Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 17

® Academy oi Management Review

2001, Vol. 26, No. 1, 41-56.

IS THE RESOURCE-BASED "VIEW" A USEFUL


PERSPECTIVE FOR STRATEGIC
MANAGEMENT RESEARCH? YES
JAY B. BARNEY
The Ohio State University

Here I examine each of the major issues raised by Priem and Butler (this issue) about
my 1991 article and subsequent resource-based research. While it turns out that Priem
and Butler's direct criticisms oi the 1991 article are unfounded, they do remind
resource-based researchers of some important requirements of this kind of research.
I also discuss some important issues not raised by Priem and Butler—the resolutions
of which will be necessary if a more complete resource-based theory of strategic
advantage is to be developed.

Priem and Butler's (this issue) critique of my dress if the field of strategic management is to
1991 Journal of Management article raises sev- continue to progress.
eral important issues, about both the article and
subsequent developments in the resource-based THE TAUTOLOGY CRITIQUE
view (RBV) of the firm. While I disagree with
most of these authors' criticisms, they clearly Priem and Butler's first and, in many ways,
provide a service by creating a forum within most important critique of the 1991 article is that
which the creation, development, and future of the RBV presented is tautological—that its pri-
resource-based models of competition can be mary assertions are true by definition and, thus,
discussed and debated. not subject to empirical test (Williamson, 1999).
Priem and Butler's criticisms fall into four Following Bacharach (1989), the authors attempt
broad categories: (1) that the resource-based to demonstrate the tautological nature of the
theory I develop in the 1991 paper is tautologi- 1991 argument by substituting the definitions of
cal, (2) that my argument fails to acknowledge value, rarity, and strategic advantage given
that many different resource configurations there into what they characterize as one of the
could generate the same value for firms and, central empirical assertions of the RBV: only
thus, would not be sources of competitive ad- valuable and rare resources can be sources of
vantage, (3) that the role of product markets is competitive advantage. The assertions thus de-
underdeveloped in the argument, and (4) that rived are clearly tautological. However, the fact
the theory developed in the article has limited that Priem and Butler are able to restate parts of
prescriptive implications. I discuss each of these the 1991 argument in ways that make it tauto-
criticisms in turn. At the end of this response, I logical is not the same thing as demonstrating
also discuss several important issues in the that the argument is, in fact, tautological.
field of strategic management that are ad- It is important to recognize that, at this defini-
dressed neither in the 1991 paper nor in subse- tional level, all strategic management theories
quent resource-based work. These issues, I are tautological in the way Priem and Butler
think, constitute part of the research agenda describe. For example. Porter's (1980) assertions
that resource-based and other theorists must ad- about the relationship between industry attrac-
tiveness and firm performance can be reduced
to tautology by observing that firms in attractive
Comments and suggestions from Asli Arikan. Valentina industries will outperform firms in unattractive
Delia Corte, Konstantina Kiousis, Michael Leiblein, Doug industries and by defining industry attractive-
Miller, Mike Peng, Mauro Sciarelli, and Heli Wang have ness in terms of the ability of firms to perform
been helpful in writing this article. I began writing this well. Transaction cost economics also can be
article while visiting the Marketing Department at Boconni
University in Milan, Italy. I am grateful for the space and reduced to tautology: hierarchical forms of gov-
intellectual climate I was provided there. ernance will replace market forms of gover-
41
42 Academy of Management Review January

nance when the costs of market governance are manage through hierarchical governance than
greater than the costs of hierarchical gover- through market governance.
nance. Indeed, this is known as the Coasian Thus, the real theoretical challenge presented
tautology. Thus, the ability to restate a theory in by Priem and Butler is not "Can the RBV pre-
ways that make it tautological provides no in- sented in the 1991 paper be restated in a way
sights about the empirical testability of the the- that makes it tautological?" but is, rather, "Are
ory whatsoever.' some aspects of this resource-based theory pa-
Of course, the critical issue is not whether a rameterized in ways that can generate testable
theory can be restated in such a way as to make hypotheses?" In the next sections I examine the
it tautological—since this can always be done— extent to which each of the components of this
but whether at least some of the elements of that resource-based theory are parameterized in
theory have been parameterized in a way that ways that can generate testable propositions.
makes it possible to generate testable empirical
assertions. For example. Porter's theory is
clearly not tautological since he specifies the Parameterizing Value
conditions that make an industry more or less
attractive independent of the performance of Clearly, of all the theory elements in the 1991
firms in that industry. Porter parameterizes in- article, the value variable is the least fully pa-
dustry attractiveness through the well-known rameterized. This is because, as Priem and But-
"five forces" framework, a parameterization that ler correctly observe, the determination of the
enables Porter to make empirically testable as- value of a firm's resources is exogenous to the
sertions of the form, firms operating in industries resource-based theory presented in the 1991 ar-
characterized by high rivalry, high threat of sub- ticle. In fact, the exogenous nature of value de-
stitutes, high threat oi entry, high buyer power, termination is stated in the 1991 article:
and high supplier power will perform at a lower
level than firms operating in industiies without These environmental models help isolate those
these attributes. firm attributes that exploit opportunities and/or
neutralize threats, and thus specify which firm
In a similar way, Williamson (1975) parame- attributes can be considered as resources. The
terizes the attributes of transactions in ways resource-based model then suggests what addi-
that make it possible to specify conditions under tional characteristics that these resources must
possess if they are to generate sustained compet-
which the costs of market governance will be itive advantage (Barney, 1991: 100; emphasis
greater than the costs of hierarchical gover- added).
nance. Williamson has explored several ver-
sions of this parameterization, but the most crit- Since the determination of the value of a re-
ical transaction attribute he has identified source is exogenous to the argument presented
seems to be transaction-specific investment. in the 1991 article, it is not surprising that the
This parameterization enables Williamson to conditions under which resources will and will
make empirically testable assertions of the not be valuable are not fully specified there.
form, transactions characterized by high trans- That said, it would be inappropriate to sug-
action-specific investment will be less costly to gest that the 1991 article fails to give at least
some guidance as to how the value of a resource
can be determined. In particular, the article in-
dicates that resource value must be determined
' Moreover, because a theory is tautological does not by models of the competitive environment
mean that it might not be insightful and even empirically
fruitful. For example, all game theoretic models are tauto-
within which a firm competes. Indeed, since
logical in the sense that the hypotheses they generate are 1991, work has continued on using these kinds of
completely determined by the assumptions adopted in the models to estimate resource value.
models and the laws of mathematics applied to these as- This work falls into two large categories: (1)
sumptions. However, these tautological models can some- efforts to use structure-conduct-performance (S-
times generate quite counterintuitive insights that can, in
principle, lead to important empirical research. Again, the
C-P; Bain, 1956)-based theories to specify the
issue is not tautology, per se, but, rather, whether the prop- conditions under which different firm resources
ositions derived from a tautology can be parametrized in a will be valuable and (2) efforts to determine the
way that makes empirical testing possible. value of firm resources that apply other theories
2001 Barney 43

