
Anderson, Erin and Anne Coughlan (1987), “International Market Entry Wijkman, eds. New York: Holmes and Meier, 395–418.
Through Expansion via Independent or Integrated Channels of Distribution,” (2009), “The Key Literature on IB Activities,
Journal of Marketing, 51, 71–82. 1960–2006,” in The Oxford Handbook of International Business, Alan Rug-
Anderson, Erin and Hubert Gatignon (1986), “Modes of Foreign Entry: A Trans- man ed (2nd ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press, 39–71.
action Cost Analysis and Propositions,” Journal of International Business Dunning, John and Alan Rugman (1985), “The Influence of Hymer’s Disser-
Studies, 17 (3), 1–26. tation on the Theory of Foreign Direct Investment,” American Economic
Review, 75, 228–32.
Dyer, Jeffrey (1996), “Specialized Supplier Networks as a Source of Compet-
8 See Tomassen and Benito (2009) for an interesting attempt to evaluate the itive Advantage: Evidence from the Auto Industry,” Strategic Management
impact of these on subsidiary performance. Journal, 17, 271–92.
268 J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269

Erramili, M. Krishnan and C.P. Rao (1993), “Service Firms’ International Entry Hymer, Stephen (1960). “The International Operations of National Firms.” Ph.D.
Mode Choice: A Modified Transaction Cost Analysis Approach,” Journal dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
of Marketing, 57, 19–38. (1976), The International Operations of National Firms,
Eswaran, Mukesh and Ashok Kotwal (1985), “A Theory of Contractual Structure Boston: MIT Press.
in Agriculture,” American Economic Review, 75 (3), 352–67. Jackson, Donald, Janet Keith and John Schlacter (1983), “Evaluation of Selling
Fieldhouse, David Kenneth (1986), “The Multinational: A Critique of a Con- Performance: A Study of Current Practices,” Journal of Personal Selling and
cept,” in The Multinational Enterprise in Historical Perspective, Alice Sales Management, 3 (November), 42–51.
Teichova ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Jensen, Michael and William Meckling (1976), “Theory of the Firm: Manage-
Fladmoe-Lindquist, Karin and Laurent Jacque (2005), “To Own or to Franchise: rial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Capital Structure,” Journal of Financial
International Control Decisions for Service Companies,” Journal of Applied Economics, 3, 305–60.
Corporate Finance, 9 (3), 98–109. John, George and Barton Weitz (1989), “Salesforce Compensation: An Empir-
Franz, Juergen, Bo Sternberg and John Strongman (1986), Iron Ore: Global ical Investigation of Factors Related to Use of Salary vs. Incentive
Prospects for the Industry, Washington, DC: World Bank. Compensation,” Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 1–14.
Gatignon, Hubert and Erin Anderson (1988), “The Multinational Corporation’s Jones, Geoffrey (2005), Multinationals and Global Capitalism, Oxford: Oxford
Degree of Control over Foreign Subsidiaries: An Empirical Test of a Trans- University Press.
action Cost Explanation,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4, Kidwell, Roland, Arne Nygaard and Ragnhild Silkoset (2007), “Antecedents and
305–36. Effects of Free-Riding in the Franchisor–Franchisee Relationship,” Journal
Gereffi, Gary, John Humphrey and Timothy Sturgeon (2005), “The Governance of Business Venturing, 22, 522–44.
of Global Value Chains,” Review of International Political Economy, 12 (1), Kindleberger, Charles (1969), American Business Abroad, New Haven: Yale
78–104. University Press.
Gomes-Casseres, Benjamin (1989), “Ownership Structures of Foreign Sub- Klein, Saul, Gary Frazier and Victor Roth (1990), “A Transaction Cost Anal-
sidiaries: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Economic Behavior and ysis Model of Channel Integration in International Markets,” Journal of
Organization, 11, 1–25. Marketing Research, 23, 196–208.