derived from industrial organization models this and even a suggestion of some ways it
(I/O) of perfect and imperfect competition (Con- might be done. While, strictly speaking, Priem
ner, 1991). In my own work I acknowledge the and Butler's critique does not directly apply to
insights that can be generated from applying the 1991 argument, it does apply to resource-
the S-C-P framework to understanding the value based theorists who have tried to examine the
of firm attributes (Barney, 1991: 100), but I have implications of resource-based logic without
focused more on non-S-C-P-based theories of considering the market conditions under which
the value of firm attributes. a firm's resources will and will not be valuable.
Consider, for example, my 1997 discussion of Indeed, if I were to write the 1991 article today, I
the ability of cost leadership strategies to gen- would definitely enhance the discussion of
erate sustained competitive advantages (Bar- value along the lines outlined here. The brief
ney, 1997: Chapter 6). I begin this discussion by discussion of value in the 1991 article could
describing several firm attributes that may be have indicated to some that determining the
associated with cost leadership (e.g., volume- value of resources is less important than deter-
derived economies of scale, cumulative volume- mining the rarity and imitability of resources—a
derived learning curve economies, policy point of view with which I clearly disagree.
choices, and so forth) and then show how these
attributes can generate economic value in at
Parameterizing Rarity
least some market settings. The logic I use to
demonstrate the value of these attributes is a Priem and Butler also suggest that the term
market structure logic that is consistent with rare is not parameterized in the 1991 article and,
traditional microeconomics (see Figure 6.4 in thus, that any assertions including "rare" must
Barney, 1997). Only after identifying the condi- be tautological. I certainly agree that since the
tions under which cost leadership can generate concept of rarity is not exogenous to the RBV
economic value do I turn the discussion to the developed in the 1991 paper, if rare was not
conditions under which cost leadership can be a p a r a m e t e r i z e d in that article, then any
source of competitive advantage (i.e., rare) and assertions made with this term must remain tau-
sustained competitive advantage (i.e., rare and tological. However, in fact, rare is parameterized
costly to imitate). in the 1991 article. Although this parameteriza-
Nor am I the only researcher that has followed tion is not as complete as I would like, it is
up on the suggestions in the 1991 article for how nevertheless specific enough to generate empir-
to value firm resources. Theoretically, progress ically testable assertions.
on this front can be found in Leonard-Barton The parameterization of rare is discussed in
(1992), Barney and Hansen (1994), McWilliams the last paragraph of the section titled Rare Re-
and Smart (1995), and Hunt (1997, 2000), among sources:
others. Empirically, two of the papers cited by How rare a valuable firm resource must be in
Priem and Butler (i.e.. Brush & Artz, 1999, and order to have the potential for generating a com-
Miller & Shamsie, 1996). are important precisely petitive advantage is a difficult question ... In
because they address the value of resources general, as long as the number of firms that pos-
question. Additional empirical work has been sess a particular valuable resource ... is less
than the number of firms needed to generate per-
done by Barnett, Greve, and Park (1994), fect competition dynamics in an industry ... that
Makadok (1998, 1999), Poppo and Zenger (1998), resource has the potential of generating a com-
and many others. In all high-quality resource- petitive advantage (Barney, 1991: 107).^
based work, researchers must begin by address-
ing the value of resources with theoretical tools Of course, a complete parameterization of rare
that specify the market conditions under which would enable a researcher to specify the maxi-
different resources will and will not be valuable.
Although additional work is required, I believe
we are developing a more complete understand- ^ As will become clear later, I wish I had not used the term
ing of these conditions. industry in this parametrization of the concept of rarity.
Rather, I should have focused simply on the number of firms
Thus, although the value variable in Barney that must possess a resource in order to generate perfect
(1991) is not fully parameterized, in the article competition dynamics, independent of whether those firms
there is recognition of the importance of doing operated in a particular industry.
44 Academy of Management Review January

mum number of competing firms that can pos- ness in ways that generate competitive advan-
sess a particular resource and still have perfect tages, then these assertions are contradicted.
competition based on that resource not exist. One could test these assertions by measuring
However, in 19911 was unaware of a sufficiently the extent to which a firm uniquely possesses a
rigorous theory to specify such a number. I sus- valuable resource (e.g., a valuable organization-
pect, in fact, that such a theory would show that al culture), measuring the activities that differ-
how rare a particular resource must be in order ent firms engage in to improve their efficiency
for perfect competition based on that resource to and effectiveness, and then seeing if there are
not exist will depend upon several attributes of some activities a firm with the unique culture
the market structure within which firms are engages in to improve its effectiveness and ef-
competing. ficiency—activities not engaged in by other
However, even though in the 1991 article I do competing firms.^
not specify the maximum number of competing Of course, there are difficult measurement
firms fhat can possess a resource beyond which problems associated with testing assertions of
perfect competition will exist, I do suggest that this form. Measurement problems RBV research-
such a number exists. Moreover, even without a ers face, however, are similar fo those other
complete parameterization of resource rarity, it strategy researchers face, including those look-
is still possible to observe that if only one com- ing to test implications derived from transaction
peting firm possesses a particular valuable re- cost economics and agency theory (Godfrey &
source, perfect competition around this resource Hill, 1995). Moreover, Priem and Butler's argu-
will not exist. In fact, this assertion is made in ment is not that assertions derived from fhe 1991
the 1991 article (Barney, 1991: 107). This makes it are difficult to test but, rather, that they are, in
possible to generate testable assertions of the principle, not testable.
form: All this said, it is clear that additional work is
If only one competing firm possesses a needed to complete the parameterization of the
particular valuable resource (where concept of rarity. Indeed, unlike the theoretical
the value of that resource is deter- work and empirical work that have enabled a
mined in ways that are exogenous to more complete parameterization of resource
the theory developed in the 1991 arti- value, there has been less work on developing a
cle), then that firm can gain a compet- more complete parameterization of the rarity
itive advantage (i.e., it can improve its variable. In most empirical and theoretical work
efficiency and effectiveness in ways on rarity since the 1991 article, researchers have
that competing firms cannot). either implicitly focused on the competitive im-
plications of valuable and unique resources
One example of this form of a testable asser- (Barney, 1988) or have been rather imprecise in
tion can be found in Barney (1986b). In that arti- specifying how rare a resource must be among
cle I examine the ability of organizational cul- competing firms to still generate competitive
ture to be a source of competitive advantage. advantages. Priem and Butler certainly provide
Much of that argument can be summarized an important service by reminding us of the
through an empirical assertion of the form: importance of further refining the parameteriza-
tion of the concept of rarity, even though their
// only one competing firm possesses a specific critique of the concept of rarity in the
valuable organizational culture 1991 article as tautological is incorrect.
(where the value of that culture is de-
termined in ways that are exogenous
to the theory developed in the 1991 Parameterizing Imitability
article), then that firm can gain a com-
petitive advantage (i.e., it can im- Ironically, Priem and Butler do not comment
prove its efficiency and effectiveness on the extent to which arguments in the 1991
in ways that competing firms cannot). article can be used to derive empirically test-
Both these assertions are clearly testable. If a
firm uniquely possesses a valuable resource ^ This discussion temporarily sets aside substitutability
and cannot improve its efficiency and effecfive- considerations.
2001 Barney 45

able assertions about the relationship between rameterize all the concepts they use to derive
the imitability of valuable and rare firm re- empirical assertions. However, if at least some
sources and sustained competitive advantage. of these concepts are parameterized, then it is
At one point in their article, Priem and Butler possible to deduce testable empirical assertions
state, "For ease of exposition, we examine those from these theories.
terms associated with competitive advantage Porter (1980), for example, parameterizes in-
first and set aside issues associated with sus- dustry attractiveness but does not provide theo-
tainability" (p. 27). But tautology questions are retical tools for determining when an industry
never subsequently raised concerning the imi- does or does not exist (Caves & Porter, 1977). It is
tability variable.* still possible, however, to deduce testable em-
This is, of course, because the concept of imi- pirical assertions from Porter's work. In the
tability is clearly parameterized in the 1991 ar- same way, Williamson (1975) parameterizes the
ticle. This parameterization makes it possible to attributes of transactions that can have the ef-
generate testable assertions of the form: fect of making hierarchical governance less
costly than market governance, but he does not
A firm that possesses a particular initially provide theoretical tools for examining
valuable resource fwhere fhe value of the impact of production costs on governance
that resource is determined in ways choices (Riordan & Williamson, 1985). Porter and
that are exogenous to the theory de- Williamson, like all theorists, make choices
veloped in the 1991 article) that is rare about which aspects of their theory to parame-
(possessed by fewer firms than re- terize, and which aspects not to parameterize,
quired to generate perfect competition based primarily on decisions about which as-
dynamics) and obtained in unique his- pects of the theory being developed seem most
torical circumstances can gain a sus- likely to generate important testable empirical
tained competitive advantage (i.e., assertions.
can improve its efficiency and effec-
tiveness in ways that competing firms In the 1991 article I gave the parameterization
cannot and in ways that competing of imitability the most attention because I be-
firms cannot imitate over time). lieved the empirical assertions derived from this
concept were likely to be among the most impor-
Additional empirical assertions about the re- tant to come out of resource-based theory. After
lationship between firm resources and sus- all, what is most new about resource-based the-
tained competitive advantages can be gener- ory is not an explanation of temporary compet-
ated by substituting the other attributes of itive advantages for firms. These competitive
resources that can lead to costly imitation cited advantages can be understood simply as dis-
in the 1991 article for "unique historical condi- equilibrium phenomena in a more traditional
tions"—that is, causal ambiguity and social I/O theoretical framework. Following Lippman
complexity. and Rumelt (1982), I concluded that what was
Indeed, even if Priem and Butler were correct most new about resource-based theory was the
about assertions that included the terms vaJu- ability to specify conditions under which firms
abJe and rare being tautological, which they are would possess competitive advantages in equi-
not, the fact that empirical assertions can be librium. Thus, reasons why a firm's valuable
derived from the 1991 article's analysis of imita- and rare resources can be costly to imitate be-
bility and sustained competitive advantage un- come very important in the 1991 article.
dermines their general assertion that the RBV Indeed, the RBV research cited by Priem and
developed in the 1991 article is tautological. Af- Butler since the 1991 article seems to be consis-
ter all, in few theories do researchers fully pa- tent with these expectations. Research on the
competitive implications of such firm resources
as knowledge, learning, culture, teamwork, and
•• Indeed, in their discussion of the prescriptive limits of human capital, among others, was given a sig-
the RBV, Priem and Butler acknowledge that those resource nificant boost by resource-based theory—a the-
attributes associated with the sustainability of competitive
advantages identified in Barney (1991) do have prescriptive
ory that indicated it was these kinds of re-
implications and, thus, are not tautological in the ways they sources that were most likely to be sources of
assert resource value and rarity are. sustained competitive advantage for firms.
46 Academy ol Management Review January

Thus, while Priem and Butler clearly demon- funds to increase their market share. He mea-
strate that it is possible to restate the RBV de- sures the value of these economies of scale by
veloped in the 1991 article in a way that is tau- firsf estimating the impact of the size of a family
tological, their critique that the argument in the of funds on both its weighted-average, risk-
1991 article is itself fautological is unfounded. At adjusted gross yield and its weighted-average
its core, these authors' critique fails to acknowl- expense ratio, and then shows that these yields
edge the ways that the key variables in the 1991 and expenses affecf the market share of the fam-
article are parameterized. ily of funds. Makadok measures the rarity of
economies of scale by showing that they vary
across families of funds, and he examines the
Empirical Tests of the RBV
imitability of these scale differences by examin-
Of course, logical debates about whether the ing their impact on the market shares of families
1991 argument is tautological would be moot in of funds over time. Consistent with the 1991 ar-
the face of rigorous empirical tests. Indeed, as ticle, because economies of scale are not path
Priem and Butler suggest, in numerous sub- dependent, causally ambiguous, or socially
sequent works—many of them empirical— complex, Makadok does not expect these capa-
researchers have cited the 1991 paper. However, bility differences to be a source of sustained
many of fhese citations are used primarily to^ competitive advantage. In fact, the impact of
help establish the context of some empirical re- scale differences on market share becomes
search—for example, fhat the focus is on the smaller over time—results that are again con-
performance implications of some internal at- sistent with the 1991 argument.
tribute of a firm—and are not really direct tests Moreover, not all empirical tests of the 1991
of the theory developed in the 1991 article. None- argument are consistent with that argument. For
theless, there is some empirical work that con- example, Poppo and Zenger (1998) examined
stitutes quite direct tests of the resource-based some implications of the 1991 paper (developed
theory I developed in the 1991 paper. by Conner & Prahalad, 1996) and found results
Consider, for example, Henderson and Cock- that are inconsistent with resource-based ex-
burn's (1994) examination of the impact of pectations and more consistent with transaction
"componenf competence" and "architectural cost expectations. Unfortunately, data limita-
competence" on the research productivity of tions make it difficult to understand exactly
pharmaceutical firms. Henderson and Cockburn where the resource-based argument falls short:
measure the value of these competencies by es- is it around the value of resources, their rarity, or
timating their impact on the research productiv- their imitability? However, such contrary empir-
ity of pharmaceutical firms, under the assump- ical results would certainly not be possible if
tion that pharmaceutical firms with more resource-based theory in general and the 1991
productive research efforts will outperform argument in particular were purely tautological.
pharmaceufical firms with less productive re- Thus, Priem and Butler demonstrate that it is
search efforts. They measure the rarity of these possible to restate the 1991 argument as if it
competencies by showing that their level varies were tautological, but they fail to demonstrate
across competing pharmaceutical firms, and that the argument is, in fact, tautological. In-
they measure the imitability of these competen- deed, it is possible to derive empirically testable
cies by showing that firm differences in fhe level assertions from the 1991 article—assertions that
of these competencies remain very stable over have, in fact, been tested.
time. To the extent that high levels of research
productivity are valuable in the pharmaceutical
industry, Henderson and Cockburn's results are EQUIFINALITY IN THE RBV
consistent with the RBV developed in my 1991 Although Priem and Butler do not label it as a
article. major limitation of the RBV, they do suggest that
Makadok (1999) authored another paper in another weakness of this logic, as developed in
which the argument developed in the 1991 paper the 1991 article, is the problem of equifinality:
is tested. In his article Makadok examines the there may be many different resource configu-
impact of differential levels of economies of rations that could generate the same value for
scale on the ability of money market mutual firms and, thus, would not be sources of compet-
2001 Barney 47