Hayek, Frederic (1945), “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” American Eco- Kogut, Bruce and Udo Zander (1993), “Knowledge of the Firm and the Evolu-
nomic Review, 35, 519–30. tionary Theory of the Multinational Corporation,” Journal of International
Heide, Jan (1994), “Interorganizational Governance in Marketing Channels,” Business Studies, 24, 625–4.
Journal of Marketing, 58 (1), 71–85. Krafft, Manfred, Sonke Albers and Rajiv Lal (2004), “Relative Explanatory
Hennart, Jean-François (1977), “A Theory of Foreign Direct Investment.” Ph.D. Power of Agency Theory and Transaction Cost Analysis in German Sales-
dissertation, University of Maryland. forces,” International Journal of Research in Marketing, 21, 265–83.
(1982), A Theory of Multinational Enterprise, Ann Kreps, David (1990), A Course in Microeconomics Theory, Princeton: Princeton
Arbor: University of Michigan Press. University Press.
Hennart, Jean-François (1986), “What is Internalization?,” Weltwirtschaftliches Lafontaine, Francine (1992), “Agency Theory and Franchising: Some Empirical
Archiv, CXII (Winter), 791–804. Results,” Rand Journal of Economics, 23 (2), 263–8.
(1988a), “A Transaction Cost Theory of Equity Joint Lafontaine, Francine and Kathryn Shaw (2005), “Targeting Managerial Control:
Ventures,” Strategic Management Journal, 9 (4), 361–74. Evidence from Franchising,” Rand Journal of Economics, 36 (1), 131–50.
(1988b), “Vertical Integration in the Aluminum and Lafontaine, Francine and Margaret Slade (2002), “Incentives Contracts and
Tin Industries,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 9 (3), the Franchising Decision,” in Game Theory and Business Applications,
281–300. Kaylan Chatterjee and William, Samuelson eds. New York: Kluwer,
(1989), “Can the New Forms of Investment Substitute for 133–88.
the ‘Old Forms’. A Transaction Cost Perspective,” Journal of International Lange, Oskar (1936), “On the Economic Theory of Socialism,” Review of Eco-
Business Studies, 20 (2), 211–34. nomic Studies, 4, 53–71.
(1991a), “The Transaction Costs Theory of Joint Ven- Levin, Richard, Alan Klevorick, Richard Nelson and Sidney Winter (1987),
tures: An Empirical Study of Japanese Subsidiaries in the United States,” “Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development,”
Management Science, 37 (4), 483–97. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 783–820.
(1991b), “Control in Multinational Firms: The Role of Litvak, Isaiah and Christopher Maule (1977), “Transnational Corporations and
Price and Hierarchy,” Management International Review, 31 (special issue), Vertical Integration: The Banana Case,” Journal of World Trade Law, 11/6,
71–96. 537–49.
(1993), “Explaining the Swollen Middle: Why Most Magee, Stephen (1977), “Information and the Multinational Corporation: An
Transactions are a Mix of Market and Hierarchy,” Organization Science, Appropriability Theory of Direct Foreign Investment,” in The New Inter-
4 (4), 529–47. national Economic Order, Jagdish Bhagwhati ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT
(1994a), “International Capital Transfers: A Transaction Press.
Cost Framework,” Business History, 36, 51–70. Masten, Scott (1988), “A Legal Basis for the Firm,” Journal of Law, Economics,
(1994b), “Free-Standing Firms and the Internalization of and Organization, 4, 181–97.
Markets for Financial Capital: A Response to Casson,” Business History, 36 McManus, John (1972), “The Theory of the Multinational Firm,” in The Multi-
(4), 118–31. national Firm and the Nation State, Gilles Paquet ed. Don Mills, Ontario:
(1998), “Transaction-Cost Theory and the Free-Standing Macmillan.
Firm,” in The Free Standing Company in the World Economy, Mira Wilkins Menard, Claude (1996), “On Clusters, Hybrids and Other Strange Forms: The
and Harm, Schroeter eds. London: Oxford University Press, 65–98. Case of the French Poultry Industry,” Review of Institutional and Theoretical
(2000), “Transaction Costs Theory and the Multinational Economics, 152, 154–83.