itive advantage. Their solution to this supposed fining a firm's industry for three reasons. First,
problem is to adopt what they describe as a determining the theoretically appropriate
more "traditional" definition of competitive ad- boundaries of a particular industry can be very
vantage: a firm "systematically creating above difficult. On the margin, decisions about which
average returns" (Schoemaker, 1990: 1179). This firms to include within the boundary of an in-
leads them to suggest that it is not the value and dustry, and which to exclude, are quite arbi-
rarity of a resource that generates competitive trary. Moreover, these decisions can have very
advantage (as defined by Schoemaker, 1990) but, important implications for the calculated aver-
rather, the reiafive vaJue of different resources age returns in an industry and, thus, important
and capabilities. implications for determining whether a particu-
However, in the 1991 article I explicitly recog- lar firm has a competitive advantage.^ This can
nized the potential problem of equifinality. In introduce a significant degree of arbitrariness
fact, that is why I introduced the substitutability into research on competitive advantage.
variable into the 1991 argument. Substitutability Second, defining industry boundaries as-
is defined with respect to strategic equivalence: sumes a level of stability in technology and
competition that, in many situations, is inappro-
"Two valuable firm resources ... are strategi- priate. It was often inappropriate in 1991. It is
cally equivalent when they can each be exploited even more inappropriate in the twenty-first cen-
separately to implement the same strategies"
(Barney, 1991: 111). tury, when traditional industry boundaries are
being destroyed and when competition can
The general conclusion is that even if a resource come from numerous sources, not just from firms
is valuable, rare, and costly to imitate, if it has within the well-defined boundaries of an indus-
strategically equivalent substitutes that are try. In the new economy it will often be inappro-
themselves not rare or not costly to imitate, then priate to adopt a definition of competitive ad-
it cannot be a source of sustained competitive vantage that builds on concepts assuming a
advantage. The existence of strategic substi- technological and competitive stability that
tutes indicates that strategic equifinality exists does not exist. In the long run, I suspect that the
in a competitive situation and, thus, that com- tradition of introducing industry controls into
petitive advantage cannot exist. If strategic sub- the empirical analysis of firm performance will
stitutes do not exist, then strategic equifinality be replaced by a tradition of introducing con-
does not exist, and competitive advantages are trols for the competitiveness of the context
possible. Thus, substitutability deals with ambi- within which a firm is operating—a context that
guities that may be introduced into empirical can only be imperfectly described using the con-
assertions derived from the RBV because of the cept of industry.
problem of equifinality. Third and finally, resource-based logic takes
Although the equifinality critique presented as its unit of analysis the firm. To maintain
by Priem and Butler is unfounded, their decision theoretical consistency, it was important for me
to adopt "systematically creating above aver- to adopt a firm-level dependent variable. Thus,
age returns" as the appropriate definition of rather than adopt a definition of competitive
competitive advantage in this part of their cri- advantage that required the concept of an in-
tique is interesting. This definition implicitly re-
introduces the concept of industry into the dis-
cussion of competitive advantage. In order to
know whether a firm's returns are above aver- ^ For example, when Alcoa attempted to acquire Rome
age, an average must be calculated. That aver- Cable, the combined firm's "competitive advantage" de-
pended significantly on how this firm's industry was de-
age almost certainly would be calculated on the fined. If this industry was defined as "insulated wire and
basis of returns of firms in a particular industry. cable," the combined firm's market share was only 1.6 per-
Thus, in their definition of competitive advan- cent, and its market power-based competitive advantage
tage, Priem and Butler compare a particular was quite small. If this industry was defined as "insulated
firm's performance with the performance of aluminum wire and cable," the combined firm's market
share was 16.3 percent. In this setting it presumably enjoyed
other firms in that industry. a much more substantial market power-based competitive
In the 1991 article I chose a definition of com- advantage (Scherer, 1980:552). Unfortunately, both these def-
petitive advantage that did not depend on de- initions of industry were quite reasonable.
48 Academy of Management fleview January

dustry, I defined competitive advantage at the competitive advantage by exploiting valuable,


firm level. rare, costly to imitate, and nonsubstitutable re-
In general, there are at least two ways to de- sources, but whether this competitive advan-
fine competitive advantage at the firm level. tage is a source of economic rents depends on
First, as is done in the 1991 article, a firm's the conditions under which the resources con-
competitive advantage can be defined with re- trolled were acquired or developed. If the cost of
spect to the actions of other firms—either cur- acquiring or developing these special resources
rent or potential competitors. In this approach, a equals the value they create when used to con-
firm is said to have a competitive advantage ceive of and implement a strategy, they will not
when it is engaging in activities that increase be a source of economic rent (Barney, 1986a).
its efficiency or effectiveness in ways that com- This kind of analysis is difficult to do if compet-
peting firms are not, regardless of whether those itive advantage is defined in terms of a firm
other firms are in a particular firm's industry. experiencing "above average returns" in an in-
Second, a firm's competitive advantage can be dustry, because in this definition the causes of
defined with respect to return expectations of that competitive advantage are not distinguished
firm's owners. Stockholders, as residual claim- from the effects.
ants, develop expectations about the returns a Given the proliferation of different definitions
firm will generate. In this definitional approach, of competitive advantage in the strategic man-
firms that generate higher returns than were ex- agement literature, it might be time to abandon
pected by stockholders (at constant levels of risk) this term altoge-ther. Rather than refer to the
have a competitive advantage. This definition of definitionally ambiguous "competitive advan-
competitive advantage is often called an eco- tage," researchers should specify exactly what it
nomic rent and is the definition of competitive is they are trying to explain: above-industry-
advantage explored in Bamey (1986a). average profits (as in Priem & Butler), a firm
Although these two firm-level approaches to de- improving its efficiency and effectiveness in
fining competitive advantage are different, they ways that competing firms are not (what might
can be related. For example, one reason a firm be called "strategic advantage," as in Barney,
may be able to generate an economic rent is that 1991), or economic rents (as in Barney, 1986a).
it is able to increase its efficiency and effective- Finally, Priem and Butler's argument that it is
ness in ways that other firms are not. If expecta- a resource's relative value and not its value and
tions about firm returns are based on firms that do rarity that determines the extent to which a re-
not possess this competitive advantage, this com- source can be a source of above-industry-
petitive advantage can generate an economic average profits, I think, confuses cause and ef-
rent. Also, sustainability is possible in both of fect. Clearly, the competitive actions two firms
these definitional approaches. According to the engage in might have very different conse-
first definition of a competitive advantage, a firm quences for the relative value of these firms. All
possesses a sustained competitive advantage resource-based logic suggests is that these dif-
when it is improving its efficiency and effective- ferences reflect differences in the underlying re-
ness in ways that competing firms are not and. sources of firms that enable them to engage in
when these other firms have ceased efforts to im- some competitive actions and not others. That
itate these activities. In the second definition a is, if the relative value of a firm's competitive
firm creates a sustained economic rent when it is actions are effects, then resource-based logic
able to consistently exceed the performance ex- indicates that attributes of firm resources—their
pectations of its owners, despite that these expec- value, rarity, imitability, and substitutability—
tations will be adjusted given a firm's prior per- are the causes.
formance levels. In this sense, a sustained
economic rent reflects the creative and entrepre-
neurial ability of firms to constantly discover how THE PRODUCT MARKET CRITIQUE
to generate value with their resources in ways Priem and Butler's next critique of the 1991
that outside owners cannot anticipate. article focuses on the underdeveloped role of
That these two definitions of competitive ad- product markets in the RBV I develop there. I
vantage can be related, however, does not mean have already acknowledged that the question of
that they will always be. A firm may possess a value is exogenous to the RBV developed in the
2001 Barney 49