Enterprise,” in The Nature of the Transnational Firm, Christos Pitelis and Monteverde, Kirk and David Teece (1982), “Supplier Switching Costs and Ver-
Rodger Sugden , eds (2nd ed.). London: Routledge, 72–118. tical Integration in the Automobile Industry,” Bell Journal of Economics, 19,
(2009), “Down with MNE-Centric Theories! Market 623–32.
Entry and Expansion as the Bundling of MNE and Local Assets,” Jour- Mowery, David, Joanne Oxley and Brian Silverman (1996), “Strategic Alliances
nal of International Business Studies, special 40th anniversary issue, 40 (9), and Inter-Firm Knowledge Transfer,” Strategic Management Journal, 17,
1432–54. 77–91.
Hennart, Jean-François and Yeung Ryeol Park (1993), “Greenfield vs. Acquisi- Nicholas, Stephen (1983), “Agency Contracts, Institutional Modes, and the Tran-
tion: The Strategy of Japanese Investors in the United States,” Management sition to Foreign Direct Investment by British Manufacturing Multinationals
Science, 39 (9), 1054–70. Before 1935,” Journal of Economic History, 48, 675–86.
J.-F. Hennart / Journal of Retailing 86 (3, 2010) 257–269 269

Ouchi, William (1979), “A Conceptual Framework for the Design (1981), “The Multinational Enterprise: Market Failure
of Organizational Control Mechanisms,” Management Science, 25, and Market Power Considerations,” Sloan Management Review, 22 (3), 3–17.
833–48. Tokatli, Nebahat (2008), “Global Sourcing: Insights from the Global Clothing
Oxley, Joanne (1997), “Appropriability Hazards and Governance in Strategic Industry—The Case of Zara, a Fast Fashion Retailer,” Journal of Economic
Alliances: A Transaction Cost Approach,” Journal of Law, Economics and Geography, 8, 21–38.
Organization, 13, 387–409. Tomassen, Sverre and Gabriel Benito (2009), “The Costs of Governance in
Read, Robert (1986), “The Banana Industry: Oligopoly and Barriers to Entry,” International Companies,” International Business Review, 18, 292–304.
in Multinationals and World Trade, Mark Casson and Associates, London: Wilkins, Mira (1970), The Emergence of Multinational Enterprise: American
Allen & Unwin, 317–42. Business Abroad from the Colonial Era to 1914, Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Robertson, Diana and Erin Anderson (1993), “Control System and Task Envi- University Press.
ronment Effect on Ethical Judgment: An Exploration Study of Industrial Wilkins, Mira and Harm Schroeter (1998), The Free Standing Company in the
Salespeople,” Organization Science, 4 (4), 617–44. World Economy, New York: Oxford University Press.
Rugman, Alan (1981), Inside the Multinationals, New York: Columbia Univer- Williamson, Oliver (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust
sity Press. Implications, New York: Free Press.
Sales and Marketing Management (1989), 1989 Survey of Selling Costs, Febru- (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New
ary 20, 20. York: Free Press.
Stinchcombe, Arthur (1985), “Contracts as Hierarchical Documents,” in Orga- (1988), “Corporate Finance and Corporate Governance,”
nization Theory and Project Management., Arthur Stinchcombe and Carol, Journal of Finance, 63/3, 567–98.
Heimer eds. Oslo: Norwegian University Press, 121–7. (1991), “Comparative Economic Organization: The
Stuckey, John (1983), Vertical Integration and Joint Ventures in the Aluminum Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives,” Administrative Science Quar-
Industry, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. terly, 36, 269–96.
Teece, David (1976), Vertical Integration and Vertical Divestiture in the US (1996), “Economic Organization: The Case for Candor,”
Petroleum Industry, Stanford: Institute for Energy Studies. Academy of Management Review, 21, 48–57.

Вам также может понравиться