1991 paper. Indeed, in that article I argue that a rial manipulation. However, the fact that the
complete model of strategic advantage would kinds of firm resources that are most likely to be
require the full integration of models of the com- sources of sustained strategic advantage are
petitive environment (i.e., product market mod- not amenable to manipulation does not imply
els) with models of firm resources (i.e., factor that resource-based logic has no managerial
market models). In fact, in their article Priem implications. This implies only that the nature of
and Butler present a very simple model of factor those managerial implications might be differ-
and product markets that partially accom- ent from those Priem and Butler would prefer
plishes this integration (see their Figure 1), but (Mosakowski, 1998).
observe that this simple model fails to recognize In fact, resource-based logic has several very
the role of "entrepreneurial insights concerning important practical implications for managers.
future demand shifts in product or factor mar- For example, this logic can be used to help man-
kets" and "first mover advantage [that] would agers in firms experiencing strategic disadvan-
result, because follow-on competitors could only tages to gain strategic parity through identify-
acquire . . . factors [of production] at higher cost" ing those valuable and rare resources their firm
(p. 31). currently does not possess and pointing out that
I, of course, agree with all these points. In fact, the value of these resources can be duplicated
I wrote an article in 1986 in which I made them either by imitation or substitution. In this sense,
(Barney, 1986a). In this sense, the 1991 article resource-based logic can be used to provide a
really needs to be understood within the context theoretical underpinning to the process of
of the 1986 paper. In the 1986 article I develop benchmarking in which many firms engage.
just the kind of factor market/product market Resource-based logic can also be used to help
model that Priem and Butler think is important. managers in firms that have the potential for
In the 1991 article I then focus only on the factor gaining sustained strategic advantages, but
market side of the equation—not because the where that potential is not being fully realized,
factor market/product market issues are not im- to more fully realize this potential. Resource-
portant, but because I had addressed them in a based logic can help managers more completely
previous article. understand the kinds of resources that can gen-
erate sustained strategic advantages, help them
use this understanding to evaluate the full
THE INAPPLICABILITY CRITIQUE range of resources their firm may possess, and
Priem and Butler also critique the RBV devel- then exploit those resources that have the po-
oped in the 1991 article by stating that it has tential to generate sustained strategic advan-
limited prescriptive ability. They cite four as- tage. It can help identify what the most critical
pects of RBV theory that limit its applicability: (1) resources controlled by a firm are and thereby
the attributes of resources that can generate increase the likelihood that they will be used to
strategic advantages and sustained strategic gain sustained strategic advantages.
advantages identified by the theory are not Managers can also use resource-based logic
amenable to managerial manipulation, (2) the to ensure that they nurture and maintain those
context within which the theory applies is not resources that are sources of a firm's current
specified, (3) the definition of resources is all strategic advantages. As suggested in the 1991
inclusive, and (4) the theory is static and not article, strategic advantages for firms are often
dynamic. I examine each of these alleged weak- based on bundles of related resources. Some of
nesses of the RBV developed in the 1991 article these resources are likely to be valuable but
below. either not rare, not imperfectly imitable, or not
nonsubstitutable. Others of these resources are
likely to have these competitively important at-
Managerial Manipulation of Resources tributes. Nurturing and protecting this second
Priem and Butler correctly observe that many class of resources are important, if a firm is to
of the attributes of resources that make them maintain its sustained strategic advantage.
likely to be sources of sustained strategic ad- For example, suppose a firm possesses a nur-
vantage—especially path dependence and so- turing organizational culture. In some market
cial complexity—are not amenable to manage- settings, such a culture may be valuable. If only
50 Academy of Management Review January

one competing firm possesses this culture, it is propriated by those who invented and marketed
rare, and, thus, perfect competition dynamics this rule.
around this culture are not likely to develop. Thus, although the resources identified by re-
Moreover, because an organizational culture de- source-based logic as being most likely to gen-
velops over long periods of time (the role of erate sustained strategic advantages frequently
history) and is socially complex, it is likely to be are not amenable to managerial manipulation,
costly to imitate. Finally, there are few obvious it certainly does not follow that there are no
close strategic substitutes for an organizational prescriptive implications of that resource-based
culture. In this situation it is likely that a firm's logic. Indeed, that resource-based logic is con-
culture will be a source of sustained strategic sistent with causal ambiguity and "rules for
advantage. However, even if it takes many de- riches" constraints on theory-derived prescrip-
cades for an organizational culture with these tion provides an important external validity
specific attributes to develop, that culture can check on this logic.^
be destroyed very quickly by senior managers in
a firm if they make decisions inconsistent with
that culture. Resource-based logic helps identify Context Nonspecification
this kind of culture as a potentially important Priem and Butler also suggest that prescrip-
source of sustained strategic advantage. Armed tion from the RBV developed in the 1991 article is
with this understanding, managers in an organ- limited because there is no specification of the
ization might be less inclined to make decisions context within which the RBV is valid. This, of
that have the effect of destroying the very re- course, is simply a different way of saying that
source that is generating a sustained strategic the determination of the value of a firm's re-
advantage for their firm. sources is exogenous to the RBV developed in
However, while it is clear that resource-based the 1991 article. This concern about the RBV has
logic can have very important managerial im- already been addressed and so will not be dis-
plications, this logic also indicates that there cussed further here.
are important prescriptive limits associated
with resource-based theories of strategic advan-
tage. First, to the extent that a firm's strategic All-inclusive Definition of Resources
advantage is based on causally ambiguous re- Priem and Butler argue that since the defini-
sources, managers in that firm cannot know, tion of firm resources, as articulated in Barney
with certainty, which of their resources actually (1991) and Wernerfelt (1984), includes almost any
generate that strategic advantage. This can sig- firm attribute, little prescriptive guidance can
nificantly limit prescriptions derived from the
theory.
Second, no theories of sustained strategic
^ Although their critique is not as developed as related
advantage can be used by managers in firms critiques about the managerial implications of the RBV,
having no potential for generating sustained Priem and Butler do observe that luck plays an important
strategic advantages fo create them. That is, role in determing a firm's strategic advantage or economic
resource-based logic cannot be used to create rents. They seem to believe that any firm advantages attrib-
utable to luck cannot have managerial implications.
sustained strategic advantages when the poten- Clearly, a firm's path-dependent and socially complex re-
tial for these advantages does not already exist. sources may be a manifestation of a firm's good luck. How-
Any theory that purports to be able to accom- ever, even if a firm is lucky, it must still understand how it is
plish this is proposing a "rule for riches," and, as lucky in order to take full advantage of its fortunate circum-
is well known, there can be no "rule for riches." stances. The RBV can be important in specifying when a firm
is and is not lucky. Also, acknowledging the role of luck in
If the application of a theory to a firm without determining a firm's competitive position is important in
any special resources can be used to create stra- guiding a firm's future investment strategies. If most of a
tegic advantages for that firm, then it could be firm's success can be attributed to its good luck, then a
used to create strategic advantages for any firm, reasonable prescription might be to extract the full value of
that good luck and then move on, reducing nonessential
and the actions undertaken by any one of these investments as much as possible. A firm also may be lucky
firms would not be a source of sustained strate- in developing causally ambiguous resources. As before, the
gic advantage. Even if a "rule for riches" created prescriptive implications of these kinds of resources are
economic value, that value would be fully ap- limited.
2001 Barney 51

be derived from the RBV. There is little doubt early RBV work is dynamic, citing Penrose (1959),
that the definition of resources presented in Wernerfelt (1984), and Dierickx and Cool (1989),
these two papers is, in fact, very inclusive. That but they fail to cite the 1991 article as an exam-
inclusiveness, however, actually enhances ple of dynamic RBV, even though later in their
rather than reduces the prescriptive implica- critique they recognize that "Barney's (1991) def-
tions of the RBV. inition of sustainable competitive advantage as
Resource-based theorists do not pretend to be occurring when competitors have ceased at-
able to generate a list of critical resources every tempts at imitation also lends itself to temporal
firm must possess in order to gain sustained stra- theory building" (p. 35).
tegic advantages. This is because, as has already Certainly, the quality of resource-based work
been suggested, the value of particular resources published subsequent to the 1991 article varies.
depends on the specific market context in which The very worst of it is clearly tautological—
they are applied. However, theorists do describe where those firm resources that can generate a
the attributes that these valuable resources must sustained strategic advantage are identified by
have if they are going to be sources of sustained their ability to generate a sustained strategic
strategic advantage for firms. After managers as- advantage. In general, static theoretical and
certain whether or not a particular resource is empirical work is more likely to be tautological
valuable, they can then use resource-based logic in this sense than dynamic work.
to anticipate strategic advantages that a resource I also agree with Priem and Butler that dy-
might create. Rather than limit its prescriptions to namic research—where the conditions under
specific resources that can be identified, a priori, which resources are developed or acquired in
managers can apply resource-based logic to any one period have implications for the strategic
resource whose value can be determined from the advantages of firms in subsequent periods—is
market context within which the resource is to be particularly important in studying strategic ad-
applied. vantages, and particularly important for study-
Indeed, this characteristic of resource-based ing resource-based theories of strategic advan-
theory undermines Priem and Butler's assertion tage. Empirically, in this research scholars need
that recent advances of resource-based theory, in- to adopt time series approaches similar to those
cluding Miller and Shamsie's (1996) analysis of used by Miller and Shamsie (1996), Makadok
resources in the motion picture industry and Con- (1999), and others. Theoretically, researchers
ner and Prahalad's (1996) and Kogut and Zander's need to adopt either an equilibrium or evolu-
(1996) efforts to develop a "knowledge-based" the- tionary approach to analysis.
ory of the firm, do not actually apply RBV logic. In In economics the traditional way to develop
fact, at least one contribution of RBV logic to these dynamic theory has been to engage in equilib-
research efforts has been to indicate those kinds rium analysis. By describing an economic sys-
of resources most likely to be sources of sustained tem's equilibrium and then comparing that
strategic advantage for firms. Given that RBV equilibrium to a system's actual state, theorists
logic was instrumental in pointing to the kinds of can predict how that economic system will
variables that should be included in this recent change over time. Thus, while equilibrium anal-
work (different kinds of assets in Miller and Sham- ysis has often been criticized as static, in reality,
sie and tacit knowledge in Conner and Prahalad theorists focus on equilibrium arguments in or-
and Kogut and Zander), it is difficult to understand der to more fully understand the dynamics of
what Priem and Butler mean when they say that systems that are not in equilibrium. In this con-
this work makes significant contributions "with- text, observations that most economic systems
out the RBV itself making an elemental contribu- rarely reach equilibrium conditions miss the
tion" (p. 33). point of equilibrium analysis.
More recently, an alternative to equilibrium
analysis, rooted in what has become known as
Static Resource-Based Logic evolutionary economics, has been proposed
Finally, Priem and Butler suggest that RBV (Nelson & Winter, 1982). Instead of focusing on
prescription is limited because much of the work an economic system's equilibrium and compar-
subsequent to the 1991 article is static rather ing this equilibrium to a system's current state,
than dynamic in character. They do admit that system dynamics are studied by comparing the
52 Academy of Management Review January

state of a system at one time with the state of develop a more complete theory of resource
that system at a later time. One of the advan- value, too many authors have simply assumed
tages of this evolutionary approach is that it is away this question and, thus, have failed to help
possible to study the dynamics of systems with develop a more complete theory of firm advan-
equilibria that can only be specified by adopt- tages. Fully parameterizing the rarity of firm
ing heroic (and often unrealistic) assumptions. resources has actually received less attention
Both of these approaches to dynamic analysis subsequent to the 1991 article than fully param-
have been applied in a resource-based context. eterizing the value of those resources.
For example, Lippman and Rumelt (1982), Bar- Priem and Butler's critique also reminds us of
ney (1986a), and Makadok and Barney (in press) the logical limits of prescriptions derived from
all apply equilibrium analysis to studying sus- theories of sustained firm advantage. These the-
tained strategic advantages from a resource- ories often have important managerial implica-
based perspective. Barnett et al. (1994), Levinthal tions, but those implications are limited by the
and Myatt (1994), Foss, Knudsen, and Montgom- "rules for riches" paradox. Efforts to develop the-
ery (1995), Hunt (1997), and Teece, Pisano, and ories that, when applied, will always generate
Shuen (1997) adopt evolutionary approaches to sustained strategic advantages clearly are
studying sustained strategic advantages from a foolish.
resource-based perspective.
Priem and Butler remind us as well that a
Whether it is through equilibrium or evolu- comprehensive list of potential sources of sus-
tionary analysis, Priem and Butler are correct to tained strategic advantage for firms cannot be
emphasize the importance of dynamic analysis
of sustained strategic advantage, for it is only derived from resource-based logic. This logic,
through this kind of analysis that the full impli- however, does make it possible to specify the
cations of resource-based logic for the sustained attributes that can lead some of these resources
strategic advantages of firms can be under- to be sources of sustained strategic advantage.
stood. This type of theory can generate both testable
empirical assertions and concrete managerial
prescriptions, even though it cannot generate a
DISCUSSION comprehensive list of potential sources of sus-
As indicated earlier, Priem and Butler's criti- tained strategic advantage.
cisms of the 1991 article are unfounded. Some of Finally, Priem and Butler remind us of the
their criticisms fail when examined in light of important role dynamic analysis plays in re-
the totality of the argument presented in the source-based logic. In order to avoid tautology
1991 paper. Some of their criticisms focus on problems, authors of empirical resource-based
underdeveloped aspects of the 1991 article, even work must usually adopt time series or some
though in the article there is an acknowledg- other form of dynamic analysis. Theoretically,
ment of the importance of these aspects of the either equilibrium or evolutionary analysis can
argument and even suggestions of ways they be applied to resource-based logic to under-
can be developed. These suggestions have stand the implications of competition for re-
turned out to be fruitful approaches in further sources in one time period for competition
developing the RBV. Finally, some of Priem and among firms in another.
Butler's criticisms focus on subsequent work to However, although Priem and Butler have re-
the 1991 article and therefore do not constitute minded us of some important attributes of the
criticisms of the 1991 paper per se. RBV, they fail to raise some of the very important
Yet, although Priem and Butler's primary crit- questions in the field of strategic management
icisms of the 1991 article are unfounded, their that are fully addressed neither in the 1991 arti-
observations remind us of important attributes cle nor in subsequent resource-based work.
of the RBV—attributes that many applications of These questions include: (1) Where do a firm's
this logic have not fully appreciated. For exam- strategic alternatives come from? (2) How are
ple, Priem and Butler remind us that fhe value of the rents created through strategies appropri-
a firm's resources must be understood in the ated? and (3) How are these strategies to be
specific market context within which a firm is implemented? I discuss each of these questions
operating. While some authors have begun to briefly below.
2001 Barney 53

Strategic Alternatives Rent Appropriation


Resource-based theory, as developed in and As has already been suggested, resource-
subsequent to the 1991 article, includes a very based theory can be used to evaluate the com-
simple view about how resources are connected petitive potential of the different strategic alter-
to the strategies a firm pursues. It is almost as natives firms face. However, this logic, a s
though once a firm becomes aware of the valu- developed in the 1991 article and as it has
able, rare, costly to imitate, and nonsubstitut- evolved since, does not address how the eco-
able resources it controls, the actions the firm nomic rents a strategy might create are appro-
should take to exploit these resources will be priated by a firm's stakeholders. It might be the
self-evident. That certainly may be true some of case, for example, that implementing a particu-
lar strategy generates real economic rents for a
the time. For example, if a firm possesses valu-
firm but that those rents are fully appropriated
able, rare, costly to imitate, and nonsubstitut-
by a firm's employees, its customers, or even its
able economies of scale, learning curve econo-
suppliers.
mies, access to low-cost factors of production,
Some scholars have begun to examine this
and technological resources, it seems clear that
rent appropriation process (e.g., Coff, 1999).
the firm should pursue a cost leadership strat-
Their work focuses on the relative bargaining
egy (Barney, 1997: Chapter 6).
power of a firm's stakeholders and the role of
However, it may often be the case that the link team production (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972) in
between resources and the strategies a firm determining how rents are distributed among a
should pursue will not be so obvious. For exam- firm's stakeholders. While this work is promis-
ple, sometimes it might happen that a firm's ing, it still does not constitute a complete theory
resources will be consistent with several differ- of the rent appropriation process. For example,
ent strategies, all with the ability to create the how do different stakeholders come to enjoy dif-
same level of competitive advantage. In this ferent bargaining positions? Why isn't the value
situation, how should a firm decide which of of a stakeholder's bargaining position reflected
these several different strategies it should pur- in the cost of the investments necessary to cre-
sue? ate that position? Under what conditions will
Even more important, there may be times team production reduce the ability of employees
when choosing a strategy consistent with the to appropriate rents created by a firm's strate-
resources a firm controls is a creative and even gies? Why would employees agree to employ-
entrepreneurial act. This might occur, for exam- ment conditions that significantly reduce their
ple, when a firm possesses valuable, rare, costly ability to appropriate the rents created when a
to imitate, and nonsubstitutable resources firm implements its strategies?
broadly seen as consistent with one strategy,
and the firm is able to conceive of and imple-
ment a very different strategy that exploits these Strategy Implementation
same resources, but in very different ways. Finally, in the 1991 article, issues of strategy
To the extent that developing strategic alter- implementation do not receive sufficient atten-
natives a firm can use to exploit the resources it tion. As a theoretical convenience, I adopted the
controls is a creative and entrepreneurial pro- simple view that once a firm understands how to
cess, resource-based models of strategic advan- use its resources to implement strategies that
tage may need to be augmented by theories of can be sources of sustained strategic advan-
the creative and entrepreneurial process. These tage, implementation follows, almost automati-
theories could then be applied to understand the cally. This view is inconsistent both with agency
strategic alternatives a firm might be able to theory arguments taken from organizational
pursue, given the resources it controls. While I economics (Jensen & Meckling, 1976) and a huge
am currently unaware of such a highly devel- body of organizational behavior literature on
oped theory, these observations suggest a very motivation, cooperation, and managerial deci-
close relationship between theories of strategic sion making.
advantage and theories of creativity and entre- In general, there have been two approaches to
preneurship. addressing strategy implementation issues in
54 Academy of Management Review January

the context of resource-based theory. First, some believe that the equilibrium approach to under-
have suggested that the ability to implement standing sustained strategic advantage in the
strategies is, itself, a resource that can be a 1991 paper is very powerful. I also believe the
source of sustained strategic advantage. Work 1991 article was helpful in reintroducing firm
on the role of "cooperative capabilities" in im- attributes into strategic management research
plementing strategic alliance strategies (e.g., after a period in which work focused almost
Hansen, Hoskisson, & Barney, 2000) and the im- exclusively on industry determinants of firm
pact of "trustworthiness" on exchange opportu- performance. I have also been very gratified to
nities for a firm (Barney & Hansen, 1994) is con- see at least portions of the 1991 argument being
sistent with this first approach. applied in nonstrategic management disci-
Second, it has also been suggested that im- plines (e.g., human resource management, man-
plementation depends on resources that are not agement information systems, and marketing)
themselves sources of sustained advantage but, and to strategic management questions (e.g.,
rather, are strategic complements to the other knowledge-based theories of competitive ad-
valuable, rare, costly to imitate, and nonsubsti- vantage, resource-based theories of the firm, re-
tutable resources controlled by a firm (Barney, source-based theories of innovation, and re-
1995, 1997). source-based theories of interfirm cooperation)
Which of these approaches ultimately is most in ways I did not anticipate. ~
fruitful in bringing the analysis of strategy im- That said, I think I would make some changes
plementation into resource-based logic is an to the article if I wrote it today, and many of
open question. It is clear, however, that addi- those changes involve the issues that Priem and
tional work is required. Butler focus on. For example, I think I would
spend more time on the question of value and
CONCLUSION how to parameterize it and how value is related
to market structure. I would adopt a simpler
There is little doubt that Priem and Butler definition of resources (i.e., resources are the
have provided an important service to the field tangible and intangible assets a firm uses to
of strategic management in general and to re- choose and implement its strategies). I would
source-based theorists in particular. Throughout link the argument much more closely to other
their article they highlight those aspects of re- economic traditions, including Ricardian
source-based theory that require further devel- (Ricardo, 1817) economics and evolutionary eco-
opment and refinement and end up calling for nomics. And I would explicitly raise the issue of
increased efforts to understand its theoretical tautology, suggest how this issue could be
and empirical implications. In this sense, Priem avoided, and strongly argue for the importance
and Butler end up answering the question posed of temporal empirical tests of the argument.
in the title of their own paper—"Is the resource-
based 'view' a useful perspective for strategic
management research?"—with a resounding yes. REFERENCES
In addition, Priem and Butler have given me a Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. 1972. Production, information
rare opportunity to go back and think about a costs, and economic organization. American Economic
paper I wrote over a decade ago. In this process Review, 62: 777-795.
I have asked myself the question "Would I write Bacharach, S. B. 1989. Organizational theories: Some criteria
the same paper today?" Certainly, some aspects for evaluation. Academy ol Management Review, 14:
496-515.
of the 1991 article have, I think, stood the test of
time. The notions of resource heterogeneity and Bain, J. S. 1956. Barriers to new competition. Cambridge, MA:
resource immobility remain, I think, important Harvard University Press.
contributions, as do the discussions of rarity, Barnett, W. P., Greve, H. R., & Park, D. Y. 1994. An evolution-
imitability, and substitutability.'' While still con- ary model of organizational performance. Strategic
Management Journal, 15(Winter Special Issue): 11-28.
troversial among many strategy researchers, I
ogeneously distributed and may be imperfectly mobile. The
' Some observers have concluded that, taken to its ex- extent to which these conditions actually exist is an empir-
treme, the RBV indicates that all firms are unique. However, ical question. Certainly, some resources may not be rare and
the 1991 article only suggests that resources may be heter- others may not be costly to imitate.
2001 Bamey 55

Barney, J. B. 1986a. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, Hunt, S. D. 2000. A general theory of competition: Resources,
luck and business strategy. Managemenf Science, 32: competences, productivity, and economic growth. Thou-
1512-1514. sand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Barney, J. B. 1986b. Organizational culture: Can it be a source Jensen, M. C, & Meckling, W. H. 1976. Theory of the firm:
of sustained competitive advantage? Academy of Man- Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership
agement Review, 11: 656-665. structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-360.
Barney, J. B. 1988. Returns to bidding firms in mergers and Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1996. What firms do? Coordination,
acquisitions: Reconsidering the relatedness hypothesis. identity, and leaming. Organizational Science, 7: 502-518.
Strategic Management Journal, 9: 71-78. Leonard-Barton, D. 1992. Core capabilities and core rigidi-
Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive ties: A paradox in managing new product development.
advantage. Journal of Management, 17: 99-120. Strategic Management/ournai, 13: 111-125.
Barney, J. B. 1995. Looking inside for competitive advantage. Levinthal, D., & Myatt, J. 1994. Co-evolution of capabilities
Academy of Management Executive, 9(4): 49-61. and industry: The evolution of mutual fund processing.
Strategic Management Journal, 15(Special Issue): 45-62.
Barney, J. B. 1997. Gaining and sustaining compefifive ad-
vantages. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Lippman, S., & Rumelt, R. 1982. Uncertain imitability: An
analysis of interfirm differences in efficiency under
Barney, J. B., & Hansen, M. H. 1994. Trustworthiness as a
competition. Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 418-438.
source of competitive advantage. Strategic Manage-
ment Journal, 15(Winter Special Issue): 175-190. Makadok, R. 1998. Can first-mover and early-mover advan-
tages be sustained in an industry with low barriers to
Brush, T. H., & Artz, K. W. 1999. Toward a contingent resource-
entry/imitation? Strategic Management Journal, 19: 683-
based theory: The impact of information asymmetry on
696.
the value of capabilities in veterinary medicine. Strate-
gic Management Journal, 20: 223-250. Makadok, R. 1999. Interfirm differences in scale economies
Caves, R. E., & Porter, M. E. 1977. From entry barriers to and the evolution of market shares. Strategic Manage-
mobility barriers: Conjectural decisions and contrived ment Journal, 20: 935-952.
deterrence to new competition. Quarterly Journal of Eco- Makadok, R., & Barney, J. B. In press. Information as a pre-
nomics, 91: 241-262. condition for strategy formulation: Toward a theory of
Coff, R. 1999. When competitive advantage doesn't lead to strategic information acquisition and competitor intelli-
performance: Resource-based theory and stakeholder gence. Management Science.
bargaining power. Organization Science.* 10: 119-133. McWilliams, A., & Smart, D. L. 1995. The resource-based view
of the firm: Does it go far enough in shedding the as-
Conner, K. R. 1991. A historical comparison of resource-
sumptions of the S-C-P paradigm? /ournai of Manage-
based theory and five schools of thought within indus-
trial organization economics: Do we have a new theory ment Inquiry, 4: 309-316.
of the firm? /ournaJ of Management, 17: 121-154. Miller, D., & Shamsie, J. 1996. The resource-based view of the
Conner, K. R., & Prahalad, C. K. 1996. A resource-based the- firm in two environments: The Hollywood film studios
ory of the firm: Knowledge versus opportunism. Organi- from 1936-1965. Academy of Management Journal, 39:
zational Science, 7: 477-501. 519-543.
Mosakowski, E. 1998. Managerial prescriptions under the
Dierickx, 1., & Cool, K. 1989. Asset stock accumulation and
resource-based view of strategy: The example of moti-
sustainability of competitive advantage. Management
vational techniques. Strategic Management Journal, 19:
Science, 35: 1504-1511.
1169-1182.
Foss, N., Knudsen, S., & Montgomery, C. A. (Eds.). 1995.
Resource-based and evoiutionaiy theories of the firm: Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of eco-
Towards a synthesis. Boston: Kluwer. nomic change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Har-
vard University Press.
Godfrey, P. C, & Hill, C. W. L. 1995. The problem of unob-
servables in strategic management research. Strategic Penrose, E. T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New
Management Journal, 16: 519-533. York: Wiley.
Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. 1998. Testing altemative theories of the
Hansen, M. H., Hoskisson, R. E., & Barney, J. B. 2000. Resolving
firm: Transaction cost, knowledge-based and measure-
the opportunism minimization-opportunity maximiza-
ment explanations for make-or-buy decisions in informa-
tion paradox. Working paper. Fisher College of Busi-
tion services. Strategic Management Journal, 19: 853-877.
ness, The Ohio State University, Columbus.
Henderson, R., & Cockburn, I. 1994. Measuring competence?: Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive strategy. New York: Free Press.
Exploring firm effects in pharmaceutical research. Stra- Ricardo, D. 1817. Principles of political economy and taxa-
tegic Management Journal, 15(Special Issue): 63-84. tion. London: Murray.
Hunt, S. D. 1997. Resource-advantage theory: An evolution- Riordan, M., & Williamson, O. 1985. Asset specificity and
ary theory of competitive firm behavior? Journal of Eco- economic organization. International Journal of Indus-
nomic Issues, 1: 59-77. trial Organization, 3: 365-378.
56 Academy of Management Review January

Scherer, F. M. 1980. Industrial market structure and economic Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Stra-
performance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. ' tegic Management Journal, 5: 171-180.
Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1990. Strategy, complexity and economic Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis
rent. Management Science, 3: 1178-1192. and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.
Teece, D., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. 1997. Dynamic capabilities Williamson, O. E. 1999. Strategy research: Governance and
and strategic management. SJrafegicManagemenf/our- competence perspectives. Strategic Management Jour-
nal, 18: 509-533. nal, 20: 1087-1108.

Jay B. Barney holds the Bank One Chair for Excellence in Corporate Strategy at the
Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University. He received his Ph.D. at Yale
University and has previously served on the faculties at UCLA and Texas A&M. His
research interests focus on the resource-based view of the firm and organizational
economics.

Вам также может понравиться